45
Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

Econ 522Economics of Law

Dan Quint

Fall 2011

Lecture 19

Page 2: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

2

MT2 graded, will be returned today

HW4 (last one) online – due Thurs Dec 8 Longer than last couple

Logistics

Page 3: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

3

Monday’sexperiment

Page 4: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

4

You have been asked to serve on a jury on a lawsuit dealing with personal injury. In the case before you, a 50-year-old construction worker was injured on the job due to the negligence of his employer. As a result, this man had his right leg amputated at the knee. Due to this disability, he cannot return to the construction trade and has few other skills with which he could pursue alternative employment.

The negligence of the employer has been firmly established, and health insurance covered all of the related medical expenses. Therefore, your job is to determine how to compensate this worker for the loss of his livelihood and the reduction in his quality of life.

Experiment

Page 5: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

5

What were we trying to test?

(a) Should the plaintiff in this case be awarded more or less than $10,000?

(b) How much should the plaintiff receive? (Please give a number.)

(c) Are you male or female?

The other half were asked…Half of you were asked…

(a) Should the plaintiff in this case be awarded more or less than $10,000,000?

(b) How much should the plaintiff receive? (Please give a number.)

(c) Are you male or female?

The question: how much did the “suggestion” affect answers to question (b)?

Page 6: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

6

The results

Page 7: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

7

The results

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

up to 100k 100k to300k

300k to900k

900k to3MM

3MM to9MM

more than9MM

asked 10k

asked 10MM

Page 8: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

8

The results

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

up to 100k 100k to300k

300k to900k

900k to3MM

3MM to9MM

more than9MM

asked 10k

asked 10MM

Page 9: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

9

The results

1,000,000100,00025th Percentile

80%36%% at least $1 MM

22,500,00010,750,806Largest

4.6 x

5,000,0001,000,00075th Percentile

1,600,000250,000Median

140,00050,000Smallest

5.5 x2,086,764382,653Geometric Mean

3,892,0001,294,355Average

RatioAsked

$10,000,000Asked

$10,000

3.0 x

Page 10: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

10

The results

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

up to 500k 500k to 2MM more than 2MM

asked 10k

asked 10MM

Page 11: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

11

Nobody knows what a leg is worth

“Reference point bias”

“Framing effects”

What does it mean?

Page 12: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

12

Back to work…

Page 13: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

13

Punitivedamages

Page 14: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

14

Damage awards vary greatly across countries, even across individual cases

We saw last week: As long as damages are correct on average, random inconsistency

doesn’t affect incentives (under either strict liability or negligence)

But, if appropriate level of damages isn’t well-established, more incentive to spend more fighting

Inconsistency of damages

Page 15: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

15

What we’ve discussed so far: compensatory damages Meant to “make victim whole”/compensate for actual damage done

In addition, courts sometimes award punitive damages Additional damages meant to punish injurer Create stronger incentive to avoid initial harm

Punitive damages generally not awarded for innocent mistakes, but may be used when injurer’s behavior was

“malicious, oppressive, gross, willful and wanton, or fraudulent”

Punitive damages

Page 16: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

16

Calculation of punitive damages even less well-defined than compensatory damages

Level of punitive damages supposed to bear “reasonable relationship” to level of compensatory damages Not clear exactly what this means U.S. Supreme Court: punitive damages more than ten times

compensatory damages will attract “close scrutiny,” but not explicitly ruled out

Punitive damages

Page 17: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

17

Stella Liebeck was badly burned when she spilled a cup of McDonalds coffee in her lap

Awarded $160,000 in compensatory damages, plus $2.9 million in punitive damages

Case became “poster child” for excessive damages, but…

Example of punitive damages: Liebeck v McDonalds (1994) (“the coffee cup case”)

Page 18: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

18

Stella Liebeck dumped coffee in her lap while adding cream/sugar Third degree burns, 8 days in hospital, skin grafts, 2 years treatment Initially sued for $20,000, mostly for medical costs McDonalds offered to settle for $800

McDonalds serves coffee at 180-190 degrees At 180 degrees, coffee can cause a third-degree burn requiring skin grafts

in 12-15 seconds Lower temperature would increase length of exposure necessary McDonalds had received 700 prior complaints of burns, and had settled

with some of the victims Quality control manager testified that 700 complaints, given how many cups

of coffee McDonalds serves, was not sufficient for McDonalds to reexamine practices

Liebeck v McDonalds (1994)

Page 19: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

19

Rule in place was comparative negligence Jury found both parties negligent, McDonalds 80% responsible Calculated compensatory damages of $200,000 times 80% gives $160,000 Added $2.9 million in punitive damages Judge reduced punitive damages to 3X compensatory, making total

damages $640,000 During appeal, parties settled out of court for some smaller amount

Jury seemed to be using punitive damages to punish McDonalds for being arrogant and uncaring

Liebeck v McDonalds (1994)

Page 20: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

20

We’ve said all along: with perfect compensation, incentives for injurer are set correctly. So why punitive damages?

