105
Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved. Capital Structure Policy Chapter 15

M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

  • Upload
    jiwonp

  • View
    207

  • Download
    10

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Citation preview

Page 1: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.

Capital Structure Policy

Chapter 15

Page 2: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-2

Slide Contents

• Learning Objectives• Principles Used in This Chapter

1.A Glance at Capital Structure Choices in Practice2.Capital Structure Theory3.Why Do Capital Structures Differ Across Industries?4.Making Financing Decisions

• Key Terms

Page 3: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-3

Learning Objectives

1. Describe a firm’s capital structure.2. Explain why firms have different capital

structures and how capital structure influences a firm’s weighted average cost of capital.

3. Use the basic tools of financial analysis to analyze a firm’s financing decision.

Page 4: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-4

Principles Used in This Chapter

• Principle 2: There is a Risk-Return Tradeoff.– Managers are often tempted to take on more

debt as it can increase the rate of return earned on the stockholders’ investment in the firm. However, this higher return comes with a cost – the higher use of debt financing makes the firm’s stock riskier, which increases the required rate of return on stock. In addition, it increases the default risk of the firm.

Page 5: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-5

Principles Used in This Chapter (cont.)

• Principle 3: Cash Flows Are the Source of Value.

– Capital structure choice impacts the cash flows and thus affects the value of the firm.

Page 6: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.

15.1 A Glance at Capital Structure Choices in Practice

Page 7: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-7

A Glance at Capital Structure Choices in Practice

• The primary objective of capital structure management is to maximize the value of the shareholders’ equity.

• The resulting financing mix that maximizes shareholder value is called the optimal capital structure.

Page 8: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-8

Defining the Firm’s Capital Structure

• A firm’s capital structure consists of owner’s equity and its interest bearing debt, including short-term bank loans.

• The combination of firm’s capital structure plus the firm’s non-interest bearing liabilities such as accounts payable is called the firm’s financial structure.

Page 9: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-9

Defining the Firm’s Capital Structure (cont.)

• A firm’s financial structure is often described by the debt ratio.

Page 10: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-10

Defining the Firm’s Capital Structure (cont.)

• The Debt to Value ratio is commonly used to describe a firm’s capital structure.

• This ratio includes only interest bearing debt and uses current market values rather than book values.

Page 11: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-11

Defining the Firm’s Capital Structure (cont.)

• The total book value of interest bearing debt includes:– Short-term notes payable (e.g., bank loans),– Current portion of long-term debt, and– Long-term debt.

Page 12: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-12

Defining the Firm’s Capital Structure (cont.)

• Table 15-1 shows that the book value based debt ratio is always higher than the market value based debt to value ratio because:– Debt ratio is based on book value and book

value of equity is always lower than its market value.

– Debt to value ratio excludes non-interest bearing debt in the numerator resulting in a lower value.

Page 13: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-13

Page 14: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-14

Defining the Firm’s Capital Structure (cont.)

• Table 15-1 also reports the Times Interest Earned Ratio, which measures the firm’s ability to pay the interest on its debt out of operating earnings.

See Table 15-3 on the next slide

Page 15: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-15

Defining the Firm’s Capital Structure (cont.)

Page 16: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-16

Financial Leverage

• The term financial leverage is often used to describe a firm’s capital structure. Leverage allows the firm to increase the potential return to its shareholders.

• For example, if the firm is earning 17% on its investments and paying only 8% on borrowed money, the 9% differential goes to the firm’s owners. This is known as favorable financial leverage.

Page 17: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-17

Financial Leverage (cont.)

• However, if the firm earns only 6% on its investments and must pay 8% then the 2% differential must come out of the owner’s share and they suffer unfavorable financial leverage.

• So leverage is beneficial if the rate of return exceeds the borrowing cost.

Page 18: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-18

How Do Firms in Different Industries Finance Their Assets?

• Figure 15-1 shows the variations in debt to value ratios across industries.

• The average debt to value ratio is 42% with a wide variation across industries.

Page 19: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-19

Page 20: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.

15.2 Capital Structure Theory

Page 21: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-21

Capital Structure Theory

• We begin with capital structure irrelevance theory that is based on unrealistic assumptions and then relax these assumptions to examine how they influence a firm’s incentive to use debt and equity financing.

