7
American Journal of Transplantation 2006; 6: 1257–1263 Blackwell Munksgaard C 2006 The Authors Journal compilation C 2006 The American Society of Transplantation and the American Society of Transplant Surgeons doi: 10.1111/j.1600-6143.2006.01329.x Minireview Financial Outcomes in Transplantation—A Provider’s Perspective M. M. Abecassis Feinberg School of Medicine, Northwestern University, Chicago, Illinois, USA Corresponding author: Michael M. Abecassis, [email protected] Despite a relatively large body of literature on health- care economics, including the economics of transplan- tation, there is a paucity of literature on financial out- comes of transplant procedures. Yet, there is a great need for transplant professionals to understand the fi- nancial elements of their transplant programs. These include, among others, reimbursement, cost and net income. This type of analysis requires a thorough understanding of the complex interactions between payers and providers of care and an understanding of accounting practices within the individual institution including the details of cost accounting. This minire- view will address the essential components of the eval- uation of financial outcomes in transplantation. Key words: Business of transplantation, finance, financial evaluation, financial outcomes, transplant center economics, transplant profitability Received 18 January 2006, revised 17 February 2006 and accepted for publication 21 February 2006 Introduction In the past, the majority of physicians and surgeons have not paid as much attention to financial outcomes as they have to clinical outcomes. Although health-care economic studies have been used to evaluate new medical treat- ments and technologies, these analyses have typically fo- cused on cost-effectiveness (1,2), and not on financial out- comes. Transplantation procedures have been evaluated for cost-effectiveness utilizing various paradigms, and al- though the details of these economic evaluations contain multiple assumptions that may question the relevance of the analyses, in general, transplantation is felt to be cost- effective (3). For example, it is well established that kidney transplantation is cost-effective by reducing cost in the long-term when compared to chronic dialysis. Economic analyses, such as cost-effectiveness studies, measure societal relative values defined by specific economic pa- rameters. For instance, the value of a new technology is evaluated in the context of a pareto-optimal perspective in order to maximize the total societal value. Thus, the cost of an intervention is compared to the cost of other thera- peutic options to determine if the intervention in question results in overall cost reduction. Alternatively, the cost of a procedure is compared to the societal gain measured by quality-adjusted life years saved. In most studies, a dollar value is assigned to each life year saved, in order to cal- culate the potential economic benefit of the intervention under evaluation. In contrast to these types of economic analyses, financial evaluations are calculations of cost ver- sus revenue (4). Financial outcomes are defined by a num- ber of ‘margins’. The bottom line of a financial evaluation consists of a margin which is in turn defined by the reim- bursement (revenue) minus the total cost (production cost) for a specific procedure. Financial outcomes in transplan- tation can be calculated for a specific patient encounter or procedure based on knowledge of the cost allocated to the encounter and of the specific revenue recognized for the particular encounter. Alternatively, aggregate financial evaluations can be performed for a spectrum of services provided for a particular transplant recipient, for a cohort of recipients from a single payer, for organ-specific cohorts and for the transplant program as a whole at a particular institution. An accurate evaluation of the financial outcome for a clinical event is predicated on a clear understanding of the accounting practices that determine cost allocation and revenue recognition, including any reconciliation that may occur downstream in the revenue cycle. One of the caveats of financial analyses is that cost-accounting prac- tices may vary greatly between institutions. For instance, an institution may choose to allocate indirect costs to the transplant cost center, thus magnifying its impact on the profitability of the transplant program, whereas another institution may elect to allocate those costs across the institution as a whole, thus improving the profitability of the transplant cost center. Therefore, any financial evalu- ation must be adjusted for accounting practices, such as allocation of indirect costs, which may impact the calcula- tion of the production costs. Similarly, the revenue is de- fined by the type of contractual agreement between the payer and the provider for the particular service provided, as well as by the manner in which the provider recog- nizes revenue in a particular revenue cycle, especially in the context of reimbursement for bundled services. This mini-review will provide a framework for evaluating finan- cial outcomes in transplantation specifically from a provider perspective. 1257

