33
1 Evolutionary Perspectives on Firms’ Internal and External Portfolios of New Capabilities Gurneeta Vasudeva University of Minnesota 3-365 Carlson School of Management 321 19 th Avenue South Minneapolis, MN 55455 Phone: (612) 625-5940 Email: [email protected] Jaideep Anand Fisher College of Business Ohio State University 2100 Neil Avenue Columbus, OH 43210-1144 Phone: (614) 247-6851 Email: [email protected] Version: November 1, 2015 (Submitted to Strategy Science Special Issue)

Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    12

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

1

Evolutionary Perspectives on Firms’ Internal and External Portfolios of New Capabilities

Gurneeta Vasudeva

University of Minnesota

3-365 Carlson School of Management

321 19th Avenue South

Minneapolis, MN 55455

Phone: (612) 625-5940

Email: [email protected]

Jaideep Anand

Fisher College of Business

Ohio State University

2100 Neil Avenue

Columbus, OH 43210-1144

Phone: (614) 247-6851

Email: [email protected]

Version: November 1, 2015

(Submitted to Strategy Science Special Issue)

Page 2: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

2

Evolutionary Perspectives on Firms’ Internal and External Portfolios of New Capabilities

Abstract

Received wisdom from evolutionary theory and behavioral approaches yields potentially heterogeneous

search pathways for firms under uncertain conditions. On one hand, the need for experimentation under

uncertainty propels firms to initiate a broad-based search, followed by the selection and retention of a

narrow set of capabilities as learning occurs. We label this search pathway as ‘outside-in’ wherein variety

is followed by focus. On the other hand, behavioral assumptions of cognitive constraints and routines

point to a focused set of capabilities, which broaden as firms build absorptive capacity over time.

Moreover, path dependence can render the search process inflexible making selective retention more

difficult. We label this alternative search pathway as ‘inside-out’ wherein focus is followed by variety.

We find support for these two alternative search pathways in a radical technological context: ‘inside-out’

and ‘outside-in’ characterizing firms’ internal and external portfolios of capabilities, respectively. We

reason that as learning occurs, firms’ internal portfolios are reconfigured less easily relative to external

portfolios constituting more loosely coupled arrangements such as alliances. Our theory and empirical

findings hold important implications for understanding firms’ technology strategy and innovation

performance in an evolving technological context.

Page 3: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

3

Introduction

How do firms configure, adapt, and modify their capabilities in new and emergent contexts? To address

such issues, evolutionary theory based reasoning has pointed to the importance of a learning orientation

aimed at innovation and improvements upon the steady state (Nelson and Winter 1982). As Nelson

(1994:111) observed, for firms facing uncertainty in any given knowledge domain, “good responses…are

still to be learned.” Consequently, evolutionary theory suggests that confronted with alternative

approaches and solutions, firms initialize their search through variation-seeking and experimentation

because such an approach allows for flexibility for reconfiguration as firms monitor the developments in

the industry. Over time, as firms learn and gain experience, a winnowing process occurs resulting in the

retention of only the most relevant knowledge. Based on these mechanisms of variation, selection, and

retention, evolutionary theory predicts an ‘outside-in’ pathway for firms’ search characterized by

increasing diversity followed by more focused approaches.

Although the evolutionary model of variation-selection-retention offers important insights for

understanding the pattern of search, behavioral continuity manifested in cognitive constraints and

organizational routines (Cyert and March 1963, Levitt and March 1988, Levinthal and March 1993),

yields a different pattern of search. According to this reasoning, firms’ search is initialized by focused

investments, and any increase in breadth becomes possible only to the extent that firms build the

commensurate absorptive capacity. Moreover, contrary to the winnowing mechanism, this behavioral

approach emphasizes path dependencies that make it difficult for firms to reconfigure and get rid of

competencies once these are added to a firm’s repertoire. In other words as Nelson and Winter (1982:

134) observed, “firms may be expected to behave in the future, according to the routines they have

employed in the past.” Based on this logic, firms’ capabilities are likely to grow ‘inside-out’.

Thus, while evolutionary theory based reasoning is useful in offering solutions and identifying

constraints to the problems of uncertain and emergent contexts, incorporating the role of cognitive

constraints and path dependence could generate alternative pathways, suggesting therefore, that

Page 4: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

4

evolutionary theory may be underspecified. Based on these dual perspectives, we ask the question: do

alternative pathways for building new knowledge and competencies coexist or is there a unique path?

