49
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

Econ 522Economics of Law

Dan Quint

Fall 2011

Lecture 13

Page 2: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

2

HW3 is online, due next Thursday (Nov 3)

Second midterm is Wednesday Nov 9 Cumulative – covers everything up to end of contract law More weight on more recent material (contracts)

Logistics

Page 3: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

3

Regulations/immutable rules Derogation of public policy

Formation defenses and performance excuses Incompetence (but not drunkenness) Duress and necessity Impossibility, and determining the efficient bearer of a risk

Today: more ways to get out of a contract, and remedies for breach

Last Wednesday…

Page 4: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

4

Derogation of public policy

Page 5: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

5

Old urban legend:A man bought a box of extremely rare and expensive cigars, and insured them against loss or damage.

After smoking them, he filed an insurance claim, saying they had been destroyed in 20 separate small fires.

The insurance company refused to pay, the man sued and won.

But as he was leaving the courtroom, he was arrested on 20 counts of arson.

Serious question:If the intent of a contract is clear, but different from the literal meaning, which should be enforced?

Discussion question

Page 6: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

6

Contracts based onbad information

Page 7: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

7

Four doctrines for invalidating a contract

Fraud

Failure to disclose

Frustration of purpose

Mutual mistake

Contracts based on faulty information

Page 8: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

8

Fraud: one party was deliberately tricked

Fraud

source: http://www.wyff4.com/r/29030818/detail.html

Page 9: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

9

Under the civil law, there is a duty to disclose If you fail to supply information you should have, contract will be

voided – failure to disclose

Less so under the common law Seller only has to share information about hidden dangers… …not information that makes a product less valuable but not

dangerous Exception: new products come with “implied warranty of fitness” Another exception: Obde v Schlemeyer

What if you trick someone by withholding information?

Page 10: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

10

Under common law, seller required to inform buyer about hidden safety risks, generally not other information

But… Obde v Schlemeyer (1960) Seller knew building was infested with termites, did not tell buyer Termites should have been exterminated immediately to prevent

further damage Court in Obde imposed duty to disclose

Duty to disclose under common law

Page 11: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

11

Under common law, seller required to inform buyer about hidden safety risks, generally not other information

But… Obde v Schlemeyer (1960) Seller knew building was infested with termites, did not tell buyer Termites should have been exterminated immediately to prevent

further damage Court in Obde imposed duty to disclose Some states require used car dealers to reveal major repairs done,

sellers of homes to reveal certain types of defects…

Duty to disclose under common law

Page 12: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

12

Frustration of Purpose

Change in circumstance made the original promise pointless

Coronation Cases

“When a contingency makes performance pointless, assign liability to party who can bear risk at least cost”

What if both parties were misinformed?

Page 13: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

13

Frustration of Purpose

Change in circumstance made the original promise pointless

Coronation Cases

“When a contingency makes performance pointless, assign liability to party who can bear risk at least cost”

What if both parties were misinformed?

Mutual Mistake

Mutual mistake about facts Circumstances had already

changed, but we didn’t know Logger buys land with timber

on it, but forest fire had wiped out the timber the week before

Mutual mistake about identity Disagreement over what was

being sold

Page 14: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

14

Hadley v Baxendale (miller and shipper) Hadley knew shipment was time-critical But Baxendale was deciding how to ship crankshaft (boat or train)

A general principle about information: efficiency generally requires uniting knowledge and control Contracts that unite knowledge and control are generally efficient,

should be upheld Contracts that separate knowledge and control may be inefficient,

should more often be set aside

Another principle for allocating risks efficiently: uniting knowledge and control

Page 15: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

15

Mutual mistake: neither party had correct information Contract neither united nor separated knowledge and control

Unilateral mistake: one party has mistaken information I know your car is a valuable antique, you think it’s worthless You sell it to me at a low price

Contracts based on unilateral mistake are generally upheld

Mutual vs. Unilateral Mistake

Page 16: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

16

Mutual mistake: neither party had correct information Contract neither united nor separated knowledge and control

Unilateral mistake: one party has mistaken information I know your car is a valuable antique, you think it’s worthless You sell it to me at a low price