Financial Outcomes in Transplantation—A Provider's Perspective

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

American Journal of Transplantation 2006; 6: 1257–1263Blackwell Munksgaard

C© 2006 The AuthorsJournal compilation C© 2006 The American Society of

Transplantation and the American Society of Transplant Surgeons

doi: 10.1111/j.1600-6143.2006.01329.xMinireview

Financial Outcomes in Transplantation—A Provider’sPerspective

M. M. Abecassis∗

Feinberg School of Medicine, Northwestern University,Chicago, Illinois, USA∗Corresponding author: Michael M. Abecassis,[email protected]

Despite a relatively large body of literature on health-care economics, including the economics of transplan-tation, there is a paucity of literature on financial out-comes of transplant procedures. Yet, there is a greatneed for transplant professionals to understand the fi-nancial elements of their transplant programs. Theseinclude, among others, reimbursement, cost and netincome. This type of analysis requires a thoroughunderstanding of the complex interactions betweenpayers and providers of care and an understanding ofaccounting practices within the individual institutionincluding the details of cost accounting. This minire-view will address the essential components of the eval-uation of financial outcomes in transplantation.

Key words: Business of transplantation, finance,financial evaluation, financial outcomes, transplantcenter economics, transplant profitability

Received 18 January 2006, revised 17 February 2006and accepted for publication 21 February 2006

Introduction

In the past, the majority of physicians and surgeons have

not paid as much attention to financial outcomes as they

have to clinical outcomes. Although health-care economic

studies have been used to evaluate new medical treat-

ments and technologies, these analyses have typically fo-

cused on cost-effectiveness (1,2), and not on financial out-

comes. Transplantation procedures have been evaluated

for cost-effectiveness utilizing various paradigms, and al-

though the details of these economic evaluations contain

multiple assumptions that may question the relevance of

the analyses, in general, transplantation is felt to be cost-

effective (3). For example, it is well established that kidney

transplantation is cost-effective by reducing cost in the

long-term when compared to chronic dialysis. Economic

analyses, such as cost-effectiveness studies, measure

societal relative values defined by specific economic pa-

rameters. For instance, the value of a new technology is

evaluated in the context of a pareto-optimal perspective in

order to maximize the total societal value. Thus, the cost

of an intervention is compared to the cost of other thera-

peutic options to determine if the intervention in question

results in overall cost reduction. Alternatively, the cost of

a procedure is compared to the societal gain measured by

quality-adjusted life years saved. In most studies, a dollar

value is assigned to each life year saved, in order to cal-

culate the potential economic benefit of the intervention

under evaluation. In contrast to these types of economic

analyses, financial evaluations are calculations of cost ver-

sus revenue (4). Financial outcomes are defined by a num-

ber of ‘margins’. The bottom line of a financial evaluation

consists of a margin which is in turn defined by the reim-

bursement (revenue) minus the total cost (production cost)

for a specific procedure. Financial outcomes in transplan-

tation can be calculated for a specific patient encounter

or procedure based on knowledge of the cost allocated to

the encounter and of the specific revenue recognized for

the particular encounter. Alternatively, aggregate financial

evaluations can be performed for a spectrum of services

provided for a particular transplant recipient, for a cohort

of recipients from a single payer, for organ-specific cohorts

and for the transplant program as a whole at a particular

institution. An accurate evaluation of the financial outcome

for a clinical event is predicated on a clear understanding

of the accounting practices that determine cost allocation

and revenue recognition, including any reconciliation that

may occur downstream in the revenue cycle. One of the

caveats of financial analyses is that cost-accounting prac-

tices may vary greatly between institutions. For instance,

an institution may choose to allocate indirect costs to the

transplant cost center, thus magnifying its impact on the

profitability of the transplant program, whereas another

institution may elect to allocate those costs across the

institution as a whole, thus improving the profitability of

the transplant cost center. Therefore, any financial evalu-

ation must be adjusted for accounting practices, such as

allocation of indirect costs, which may impact the calcula-

tion of the production costs. Similarly, the revenue is de-

fined by the type of contractual agreement between the

payer and the provider for the particular service provided,

as well as by the manner in which the provider recog-

nizes revenue in a particular revenue cycle, especially in

the context of reimbursement for bundled services. This

mini-review will provide a framework for evaluating finan-

cial outcomes in transplantation specifically from a provider

perspective.

1257

Abecassis

Providers and Payers

We will limit the definition of providers to hospitals and

physicians, since most contractual agreements for the pro-

vision of transplant services include these two groups.