Example… Suppose manufacturer can eliminate 10 accidents a year, each causing

$1,000 in damages, for $9,000 Clearly efficient If every accident victim would sue and win, company has incentive to

take this precaution But if some won’t, then not enough incentive Suppose only half the victims will bring successful lawsuits Compensatory damages would be $5,000; company is better off paying

that then taking efficient precaution One way to fix this: award higher damages in the cases that are brought

What is the economic purpose of punitive damages?

Page 21: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

21

Punitive damages should be related to compensatory damages, but higher the more likely injurer is to “get away with it” If 50% of accidents will lead to successful lawsuits, total damages

should be 2 X harm Which requires punitive damages = compensatory damages If 10% of accidents lead to awards, damages should be 10 X harm So punitive damages should be 9 X compensatory damages

Seems most appropriate when injurer’s actions were deliberately fraudulent, since may have been based on cost-benefit analysis of chance of being caught

This suggests…

Page 22: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

22

Some empirical observations about tort system in the U.S.

Page 23: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

23

In 1990s, tort cases passed contract cases as most common form of lawsuit Most handled at state level: in 1994, 41,000 tort cases resolved in federal

courts, 378,000 in state courts in largest 75 counties Most involve a single plaintiff (many contract cases involve multiple

plaintiffs)

Among tort cases in 75 largest U.S. counties… 60% were auto accidents 17% were “premises liability” (slip-and-fall in restaurants, businesses,

government offices, etc.) 5% were medical malpractice 3% were product liability

U.S. tort system

Page 24: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

24

Punitive damages historically very rare 1965-1990, punitive damages in product liability cases were awarded

353 times Average damage award was $625,000, reduced to $135,000 on

appeal Average punitive damages only slightly higher than compensatory

In many states, punitive damages limited, or require higher standard of evidence Civil suits generally require “preponderance of evidence” In many states, punitive damages require “clear and convincing”

evidence

U.S. tort system

Page 25: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

25

Medical malpractice New York study in 1980s: 1% of hospital admissions involved

serious injury due to negligent care Some estimates: 5% of total health care costs are “defensive

medicine” – procedures undertaken purely to prevent lawsuits Some states have considered caps on damages for medical

malpractice

U.S. tort system

Page 26: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

26

Product liability Recent survey of CEOs: “liability concerns caused 47% of those

surveyed to drop one or more product lines, 25% to stop some research and development, and 39% to cancel plans for a new product.”

Liability standard for product-related accidents is “strict products liability” Manufacturer is liable if product determined to be defective Defect in design Defect in manufacture Defect in warning

U.S. tort system

Page 27: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

27

Most vaccines are weakened version of disease itself Make you much less likely to acquire the disease But often come with very small chance of contracting disease

directly from vaccine Sabin polio vaccine wiped out polio, but caused 1 in 4,000,000

people vaccinated to contract polio

1974 case established maker had to warn about risk Since then, some people were awarded damages after their

children developed polio from vaccine If liability can’t be avoided, built into cost of the drug And discourages companies from developing vaccines

Vaccines

Page 28: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

28

Since health risks of asbestos understood, over 600,000 people have brought lawsuits against 6,000 defendants

DES (drug administered to pregnant women in 1950s) Impossible to establish which firm produced dose given to a particular

woman California Supreme Court introduced “market share liability”

Class action lawsuit Small, dispersed harms – no plaintiff might find it worthwhile to sue Class action suits allow large lawsuits with lots of plaintiffs Give more incentive for precaution against diffuse harms But…

Mass torts

Page 29: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

29

Critics claim juries routinely hand out excessive awards and tort system is out of control…

…but actually it functions reasonably well

Outside of occasional, well-publicized outliers, damage awards are generally reasonable…

…and liability has led to decreases in accidents in many industries

Cooter and Ulen’s overall assessment of U.S. tort system

Page 30: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

30

“A tort plaintiff succeeded in collecting a large damage judgment.

The defendant’s attorney, confident that the claimed injury was bogus, went over to the plaintiff after the trial

and warned him that if he was ever seen out of his wheelchair he would be back in court on a charge of fraud.

The plaintiff replied that to save the lawyer the cost of having him followed, he would be happy to describe his travel plans.

He reached into his pocket and drew out an airline ticket –

to Lourdes, the site of a Catholic shrine famous for miracles.”