Page 22: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-22

A First Look at the Modigliani and Miller Capital Structure Theorem

• Modigliani and Miller showed that, under idealistic conditions, it does not matter whether a firm uses no debt, a little debt or a lot of debt in its capital structure. The theory relies on two basic assumptions:1. The cash flows that a firm generates are not

affected by how the firm is financed.2. Financial markets are perfect.

Page 23: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-23

A First Look at the Modigliani and Miller Capital Structure Theorem (cont.)

• Figure 15-2 illustrates assumption 1.

Page 24: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-24

Page 25: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-25

A First Look at the Modigliani and Miller Capital Structure Theorem (cont.)

• Assumption 2 of perfect market implies that the packaging of cash flows, that is whether they are distributed to investors as dividends or interest payments, is not important.

Page 26: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-26

Yogi Berra and the M&M Capital Structure Theory

• The number of pieces that a pizza is cut into doesn’t affect the total amount that is eaten.

• The size of the pizza pie (the value of the firm, which is determined by the cash flows to both creditors and owners) does not depend on the size of the slices (the portions of firm’s cash flow that is distributed to creditors or stockholders and consequently how much of the firm is financed with debt and equity).

Page 27: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-27

Capital Structure, the Cost of Equity, and the Weighted Average Cost of Capital

• When there are no taxes, the firm’s weighted average cost of capital is also unaffected by its capital structure.

Page 28: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-28

Capital Structure, the Cost of Equity, and the Weighted Average Cost of Capital (cont.)

• Assume, we are valuing a firm whose cash flows are a level perpetuity. The value of the firms is then represented by the following equation.

Page 29: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-29

Capital Structure, the Cost of Equity, and the Weighted Average Cost of Capital (cont.)

• Since firm value and firm cash flows are unaffected by the capital structure, the firm’s weighted average cost of capital is also unaffected.

Page 30: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-30

Capital Structure, the Cost of Equity, and the Weighted Average Cost of Capital (cont.)

• The cost of equity will increase with the debt to equity ratio (D/E).

• However, because there is less weight on the more expensive equity, the firm’s WACC (equation 15-5) does not change and is always equal to the cost of capital of an unlevered firm.

Page 31: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-31

Capital Structure, the Cost of Equity, and the Weighted Average Cost of Capital (cont.)

• Example 15.1

• JNK can borrow money at 9% and its cost of capital if it uses no financial leverage is 11%. It has a debt-to-equity ratio of 1.0, the cost of debt is 8%, and weighted average cost of capital is 10%. What is the cost of equity for JNK?

Page 32: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-32

Capital Structure, the Cost of Equity, and the Weighted Average Cost of Capital (cont.)

• Cost of equity = .11 + (.11-.08) × 1.0 = .14 or 14%

Page 33: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-33Figure 15.3 (Cont.)

Page 34: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-34

Figure 15.3

Page 35: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-35

Why Capital Structure Matters in Reality?

• In reality, financial managers care a great deal about how their firms are financed. Indeed, there can be negative consequences for firms that select an inappropriate capital structure, which means that, in reality, at least one of the two M&M assumptions is violated.

Page 36: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-36

Violation of Assumption 2

• Transaction costs can be important and because of these costs, the rate at which investors can borrow may differ from the rate at which firms can borrow.

• When this is the case, firm values may depend on how they are financed because individuals cannot substitute their individual borrowings for corporate borrowings to achieve a desired level of financial leverage.

Page 37: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-37

Violation of Assumption 1

• There are three reasons why capital structure affects the total cash flows available to its debt and equity holders:1. Interest is a tax-deductible expense, while

dividends are not. Thus, after taxes, firms have more money to distribute to their debt and equity holders if they use more debt financing.

Page 38: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-38

Violation of Assumption 1 (cont.)

2. Debt financing creates a fixed legal obligation. If the firm defaults on its payments, the creditors can force the firm into bankruptcy and the firm will incur the added cost that this process entails.

3. The threat of bankruptcy can influence the behavior of a firm’s executives as well as its employees and customers.

Page 39: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-39

Corporate Taxes and Capital Structure

• Since interest payments are tax deductible, the after-tax cash flows will be higher if the firm’s capital structure includes more debt.

• An illustration follows.

Page 40: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-40

Corporate Taxes and Capital Structure (cont.)