It should be clear that the relationship between hospi-

tals and physicians may vary greatly between institutions.

For the physicians, the provider under contract consists

of the physicians’ employer. The hospital may employ the

physicians, and in this case, there is only one contracted

provider, whereas in the case where the physicians are em-

ployed by a practice plan, or the school of medicine, there

are two providers under contract who may need to develop

their own internal contractual agreements: the physicians

and the hospital. For instance, a practice plan may charge

a hospital for services rendered by physicians on behalf of

the hospital’s transplant program. In this case, the hospi-

tal will receive payments from the payer and in turn will

compensate the practice plan for services rendered. Alter-

natively, the physicians and the hospital could both bill the

payer separately, in which case revenue is recognized in-

dividually by each party against their respective charges.

These peculiarities will affect financial evaluations greatly,

especially in the calculation of costs, and in the recognition

of revenue.

The payers can be divided into regulatory payers, namely

Medicare and Medicaid (Center for Medicare and Medi-

caid Services, CMS), and commercial payers. It should be

noted that the commercial payers consist primarily of trans-

plant payer networks. These payers differ greatly from the

typical third-party commercial payer because coverage for

transplant services is typically ‘carved out’ of most pa-

tients’ coverage benefits (5). Therefore, when hospitals

or physician-groups contract for general medical and sur-

gical care of patients covered by specific insurers, trans-

plant benefits are not included. Instead, these carved-out

services are contracted separately. Most insurers will not

contract directly with providers for these services. Rather,

they will outsource contracting for these services to large

transplant payer networks in exchange for some type of

monetary compensation consisting of either part of the

insurance premium fee, or alternatively a ‘broker’ fee of

sorts. Therefore, an insurer will pay a certain amount for a

‘case-rate’, and in turn, the ‘broker’ will pay a contracted

rate to the provider that is the balance of the insurer’s fee

minus the broker’s fee. There are about a dozen such net-

works that manage the majority of transplant procedures

in the United States. These networks compete for insurer

groups to provide ‘transplant network benefits’ to patients

otherwise insured by third-party payers. Reimbursement

from the regulatory payers is straightforward for the most

part, whereas reimbursement from commercial payers can

be extremely complex, especially in terms of recognizing

revenue against cost. For the most part, reimbursement

from commercial payers is predicated on the principles of

managed care. This means that the financial risk is shared

between the payer and the provider. Instead of a one-to-

one relationship between cost and reimbursement (indem-

nity insurance) where the payer assumes all the financial

risk, in managed care arrangements, the provider will as-

sume part of the risk, especially in ‘bad cases’, where costs

become exceedingly high due to clinical complications.

Under these conditions, reimbursement may be essen-

tially ‘capped’ under a case-rate or under a global payment

schedule. For commercial payers, this payment methodol-

ogy may involve all components of cost, including physi-

cians, hospital and organ acquisition, whereas for regula-

tory payers, this type of global reimbursement is applicable

namely to hospitalization charges.

Financial evaluations must take into consideration these

complex interactions between providers and payers in or-

der to allocate costs and recognize revenues appropriately

(Figure 1).

Cost Allocation

In transplantation, there are three components of cost:

physician services, hospital services and organ acquisition

costs (OACs). The latter is unique to transplantation and

causes the most confusion. OACs are defined by a set of

CMS regulations (6) which are subject to some interpreta-

tion, but which in turn are auditable by the Office of the

Inspector General (7). Costs attributable to OAC include,

in addition to the cost of the procuring all organ(s) trans-

planted, any costs incurred in the evaluation of all potential

recipients and living donors at a specific institution for a

defined period of time, regardless of whether the patients

become actual transplant recipients. This may include the

salaries and benefits of all personnel involved in these ac-

tivities, as well as indirect costs directly attributable to

these activities, including office rent, computers, office

supplies, etc. In addition, physician services necessary for

these evaluations can be charged to the organ-specific or-

gan acquisition cost center (OACC). The OAC also includes

any costs incurred in maintaining organ-specific recipient

candidate waiting lists, such as the cost of immunologi-

cal testing necessary to define the status of the potential

recipient.

Hospital services for transplantation can be defined in

terms of the type of patient encounter. The most straight-

forward consists of the transplant admission or episode.