To wrap up tort law, a funny story from Friedman…

Page 31: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

31

The legalprocess

Page 32: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

32

Developed theories of property/nuisance law, contract law, and tort law

Looked at how rules of legal liability create incentives

Thought about how these rules can be chosen to try to achieve efficient outcomes

Over the last 2 ½ months, we have…

Page 33: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

33

To achieve efficiency, we’ve generally tried to set a party’s liability equal to the harm he caused someone else Damages in nuisance law Expectation damages in contract law Compensatory damages in tort law That way, he internalizes the externality he imposes, leading to

efficient decisions

In doing this, we’ve been making two big assumptions: The legal system works flawlessly The legal system costs nothing

Over the last 2 ½ months, we have…

Page 34: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

34

I hit you with my car and did $10,000 worth of damage We both know I was negligent But courts aren’t perfect If we go to trial, 80% chance I’ll be found liable, 20% I won’t If I’m held liable, damages are correctly set at $10,000 So on average, if we go to trial, you expect to recover $8,000

But if we go to trial, we both have to hire lawyers Suppose this costs us each $3,000 Now your expected gain from going to trial is $8,000 – 3,000 = 5,000 And my expected cost is $8,000 + 3,000 = 11,000

An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

Page 35: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

35

So… Going to trial gains you $5,000 (in expectation) Going to trial costs me $11,000 (in expectation)

Maybe we can settle out of court If we avoid going to court and I pay you any settlement between

$5,000 and $11,000, we’re both better off So maybe this happens

But…

An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

Page 36: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

36

Suppose I’m more pessimistic about my chances than you You think I’m 80% likely to be found liable I think I’m 90% likely to be found liable

You think your expected gain is $8,000 – 3,000 = $5,000

I think my expected cost is $9,000 + 3,000 = $12,000

Now the range of possible settlements is even wider Any settlement between $5,000 and $12,000 is a Pareto-improvement

over going to trial So settling is more likely

An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

Page 37: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

37

Now instead, suppose I’m more optimistic about my chances than you You think I’m 80% likely to be found liable I think I’m only 10% likely to be found liable

You think your expected gain is $8,000 – 3,000 = $5,000

I think my expected cost is $1,000 + 3,000 = $4,000

Now an out-of-court settlement is impossible There are no settlements that you and I would both agree to

An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

Page 38: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

38

And, even if our beliefs are compatible and there are settlements that we would both prefer to trial…

…private information might lead to failure to reach a settlement Remember from before: if our threat points are private

information, we might fail to reach an agreement because each of us is holding out for too big a share

So even if we had the same beliefs about what will happen at trial, private information could prevent settlement

An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

Page 39: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

39

So when litigation is costly… If the two parties agree on the likely outcome of a trial, there are

gains from settling out of court, and a range of settlements they would both prefer to going to trial

If the two parties are relatively pessimistic, settlement is even more likely

If the two parties are relatively optimistic, settlement may be impossible

Even if the two have the same beliefs or are relatively pessimistic, private information may lead to failures in bargaining

An example from Polinsky, “An Introduction to Law and Economics”

Page 40: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

40

Under strict liability… We said injurers internalize cost of accidents efficient precaution But this assumes cost of being sued = damage done If courts are unpredictable and litigation is costly, private cost of being

sued for damages could be > or < cost of accident Which could lead to too much or too little precaution

But also… If settlement talks break down and cases go to trial… …then total social cost of an accident includes the harm done, and the

resources expended during the trial! If trial costs $6,000, then social cost of the accident isn’t $10,000, but

$16,000 – which increases the efficient level of precaution!

So what?

Page 41: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

41

The legalprocess

Page 42: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

42

Tort law: efficiency meant minimizing the total social cost of accidents Actual cost of accidents Plus cost of actions taken to prevent them (precaution)

Goal of the legal process: minimize its social costs Direct (administrative) costs Error costs

The goal of the legal process

Page 43: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

43

Administrative costs Hiring judges, building courthouse, paying jurors… More complex process higher cost

Error costs Any legal process is imperfect Errors are any judgments that differ from theoretically perfect ones An error in computing damages after the fact only affects distribution,

not efficiency But anticipated errors affect incentives, which may lead to actions

which aren’t efficient Error costs are costs of distortions in actions people take

(precaution, activity levels, etc.) due to flaws in legal system

Administrative costs and error costs

Page 44: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

44

So theoretically, the efficient legal process is the one that minimizes the sum of…

The direct costs of administering the system, and

The economic effects of errors due to that process not being perfect

The goal of the legal process

Page 45: Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 19

45

Nice job!

Similar distribution to first – mean 84, median 85

Again, not actually assigning letter grades till after final…

…but roughly, 80-88 is about the B range

Midterm

A-G N-ZH-M