21
AN ECONOMIC THEORY OF PLANNED OBSOLESCENCE JEREMY BULOW “Planned Obsolescence” is the production of goods with uneconomically short useful lives so that customers will have to make repeat purchases. However, rational customers will pay for only the present value of the future services of a product. Therefore, profit maximization seemingly implies producing any given flow of services as cheaply as possible, with production involving efficient useful lives. This paper shows why this analysis is incomplete and therefore incorrect. Monopolists are shown to desire uneconomically short useful lives for their goods. Oligopolists have the monopolist’s incentive for short lives as well as a second incentive that may either increase or decrease their chosen durability. However, oligopolists can generally gain by colluding to reduce durability and increase rentals relative to sales. Some evidence is presented that appears to be generally consistent with the predictions of the theory. I. INTRODUCTION Suppliers of darables in imperfectly competitive markets have been suspected ofproducing goods with uneconomically short use- ful lives, so that consumers will have to repurchase more often. 1 However, the theory behind ~planned obsolescence” has been no- tably weak.2 Will customers not pay less for products that have a shorter useful life? If the firm decides to sell customers any given flow of services, does profit-maximizing behavior not imply producing those services as cheaply as possible?3 These are the questions with which an economic theory ofplanned obsolescence must deal. *Thanks to Paul Klemperer, Paul Pfleiderer, John Roberts, Myron Scholes, and Larry Summers for valuable comments. Thanks also to the participants in seminars at Chicago, Columbia, Michigan, MIT, Princeton, Stanford, and Wis- consin. This paper was begun at Stanford Business School and revised at the Center for the Study of the Economy and the State, University of Chicago. I am grateful to George Stigler for arranging my visit there. 1. See, e.g., Galbraith [1958, p. 352] discussing the wastefulness of chan~ng automobile models. Probably the best known empirical work in this area is Fis er, Griliches, and Kaysen [1962]. 2. Martin [1962], Kleiman and Ophir [1966], Levhari and Srinivasan [1969], and Schmalensee [1970] all concluded that monopolists would choose inefficiently short asset lives, but did so via flawed analyses. Barro [1972]relied on consumers and producers facing different discount rates to derive planned obsolescence. 3. See Swan [1972, 1977] and Sieper and Swan [1973] for a detailed presen- tation of this argument. These papers also showed the errors made by the first several authors cited in footnote 2. For a good survey of the durability literature until 1980, see Schmalensee [19791.

AN ECONOMIC THEORY OF PLANNED OBSOLESCENCE

  • Upload
    vonhu

  • View
    235

  • Download
    5

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

AN ECONOMIC THEORY OF PLANNED OBSOLESCENCE

JEREMY BULOW

“PlannedObsolescence”is theproductionof goodswith uneconomicallyshortuseful lives so that customerswill have to makerepeatpurchases.However,rationalcustomerswill payfor only the presentvalueof the future servicesof aproduct.Therefore,profit maximizationseeminglyimplies producinganygivenflow of servicesascheaplyaspossible,with productioninvolving efficient usefullives. This papershowswhy this analysisis incompleteandthereforeincorrect.Monopolistsareshownto desireuneconomicallyshortusefullives for their goods.Oligopolistshavethe monopolist’s incentivefor short lives as well as a secondincentivethatmayeither increaseor decreasetheir chosendurability. However,oligopolists can generallygain by colluding to reducedurability and increaserentalsrelativeto sales.Someevidenceis presentedthatappearsto begenerallyconsistentwith the predictionsof the theory.

I. INTRODUCTION

Suppliersof darablesin imperfectlycompetitivemarketshavebeensuspectedofproducinggoodswith uneconomicallyshortuse-ful lives, so thatconsumerswill haveto repurchasemoreoften.1However,thetheorybehind~plannedobsolescence”hasbeenno-tably weak.2Will customersnotpay lessfor productsthat havea shorteruseful life? If the firm decidesto sell customersanygivenflow ofservices,doesprofit-maximizingbehaviornotimplyproducingthoseservicesas cheaplyas possible?3Thesearethequestionswith whichaneconomictheoryofplannedobsolescencemustdeal.

*Thanksto PaulKlemperer,PaulPfleiderer,JohnRoberts,Myron Scholes,andLarry Summersfor valuablecomments.Thanksalsoto the participantsinseminarsat Chicago, Columbia,Michigan, MIT, Princeton,Stanford,andWis-consin. This paperwas begunat StanfordBusinessSchooland revisedat theCenterfor the Studyof the EconomyandtheState,University of Chicago.I amgrateful to GeorgeStiglerfor arrangingmy visit there.

1. See,e.g.,Galbraith[1958,p. 352] discussingthe wastefulnessof chan~ngautomobilemodels.Probablythebestknownempiricalworkin thisareais Fis er,Griliches, andKaysen[1962].

2. Martin [1962],KleimanandOphir [1966],Levhari andSrinivasan[1969],andSchmalensee[1970]all concludedthatmonopolistswouldchooseinefficientlyshortassetlives,but did so via flawedanalyses.Barro [1972]reliedon consumersandproducersfacingdifferentdiscountratesto deriveplannedobsolescence.

3. SeeSwan[1972,1977] andSieperandSwan[1973] for a detailedpresen-tation of this argument.Thesepapersalso showedthe errorsmadeby the firstseveralauthorscited in footnote2. Foragood survey of the durability literatureuntil 1980,seeSchmalensee[19791.

730 QUARTERLYJOURNALOFECONOMICS

This paperexplainswhy, in a full informationmodel4 withrationalcustomers,afirm might opt to give its productsashorterthaneconomicallydesirableusefullife. Sometimesfirms mayevenpaymore to produceashorterlived asset.Thekeyresultsof thepaperfollow:

1. Except underunusualcost conditions5a monopolistnotthreatenedby entry will producegoodswith inefficiently shortuseful lives. This result is closelylinked to theobservationthata durablegoodsmonopolistwill prefer to rent, ratherthan sellits output.6

2. An oligopolist,or equivalentlyamonopolistfacingcertainentry in asubsequentperiod,alsohasacountervailingincentiveto extenddurability. As acorollary, suchfirms haveanincentiveto steercustomersto purchaseratherthanrentalcontracts.Thissameresultalsoholdsif futurecompetitionis to be overarelatedbutnotidenticalsubstituteproduct.Therefore,whilemonopolistswill optfor inefficiently shortusefullives,oligopolistsmaychooseeitheruneconomicallyshortor longlives,dependingontheirtech-nologies and market conditions. There is also an incentivetoincreasedurability to deterentry.7

3. Thereis generallyan incentivefor oligopoliststo colludeto reducedurability, below noncooperativelevels.

4. While antitrustpolicy requiring firms to sell ratherthanrent their productswill reduceprofitability and any monopolypower,it mayalsodecreasewelfare.