Costs assigned to this episode typically include costs in-

curred from 24 hours prior to the transplant procedure to

the time of discharge of the patient from the hospital. Thus,

if the patient is in the hospital for any period of time prior to

the transplant, or if the patient is readmitted to the hospital

following transplantation, costs associated with these pe-

riods of care are not included in the calculation of cost for

the transplant procedure unless the contractual arrange-

ment does not allow for the separation of the cost related

1258 American Journal of Transplantation 2006; 6: 1257–1263

Financial Outcomes in Transplantation

The Market -- Payers and Providers

Regulated

Payers(CMS)

Commercial

Payers(Transplant

Networks)

Self Funded

Employer

Insurance

Hospital

MD Group Providers

Payers

Figure 1: Complex interactions be-tween providers of care, and pay-ers. The role of the commercial payer

network as a ‘broker’ for third-party

payers is highlighted. Arrows denote

relationships between the transplant

networks, third-party payers and the

various providers of care that may re-

sult in variances in financial outcomes.

to these events. This issue will be revisited below in the

reimbursement section.

Physician services do not lend themselves easily to cost

analyses, since it is difficult to allocate cost to a patient

encounter. This would require defining an hourly cost of

physician time and allocation of cost based purely on a per-

centage of salary and including benefits. Instead, physician

cost is typically defined by relative value units (RVUs) as-

signed to each procedure in the Medicare Fee Schedule

(MFS) (8). Each physician or physician-group will then as-

sign a ‘price’ for their services, also known as a ‘charge’

based on a percentile of national or regional standards pub-

lished by groups such as the AAMC (9). The real cost of the

physicians is based on the aggregate cost of salaries and

benefits, malpractice insurance and other indirect costs,

such as billing costs and other practice expenses. Unfortu-

nately, it is difficult to allocate costs to a particular proce-

dure or encounter. An hourly formula is often used to bill

the hospital for physician services rendered on behalf of

the hospital cost centers, such as OACC, but this requires

careful documentation and time-studies that can withstand

federal audits.

Cost-accounting principles may vary greatly between insti-

tutions. Ultimately, there are two components of any cost

that must be calculated in order to perform appropriate fi-

nancial evaluations. The first is the variable cost, and the

second the fixed cost. The variable cost of a procedure in-

cludes every cost directly associated with the procedure.

There may be both direct and indirect costs associated to

the variable cost. For a transplant procedure, these costs

may include operating room costs, laboratory costs, room

and board costs, pharmacy costs as well as other costs.

These costs would not be incurred if the procedure were

not performed. In contrast, fixed costs consist primarily of

overhead costs, which may also have direct and indirect

components. These costs may include salaries of nurses

and other nonmedical staff such as administrators, building

costs for the hospital, the cost of equipment and the cost

of maintaining the facilities and the equipment, as well as

other costs, such as capital costs. In calculating the pro-

duction cost of the transplant episode or admission, it is

the total or full cost that will define the production cost

against which reimbursement will be recognized or recon-

ciled. Therefore, it is essential that the hospital’s informa-

tion systems capture these costs in real time, so that they

can be accounted for accurately. An accurate allocation of

cost and cost-accounting which assigns ‘true’ institutional

costs to a procedure, an encounter or an admission is one

of the most elusive objectives for most transplant pro-

grams. Allocation of indirect costs (overhead) is extremely

difficult to accomplish to everyone’s satisfaction. Activity-

based cost (ABC) accounting, which in theory assigns fixed

costs accurately to specific activities based on the exact

utilization of resources required for the particular event,

remains an insurmountable challenge for most transplant

programs since this type of cost accounting requires pre-

cise measures of time, space and ancillary equipment uti-

lization for each event. In addition, allocation of indirect

costs vary tremendously in dollar amounts depending on

the size of the institution, the number of beds and a host

of other characteristics that determine the ‘universe’ over

which overhead can be distributed or allocated, and con-

stitutes one of the main reasons for the variation in cost

between institutions.