Our goal in this study is to develop and empirically test the implications of evolutionary theory

applied to firms’ internal and external portfolios in an emergent technological setting. Given the

important consequences of new capabilities, especially in the context of radical and uncertain

technological shifts (Henderson and Clark 1990, Nagarajan and Mitchell 1998, Tripsas and Gavetti 2000),

understanding their evolutionary path over time becomes a crucial research question. We propose two

distinct evolutionary processes and argue that they apply differentially to the configuration and

reconfiguration of internal and external portfolios of technological capabilities. We test our hypotheses

using data on the technological diversity of firms’ internal portfolios comprising fuel cell technology

patents produced by firms’ R&D units, and their external portfolios characterized by the fuel cell

technology patents held by their alliance partners, over the period 1981-2004. Fuel cell patents can be

categorized into technological areas that represent the various types and components of fuel cells. The

diversity of firms’ patents therefore, conveys important information about whether firms are

simultaneously developing multiple capabilities or focusing in a few areas.

We find that the evolution of internal portfolios is characterized by an approach which we label

‘inside-out’ whereby focused competencies expand into a broader set of capabilities as the firm builds

absorptive capacity over time. At the same time, internal portfolios are slower to reconfigure implying

that embedded routines and path dependence limit the winnowing process. In contrast to internal

portfolios, the external portfolios evolve ‘outside-in’ which conforms to the more classical prediction of

greater variation in the initial stages, and subsequent reconfiguration through the selection and retention

mechanisms. We suggest that such a path is enabled by loosely coupled inter-organizational arrangements

that lend themselves to experimentation and selective retention as learning occurs. Our findings reveal

that firms may use their internal and external portfolios strategically to counterbalance each other, such

that a greater degree of variation in one is offset by a greater degree of focus in the other, and one is

subject to faster reconfiguration than the other.

Page 5: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

5

Theory and Hypotheses

There exists an array of theoretical perspectives on firms’ ability to reconfigure or modify their resources

and capabilities to sustain competitive advantage. On one end of the spectrum, a resource-based

perspective views firms as bundles of capabilities which create value to the extent that the underlying

resources tend to be durable and are not easily replicated or redistributed (e.g., Wernerfelt 1984, Barney

1991, Priem and Butler 2001), leaving firms with few alternatives other than governance mechanisms

rooted in transaction cost economics (Williamson, 1991), to protect and coordinate existing resources and

capabilities. At the other extreme, population ecology argues that firms are fundamentally incapable of

engineering a resource reconfiguration. Instead, in this ecological perspective, change is accomplished at

the population level by organizational birth and death (e.g., Hannan and Freeman 1984, Haveman 1992).

Our approach takes an evolutionary view which resides somewhere in between these contrasting

perspectives concerning firms’ adaptation to a changing environment (Nelson and Winter, 1982). It

emphasizes the ability of firms to reconfigure their portfolios of capabilities, albeit, in a ‘Lamarckian’

sense, limited by cognitive constraints, organizational routines and path dependence. Such a skill

constitutes a dynamic capability which refers to “the firm’s ability to integrate, build, and reconfigure

internal and external competences to address rapidly changing environments” (Teece et al. 1997: 516) and

sustain competitive advantage (Helfat and Peteraf 2003, Helfat et al. 2007).

Alternative evolutionary pathways: ‘outside-in’ and ‘inside-out’

When competing in a new and emergent context, firms are usually faced with a considerable amount of

uncertainty stemming from various unknowns. For example, in the context of technological change, often

players do not know which technologies will emerge as the dominant designs, what kinds of skills and

resources they need to or can develop (Abernathy and Utterback 1978, Tushman and Anderson 1986,

Henderson and Clark 1990), or which firms or industries will ultimately become their competitors or

collaborators. Under such uncertain conditions, evolutionary theory based reasoning calls for learning

through trial and error entailing experimentation with alternatives (Nelson and Winter 1982, Nelson 1994,

Zollo and Winter 2002). As firms receive feedback from their trials and the external environment, they

Page 6: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

6

learn about the capabilities most suited to successful competition. Such learning leads to an increase in

focus (Levitt and March 1988). This logic yields the classic evolutionary trajectory of capabilities

characterized by variation-selection-retention, whereby firms initiate search through broad-based

approaches, and then based on the ensuing learning, make their bets and winnow out certain capabilities

while retaining others, resulting in the selection and retention of a narrower set of capabilities. We label

this approach as ‘outside-in’ because in this evolutionary model, firms’ initial response is to broaden their

scope and then narrow it down.