In SectionII thebasicmodel of amonopolistchoosingadu-rability is developed.While competitivefirms will choosetheef-

4. We meanto ruleout equilibria wheredurability is unobservableprior topurchase,firms haveacostincentiveto produceshoddyproducts,andcustomersthereforeassumethat low-durability productswill be produced.

5. Specifically,a firm’s marginal costcurvehavingasteeperslope thanitsdemandcurvearoundequilibrium.

6. SeeBulow [1982]for an expositionon the advantagesof renting for sucha monopolist.The link is that by renting the monopolistis selling off thenon-durableservicesof hisproductsandmaythusachievemanyof the advantagesoflowdurabilitywithoutthecostsofinefficient production.However,therearemanydurableproduct marketswhere rental marketshave their own inefficiencies.Consider,for example,the incentiveproblemsin automobilerental.A goodpaperdiscussingtheleaseversusbuyquestionin acompetitiveenvironmentis Wolfson[1985].

7. Thereis anextensiveliteratureon increasingthe durabilityof investmentassetsto deterentry.The analogouspointon the demandsideis thatentryis lessonglives.if customersaretiedto long-termcontractsor alreadyown assetswith

A THEORYOF PLANNEDOBSOLESCENCE 731

ficient level ofdurability, themonopolist’sprofit-maximizingrateofdurability is shownto equaltheefficient level plusatermthatis generallynegative.

SectionIII extendsthebasicmodelto oligopolies.Olrgopolistsmust add an extra term to the monopolist’s durability choice,generallycausingthem(in quantitycompetition)to decreasetherateof obsolescence.

SectionIV providesillustrationsof monopolyand oligopolydurability choiceto indicate how an oligopolist or a monopolistfacing actual or potential entry will changeobsolescencefromefficient levels.Themonopolistfacingentrymaychoosedurabilityto effectivelybecomeaStackelbergleaderin thepost-entryperiod.We alsofind that anoligopolistic industrycan gainby colludingto increasetherateof obsolescencebeyondnoncooperativelevels.

In SectionV we examinethestrategicconsequencesto im-perfectly competitivefirms of rentingversusselling. Increasingthe sales-rentalratio is the strategicequivalent of increasingdurability. This analysissuggeststhatprior to introducinganewmodel in anoligopolistic marketafirm maychooseto sell ratherthanrent its old units.This incentiveexistseventhoughagreatersales-rentalratio with thestockof outstandingunitsunchangedwill leadto alower salesprice.The analysisalsopredictsthatasa monopolist’smarketsbecomemore competitive,the firm willincreaseits sales-rentalratio. This predictionis looselycorrob-oratedempirically.

SectionVI summarizesandconcludesthepaper.

II. MONOPOLY AND PLANNED OBSOLESCENCE

We begin by consideringa monopolistwho is maximizingprofitsovertwo periods.In thefirst periodit choosesbothaquan-tity q1 anda durability 5. Of the initial q1 units sold, (1 —

disappearat theendof the first periodandSq1 remainin period2. Thefirm may alsoproducean additionalq~ units in period2.The implicit rentalprice of a unit in period 1 is f1(q1) andtheimplicit rentalprice in period2 is (1 + r)(f2(Sqi + q2)), where ris theinterestrate.Total costsin period1 areC1(q1,5),andperiod2 costsare(1 + r)C2(q2).Thepresentvalueofsecond-periodreve-nuesis thusf2(5q1 + q2), andthepresentvalueof second-periodcostsis C2(q2). The firm is requiredto sell, ratherthenrent, its

732 QUARTERLYJOURNALOFECONOMICS

output.8Finally, we assumea perfectsecond-handmarket:anyfirst-periodpurchaserof oneunit canresellhis remaining5 unitsin thesecondperiodat themarketpriceofnew output.9

Theproblemof themonopolistis to

max ~n= q1f1(q1) + (Sqi + q2)f2(5q1 + q2)

(1) ql,q2,5

— C1(qi,5) —

wherethe first two terms representthepresentvalue of totalrevenuesandthe last two termsarethe presentvalue of totalcosts.

Left unconstrained,themonopolistfacesthe following first-orderconditions:

alT aC1(2) —=f1+q1f{+5f2±(5qi+q2)Sf~—-—=0aq1 ~9q1

(3) aq2(4) — qif2 + (Sq1 + q2)q1f;2 — aC1 —

as as

Combiningthe last two conditionsyields

1 aC1 _

— C~.

Condition (5) statesthat the firm will choosean efficient dura-bility: it equatesthecostofmakingits originalunitsalittle moredurableso thatonemoreof theoriginal units will still be usefulin thesecondperiod,((lIqD(aC1/aS)), with thepresentvalueofthe

8. We alsoruleoutthe monopolist’sengagingin financialcontractsthatplacehim in the equivalentpositionof a renter.The simplestsuchcontractwould beoneto repurchaseall scild itemsatafixedpriceattheendof oneperioiAnderson[1984]suggestsfuturescontractswherethemonopolist,by holdingfutures,couldinternalizechangesin thegenerallevelof priceswhile makingindividualownersresponsiblefor changesin specific assetvaluesdueto differing levels of main-tenance.One difficulty with such a contractis that it may be difficult for themonopolistto makeits net futuresmarketpositionpublicly observable.

9. Thisassumptionhasseveralimplications.Combinedwith the assumptionof adownwardslopingdemandcurve, it implies thatfirst-periodconsumersaremadeworse off by increasedsecond-periodproduction.Note that sometimesamonopolistmaywishto deterthe second-handmarket;considerafirm thatofferstiedservicecontractsto customerswhichareonlyvalid for theoriginalpurchaserof a good. Imperfectionsin the second-handmarkethavethe effectofreducingthe economicdurability of aproduct(seeBulow [1982]).

A THEORYOFPLANNEDOBSOLESCENCE 733

costof replacingan extraunit in thesecondperiod, (Cs). This istheconclusionof Swan[19721:for anygiven flow of servicesthemonopolistchoosesto produce,profit maximizationimplies thatth’eseservicesbe producedas cheaplyaspossible.