American Journal of Transplantation 2006; 6: 1257–1263 1259

Abecassis

Global Case Rate

Components of Transplant Cost and Reimbursement

OACC DRGPhysician

Reimbursement

% Discount from Charges

Figure 2: The three components ofcost and reimbursement for thetransplant episode. Regulated pay-

ers such as Medicare reimburse OAC

on a full-cost, ‘pass-through’ basis, the

DRG component as a fixed case-rate

and physician services based on the

MFS. In contrast, commercial payers

typically bundle all three; the OAC and

DRG components are typically reim-

bursed together at either a discount

of billed charges, or alternatively as

a case-rate. On occasion, physicians

are reimbursed on a schedule different

from the hospital.

Revenue Recognition and Reconciliation

For the purposes of this review, clinical revenue is syn-

onymous with reimbursement. Thus, revenue depends

greatly on contractual allowances that govern reimburse-

ment rates. These, in turn, vary greatly not only between

payers, but also depending on the specific cost center. We

stated earlier that in transplantation, there are three compo-

nents of cost. Reimbursement is different for each compo-

nent, and can be quite variable (Figure 2). For OAC, the reg-

ulatory payers vary from the commercial payers in terms

of reimbursement. Medicare reimbursement for OAC is

cost-based. Therefore, for Medicare recipients, OAC is re-

imbursed 1:1 according to the ‘production cost’, on a ‘rea-

sonable cost-basis’. In contrast, for Medicaid kidney recip-

ients, no such formula exists. In some states, there is no

reimbursement for kidney acquisition costs by Medicaid,

resulting in a net loss for the program since this cost cannot

be recovered. In contrast, liver acquisition costs are typi-

cally recovered from Medicaid at a discount from charges.

Medicaid reimbursement is also dependent on the bud-

getary health of the specific state, and despite strong con-

tractual agreements, reimbursement may not occur once

the state budget is exhausted. For commercial payers, re-

imbursement for OAC is bundled with reimbursement for

the transplant episode or admission. Thus, in a contracted

case-rate, the hospitalization costs as well as the OAC ap-

pears as a single cost but reimbursement must be recog-

nized for each independently, making financial evaluations

more difficult. Moreover, there may be financial reconcilia-

tions that occur at periodic intervals between both regula-

tory and commercial payers and hospitals that add another

level of complexity to revenue recognition.

Physician services are reimbursed by regulatory payers

on a ‘fee-for-service’ basis, which is predicated on RVUs

published in the MFS. Commercial payers will often at-

tempt to bundle physician reimbursement with hospital

reimbursement as global case-rates, including OAC in or-

der to minimize both their risk exposure, and the com-

plexity of managing transplant contracts. It is easier and

cheaper in general for payers to make global payments

triggered on events such as the transplant procedure, than

to make payments that recognize specific costs. In con-

trast, providers prefer reimbursement that recognizes pa-

tient encounters or procedures, and reimbursement sched-

ules based on institutional charges. Therefore, contractual

agreements between providers and payers are typically

hybrids of both, making assignment of reimbursement to

specific cost postings almost impossible. Ideally, ‘line item

posting’ of charges for specific services whereby specific

costs are reconciled with assigned reimbursements for the

same services would clarify this issue. However, in reality,

this does not occur. Therefore, revenue recognition com-

prises the biggest challenge to both payers and providers,

especially as accrual accounting principles are based on

assumptions of fixed reimbursement cycles. In real life,

reimbursement cycles may differ, violating one of the ba-

sic principles of accrual accounting. Consequently, trying to

recognize revenues, in the context of long waiting times for

transplantation as well as great variation in cost between

easy cases and more complicated ones, adds further com-

plexity to financial analyses for transplant programs.

