46
Figure 13.1 Tariff- inclusive price

Figure 13.1

  • Upload
    lee

  • View
    70

  • Download
    1

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

Figure 13.1. Tariff-inclusive price. Fig. 19.3. Fig. 19.4. Source: IMF WEO 07. Tariff Structures and Effective Protection. The nominal tariff rate, t , is. (13.1). Where p ′ is the tariff-inclusive price p is the free trade price. Tariff Structures and Effective Protection. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

Citation preview

Page 1: Figure 13.1

Figure 13.1

Tariff-inclusive price

Page 2: Figure 13.1
Page 3: Figure 13.1
Page 4: Figure 13.1

Single good, small country Import tariff: Welfare loss Revenue gain Distribution issues (producers gain/lobby) Domestic producer subsidy Welfare loss (though less than tariff) Revenue cost Distribution issues (producers gain/lobby)

Page 5: Figure 13.1

Quotas Equivalent to tariff in protection terms

(if no uncertainty) Revenue cost Distribution even more toward producers/importers Uncertainty makes tariffs and quotas non-equivalent.

Tariff leaves quantity of imports uncertain Quota leaves domestic price uncertain

Page 6: Figure 13.1

Export subsidy Welfare loss Revenue cost Distribution issues If downward sloping world demand curve then

may be terms of trade cost Whole economy: uniform import tariff = uniform export tax

Page 7: Figure 13.1

These are the static effects. Arguably more important in the long-run are: Dynamic effects: Infant industry argument (learning by doing, Horndal effect) Competitive pressure argument

(Productivity only way to survive) And

Problem of rent-seeking and corruption associated with discretionary trade restrictions

Page 8: Figure 13.1

Source: IMF WEO 07

Page 9: Figure 13.1
Page 10: Figure 13.1
Page 11: Figure 13.1

Tariff Structures and Effective Protection

p

ppt

The nominal tariff rate, t, is

Wherep′ is the tariff-inclusive pricep is the free trade price

(13.1)

Page 12: Figure 13.1

Tariff Structures and Effective Protection

v

vvg

The effective tariff rate, g, is

Wherev′ is the value added per unit of output,inclusive of the tariffv is the value added per unit of outputunder free trade

(13.2)

Page 13: Figure 13.1

Table 13.1

Page 14: Figure 13.1

Small positive effects reflect: 1. Monopolistic intermediaries meant that only about half the price increase passed to farmers 2. India acts as monopsonistic buyer of raw cashews (Terms of trade loss from additional output) 3. Weak supply response – little new planting (Maybe due lack of confidence that policy will stick).

Page 15: Figure 13.1
Page 16: Figure 13.1

Figure 13.3

Page 17: Figure 13.1

Free trade bad for the poorest?

• Panagariya’s six fallacies (World Economy, 2005)

• Surprising facts neglected in the debate about Doha

• No obvious political bias—some strange bedfellows

• (Oxfam and the IMF MD both sign up to most of them)

• Relates to current discussion about rising food prices and the poor.

http://www.blackwell-synergy.com/doi/pdf/10.1111/j.1467-9701.2005.00734.x?cookieSet=1

Page 18: Figure 13.1

Panagariya’s six fallacies

1. Agricultural border protection and subsidies are largely a rich country thing

2. Rich country subsidies and protection …hurt the poorest countries most

3. …hurt the poor rural households in the poorest countries

4. …constitute the principal barrier to the development of the poorest countries

5. Agricultural protection reflects double standards and hypocrisy in the rich countries

6. Benefits of aid to the poorest countries are more than offset by the losses from developed countries

Page 19: Figure 13.1

Panagariya’s six fallacies

Implications:

A Doha round fully liberalizing trade could badly damage the poorest countries

Though it would be good for middle income countries

And for the world as a whole,

The poorest countries would need to be compensated for this loss

Page 20: Figure 13.1

Different groups

• Least Developed Countries– Most of Africa, Afghanistan, Bangladesh,

Cambodia, Nepal etc.

• Cairns Group– With strong comparative advantage in Ag– Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa

Roca, Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, South Africa, Thailand and Uruguay

• Other developing countries– (mixed bag includes India, China….)