• Consider two firms identical in every respect except for their capital structure. – Firm A has no debt and has total equity

financing of $2,000.– Firm B has borrowed $1,000 on which it pays

5% interest and raised the remaining $1,000 with equity.

– Each firm has operating income of $200,000.– The corporate tax rate is 25%.

Page 41: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-41

Corporate Taxes and Capital Structure (cont.)

Firm A Firm B

Operating Income $200 $200

Less: Interest Expense

- -$50

EBT $200 $150

Less : Taxes -$50 -37.50

Net Income $150 $112.50

Page 42: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-42

Corporate Taxes and Capital Structure (cont.)

• If we assume that both firms payout 100% of earnings in common stock dividends, we get the following:

Firm A Firm B

Equity Dividends $150 $112.50

Interest Payments - $50.00

Total Distributions (to stockholders and bondholders)

$150.00 $162.50

Page 43: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-43

Corporate Taxes and Capital Structure (cont.)

• The $12.50 additional distribution to Firm B can be traced to the tax benefits of interest payments, 0.25 ×$50 = $12.50. This is referred to as interest tax savings.

• These tax savings add value to the firm and provide an incentive to the firm to include more debt in the capital structure.

Page 44: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-44

Corporate Taxes and Capital Structure (cont.)

• If the firm saves $12.50 in taxes every year, then the present value of these tax savings is the extra value added by using debt financing.

Page 45: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-45

Corporate Taxes and Capital Structure (cont.)

Page 46: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-46

Corporate Taxes and the WACC

• The tax deductibility of interest expense causes the firm’s weighted average cost of capital to decline as it includes more debt in the capital structure.

Page 47: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-47

Corporate Taxes and the WACC (cont.)

• Example 15.2 • JNK’s cost of capital if it uses no financial

leverage is 11%. It has a debt equity ratio of 1.0, the cost of debt is 8% before taxes, and the tax rate is 40%. What will be the cost of equity and weighted average cost of capital if the debt to equity ratio is 1 (i.e. 50% debt and 50% equity).

Page 48: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-48

Corporate Taxes and the WACC (cont.)

Cost of equity =.11 + (.11-.08)(1)(1-.40) = .128 or 12.8%

Page 49: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-49

Corporate Taxes and the WACC (cont.)

kWACC = .08(1-.40) × .50 + .128 × .50

kWACC = .088 or 8.8%

Page 50: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-50

Corporate Taxes and the WACC (cont.)

• Figure 15-4 shows that as debt to equity ratio rises, the WACC declines while the cost of equity increases.

• Thus the tax benefit of interest expense favors use of debt over equity.

Page 51: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-51

Figure 15.4 (Cont.)

Page 52: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-52

Figure 15.4

Page 53: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-53

Bankruptcy and Financial Distress Costs

• However, a firm cannot keep on increasing debt because if the firm’s debt obligations exceed it’s ability to generate cash, it will be forced into bankruptcy and incur financial distress costs.

• Furthermore, debt financing also severely limits financial manager’s flexibility to raise additional funds.

Page 54: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-54

Page 55: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-55

The Tradeoff Theory and the Optimal Capital Structure

• Thus two factors can have material impact on the role of capital structure in determining firm value and firms must tradeoff the pluses and minuses of both these factors:– Interest expense is tax deductible.– Debt makes it more likely that firms will

experience financial distress costs.

Page 56: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-56

Page 57: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-57

Capital Structure Decisions and Agency Costs

• It is argued that debt financing can help reduce agency costs.

• For example, debt financing by creating fixed dollar obligations will reduce the firm’s discretionary control over cash and thus reduce wasteful spending.

Page 58: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-58

Making Financing Choices When Managers are Better Informed than Shareholders

• When firms issue new shares, it is perceived that the firm’s stock is overpriced and accordingly share price generally falls. This provides an added incentive for firms to prefer debt.

Page 59: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-59

Making Financing Choices When Managers are Better Informed than Shareholders (cont.)

• Stewart Myers suggested that because of the information issues that arise when firms issue equity, firms tend to adhere to the following pecking order when they raise capital:– Internal sources of financing– Marketable securities– Debt – Hybrid securities– Equity

Page 60: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-60

Managerial Implications

1. Higher levels of debt can benefit the firm due to tax savings and potential to reduce agency costs.

2. Higher levels of debt increase the probability of financial distress costs and offset tax and agency cost benefits of debt.