Contracts based on unilateral mistake are generally upheld Contracts based on unilateral mistake generally unite knowledge and

control And, enforcing them creates an incentive to gather information

Unilateral mistake

Page 17: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

17

War of 1812: British blockaded port of New Orleans Price of tobacco fell, since it couldn’t be exported

Organ (tobacco buyer) learned the war was over Immediately negotiated with Laidlaw firm to buy a bunch of tobacco

at the depressed wartime price

Next day, news broke the war had ended, price of tobacco went up, Laidlaw sued Supreme Court ruled that Organ was not required to communicate

his information

Unilateral mistake: Laidlaw v Organ (U.S. Supreme Court, 1815)

Page 18: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

18

Productive information: information that can be used to produce more wealth

Redistributive information: information that can be used to redistribute wealth in favor of informed party

Cooter and Ulen Contracts based on one party’s knowledge of productive information

should be enforced… …especially if that knowledge was the result of active investment Contracts based on one party’s knowledge of purely redistributive

information, or fortuitously acquired information, should not be enforced

Unilateral mistake: productive versus redistributive information

Page 19: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

19

Other reasons a contract may not be enforced

Page 20: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

20

Courts will generally not enforce contract terms that are overly vague

Can be thought of as a penalty default

But some exceptions Parties may commit to renegotiating the contract “in good faith”

under certain contingencies

Vague contract terms

Page 21: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

21

Back when software came on disks or CDs… Box was wrapped in cellophane Inside, “By unwrapping this box, you agree to the following terms…”

If party given no opportunity to review contract, not binding

“Shrink-wrap” licenses

“Due to the unscheduled trip to the autowrecking yard the school bus will be out of commission for two weeks. Note by reading this letter out loud you have waived any responsibility on our part in perpetuity throughout the known universe.”

Page 22: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

22

What if a party chose not to review the contract?

Source: http://www.foxnews.com/scitech/2010/04/15/online-shoppers-unknowingly-sold-souls/

Page 23: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

23

British computer game retailer GameStation, on April Fool’s Day, added this to Terms & Conditions customers agreed to before buying online:

“By placing an order via this website… you agree to grant us anon-transferable option to claim, for now and for ever more, your immortal soul.

Should we wish to exercise this option, you agree to surrender your immortal soul, and any claim you may have on it, within 5 (five) working days of receiving written notification from gamestation.co.uk or one of its duly authorised minions.

…If you a) do not believe you have an immortal soul, b) have already given it to another party, or c) do not wish to grant us such a license, please click the link below to nullify this sub-clause and proceed with your transaction.”

What if a party chose not to review the contract?

Page 24: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

24

Adhesion: standardized “take-it-or-leave-it” contracts where terms are not negotiable “Bogus duress”

Not illegal per se, but might attract “closer scrutiny” A few state courts have adopted a rule: if I put a clause in a

contract that I think you would not agree to if you noticed it, then it doesn’t count

Contracts of adhesion

Page 25: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

25

Under the bargain theory, courts should ask only whether a bargain occurred, not whether it was fair Hamer v Sidway (drinking and smoking)

But both common and civil law have doctrines for not enforcing overly one-sided contracts Unconscionability/Lesion “Absence of meaningful choice on the part of one party due to one-

sided contract provisions, together with terms which are so oppressive that no reasonable person would make them and no fair and honest person would accept them”

When “the sum total of its provisions drives too hard a bargain for a court of conscience to assist”

Terms which would “shock the conscience of the court”

What if you signed a contract that was dramatically unfair?

Page 26: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

26

“Unconscionability has generally been recognized to include an absence of meaningful choice on the part of one of the parties together with contract terms which are unreasonably favorable to the other party.

…In many cases the meaningfulness of the choice is negated by a gross inequality of bargaining power.”

Unconscionability: Williams v Walker-Thomas Furniture (CA Dist Ct, 1965)

Page 27: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

27

“Unconscionability has generally been recognized to include an absence of meaningful choice on the part of one of the parties together with contract terms which are unreasonably favorable to the other party.

…In many cases the meaningfulness of the choice is negated by a gross inequality of bargaining power.”

Unconscionability: Williams v Walker-Thomas Furniture (CA Dist Ct, 1965)

Page 28: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

28

“Unconscionability has generally been recognized to include an absence of meaningful choice on the part of one of the parties together with contract terms which are unreasonably favorable to the other party.