Page 21: Figure 13.1

Panagariya’s six fallacies

1. Agricultural border protection and subsidies are largely a rich country thing

2. Rich country subsidies and protection …hurt the poorest countries most

3. …hurt the poor rural households in the poorest countries

4. …constitute the principal barrier to the development of the poorest countries

5. Agricultural protection reflects double standards and hypocrisy in the rich countries

6. Benefits of aid to the poorest countries are more than offset by the losses from developed countries

Page 22: Figure 13.1

60

40

20

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

NOR

CHEIS

LEU15

NZDUSA

CANAUS

IND

TUNRO

MCO

LBG

DTUR

KOR

VENPO

LLK

AID

NM

EXBRA PHI

THAARG

HUNM

YSCZE

IPN

Bound tariff

% of goods duty free

Page 23: Figure 13.1

Bound and Actual Tariffs

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

0 50 100 150 200

Bound

Act

ua

l

Page 24: Figure 13.1

Panagariya’s six fallacies

1. Agricultural border protection and subsidies are largely a rich country thing

2. Rich country subsidies and protection …hurt the poorest countries most

3. …hurt the poor rural households in the poorest countries

4. …constitute the principal barrier to the development of the poorest countries

5. Agricultural protection reflects double standards and hypocrisy in the rich countries

6. Benefits of aid to the poorest countries are more than offset by the losses from developed countries

Page 25: Figure 13.1

The Key Step in the Argument• Poorest countries already have free access under EBA

• And therefore they benefit from measures that raise internal EU prices (such as export subsidies)

• Importing LeastDCs also benefit from EU’s export and output subsidies (as they both lower the world price)

• Lower import price; higher export price for LeastDCs

• (But what about Cotton?)

Page 26: Figure 13.1

EU output subsidies lower world price

• EU is large enough to affect the world price

• So exporters in the rest of the world selling their agricultural produce at the world price are made worse off by the EU output subsidy.

• Importers in ROW benefit from EU output subsidy

• For simplicity the figure shows things as if only an output subsidy exists – in fact there are also tariffs and export subsidies

Page 27: Figure 13.1

EU ROW

Page 28: Figure 13.1

EU export subsidies raise the internal EU price above world price

• This benefits EU producers…

…but also exporters from LeastDCs who can sell directly into the EU market without tariffs

• It also lowers the world price, which is good for food importers in ROW

• Losers are other exporters from outside the EU

Page 29: Figure 13.1

EU ROW

Page 30: Figure 13.1

At least in the short-run• Many of the poorest countries are net importers of food and of

agricultural products

• (But what about Cotton?)Yes, it’s an exception

EU doesn’t produce it, so no big production subsidiesAnd it is an important export of some LeastDCs

• Another caveat: regulatory, sanitary and phytosanitary (plant health) requirements represent significant barriers

• On the other hand:it’s not just the EU’s “Everything but Aid” initiative: US “Africa Growth and Opportunity Act” (among other regionally focused initiatives) also provides duty free access for a lot.

Page 31: Figure 13.1

Many LICs are net importers of food

Page 32: Figure 13.1

Many LICs are net importers of agric prods

Page 33: Figure 13.1

In the longer run

• Importers can become exporters

• Maybe quite quickly…

• Dynamic effects need to be taken into a/c

• But internal conditions and policies key to ability of LeastDCs to take advantage

Page 34: Figure 13.1
Page 35: Figure 13.1

Panagariya’s six fallacies

1. Agricultural border protection and subsidies are largely a rich country thing

2. Rich country subsidies and protection …hurt the poorest countries most

3. …hurt the poor rural households in the poorest countries

4. …constitute the principal barrier to the development of the poorest countries

5. Agricultural protection reflects double standards and hypocrisy in the rich countries

6. Benefits of aid to the poorest countries are more than offset by the losses from developed countries

The other “fallacies are a bit rhetorical, making the general point that over-concentration on trade liberalization could lead to a backlash in countries where the most crucial barriers to growth are non-trade

Page 36: Figure 13.1

World Bank Global Economic Prospects 2005

Page 37: Figure 13.1
Page 38: Figure 13.1
Page 39: Figure 13.1
Page 40: Figure 13.1

Trading blocs in the global South

Page 41: Figure 13.1
Page 42: Figure 13.1
Page 43: Figure 13.1

Regional preference within Africa?

• Africa's non-oil exports are concentrated in a few products, none of them important regional imports.

• There is relatively little intra-African trade and the mismatch between African exports and imports cannot quickly change.

• Moreover, intra-African trade is highly concentrated, geographically, with almost no trade between East and West Africa.

• This finding makes less compelling the arguments that regional trade can help overcome problems of small domestic markets.

• Giving preference to imports from other African countries risks making your own exports uncompetitive in the world market

• In short, regional trade agreements seem to present Africa with a "lose-lose" situation.

Yeats, 1998

Page 44: Figure 13.1

Nunn QJE 2008

Page 45: Figure 13.1
Page 46: Figure 13.1