However,this analysisis incompleteand consequentlyin-correct.The problemof thedurablegoodsmonopolistis that theunconstrainedsolutionto (1) is generallynot dynamicallycon-sistent.10When the secondperiod arrives,the monopolist willregardthe first periodas water underthebridge. It thenfacestheproblem,

max q2f2(8q1 + q2) —

q2

thesolution of which implies that

(6) q2f~+f2—C~=O.

Note how (6) compareswith (3): thedifferenceis that in thesecondperiodwhenthemonopolistproducesanextraunit it con-siderstheeffectofthatunit on thepricehereceivesfor theotherq2 unitssold(andthussetsMR = q2f~ + f2 = MC = C~) butdoesnot considerthe reductionin the rentalvalue of the units pre-viously soldbut now ownedby others,5q1f~. Of course,rationalconsumersrecognizethat themonopolistwill not considertheirinterestsin thesecondperiodandwill adjustthepricethey arewilling to pay for first-periodpurchasesaccordingly.Thus,withrationalconsumersthe presentvalueof the firm’s revenuewillequalthepresentvalueof the implicit rentsits salesgenerate,so the firm still wishesto maximize (1). It mustdo so,however,with (6) asa constraint.

11Maximizing (1) subjectto (6), by cal-

10. Expositionsof the dynamicproblemof the durablegoodsmonopolistareprovided by Coase[1972], Bulow [1982],KahnIIl982], andStokey [1981].Tworecentpapersof interestin thisfield areSobel[1984]andConlisk,Gerstner,andSobel [1984].Gul, Sonnenschein,andWilson [1985]areresponsiblefor two majoradvancesin the field, beingthefirst to modelthe dynamicmonopolyproblemasaformal gameandprovidingthefirst generalproofof Coase’soriginal intuition.

11. Note thatif the firm couldrent its output insteadof selling it, themo-nopolistcould maximizethe unconstrainedproblem.The reasonis with rentalsthe monopolistownsall of the outstandingunits andis thusableto internalizethecapital loss on old units.However,in somemarketsrental is impractical.Forexample,theautorentalmarketfacesaseriousproblemin monitoringthedamagecausedby rentersandthereforecannotforce rentersto treatthe carsas if theyweretheir own. In somemarkets(e.g.,computers,copiers,andshoemachinery)the governmenthasrequiredadominantfirm to sell insteadof rent someof itsoutput.

734 QUARTERLYJOURNALOFECONOMICS

culatingd7r/d~ andrecognizingthat dq2/d5q1is implicitly deter-minedby the constraint,leadsto the following condition on du-rability:

(7) — — = C~ + 5qif~ d(5q1 + q2

)

1 ac1 d~q1qi a5

The intuition behindthelast term in (7) is asfollows: becauseoftheconstraintthemonopolistsuffersa lossof ~q1f!~on themar-ginal unit it sells in the secondperiod, relativeto its precom-mitmentin thefirst-periodoutput. The term 5q1f~ is simply thedifferencebetween(3) and(6). When5q1 is increasedby oneunitdue to increaseddurability, the choiceof q2 is changedby dq2Id~q1, which can be found by totally differentiating(6). On net,thenumberofunitsoutstandingin thesecondperiodchangesbyd(5q1 + q2)/d5q1,which aswe will seebelow is usuallypositive.Increasingdurability thus has the extra cost in this model ofincreasingtheunitsonthemarketin thesecondperiod,andthoseextraunits reduceprofits. Thereis thus an incentive to reducedurability belowtheefficient level.

By totally differentiating(6), we find that

(8) d(5q1 + q2) _ —

d~q1 2f~ + q2f~ —

whichcanbewritten as

(8’)

d(~q1 + q2) slope of demandcurve — slope ofMC curved8q1 slopeof MR curve — slopeof MC curve

The denominatorof (8’) mustbe negative:aroundthe opti-mum theslope of themarginal revenuecurve mustbe steeperthantheslopeofthemarginalcostcurve. If thedemandcurveismore steeplydownwardsloping than the marginal cost curve,thenthenumeratoris alsonegative,and(8’) is positive. In thiscasean increasein 8q1 causedby increasingdurability also in-creases~q1+ q2,andbecauseofthiseffectthemonopolistchoosesalowerdurability,or ~plannedobsolescence.”If themarginalcostcurveis steeperthanthedemandcurve,anincreasein ~qi leadsto adecreasein (~q1 + q2), andthemonopolistthereforechoosesto producetoo durableaproduct.

12Fortheremainderofthepaperwe shall assumethe ~normal” caseof the demandcurve being

12. For example,if P2 = a — — f3~q2 andMC2 = y — (I~ + s)q2, then

q2 = (a.— y)1(13 — e) — ~3I(I3— s)~qi, soanincreasein Sq

1of oneunitwill decrease

A THEORYOFPLANNEDOBSOLESCENCE 735

moresteeplydownwardslopingthanthemarginalcostcurve, inwhich casethe monopolist unambiguouslychoosesan insuffi-ciently durableproduct.13

Thus,themonopolistwill generallychooseadurabilitybelowefficient levels.14However,in theunusualcasewhereanincreasein ~q

1will decrease~q1+ q~, which is the casewhen aroundequilibriumthemarginalcostcurveslopesdownwardmoresteeplythanthedemandcurve, themonopolistwill producetoo durableaproduct.

In reality, plannedobsolescenceis just oneof severalwaysin which a monopolistmight mitigatethecommitmentproblem.While thereis no roomfor it in our finite time, full information,one-productmodel, firms may expendresourcesto establishareputationassuggestedby Kreps andWilson [1982]. They maydo soby developingapatternfor pricingaparticularproductovertime or throughpricing relatedproductsthat are producedse-quentially. (A publishercan gain a reputationfor enforcingasubstantialwait betweenthepublicationof hardcoverandpa-perbackeditions,for example.)Also, a monopolist’scurtailmentofcapacitywill affectcostcurvesandthusbeawayofcommittingto limit future outputs.The point of thispaperis thatasecono-mistswewould expectthefirm to useall themeansat its disposalto reduceits commitmentproblem, and the envelopetheoremimplies that a monopolistwill useat leasta little plannedob-solescence.The two-period limitation (versussomelarger finitenumberof shorterperiods)doesnot alter thequalitativeimpli-

q2 by F31(13 — s) andthusdecrease~q1+ q~ by sI(13 — s). Why doesthis happen?Considerthe experimentwhere&qi is increasedby one,andwewish to discoverwhetherq~ is decreasedby lessor morethanone. If 8q1 is increasedby one andq~ is decreased by exactly one, second-period marginal revenue,q2f2(aql + q~) + f2(~q1 + q~), changesby —fe, the negativeof the slopeof thedemandcurve. Marginal costschangeby — C’2’, the negativeof the slopeof themarginalcostcurve.Fromtheinitial optimumwhereMR = MC, if themarginalcostcurveis steeperthanthe demandcurve, thenincreasing8qi anddecreasingq2 by a like amountwill thusleavemarginalrevenuebelowmarginalcosts.So,to returnto MR = MC, q~ will haveto bedecreasedby morethan5qi increased.Therefore,if marginalcostsaresharplydecreasing,anincreasein durabilityfromthe economicallyefficient levelwill causeadecreasein ~ + q~ andthuscausean increasein profits.