…In many cases the meaningfulness of the choice is negated by a gross inequality of bargaining power.”

Not normal monopoly cases but “situational monopolies” Think of Ploof v Putnam (sailboat in a storm), not Microsoft

Unconscionability: Williams v Walker-Thomas Furniture (CA Dist Ct, 1965)

Page 29: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

29

Remedies for breachof contract

Page 30: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

30

Party-designed remedies Remedies specified in the contract

Court-imposed damages Court may decide promisee entitled to some level of damages

Specific performance Forces breaching party to live up to contract

Three broad types of remedy for breach of contract

Page 31: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

31

Compensate promisee for the amount he expected to benefit from performance You agreed to buy an airplane for $350,000 You expected $500,000 of benefit from it Expectation damages: if I breach, I owe you that benefit ($500,000 if you already paid, $150,000 if you didn’t)

“Positive damages”

Make promisee indifferent between performance and breach

Expectation damages

Page 32: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

32

Reimburse promisee for cost of any reliance investments made, but not for additional surplus he expected to gain

Restore promisee to level of well-being before he signed the contract You contracted to buy the plane and built a hangar If I breach, I owe you what you spent on the hangar, nothing else

“Negative damages” – undo the negative (harm) that occurred

Reliance damages

Page 33: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

33

Give promisee benefit he would have gotten from his next-best option Make promisee indifferent between breach of the contract that

was signed, and performance of best alternative contract You value plane at $500,000 You contract to buy plane from me for $350,000 Someone else was selling similar plane for $400,000 By the time I breach, that plane is no longer available I owe you $100,000 – the benefit you would have gotten from

buying the other seller’s plane

Opportunity cost damages

Page 34: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

34

You agree to sell me ticket to Wisconsin-Purdue football game for $50 Expectation damages: you owe me value of game minus $50 If I pay scalper $150, then expectation damages = $100 Reliance damages: maybe 0, or cost of

whatever pre-game investments I made

Example: expectation, reliance, and opportunity cost damages

Page 35: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

35

You agree to sell me ticket to Wisconsin-Purdue football game for $50 Expectation damages: you owe me value of game minus $50 If I pay scalper $150, then expectation damages = $100 Reliance damages: maybe 0, or cost of

whatever pre-game investments I made When you agreed to sell me ticket, other

tickets available for $70 Opportunity cost damages: $80 (I paid a scalper $150 to get in; I would

have been $80 better off if I’d ignored your offer and paid someone else $70)

Example: expectation, reliance, and opportunity cost damages

Page 36: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

36

Ranking damages

ExpectationDamages

Opportunity CostDamages

RelianceDamages

ContractI Sign

BestAlternative

Do Nothing

Breach +ExpectationDamages

Breach +Opportunity Cost

Damages

Breach +RelianceDamages

$100 $80 $15

Page 37: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

37

Hawkins had a scar on his hand

McGee promised surgery to “make the hand a hundred percent perfect”

Surgery was a disaster, left scar bigger and covered with hair

Hawkins v McGee (“hairy hand case”)

Page 38: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

38

Hawkins v McGee (“hairy hand case”)

Hairy Scarred Nextbest

doctor

100%Perfect

$

Hand

Initial Wealth

+ Reliance Damages

+ Opp Cost Damages

+ Expectation Damages

Rel

ianc

e D

amag

es

Opp

Cos

t Dam

ages

Exp

ecta

tion

Dam

ages

Page 39: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

39

Restitution Return money that was already received

Disgorgement Give up wrongfully-gained profits

Other court-ordered remedies

Page 40: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

40

Restitution Return money that was already received

Disgorgement Give up wrongfully-gained profits

Specific Performance Promisor is forced to honor promise Civil law: often ordered instead of money damages Common law: money damages more common; S.P. sometimes used

when seller breaches contract to sell a unique good Like injunctive relief

Other court-ordered remedies

Page 41: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

41

Peevyhouse v Garland Coal and Mining Co(OK Supreme Court, 1962) Garland contracted to strip-mine

coal on Peevyhouse’s farm Contract specified Garland

would restore property to originalcondition; Garland did not

Restoration would cost $29,000 But “diminution in value” of farm

was only $300 Original jury awarded $5,000 in

damages, both parties appealed OK Supreme Court reduced

damages to $300

Expectation damages vs. specific performance

Page 42: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

42

At first, sounds like a perfect example of efficient breach Performing last part of contract would cost $29,000 Benefit to Peevyhouses would be $300 Efficient to breach and pay expectation damages, which is what

happened

But… Most coal mining contracts: standard per-acre diminution payment Peevyhouses refused to sign contract unless it specifically promised the

restorative work Dissent: Peevyhouses entitled to specific performance (Peevyhouses seemed to value condition of property much more highly

than change in market value)