Page 61: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-61

Page 62: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.

15.3 Why Do Capital Structures Differ Across Industries?

Page 63: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-63

Why Do Capital Structures Differ Across Industries?

• Firms in some industries (such as utilities) tend to generate relatively more taxable income and can benefit more from tax savings on debt.

• Financial distress can be fatal for some companies (like computer and software firms like Apple) as consumers will be very reluctant to buy the product if there is a possibility of bankruptcy. Thus such firms will tend to have lower levels of debt.

Page 64: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.

15.4 Making Financing Decisions

Page 65: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-65

Benchmarking the Firm’s Capital Structure

• By benchmarking a firm’s capital structure, we compare the firm’s current and proposed capital structures to a set of firms that are considered to be in similar lines of business and consequently subject to the same types of risks.

• Table 15-4 provides a simple template for benchmarking.

Page 66: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-66

Page 67: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-67

Checkpoint 15.1

Benchmarking a Financing Decision

Sister Sarah’s Homemade Pies, Inc. is a rapidly growing manufacturer and distributor of frozen pastries and desserts. The company was founded in 1992 by Sarah Goodnight, who used old family recipes and southern home-style cooking to prepare a wide variety of desserts. By 2010 the business had grown to the point that it was expected to produce $50 million in revenues based on total assets of $29.8 million. The firm has outgrown its manufacturing facility and is planning to invest $10 million in a new, modern plant. With the added capacity of the new plant, the firm expects to increase its revenues from $50 million to $60 million per year. In addition, the 20% increase in revenues will be accompanied by a 20% increase in cost of goods sold and operating expenses. The new equipment will be depreciated over a 10-year life and result in $1 million in additional depreciation expense per year, assume a 30% tax rate.

Page 68: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-68

Checkpoint 15.1

Two financing alternatives are being considered. The first involves issuing 1.342 million shares of common stock, and the second involves borrowing the entire $10 million ($2 million in additional short-term debt and $8 million in long-term debt). The firm currently owes $6 million in combined short- and long-term debt on which it pays 8% interest and pays $1.2 million a year in principal payments. If the debt option is selected then the firm will pay 8% interest on the added $10 million in shortplus long-term debt and in addition will pay $2 million per year in principal on the new debt until the note is repaid.

What will the effect be on Sister Sarah’s Homemade Pies, Inc.’s financial ratios if the firm uses the equity alternative? What about the debt alternative?

Page 69: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-69

Checkpoint 15.1

Page 70: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-70

Checkpoint 15.1

Page 71: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-71

Checkpoint 15.1

Page 72: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-72

Checkpoint 15.1: Check Yourself

• Under the debt financing alternative, what will Sister Sarah’s financial ratios look like in just two years after the firm has repaid $4 million of the loan (assuming nothing else changes)?

Page 73: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-73

Step 1: Picture the Problem

• The pro-forma balance sheet after $4 million in long-term debt has been paid off will change and is given on the next slide.

Page 74: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-74

Step 1: Picture the Problem (cont.)

Balance Sheet Before After $4 million paid off

Accounts Payable $4,500,000 $4,500,000

Short-term Debt $3,200,000 $3,200,000

Total Current Liabilities

$7,700,000 $7,700,000

Long-term Debt $12,800,000 $8,800,000

Total Liabilities $20,500,000 $16,500,000

Common Equity $19,300,000 $19,300,000

Total Liabilities and Equity

$39,800,000 $35,800,000

Page 75: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-75

Step 1: Picture the Problem (cont.)Income Statement Pro formas Adjusted for New Financing

2010 Equity Debt

Revenues $50,000,000 $60,000,000 $60,000,000

Cost of Goods Sold (25,000,000) (30,000,000) (30,000,000)

Gross Profit $25,000,000 $30,000,000 $30,000,000

Operating Expenses (10,000,000) (12,000,000) (12,000,000)

Depreciation Expenses (2,000,000) (3,000,000) (3,000,000)

EBIT $13,000,000 $15,000,000 $15,000,000

Interest Expense (480,000) (480,000) (960,000)

Earnings before Taxes $12,520,000 $14,520,000 $14,040,000

Taxes (3,756,000) (4,356,000) (4,212,000)

Net Income $8,764,000 $10,164,000 $9,828,000

Earnings per Share $1.461 $1.603 $1.638

Return on Equity 45.4% 34.7% 50.9%

Sinking Fund Payment 1,200,000 1,200,000 2,400,000

Page 76: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-76

Step 1: Picture the Problem (cont.)