Eventually, there is some reconciliation that takes place

between cost and reimbursement especially when costs

fall outside the expected variation. The process centers

1260 American Journal of Transplantation 2006; 6: 1257–1263

Financial Outcomes in Transplantation

on the concept of ‘stop loss’, also known as ‘outlier pro-

tection’. Medicare has well-established outlier thresholds

that allow hospitals to reconcile costs with reimburse-

ment. Once hospital charges exceed the Diagnosis Related

Group (DRG) reimbursement beyond a threshold gap (set

by Medicare), reimbursement converts to a percentage of

charges rather than a fixed amount (10). This percentage

is set low enough that profit is unlikely, yet high enough so

that the hospital can recover its costs. Unfortunately, the

‘gap’ between the costs required to trigger the outlier pro-

tection and the fixed reimbursement is large enough that

this type of protection only affects outliers far in excess

of cost. Therefore all transplant recipients whose cost falls

between the two (‘in the gap’) trigger no further reimburse-

ment beyond the set DRG payment. Commercial payers

have similar language built into their contracts so that a

‘floor’ forms the basis for outlier reimbursement. There

are ‘inlier’ and ‘outlier’ thresholds that define ‘ceilings’ and

‘floors’, respectively, for case-rate reimbursements when

billed charges fall outside the expected range. Nonethe-

less, it is clear that as the cost increases as a result of

the various cost-drivers, the reimbursement-to-cost ratio

decreases, regardless of outlier protection language.

Reimbursement from commercial payers depends entirely

on the language of the contractual agreement between

the payer and the provider(s) (11). A potential threat to

providers is that with the proliferation of transplant cen-

ters, transplant services can become commoditized. Com-

modities are defined as products or services that have little

or no differentiation such that their purchase can be made

from a number of providers in a price-sensitive manner.

Any market where products or services command premi-

ums (margins) because of their differentiation will attract

new providers in search of those margins. If the barriers to

entry are high, the market will not allow new providers to

enter. If these barriers are lowered, new providers will en-

ter the market, erode margins and the products or services

become commodities. This trend is becoming apparent in

the transplant market and there may be two immediate

consequences. First, transplant programs must become

cost-efficient in order to compete (12). It is clear that as

a result of the managed care infiltration of the transplant

market, this is rapidly occurring. This is not necessarily a

bad thing, since it lowers the cost of transplantation. The

vast majority of transplant programs have become cost-

conscious in order to compete effectively. Second, trans-

plant programs must introduce differentiation back into the

services they provide, in order to be able to command a pre-

mium. Differentiation of product services has occurred as

a result of innovation by transplant physicians. Examples

of this include laparoscopic donor nephrectomy and living

donor procedures beyond the standard living donor kidney

transplant, only to name a couple. However, it is clear that

transplant payer networks also compete for market share

among the hundreds of third-party payers who seek their

volume discounts and transplant case management exper-

tise in order to minimize the risk they assume for their

covered lives. As these networks describe their transplant

coverage products to their potential clients, they too must

differentiate these products. When the networks compose

their lists of preferred providers they must balance the is-

sues of patient access to transplant centers versus the

notion of selected transplant centers of excellence. The

former is attractive to third-party payers and ultimately to

patients, since it eliminates restriction to access, whereas

the latter allows the networks to achieve both clinical and

financial objectives that define their respective networks.

Financial Evaluation and Performance

Financial evaluation requires a clear understanding of cost

allocation and revenue recognition. The operating margin,

also known as the profit margin, is defined by the rev-

enue minus the production cost, which in turn consists

of both fixed and variable costs. In contrast, the contribu-

tion margin is defined by the revenue minus the variable

cost. Therefore, the contribution margin, net of the profit

margin, defines the share of fixed cost that the transplant

program ‘contributes’ to the institution (Figure 3). In a situa-

tion with excess hospital capacity, this margin is extremely

important for the fiscal health of the institution even if the

profit margin is narrow. In contrast, in situations with lim-

ited capacity, the contribution margin becomes much less

important. Thus, in the case of excess bed capacity, every

admission contributes to the fixed cost, even at zero profit

margin, whereas in the case of limited capacity, the institu-

tion can maximize its profit margin by limiting admissions

to those with the highest profitability.

Billed charges for hospital services in particular are typi-

cally set at some multiplier of total cost. Every Medicare

provider must publish every year, as part of its Medicare

Cost Report, its charge-to-cost ratios. Therefore studies

that analyze cost at various institutions will often derive

the cost figures from charges reported by the institution

for specific procedures, such as transplants. Since charges

tend to be somewhat arbitrary and capricious, any refer-

ence to charges when considering reimbursement rates

is not generally acceptable in a financial analysis. Instead,

reimbursement must be measured in the context of the

production cost. Physician charges also represent a higher

amount than anyone expects to recover, but since charges

for physician services are tied to RVUs, they tend to be

more standard, and therefore a reference to physician

charges is more valid.