An alternative view which also draws on behavioral theory (Cyert and March 1963) predicts that

firms search cumulatively in the neighborhood of their current knowledge or tend to “climb local peaks”

(Levinthal 1997). Nelson and Winter (1994) similarly observed that “organizations are much better at

changing in the direction of “more of the same than they are at any other kind of change.” Entrenched in

competency traps (Leonard-Barton 1992) that perpetuate search in the neighborhood of their existing

technologies and products, firms are likely to demonstrate less variation at the outset. Levinthal and

March (1993) referred to this short-sighted behavior of firms as “the myopia of learning.” Even as

organizations learn to expand their capabilities, they tend to become entrenched in existing routines and

encounter organizational inertia that inhibits drastic changes or inflexion from the existing trajectory

(Levitt and March 1988, Tripsas and Gavetti 2000). Indeed, as Henderson and Clark (1990) observed,

change becomes especially problematic because it disturbs the firms’ knowledge architecture and requires

redeployment of capabilities. These insights yield a different evolutionary trajectory which is constrained

by absorptive capacity and existing routines such that firms start with a narrow set of capabilities. As

firms learn from their environment, new capabilities are added, but these capabilities persist due to path

dependence and organizational inertia. We label this approach ‘inside-out’ because it starts with a narrow

set of capabilities, continuing to expand in scope.

We suggest that firms’ responses to environmental uncertainty are likely to embody both these

approaches, but apply to different dimensions of their search. Whereas a firm’s internal portfolio of

capabilities will demonstrate the ‘inside-out’ approach, its external portfolio will demonstrate the

Page 7: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

7

‘outside-in’ approach. By considering the totality of firms’ capabilities that reside either within the firm or

are accessed through external relationships, our approach is consistent with an ecological view that

accounts for organizational interdependence. According to this view, a firm’s search and adaptation to the

changing technological landscape depends not only on its own capabilities, but also those of others in its

ecosystem thereby perpetuating cooperation and mutualism (Barnett 1990, Barnett and Carroll 1987).

The importance of external portfolios of inter-organizational alliances, in particular, stems from

their ability to help firms obtain resources from the environment, learn and develop capabilities, and

improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow

firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously scanning the environment and gathering market

intelligence to gain response time. Moreover, an external orientation helps firms to break out of their

routines and escape path dependency.

In sum, while studies have noted that both internal and external portfolios of capabilities have

important implications for firms’ competitive advantage and innovation performance (Mitchell and Singh

1996, Nagarajan and Mitchell 1998, Aggarwal and Hsu 2009, Vassolo et al. 2004, Vasudeva and Anand

2011), the evolutionary path of these portfolios remains unknown. The following hypotheses take a step

towards addressing this issue.

External portfolio: ‘Outside-in’ evolution

Before theorizing about the evolutionary path of the firm’s external portfolio comprising inter-

organizational alliances, it is useful to define the key components of the evolutionary model characterized

by variation, selection and retention. The element that varies, is selected, and ultimately retained is

technological capabilities, which in the case of external portfolios resides in the alliance partner as

opposed to the firm. The focal firm is the agent that induces variation and makes selection and retention

choices by periodically reconfiguring the mix of partners (and by extension their technological

capabilities) with which it maintains alliances. The external portfolio of alliances changes as the firm

establishes or renews alliances with certain partners, or as existing relationships are no longer

contributing to learning, either because alliances are terminated or have persisted beyond their productive

Page 8: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

8

lifespan. The portfolio’s technological capabilities may also change as partners themselves develop new

competences during the alliance lifetime. As Nelson (1994) suggests, the selection mechanism—the

criteria driving “fitness”—functions as the key to explaining the direction of the evolutionary process.

Applied to this study, it is worth clarifying what drives the firm to reconfigure its external portfolio, and

in what direction such reconfiguration will occur. We argue that the focal firm’s technological age

characterizing its lifespan and the learning that occurs from the alliance relationships function as the

primary selection mechanism underlying the process by which portfolio capabilities are reconfigured.