• The total interest expense on the income statement will reduce as $4 million of debt has been paid off.

• This will reduce the interest expense by $4,000,000 × .08 = $320,000

• New interest expense = $1,280,000 – $320,000 = $960,000

Page 77: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-77

Step 2: Decide on a Solution Strategy

• Table 15-4 can be used to solve the four key financial leverage ratios.

Page 78: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-78

Step 2: Decide on a Solution Strategy

Page 79: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-79

Step 3: Solve• Given:

2010 Equity Financing Debt Financing

Borrowing Rate 8.0% 8.0% 8.0%

Shares of Common Stock 6,000,000 6,342,309 6,000,000

Tax Rate 30.0% 30.0% 30.0%

Revenues $50,000,000 $60,000,000 $60,000,000

Cost of Goods Sold/Sales 50.0% 50.0% 50.0%

Operating Expenses/Sales 20.0% 20.0% 20.0%

Depreciation Expense $2,000,000 $3,000,000 $3,000,000

New Borrowing — $10,000,000

New Equity $10,000,000 —

Price Earnings Ratio 20 20 20

Sinking Fund as % of Debt 20% 20% 20%

Cost of Capital Equipment 10,000,000.00 10,000,000.00

Depreciable Life 10 10

Page 80: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-80

Step 3: Solve (cont.)

($7.7m + $8.8m)/$35.8m

($3.2m+$8.8m)/$35.8m

$15m/$0.96m

$15m+$.96m$.96m+$2.4m/.7

Ratio

Ratio with Current

Debt Financing

Ratios after 2-years with $4 million

debt paid off

Debt Ratio 51.5% 46.09%

Interest Bearing Debt Ratio

40.020% 33.52%

Times Interest Earned Ratio

11.72 15.625

EBITDA Coverage Ratio

3.08 4.10

Page 81: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-81

Step 4: Analyze

• We observe in step 3 that all ratios drop and become stronger, after $4 million debt is paid off.

• Comparing it to the benchmark ratios given, we can conclude that the debt alternative is still more aggressive compared to industry norms.

Page 82: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-82

Step 4: Analyze (cont.)

• The firm’s management will have to analyze and determine whether the firm can support a higher than average leverage in the capital structure. If the firm’s future earnings prospects are favorable, a higher leverage may be justified.

Page 83: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-83

Evaluating the Effect of Financial Leverage on Firm’s Earnings per Share

• Firms that use more debt financing will experience greater swings in their earnings per share in response to changes in firm revenues and operating earnings. This is referred to as the financial leverage effect.

Page 84: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-84

Page 85: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-85

Financial Leverage and the Volatility of EPS

• The table below also illustrates the impact of financial leverage on the volatility of earnings per share.

Capital Structure

Worst caseEBIT =$10,000

Best CaseEBIT = $40,000

$ Change in EPS

% Change in EPS

Plan A 2.50 10.00 7.50 300%

Plan B 2.00 12.00 10.00 500%

Plan C 1.50 14.00 12.50 833%

Page 86: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-86

Financial Leverage and the Volatility of EPS (cont.)

• We observe that when EBIT is high, a more levered firm will realize higher EPS. However, if EBIT falls, a firm that uses more financial leverage will suffer a large drop in earnings per share (EPS) than a firm that relies less on financial leverage.

Page 87: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-87

Using the EBIT-EPS Chart to Analyze the Effect of Capital Structure on EPS

• Checkpoint 15.2 illustrates the EBIT-EPS chart that evaluates the effect of capital structure choices on earnings per share.

• The EBIT-EPS chart analyzes:– Whether the debt plan produces a higher level

of EPS for the most likely range of EBIT values.– Possible swings in EPS that might occur under

the capital structure alternatives.