Because costs are defined differently for physicians than

hospitals, it is essential that the total cost of a patient en-

counter, a procedure or a global care period be accurately

evaluated in order to calculate the appropriate margins.

Similarly, revenue to both the hospital and the physicians

must be recognized in the context of the cost allocated to

each service. Moreover, the OAC must be recovered from

all payers at full cost, whether as a ‘pass-through’ payment

American Journal of Transplantation 2006; 6: 1257–1263 1261

Abecassis

Figure 3: Relationship betweenbilled charges, reimbursement (rev-enue), full cost (fixed plus variable),and contribution and profit mar-gins. Note that the contribution margin

includes fixed cost and profit margin,

since it represents reimbursement net

of variable cost.

from regulatory payers or as an internal transfer to the OAC

from global payments from the payer network. It is impor-

tant to understand that the OAC may be as much as two

or three times the cost of the transplant admission, es-

pecially for kidney transplants. Since reimbursement from

regulatory payers does not allow for any profit in OACC,

the profitability of the transplant program relies entirely on

the margin of the hospitalization. Therefore, the reimburse-

ment minus the cost of the hospitalization or admission

for the transplant will ultimately define the profitability of

the transplant program. This means that close attention to

cost-drivers, such as length-of-stay, resource utilization and

pharmacy costs, will define profit margins. Length-of-stay

is an excellent surrogate for cost, since per diem utiliza-

tion of resources generally drives inpatient costs. For com-

mercial payers, since the reimbursement for OAC and the

hospitalization is bundled, the OAC will also define the prof-

itability and the competitive advantage (or disadvantage) of

the transplant program. The higher the OAC, and the least

cost-efficient the program, the lower the profitability (13).

Conclusion

Financial outcomes and performance should take a dis-

tant third place to standard quality measures such as

clinical outcomes and patient satisfaction. Clearly, finan-

cial performance should compromise neither. Clinical out-

comes can be risk-adjusted in order to assess clinical

performance. In contrast, financial outcomes do not typi-

cally involve incremental risk-adjustment and therefore dif-

ficult cases result in significant financial risk exposure for

both the provider and the insurer. Managed care contracts

spread the financial risk, and outlier protection blunts the

financial impact of risk for both parties, but only when

billed charges exceed contracted thresholds. Nonetheless,

high-risk cases can impact negatively on the financial per-

formance of all parties with the exception of the payer

networks. In high-risk cases, provider charges may be as-

tronomical, but the providers will get reimbursed based on

outlier protection, at a fraction of their charges and typi-

cally without profit. The insurers are exposed to financial

risk as well based on the standard case-rate plus the out-

lier payments. Reinsurance, which is typically acquired by

insurers to cover catastrophic risk, will soften the blow

for the insurer. In contrast, the payer network will recover

their fee regardless, but in high-risk cases, will be able to

demonstrate to their client, the insurer, that belonging

to the payer network has resulted in significant savings

to the insurer, thus reiterating the importance of the payer

networks.

For the provider, financial evaluations can be reported in

a number of ways, the most important being the cost-to-

reimbursement ratio. This ratio can be calculated for the

transplant episode by organ type, by payer, and for the

program as a whole. A clear financial analysis will allow

the transplant center to decipher both the cost and the

reimbursement. Profitability can then be optimized either

by reducing the cost, or by maximizing revenue through a

reassessment of contractual agreements. The former may

require a better understanding of allocation of indirect costs

to the program by the institution. The latter may necessi-

tate an evaluation of the strategic importance of each payer

to the program. Thus, a program may choose to accept a

lower margin from a payer it views to be important in terms

of market share, whereas it may accept nothing short of

a wide margin from a less important payer. Alternatively, a

1262 American Journal of Transplantation 2006; 6: 1257–1263

Financial Outcomes in Transplantation

program may set a certain margin threshold for all payers,

regardless of how the payer is viewed by the institution.

Despite the best pricing strategies, the institution will ulti-

mately discover that their pricing will be influenced by that

of the competitors in their respective markets. This type of

price sensitivity is most obvious in markets saturated with

both providers and payer networks. One of the antidotes to

such commoditization consists of building brand strength,

whereby the payer sees inclusion of a certain payer as es-

sential by virtue of their ‘brand’ recognition. However, few

transplant centers can achieve such a marketable brand.