More variation in the early stages. When faced with novel and uncertain technological contexts,

firms seek alliances with other firms to access new capabilities and engage in complementary

development (Nagarajan and Mitchell 1998, Anand et al. 2010). Importantly, however, in the early stages

of an emergent technological context there is uncertainty regarding which partners the firm should ally

with, which have the best capabilities, and which will provide the best relational and technological fit

with the focal firm (Vasudeva and Anand 2011). For these reasons, in the nascent stages, firms will likely

follow a strategy of seeking variation in their search for partners’ capabilities. The purpose is to broaden

the technological scope of the external portfolio to increase exposure and postpone decisions regarding

focused investments. Such a logic for configuring the external portfolio resonates with extant work

suggesting that firms cope with uncertainty by establishing relationships with new partners bringing novel

skills and information rather than redundant resources (Beckman et al. 2004, Goerzen 2007). Moreover,

maintaining a more diverse external portfolio insures against the risk of not finding the appropriate

partners in the event of a discontinuous change, when competition for external resources--that can

potentially enhance the value of a firm’s existing capabilities—is likely to intensify. Thus, in the early

stages of a firm’s entry into an uncertain domain, a broad range of technological capabilities will be

represented in a firm’s external portfolio.

Faster reconfiguration towards selection and retention. In subsequent years, as firms gain

experience, the quest for diversity in partner capabilities will recede for three reasons. First, in the process

of experimentation firms are likely to learn about which types of partner capabilities are complementary

Page 9: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

9

with their internal capabilities. Second, as firms assimilate their partners’ diverse capabilities, they no

longer need to maintain broad-based external portfolios, and can focus on retaining partners that are most

pivotal for their technological goals. Finally, beyond a certain threshold, having ties to a highly diverse

set of partners is likely to impose constraints on firms’ absorptive capacity (Vasudeva and Anand 2011).

These factors will perpetuate the transition into a phase of selection and retention. Armed with

greater knowledge about what kinds of capabilities it needs (and does not need) to compete, in this later

stage the firm will systematically rationalize the mix of partners in its external portfolio. For example,

some firms will see more promise in competing within a particular technological segment of the broader

domain, and thus seek partnerships that strengthen its position within that segment. Other firms may seek

competitors or complementors, and thus limit alliances with firms from other domains. Firms thus

transition from a phase of variation-seeking to selection and retention (Rothaermel and Deeds 2004).

Such a transition is consistent with the work of Lavie and Rosenkopf (2006), who observed that firms

tend to balance broad-based and focused activities through strategic alliances over time—so that periods

of learning primarily through one type are followed by periods of learning primarily by another type.

In proposing that the process of external portfolio reconfiguration will be characterized by a

stage of increasing variation followed by one of decreasing variation, we do not suggest that a specific

level of variation should be regarded as the optimum for all firms within a technological domain.

However, we do suggest that consistent with evolutionary theory (Nelson and Winter 1982, Nelson 1994),

firms will first expand and then reduce their external portfolio’s scope of technological capabilities.

Hypothesis 1: In an uncertain environment, a firm’s external portfolio of alliance capabilities will

follow an evolutionary path characterized by more technological diversity in the early stages of

the firm’s technological lifespan, but faster reconfiguration towards selection and retention in the

later stages.

Internal portfolio: ‘Inside-out’ evolution

Just as a firm’s external portfolio evolves with time, its internal stock of knowledge and capabilities also

change. Although internal capabilities and external opportunities are inter-connected (Mowery et al. 1996,

Stuart 2000, Rosenkopf and Nerkar 2001), their evolutionary paths are likely to remain distinct.

Page 10: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

10

Less variation in the early stages. In the early stages of a firm’s entry into a new and uncertain

arena, the scope of its internal portfolio will be quite narrow. Given the inherent costs and organizational

complexity of growing organically, expansions in internal capabilities by way of adding R&D labs, hiring

inventors, or acquiring firms will be limited. Consistent with this idea, Tripsas and Gavetti (2000) showed

that even when firms make new technological discoveries, they often find it difficult to make

technological commitments, which reduces their internal scope in the early stages of their entry into a

new domain.

Slower reconfiguration towards selection and retention. Over time, however, firms broaden their

internal capabilities by building on their existing knowledge and assimilating external knowledge from

their external portfolios (Vasudeva and Anand 2011), for instance. Learning has the cumulative effect of

increasing the internal scope. Moreover, once investments in R&D, for instance, are made and

organizational units are established, discontinuing, downsizing or reversing these commitments can

become difficult due to organizational inertia or simply the lack of adequate information about which

technologies to divest (Sirmon et al. 2007).

For these reasons, internal portfolios tend to demonstrate more path-dependence (Karim and

Mitchell 2000) and are more difficult to reconfigure (Karim 2006). As an example, although only a small

proportion of a firm’s total patents are ever utilized for commercial application, yet, these patents provide

the firm with a platform for its subsequent technological development. Internal shakeouts that are path-

breaking are likely less frequent. Based on these observations, we suggest that as internal portfolios

expand in scope, they become less flexible, and are therefore, not easily reconfigured.