Expectation damages vs. specific performance

Page 43: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

43

Contract promised restoration work, didn’t specify remedy if it wasn’t performed

Which default rule works better: Default rule allowing Garland to breach and pay diminution fee? Default rule forcing Garland to perform restoration work?

Ayres and Gertner: default rule should penalize the better-informed party Garland routinely signed contracts like these Peevyhouses were doing this for the first time Default rule allows Garland to pay diminution fee: they have no reason to

bring it up, Peevyhouses don’t know Default rule forces Garland to do cleanup: if that’s inefficient, they could

bring it up during negotiations In this case, specific performance would serve as a penalty default

Think about Peevyhouse in terms of penalty defaults

Page 44: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

44

Remedy for breach could be written directly into contract

But common law courts don’t always enforce remedy terms Liquidated damages – party-specified damages that reasonably

approximate actual harm done by breach Penalty damages – damages greater than actual harm done Civil law courts are generally willing to enforce penalty damages But common law courts often do not

Party-designed remedies

Page 45: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

45

Peevyhouse v Garland Coal Peevyhouses only wanted farm strip-mined if it would be restored

to original condition after Suppose coal extracted worth $70,000 Garland paid $25,000 for rights to mine it Restoration work would cost $30,000 Diminution of value was $300 So liquidated damages would be $300 Suppose Peevyhouses got $40,000 of disutility from land being left

in poor condition

Penalty DamagesCoal worth $70,000Garland to pay $25,000Restoration would cost $30,000Liquidated damages are $300Peevyhouses value restoration at $40,000

Page 46: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

46

Liquidated damages

Peevyhouses

Sign Don’t

Garland Coal

Restore property Don’t, pay damages

(25,000, 15,000) (-14,700, 44,700)

(0, 0)

If damages limited to liquidated damages… Peevyhouses shouldn’t believe restorative work will get done So Peevyhouses better off refusing to sign Even though mining and restoring Pareto-dominates

Coal worth $70,000Garland to pay $25,000Restoration would cost $30,000Liquidated damages are $300Peevyhouses value restoration at $40,000

Page 47: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

47

Penalty damages

Peevyhouses

Sign Don’t

Garland Coal

Restore property Don’t, pay penalty

(25,000, 15,000) (25,000, 5,000)

(0, 0)

Coal worth $70,000Garland to pay $25,000Restoration would cost $30,000Liquidated damages are $300Peevyhouses value restoration at $40,000

If penalty clauses in contracts enforceable… Write contract with $40,000 penalty for leaving land unrestored Now restoration work would get done, so Peevyhouses willing to sign But if courts won’t enforce penalty damages, this won’t work

Page 48: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

48

Whatever you can accomplish with penalty clause, you could also accomplish with performance bonus I agree to pay $200,000 to get house built, but I want you to pay a

$50,000 penalty if it’s late Alternatively: I agree to pay $150,000 for house, plus a $50,000

performance bonus if it’s completed on time Either way, you get $150,000 if house is late, $200,000 if on time Courts generally enforce bonus clauses, so no problem!

Penalty clauses

Page 49: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 13

49

Whatever you can accomplish with penalty clause, you could also accomplish with performance bonus I agree to pay $200,000 to get house built, but I want you to pay a

$50,000 penalty if it’s late Alternatively: I agree to pay $150,000 for house, plus a $50,000

performance bonus if it’s completed on time Either way, you get $150,000 if house is late, $200,000 if on time Courts generally enforce bonus clauses, so no problem! Similarly, Peevyhouse example

Peevyhouses get $25,000 for mining rights, $40,000 penalty if land is not restored

Equivalently, get $65,000 for mining rights, pay $40,000 bonus if restoration is completed

But, if intent of contract is too transparent, still might not be enforced

Penalty clauses