13. Thisrestrictionon marginalcostsis fairly weak.It is worthemphasizingthatafirm couldhaveconsiderableeconomiesofscalein the~econd-perioc1(averagecostsdecreasingwith output)withouthavingrapidly decreasingmarginalcosts.

14. Thereare also sometax reasonswhy amonopolistwould prefera lessdurableproduct.By selling adurableproduct,the monopolistimmediatelypaystaxeson thepresentvalueof thefuture monopolyrentsearnedon theunits sold.Further,taxesmustbepaidon anyincomeearnedfrom reinvestingthoseprofits.With nondurableunits, taxesarepaidonly atthe timethe monopolist’sservicesareconsumed.

736 QUARTERLYJOURNALOF ECONOMICS

cationsofthemodelandoftencausestheresultsto beunderstatecLThe reasonis that a considerableamountof commitmentis al-readyimplied whenafirm thatproducesin period1 cannotpro-duceagainuntil half thetime horizonhaselapsed.With shorterperiodstheneedto ~buy” commitmentvia plannedobsolescenceandotherdevicescanincrease.

A final noteconcernsthewelfareimplicationsof thismodel.The perfectnessconstraint(6) reducesthe monopolist’sprofits;that point is one of themajor thrustsof the durablegoodsmo-nopolist literature.But theconstraintalsocausesinefficienciesin production,suchasplannedobsolescence.It isentirelypossiblethat theconstrainedmonopolist,while making low profits, willreducediscountedconsumersurplusrelativeto anunconstrainedmonopolist.’5A simple numericalexamplein thenext footnoteshowshow thereductionin monopolypowercumplannedobso-lescencecanbe welfarereducing.’6Thus, for example,antitrustpolicy requiringfirms suchasIBM andUnitedShoeto sell ratherthan only rent equipmentmay well be socially costly evenas itreducesmonopolypower.

The implication of small profits andlargewelfarelossesissimilar to theresultsof textbookmonopolisticcompetition.Be-causewe knowthat in aggregatefirms’ monopolyprofitsarerela-tively small,17resultslike theseareimportantfor justifying thesubstantialresearchin imperfectcompetition.

15. Bulow [1982,pp. 327—28] showsthataconstrainedmonopolistmaybuildartificially low capacityasaway of committingto ahigh future price,andthisin itself can leadto a reductionin discountedconsumersurplusrelativeto theunconstrainedmonopolist.While the point therewasmadein an infinite horizonmodel,it is easyto constructtwo-periodexampleswherethesameresultapplies:assumethatafirm facesademandcurveof p = 100 — q for eachof two periodsandthe interestrate is zero. Capacitycosts are $20 per unit, andoneunit ofcapacityenablesa firm to build oneunit of outputeachperiod at zeromarginalcost.A monopolistrenterwill build forty units of capacity,andproduceforty inperiod 1 andten in period2. Total profitswill be 4,100,andconsumer’ssurpluswill be 2,050.A monopolistsellerwill choosetobuild twenty-eightunitsof capacityin period1, andproducetwenty-eightunits in bothperiods.His profits will sumto 3,920, andconsumer’ssurpluswill be 1,960. Thus,the limitation on the mo-nopolist’spowerreducesbothprofits andconsumer’ssurplus.

16. Assumethat the inversedemandcurvefor rental servicesin eachof twoperiodsisp = 100 — q. Theinterestrateis zero.First-periodunits cost20 eachto build, regardlessof their durability. Second-periodunits cost10 to produce.Amonopolistrenterwould build forty-five unitsin period 1 with maximumdura-bility (5 = 1) and rentthem out eachperiod. Producer’ssurplus(grossof fixedcosts)wouldbe 4,050,andconsumer’ssurpluswouldbe 2,025for atotal of 6,075.A monopolistseller,by contrast,would produceforty units in period 1 with adurability 8 = ~. He wouldadd thirty-five new units in period 2, leavinga totalof fifty-five in the marketin thesecondperiod.Simplearithmeticshowsthattotalprofits drop to 3,725,consumer’ssurplusrisesto 2,312k,andthustotal surplusfalls to 6,037k.

17..See,for example,Salinger[1984].

A THEORYOFPLANNEDOBSOLESCENCE 737

III. THE OLIGOPOLIsTIC MAXIMIZATION PROBLEM

This sectionbeginsby outliningan oligopolist’s problemforCournotquantitycompetition.Theformula for durabilityhasoneextra termcomparedwith themonopolist’sformula, relating totheeffectofone’sdurability oncompetitors’second-periodoutput.With quantitycompetitionahigherdurability will usuallycausecompetitorsto cut output, and this increasesone’s own profita-bility. Therefore,thereis an advantageto high durability thatthe oligopolist must tradeoff with the competingadvantageoffasterobsolescence.’5

We beginby consideringanoligopolistwho choosesq, and5in thefirst periodandq

2 in thesecondperiod.It facesn competi-tors who will producea total of ~, with a durability of 5 in thefirst periodandwill produce~2(5q1)in thesecondperiod,where

= 1 q~ and q~ is thesecondperiodoutput of theCth com-petitor.Thefirm’s maximizationproblem,notmuchdifferentfrom(1), is

max q1f1(q1 + ~,) + (Sq, + q2)f2(Sq, + 5~. + q2 + ~2)(9) qi,8,q~

— C,(5,q,) — C2(q2)

subjectto

[2 + q2f~ — = 0

andsubjectto

[2 + ~ — = 0,

wherethefirst constraintis theperfectionconstraintimposedontheoligopolist,andthefinal nconstraintsrecognizethatin choos-ing Sq, theoligopolist is alsoimplicitly choosinghis competitor’ssecond-periodoutputsandthathis choicein competitors’outputsis limited by theNashrequirementthateachof thosefirms willhaveMR = MC.