Alternatively, transplant centers may provide unique ser-

vices that command a premium in the market place. There-

fore, the profitability of a program is ultimately defined first

by its ability to obtain favorable reimbursement, as defined

by payer market forces, and second by adopting both cost

containment and differentiating strategies.

Although this manuscript provides a framework for the fi-

nancial evaluation of transplantation for programs in the

United States, most of the concepts discussed can also

apply to programs in countries with single payer systems,

such as Canada, and to transplant programs in most coun-

tries in Europe and Asia. Ultimately, successful financial

outcomes depend on reimbursement for transplant ser-

vices that exceed their production costs. Finance, after all,

is a universal discipline.

References

1. Doubilet P, Weinstein MC, McNeil BJ. Use and misuse of the

term cost-effective. N Engl J Med 1986; 314: 253–256.

2. Weinstein MC, Siegel JE, Gold MR, Kamlet MS, Russell LB, for

the Panel on Cost-Effectiveness in Health and Medicine. Rec-

ommendations of the Panel on Cost-Effectiveness in Health and

Medicine. JAMA 1996; 276: 1253–1258.

3. Evans RW. Cost-effectiveness analysis of transplantation. Surg

Clin North Am 1986; 66: 603–616.

4. Torgerson D, Raftery J. Measuring outcomes in economic evalu-

ations. BMJ 1999; 318: 1413.

5. Evans RW. Discount pricing and the “cost” of liver transplantation.

Liver Transpl 2000; 6: 119–121.

6. 42 CFR 412.100.

7. www.oig.hhs.gov.

8. http://www.cms.hhs.gov/PhysicianFeeSched/.

9. AAMC Data Book. Association of American Medical Colleges,

Washington, DC.

10. Axelrod DA, Koffron AJ, Baker T et al. The economic impact of

MELD on liver transplant centers. Am J Transpl 2005; 5: 2297–

2301.

11. Ziller EC, Coburn AF, McBride TD, Andrews C. Patterns of indi-

vidual health insurance coverage. Health Affairs (Millwood) 2004;

23: 210–221.

12. Evans RW. Cost containment and managed care in liver transplan-

tation. Acta Gastroenterol Belg 1999; 62: 363–371.

13. Abecassis MM, Kaufman DB, Stuart FP. Organ transplantation fi-

nance. In: Stuart FP, Abecassis MM, Kaufman DB, eds. Organ

Transplantation, 2nd Ed. Georgetown, TX: Landes Bioscience,

2003, chap 19.

Glossary

Pareto-optimality: the best that could be achieved with-

out disadvantaging anyone in the society.

Financial outcome: profitability assessment.

Billed charges: amount billed to payer; retail pricing.

Case-rate: contracted price; wholesale pricing.

Global case-rate: contracted price for defined period of

care.

Revenue: reimbursement.

Revenue recognition: reimbursement is recognized

when it is either accrued or received by the provider.

Revenue cycle: time period between billing for a service

and recognizing reimbursement.

Revenue reconciliation: reimbursement is adjusted

from the amount accrued to the amount paid by the payer.

Production cost: total (full) cost of providing a service.

Direct cost: cost allocated directly to a cost center.

Indirect cost: overhead allocated to a cost center in pro-

portion to the direct cost.

Fixed cost: cost of infrastructure required to provide a

service; consists of both direct and indirect costs.

Variable cost: incremental cost of providing a service;

consists of both direct and indirect costs.

Cost allocation: mainly related to indirect or fixed costs;

a portion of overhead is allocated to an encounter or a pro-

cedure based on an estimated proportion.

Activity-based cost (ABC) allocation: indirect or fixed

costs allocated based on a calculated proportion of total

utilization.

Outlier: unusually high cost or charges.

Outlier threshold: amount of billed charges at which

additional reimbursement beyond contracted case-rate or

global amount is triggered.

Floor: a percentage of charges below which reimburse-

ment occurs at a percentage of charges rather than the

contracted case-rate.

Stop loss: outlier protection designed to reimburse

provider at a predetermined floor to minimize risk expo-

sure.

Contribution margin: reimbursement minus variable

cost.

Profit margin: reimbursement minus production cost.

Net income: profit margin; operating margin; bottom

line.

American Journal of Transplantation 2006; 6: 1257–1263 1263