Page 88: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-88

Checkpoint 15.2

Evaluating the Effect of Financing Decisions on EPS

The House of Toast, Inc. is considering a new investment that will cost $50,000 and that will increase the firm’s annual operating earnings (EBIT) by $10,000 per year from the current level of $20,000 to $30,000. The firm can raise the $50,000 by (1) selling 500 shares of common stock at $100 each, or (2) selling bonds that will net the firm $50,000 and carry an interest rate of 8.5 percent. What is the EPS for the expected level of EBIT equal to $30,000? What is the effect of the financing alternatives on the level and volatility of the firm’s EPS if the firm anticipates that its EBIT will fall within the range of $20,000 to $40,000 per year?

Page 89: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-89

Checkpoint 15.2

Page 90: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-90

Checkpoint 15.2

Page 91: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-91

Checkpoint 15.2

Page 92: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-92

Checkpoint 15.2

Page 93: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-93

Checkpoint 15.2: Check Yourself

• House of Toast likes the new investment very much. However, in the weeks since the project was first analyzed, the firm has learned that credit tightening in the financial markets has caused the cost of debt financing for the debt financing plan to increase to 10%. What level of EBIT produces zero EPS for the new borrowing rate?

Page 94: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-94

Step 1: Picture the Problem

• The current and prospective capital structure alternatives can be described using pro forma balance sheets as given in the next slide.

Page 95: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-95

Step 1: Picture the Problem (cont.)

Current Capital Structure

With New Debt Financing

Long-term debt at 8% $50,000 $50,000

Long-term debt at 10% $50,000

Common Stock $150,000 $150,000

Total Liabilities and Equity

$200,000 $250,000

Common Shares Outstanding

1,500 1,500

Page 96: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-96

Step 2: Decide on a Solution Strategy

• A firm’s capital structure will affect both the EPS for a given level of operating earnings (EBIT) and the volatility of changes in EPS corresponding to changes in EBIT. We can use pro forma income statements for a range of levels of EBIT that the firm believes is relevant to its future performance.

Page 97: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-97

Step 3: Solve

• We calculate the EPS over a range of EBITs. 50,000*.08+50,000*.10

EPS =Net income/1500

EBIT/EPS AnalysisEBIT $5,000 $9,000 $20,000 $25,000 $30,000 $35,000

Less: Interest Expense $9,000 $9,000 $9,000 $9,000 $9,000 $9,000

EBT $(4,000) $ — $11,000 $16,000 $21,000 $26,000

Less: Taxes $(2,000) $ — $5,500 $8,000 $10,500 $13,000

Net Income $(2,000) $ — $5,500 $8,000 $10,500 $13,000

EPS $(1.33) $ — $3.67 $5.33 $7.00 $8.67

Tax rate=50%

Page 98: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-98

Step 3: Solve (cont.)

Page 99: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-99

Step 4: Analyze

• We examine the EPS within the EBIT range of $5,000 to $35,000. The EPS ranges from a low of -$1.33 to a high of $8.67. At EBIT of $9,000, the EPS is equal to zero.

Page 100: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-100

Computing EPS Indifference Points for Capital Structure Alternatives

• The point of intersection of the two capital structure lines found in Figure 15-7 is called the EBIT-EPS indifference point. The point identifies the level at which EPS will be the same regardless of the financing plan chosen by the firm.

Page 101: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-101

Computing EPS Indifference Points for Capital Structure Alternatives (cont.)

• At EBIT amounts in excess of the EBIT indifference level, the financing plan with more leverage will generate a higher EPS.

• At EBIT amounts below the EBIT indifference level, the financing plan involving less leverage will generate a higher EPS.

Page 102: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-102

Survey Evidence: Factors that Influence CFO Debt Policy

• Figure 15-8 captures the survey of 392 CFOs who were asked about the potential determinants of capital structure choices on a scale of 0 to 4, with a 0 indicating not important and 4 representing very important.

Page 103: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-103

Page 104: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-104

Key Terms

• Agency costs• Benchmarking• Debt to value ratio• EBITDA coverage ratio• EBIT-EPS chart• EBIT-EPS indifference point• Favorable financial leverage

Page 105: M15 titman 2544318_11_fin_mgt_c15

Copyright © 2011 Pearson Prentice Hall. All rights reserved.15-105

Key Terms (cont.)

• Financial distress costs• Financial leverage effect• Interest bearing debt ratio• Interest tax savings• Internal sources of financing• Optimal capital structure• Range of earnings chart• Unfavorable financial leverage