Durability choicecanbederivedjustasin themonopolycase:

1 aC, d(Sq, + q2) ____

(10) = C~ + 5q,f~ d5q, + (Sq1 + ~2)f2~5q1.

18.Thefirstsignificantpaperdiscussingtheoligopoly versionof thisproblemhasjustbeenwritten by Gul [1985].Usingan infinite horizonsupergameframe-workwith oligopolisticpricecompetitors,Gul showsthattherearemultipleequi-libria, oneof which (asthe lengthof aperiod to whicha firm is committedto afix pricebecomessmall) is arbitrarily doseto the monopolisticprecommitmentsolution!Gul’s paper,likemostofthepreviousliterature,assumesno depreciation.

738 QUARTERLYJOURNALOFECONOMICS

All the termsin (10) shouldbe familiar from themonopolycaseexceptthelastone.It statesthatwhendurabilityisincreasedso that theamountof outputthat lastsinto thenextperiod,5q1,increasesby one,that competitors’second-periodoutputis changedby d~2/d~q1andthischangeaffectsthepricethefirm receivesforthe5q1 + q2 unitsof servicesthat its outputprovidesduringthesecondperiod.If, for example,anincreasein ~iq1causescompeti-tors to reducesecond-periodoutput, thenthe final term in (10)will bepositiveandwill act to increasedurability, thusactinginthedirectionoppositefrom theprevioustermin therelation.Notethat if afirm actsasapricetaker, (10) showsthat it choosestheefficient durability.

A sufficient condition for thelast term in (10) to bepositiveandact to increasedurability of a firm, sayfirm A, is thateachofA’s competitors’second-periodmarginalrevenueis decreasingin industryoutput.Thenanincreasein A’s durability,whichhasthesameeffect of increasingsecond-periodindustryoutput,willcauseall competitorsto contractoutputandthushelpA~sprofits.’

9

IV. ILLUSTRATIONS OF THE PROBLEMSOF DURABILITY CHOICE

The analysisof SectionsII andIII showsthat the determi-nantsofdurabilitychoiceextendbeyondefficiencyconsiderations.This sectionisolatesthesenonefficiencyconsiderationsby pro-

19. Theconditionin theparagraphabovecanbe guaranteedby twoplausibleassumptions. Define the total number of units on the market asQ 8q~ + q2+8q~ + q~, anddefinethetotal valueofimplicit rentsin thesecondperiodas TR Qf2(Q). Then the two assumptionsarefirst that no individualfirm is producingmorethan~Qin the secondperiod alone; and second,assumethata2TR

2/OQ= OMR2/aQ< 0, industrymarginalrevenueis decreasinginoutput.The detailsare left to the reader.With competitioninvolving some strategicvariableotherthanquantity,an oligopolistmayhaveastrategicincentiveeitherto increasedurability (as with quantity competition)or to decreasedurability.The crucial determinantis whetheran increasein A’s durability will raiseorlower the marginalprofitability of adoptingamore “aggressive”second-periodstrategy.Forexample,withquantitycompetitionA’s increaseddurabilityreducesthe marginalprofitability of extraoutputandthuscausescompetitorsto become“less aggressive”by reducingquantity.With pricecompetitionan increasein A’sdurability maycausecompetitorsto chargealower second-periodprice; a~~moreaggressive”strategythathasanegativeeffect on A’s profits. In the languageofBulow,Geanakoplos, andKlemperer[1984],the analogyto the last term in (10)in generalizedorigopolisticcompetitionwill causeA to increasedurability if itscompetitorsregardA’s outputasastrategicsubstituteantiwilicauseNto4ecreasedurabilityif its competitorsregardA’s outputasastrategiccomplement.Seealsothe excellentpaperby FudenbergandTirole [1984].

A THEORYOFPLANNEDOBSOLESCENCE 739

viding illustrations of durability choice in exampleswhere alldurabilitiesareequalin productiveefficiency.

The assumptionthat all durabilitiesareof equal efficiencyin productionis of special interestfor its applicationto how amanufacturerwhocouldeitherrentor sell its outputswould choosesalesasapercentageof totalplacements.By decreasingits sales-rental ratio, afirm is ableto reducetheamountof future outputservicesownedby customerswithout any lossof productiveeffi-ciency.The analogyof rental-salesstrategyto durability choiceis furtherdetailedin SectionV.

Both examplesbelow involve quantity competitionso thatfirms facingpotentialoractualcompetitionwill haveanincentiveto chooselongerdurabilitiesthan amonopolist(seeSectionIII).The first exampleillustratesa monopolistwho expectscompeti-tion in thesecondperiod.It usesdurability asaway to become,effectively,aStackelbergleaderin thesecondperiod.Thesecondexample illustratesquantity competition betweensymmetricalfirms. The optimal durability choiceis derivedasa function ofthenumberof firms in themarket,with themonopolist’schoiceof S = 0 beingtheresult for n 1.

The intuition of theexamplesprovidesthebasisfor a shortdiscussionon issuesof entry andcollusion.Finally, theproblemofa firm planningto introduceanewbut relatedproductanditsstrategyin choosingdurability andasalesversusrentalstrategyis analyzed.

Example1: TheMonopolistFacingSecond-PeriodEntry

In theseexampleswe shallassumethatfirms haveaconstantmarginalcosttechnologythatallows themto produceunits witha durability of S at a costof C(1 + 5). In thesecondperiodtheycanproduceunits lastingoneperiodat a constantmarginalcostof (1 + r)C. With this technologyproducingat all durabilitiesisequallyefficient.Thatis, thepresentvalueof total costsis equalto q1C + (Sq1 + q2)C regardlessof whetherthe firm choosestosupplysecond-perioddemandwith high durability andlow q2 orlow durability andhigh q2.

In this first exampleassumethat a first-period monopolistchoosesq1 and 5. In the secondperiod the incumbentand anentrant establisha Cournotequilibrium over the residual de-mand.The demandcurve for rental.servicesis p = a — 13q1 inperiod 1 andp = (1 ± r)(cx — pSq1 — ~3q~— Pq2) in period 2.