Hypothesis 2: In an uncertain environment, a firm’s internal portfolio of capabilities will follow

an evolutionary path characterized by less technological diversity in the early stages of a firm’s

technological lifespan, continuing to expand in the later stages, but with slower reconfiguration

towards selection and retention in the later stages.

Page 11: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

11

Data and Methodology

We test our hypotheses in the context of firms’ internal and external portfolios in the emergent fuel cell

technology domain. Fuel cells convert the chemical energy stored in hydrogen into electrical energy in

multiple applications such as automobiles, portable devices and stationary power generation. The two oil

shocks in 1973 and 1979 that stemmed from the political developments in the Middle East (Hamilton

1983) triggered exploration in a number of alternative energy technologies such as fuel cells. Not

surprisingly, 1981 marks the year of the first publicly reported fuel cell alliances between Hitachi and

Toshiba, and Hitachi and New Energy Development Organization (NEDO). Among the various

technological alternatives, industry experts regard fuel cells as a radical technology that could usher in the

new hydrogen economy (Avadikyan et al. 2003). Triggered by environmental considerations, oil price

spikes, and energy shortages, firms have used the external capabilities of their alliance partners to explore

the promise of fuel cell technologies. Fuel cell technology integrates know-how from a number of

scientific and engineering fields, yielding a broad range of products and designs and necessitating

collaboration through alliances by the multiple organizations interested in its development. Given that

most fuel cell technologies were still in the pre-commercial stages in the period covered by this study,

developers faced considerable uncertainty about which technological designs and applications will gain

market acceptance. Consequently, fuel cell technology development provides an appropriate empirical

context to study the evolution of firms’ internal and external portfolios.

Sample. We identified firms belonging to the fuel cell industry from patents granted by the U.S.

Patents and Trademarks Office (USPTO) to innovators in this domain. Based on consultation with an

expert patent examiner at the USPTO, we learned that fuel cell patents were assigned to patent class 429

(sub-classes 12–46). Firms that filed at least one patent in any of these 35 sub-classes were included in

our sample. The earliest patents granted in these sub-classes date back to 1971, and since then patenting

activity has risen sharply. The firms in the initial sampling frame represent innovators who were granted

patents in the period 1971–2004. Since our interest resides in comparing the evolutionary pathways of

firms’ internal and external portfolios, we retained only those firms that had formed at least one fuel cell

Page 12: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

12

technology development alliance until the year 2004. Thus, our sample includes the earliest cohort of

innovating firms and captures all entrants since then, providing us with an ideal setting to observe the

evolution of firms’ portfolios as the industry grew from a nascent to a pre-commercial stage. For each

firm, we constructed yearly internal and external portfolios based on alliances spanning the period 1981–

2004. Our final sample contains 109 firms from 11 countries.

External portfolios. We collected fuel cell alliance data based on publicly available archival

sources such as news reports, industry journals and trade magazines compiled in the Lexis-Nexis

databases, which includes more than 670 international titles (Ahuja 2000, Hagedoorn and Narula 1996,

Rosenkopf and Almeida 2003). Since alliance termination dates are difficult to determine and usually not

reported, following prior research we assumed that the productive lifespan of alliances lasts five years

(Gulati and Gargiulo 1999, Kogut 1988, Schilling and Phelps 2007, Stuart 2000). Thus, each individual

alliance entered a firms’ portfolio in the year it was formed and was dropped from the portfolio after five

years. Despite the errors of omission associated with this approach (some alliances may have prolonged

utility), it provided the best way to capture the dynamic aspects of external portfolios. Moreover, such

errors of omission, if any, would apply consistently across the stages of a firm’s lifecycle, and therefore,

not alter our results with regards to our predictions concerning the pattern of external portfolio evolution.

A firm’s external portfolio was recorded for each year regardless of whether the portfolio

changed in its composition, until it no longer had any alliances in the portfolio. As an illustration, for firm

X that formed its first alliance in 1990 and its second and final alliance in 1994, the external portfolio

would include one alliance in the period 1990-1993, two alliances in the year 1994, and again one alliance

in the period 1995–1998. Since we include the firm’s earliest alliances, there is no left censoring in the

data. In this manner we capture how a firm’s portfolio evolves since its first alliance. As new alliances are

formed and old alliances are phased out, the external portfolio’s characteristics change over time. Our

sample includes 655 firm external portfolios observed during the period 1981–2004. The number of

alliances in external portfolios range from one to 22, with a mean of 2.77 and standard deviation of 3.07.