Because the second-periodCournot equilibrium is q2 —

740 QUARTERLYJOURNALOFECONOMICS

= (a — 135q1 — 0)1313, the monopolist’sfirst-periodproblemcan

bethoughtofas

(11)

maxq1(a — 13q1 — C) + (Sq1 + q2)(a — p(5q1 + q2 + ~2) — C)qi,8

subjectto

= = (a — 135q1 — C)/313.

(Becauseof thesymmetryin thepositionof the incumbentandtheentrantin choosingsecond-periodoutput,themonopolist’sperfectionconstraintof second-periodMR = MC (a — r35q1 — 13q2— 213q2 — c = 0) andtheNashequilibriumrequirementfor thecompetitor’ssecond-periodoutput (a — 135q1 — 13q2 — 213~2 — c= 0)canbesimplifiedto theconstraintsabove.)Solving(11)yields

(a — C)1213, Sq1 = (a — C)/4I3—~5 =

= q~ = (a — C)/413.So theoptimumdepreciationrate,if all technologiesareequallyefficient, is 1 — S = 50 percent.Presumablyif first-period tech-nologiesweredifferentiallyefficient,themonopolistwould chooseadurability somewherebetween50 percentandthemaximallyefficient level.

It is worthnoting that in thisproblemthemonopolistis ableto producethemonopolyquantityin thefirst periodandby choos-ing its durability achievetheStackelbergleaderpositionin thesecondperiod, whereSq~ + q2 (a — C)1213 and q2 = (a — C)!413.20 This is a simple illustration of the tradeoffs in durabilitywhereincreaseddurability implies a lower second-periodpricebut a biggermarketsharefor the incumbent.

Example2: SymmetricOligopoly

Using thesamesetupasin Example1, we solvefor thesym-metricperfectCournot-Nashequilibriumin agamewith n firmsproducingin eachoftwoperiods.Welook at theproblemofafirmchoosingq1 andS in thefirst periodandq2 in thesecond,knowingthat its (n — 1) competitorswill eachproduce~ units with a

20. ThisStackelbergresultcanbe derivedunderreasonablygeneralcondi-tions.

A THEORYOFPLANNEDOBSOLESCENCE 741

durability of ~ in period1 andthata Cournot-Nashequilibriumwill be establishedon residualdemandin thesecondperiod.Thefirm’s problemis to

(12)

maxq1(a — 13q, — 13(n — 1)~~ — C) + (Sq, + q2)(a — 13(Sq,qi,8

+ S(n — 1)~, + q2 + (n — 1)~2) — C)

subjectto

= = (a — 13(Sq, + (n — 1)S~,) — C)/13(n + 1),

wheretheconstraintis againimplied by thesecond-periodequi-librium. As with (11) symmetryenablesus to combinethefirm’sperfectionconstraintson its own outputwith theconstraintsthatit is limited in its implicit choiceof competitor’ssecond-periodoutput to their meetingtheNash equilibrium conditions. It iseasyto solve(12) for a symmetricalequilibrium:

= a—C (a—C)(n—1

)

13(n + 1)’ Sq1 = = 13(n2+1)

a—C n2—1= = 13(n2+ 1)’ 5n2+f

For amonopolist(n = 1) theoptimalvalueofS is zero:thereis adisadvantageto durability in that it causeslow futureprices;thereis no correspondingadvantageto a monopolistin causingcompetitorsto cutbackonfutureoutput.2’InthisexampleS = 0.6for aduopolyandapproaches1 asn increases.While oligopolistsdohaveadurability tradeoff, this resultdoesnot imply thatwithtechnologiesof differential efficiency that moreand morefirmsin the industrywill leadto moreandmoreexcessivedurability.As more firms enter,profit marginsdecrease,and firms cannotafford to straysofar from efficient productiontechniques.

21. Note that the optimalvaluefor amonopolist’s~ is zero; the firm wouldnot chooseanegative~ evenif possible.What,economically,is anegativedepre-ciationrate?Barry Nalebuffsuggeststhat it hasa role in amodelof addiction:for given 5, themoreunits soldin the first period,thegreaterthedemandin thesecondperiod. If ourfriendlymonopolistweresellingheroin,thenit wouldpreferthatthe productbeneithersatiatingnor nonaddictive:intuitively, thosewho dobuy in thefirst periodwill be “hooked” andpayabig second-periodpricefor theproduct,but thiswill not compensatefor thecustomerswhonevertry theproductbecauseof its addictivequality.

742 QUARTERLYJOURNALOFECONOMICS

EntryDeterrenceand CollusionInspectionof theexamplesalsoprovidesintuition aboutis-

suesof entry deterrenceand oligopolistic collusion. Increasingdurability reducesthe demandfor newunits andthus reducestheprofitability of all firms includinga newentrantin period2.In Example1, themonopolistmight chooseadurability in excessof0.5 if therearefixed costsofentryandtheincreaseddurabilitywill prevententry.22

Example2 canbeusedto showtheadvantageto oligopolistsof colludingon thedurability of their products.It is easyto as-certainthatthehigherthedurability ofperiod1 output,thelowertheequilibrium price in period2. In this exampleif firms wereconstrainedto choosinga lower level of durability in period 1,they would endup (weakly) increasingq

1 relativeto what theywould chooseat theNashdurability andreducingSq1 + q2. Forexample,in a collusive agreementto setS = 0, thefirms wouldall setq1 = q2 = (a — C)I(n + 1)~ andearnCournot-Nashprofitsfor eachof two periods.Formally, themaximizationproblembe-comesthesameas(12) with theaddedconstraintthat5 5C, thecollusive5•23 In theexample,industryprofits areincreased,thelowerthecollusivedurability. Intuitively, withoutcollusionfirmschooseincreaseddurability up to thepoint wherethe total de-rivative oftheirown profitswith respectto durability is zero.Butat thispoint incrementaldurability, effectivelyincreasingfirms’second-periodquantity, reducescompetitors’ profits. So if it ispossibleto colludeon the rate of obsolescencebut not on price,firms will be ableto increaseindustryprofits by reducingdura-bility from noncooperativelevels.

If an oligopoly such as the American automobileindustrywere colluding on durability, then, it would likely be in thedi-rectionof plannedobsolescence.Theentryofforeign competitorsto makethe industry morecompetitivewould then movedura-bility towardefficient levels.

22. If thefixed costsalsomustbe paidby the monopolistfor operatingin thesecondperiod,the monopolistmayevenbe betteroff. A high enoughdurabilitymayeffectively permitthemonopolistto precommitto not producingin period 2,raisingthepricereceivedin period 1 andthepresentvalueof discountedprofits.

23. LetX~ [(n + 1)2 + 8(n — 1)]I[(n + 1)~ + ~2(n2+ 1)]. Thenif~isfixed,

eachfirm in Example2 wouldchooseq~ X(a — C)113andq~ = (1 — n~X)(a—

r3(n + 1). Industry profits over the two periods will be H~ + 112 = (a — c)2113(nX(1 — nX) + nI(n + 1)2(1 + 8X)(1 — n8X)) whichturnsout to bedecreasingin 8 overthe range0 ~ 8 ~ 1.

A THEORYOFPLANNEDOBSOLESCENCE 743

V. SALESVERSUSRENTALS

Finally, we considerhow afirm thathasthechoicebetweensellingandrentingits outputshouldbalanceits placements.Againa simplemodificationof the two illustrative examplesis of use.Assumethatall unitsproducedin thefirst periodlast twoperiodsandcost2C to produce.Units built in thesecondperiod last oneperiodandcost(1 + r)C to produce.Thefirms mustchoosefirst-periodoutputs,anddecidewhat fraction of thoseunitsshouldbesold andwhat fraction rented.Thenfirms will chooseq1 just asin theexamplesandchooseasalespercentagejust astheychoseS in theoriginal examples.

24Thatis, in Example1 themonopolistwill sell half its outputandrent half. In Example2, eacholigo-polist will sell (n2 — 1)I(n2 + 1) of its first-period output. Thereasonfor thecloseanalogybetweena rental-salesratio andadepreciationrate is that when a firm sells S units with a life oftwoperiodsandrents(1 — 5) units,it essentiallysellingoneunitof output for the current period and S units for the followingperiod,just asif it solda depreciatingasset.The soledifferenceis thattheproductionandrentalofdurablesgivesafirm marginalcostsofzeroin thesecondperioduntil all ofthefirst-periodrentalsare disposedof. Becauseexamples1 and2 give firms constantmarginalcostsandfirms alwaysdistributemoreunits in period2 thantheyrentedin period1, thisdifferencedoesnotaffecttheequilibrium in thoseexamples.25

The analogyof rental-salesstrategiesto durability enablesone to makepredictionsaboutthe evolutionof a firm’s rental-salesratio asthedegreeof competitionit faceschanges.A mo-

24. Thisexactequivalencewouldnot hold in otherexampleswheretheequi-librium numberof unitson themarketin the secondperiodwould be lessthanthe numberin the first period,for examplebecausesecond-perioddemandwasweakerthanfirst-perioddemand.

25.Moreformally, assumethatO2C1/aq~ = a

2C2Iaq~= Osothatmarginalcosts

are constanteachperiodand1 aC2 aC2q1a8 0q2

sothat thereareno economiesor diseconomiesassociatedwith achangein du-rability choice. Then the costs in the oligopolistic maximization problem~Ci(8,qi) + C2(q2), can be rewritten asC(qi,8q1 + q~). In that casethe maximi-zationproblemis preciselythe samefor a firm that facesan exogenous8 andchoosesasales-rentalratio andonethat canchoose8 but canonly sell, as longaswe haveaninterior solution(no unitsarerentedin the first periodandleftidle in thesecond).Thegeneralinterpretationof 8 would bethe fraction of first-period placementsthat arebothserviceablein the secondperiod andowned bycustomers.

744 QUARTERLYJOURNALOF ECONOMICS

nopolisthasanincentiveto rent,provingto customersthatit willnot reducepricestoo muchin thefuture. By contrast,afirm thateither facesor will shortly face somecompetitorsin its currentproductline or somecloselyrelatednew productswill alsohaveacontrastingincentiveto sell. The sales,like greaterdurability,freethefirm to placemorenewunits in thefuture andmaythusimprovethefirm’s competitiveposition.Additionally, thesmallera firm’s marketsharethemoreelasticits demandfor anygivenmarketelasticity.With price lesssensitiveto anygivenpercent-agechangein the firm’s quantity,thereis lessincentiveto rentratherthansell to committo low quantity.

To checkthepredictionthat asa dominantfirm encountersmorecompetitionit will increaseits sales-rentalratio,I gatheredall publicly availabledataonthebreakdownofrevenuesbetweensalesandrentalsfor both IBM andXerox. As Table I shows,bothfirms havesubstantiallyincreasedtheir sales-rentalratiossince1970.

Unfortunately,thereareat leastfive caveatsthat reducethe

TABLE I

BREAKDOWN OF REVENUES, 1966—1983

Sales

IBMPercentage

Rentals Services Sales

XeroxPercentage

Rentals Services

1983 57.9 23.0 19.1 45.9 39.1 15.11982 48.9 32.4 18.7 41.2 47.0 11.81981 44.4 37.3 18.3 40.1 51.0 8.91980 41.7 41.5 16.9 37.9 62.11979 41.4 44.0 14.5 34.2 65.81978 41.5 46.4 12.1 31.3 68.71977 39.1 60.9 26.9 73.11976 36.6 63.4 22.8 77.21975 31.5 68.5 20.0 80.01974 33.8 66.2 20.1 79.91973 30.7 69.3 19.1 80.91972 30.2 69.8 20.1 79.91971 26.4 73.6 20.3 79.71970 27.0 73.0 21.8 78.21969 35.8 64.2 26.2 73.81968 41.8 58.2 21.8 78.21967 35.0 65.0 N.A. N.A.1966 31.6 68.4 N.A. N.A.

N.A. = not available.Source. 10-KReportsfiled by IBM andXeroxwith SecuritiesandExchangeCommission,variousyears.

A THEORYOFPLANNEDOBSOLESCENCE 745

valueofthisevidencein confirmingthetheory.First, andperhapsmostimportant,conventionalpricediscriminationtheoryhasar-

746 QUARTERLYJOURNALOFECONOMICS

ductionshasbeendramaticallyincreasedto thepoint wherethetax advantageto manufacturerleasinghasbeenvirtually elim-inated.This changein the tax lawshasprobablyaffectedfirms’sales-rentalpolicies.28

Nevertheless,analysisin thebusinesspresshasarguedthatIBM’s recentpolicy of increasingsalesversusrentalshasbeenimplementedbecauseofcompetitiveconsiderations.TheIBM CreditCorp. was establishedtwo yearsagoto facilitate its customers’outrightpurchaseofmachinery,alteringthecompany’shistoricalpolicy of encouragingcustomersto leaseratherthanbuy its ma-chines.As aresultthefractionofcompanyrevenuesderivedfromrentalshasdroppedby overathird in two years.29‘~More impor-tant,thetrendto customers’purchasingmoreoftheir equipmentfreesthecompanyto introducemachinesmorefrequently—ale-thal competitiveedge.”30

VI. CONCLUSION

Monopolistsgenerallyhavean incentive to producegoodswith inefficiently shortusefullives. Thereareonly minor excep-tions to this rule. The reasonfor this rule derivesfrom theper-fection constraintof thedurablegoodsmonopolist,which forceshim in the long run to chargelower pricesthanwouldan uncon-strainedfirm. By reducingthedurability of its output,themo-nopolistcanreducethecostof its perfectionconstraint.

An oligopolist, or amonopolistfacing future entry, hasthesameconsiderationsasthemonopolistplus theextraconsidera-tion ofhowits durability will effectcompetitors’futurestrategies.If the firm facesCournot-Nashcompetition,it will usually findthat increaseddurability will reducecompetitors’future output.Sinceareductionin competitors’outputwill, all elseequal,raiseafirm’s profits, sucholigopolistshaveacountervailingincentiveto increasedurability andmay chooseeitherexcessivelylong orshort lives for their products.

28. For a lucid summaryof theseissuessee Miller andUpton [19761.Ofcourse,the 1981 tax law also createdincentivesfor some firms, most notablyBoeing,to leaseratherthansell. Thereasonis thatwhenequipmentsuchasanairlinerwastransferredabroadbut usedpartially in theUnitedStates,the 1981law allowed the lessora 10 percentinvestmenttax credit andan accelerateddepreciationwriteoff. SeeMerry ~1983].Thistax advantagehassincebeenelim-inated.

29. SeeTable I.30. SeeAndrewPopper,“How theIBM JuggernautWill KeepRolling,” Busi-

nessWeek,July 16, 1984,p. 106.

A THEORYOF PLANNEDOBSOLESCENCE 747

If a firm wishesto deterentry into its markets,then it willpreferlongerdurabilities,orequivalentlyit will haveapreferenceto sell ratherthanrentmoreof its output. Ontheotherhand,ifoligopolistscancolludeto setthedurability oftheindustry’sprod-ucts,theywill optfor someplannedobsolescence.Antitrust policythat requiresdurablegoodsmonopoliststo sell ratherthanrenttheirproductswill reducetheirprofitability but mayalsoreducewelfare.Thus, while suchpolicies reducemonopolypower, theywill not necessarilyaddto efficiency.

The movementsof IBM and Xerox to agreaterrelianceonsalesratherthanrentalsastheyhaveencounteredgreatercom-petitionarelooselyconsistentwith someofthepredictionsofthistheory.

Perhapsthegreatestweaknessofthispaperis that it followsin the tradition of usingdurability asa proxy for obsolescence.This assumption,combinedwith theperfectsecond-handmarketassumption,permits themodel to regardgoodsproducedat dif-ferenttimesashomogeneous,andgreatlysimplifiestheanalysis.But plannedobsolescenceis much more thana matterof dura-bility; it is alsoandperhapsprimarily abouthowoftenafirm willintroducea new product,andhow compatiblethenew productwill be with older versions.In a market suchas textbooks,thepublishers’inability to internalizethecapital lossessufferedbyholdersof usedbooks seemsto leadto excessiveefforts to makesucceedingeditionsof abook incompatiblewith oneanother;thisresultseemsconsistentwith our theory.3’ But in othermarkets,suchasthat for personalcomputers,customersmay value theirpurchasesmorehighly thegreater their expectationsof futuresales.Such marketsarenot well accommodatedby the modelpresentedhere.However,modelingsuchmarketswill necessarilyrequireabandonmentoftheperfectsecond-handmarketassump-tion, becausewith perfect second-handmarketsanddownwardslopingdemandcurvesfirst-periodpurchasersmust necessarilyloseby increasedsecond-periodsales.The inability ofcustomersto resell will introduceconsiderationsakin to thoseof conven-tional price discriminationinto theanalysis.This complication,combinedwith thedifficulty in allowing for productdifferentia-

31. JohnKaplantells thestory of oneof his Stanfordlawstudentsaskingifhe could get by with the previouseditionof Kaplan’stextbookin hiscourse.Theauthorrespondedto thestudent,“If anintelligentpersonis revisinghistextbook,do youthink he’s goingto redoit in suchaway thatyoucanusetheold version?”

748 QUARTERLYJOURNALOF ECONOMICS

tion in anenlighteningway, meansthatfurtheradvancesin thisfield will necessarilyrequiremodelsthataremorecomplexthanthis one.

Theseissuesmeanthatplannedobsolescenceisstill adifficultand poorly understoodtopic. It is my hope,however,that the

A THEORYOFPLANNEDOBSOLESCENCE 749

Miller, MertonH. andCharlesW. Upton,“Leasing,BuyingandtheCostof CapitalServices,”Journal ofFinance,XXXI (June1976)787—98.

Salinger,Michael A., “Tobin’s q’s q, Unionization,andthe Concentration-ProfitsRelationship,”RandJournalofEconomics,XV (Summer1984), 159—70.

Schmalensee,Richard,“Regulationandthe Durability of Goods,”Bell JournalofEconomicGoodsandManagementScience,I (Spring 1970),54—64.,“Market Structure,Durability,andQuality: A SelectiveSurvey,”EconomicInquiry, XVII (April 1979), 177—96.

Sieper,E., and PeterL. Swan, “Monopoly andCompetition in the Market forDurableGoods,”ReviewofEconomicStudies,XL (July 1973),333—51

Sobel,Joel,“The Timing of Sales,”ReviewofEconomicStudies,LI (April 1984),353—68.

Stokey,N. L., “Rational ExpectationsandDurableGoodsPricing,” Bell JournalofEconomics,XII (Spring 1981), 112—28.

Swan, PeterL., “Optimum Durability, Second-HandMarkets,andPlannedOb-solescence,”JournalofPoliticalEconomy,LXXX (May/June1972), 575—85.

—‘ “ProductDurability UnderMonopolyandCompetition:Comment,”Econo-metrica,XLV (Jan.1977), 229—35.

Wolfson,Mark A., ‘Tax, Incentive,andRisk-SharingIssuesin the Allocation ofPropertyRights:The GeneralizedLease-or-BuyProblem,”Journal ofBusi-ness,LVIII A ril 1985)159—72.