Page 13: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

13

Dependent variables

External portfolio technological diversity. We measure the technological scope of the external

portfolio based on the technological diversity of the firms’ partners in the alliance portfolio. Greater

technological diversity suggests greater exploration because it exposes the firm to a range of

technological capabilities. Such diversity also gives the firm the option to choose the technologies that

best suit its requirements depending on how the industry evolves (Powell et al. 1996, Wuyts et al. 2004).

Conversely, less technological diversity suggests greater focus in the alliance portfolio. Fuel cell patents

are assigned to 35 different patent sub-classes (429/12-46) that represent distinct aspects of fuel cell

technology development. These patent sub-classes are also illustrative of considerable intra-technology

competition driven by component costs, fuel conversion efficiency, fuel reformation and storage systems,

modularity and miniaturization (Avadikyan et al. 2003).

The technological diversity measure was calculated by first computing a Herfindahl index (which

measures concentration and ranges from zero to one) and then subtracting this measure from one.

Technological diversity was calculated using the formula: 1-(ni /N)2 where ni represents the cumulative

number of partners’ patents belonging to patent sub-class i (where i ranges from 1-35) and N represents

the cumulative number of fuel cell patents issued to the partners up to the observation year. A minimum

value of zero indicates that all partners concentrated their patents in one patent sub-class, and a maximum

value of one indicates equal distribution across sub-classes in the partners’ technological stock.

Internal portfolio technological diversity. The internal portfolio’s technological diversity was also

calculated using a Herfindahl index (as described earlier) where ni is the number of the focal firm’s

patents in the ith patent sub-class, and N is the total number of patents. This measure ranges from zero to

one, and accounts for the breadth of the firm’s internal technological portfolio.

Explanatory variable

Firm technological age. The focal firm’s technological age or technological lifespan is measured by the

number of years since its entry into the fuel cell technology domain, as indicated by the firm’s first fuel

cell patent application. This operationalization captures the time that a firm has spent in the fuel cell

Page 14: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

14

industry and serves as a proxy for its familiarity and experience. A zero value for technological age

indicates initialization or the founding year in which a firm entered the industry. The longer a firm has

been in the industry, the more advanced its technological age. Firms’ technological age in the sample

ranges from 0 to 32 years, with a mean of 9.98 years and a standard deviation of 8.69 years.

Control variables

Firm characteristics. The focal firm’s technological base, which reflects its stock of technological

resources was calculated as the patent count up to the observation year (Cohen et al. 2002, Griliches

1990). The cumulative number of inventors obtained from a firm’s patent records accounts for the human

resources that could impact the technological scope of the internal and external portfolio. The number of

prior citations to others captures learning effects and may influence the firm’s technological scope and its

reconfiguration. We included Freeman's (1979) degree centrality, which captures the prominence of each

firm in the overall network of fuel cell innovators which could influence alliance formation. We used

Burt's (1992) network efficiency variable to capture the extent of non-redundancy and novelty of

technological knowledge in a firm’s alliance network, where higher values of efficiency (which ranges

from 0 to 1) signify a network high in structural holes. To ascertain which players were active in the

industry in a given year, we identified their entry and exit years. We assumed that a player entered the

industry three years preceding the year of its first patent application, and exited three years following the

year of its last patent application. The technological distance between the focal firm and those in its

external portfolio captured the degree of familiarity and complementarity between the firm and its

partners which could influence the diversity of the portfolio capabilities. Jaffe's (1986) measure of

technological distance1 is calculated based on the patent sub-classes of the firm’s patents and the pooled

sub-classes of its partners’ patents. The distance measure ranges from zero (perfectly similar

technological profiles) to one (the firm and its partners’ patents are in non-overlapping sub-classes). Prior

1 Technological distance between the firm i and portfolio j was calculated as 1- Pij where Pij is the measure of

technological proximity. Pij is calculated using the formula: FiF′j/[(FiFj)(Fji)]1/2 where Fi is the vector of

technological positions for firm i, and Fj is the corresponding vector for firm i ’s portfolio j. The vector F is

represented by (F1, F2, F3…Fk) where Fk is the cumulative proportion of patents assigned to patent sub-class k.

Page 15: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

15

industry experience could lead to firm-specific capabilities and path dependencies (e.g. Benner and

Tripsas 2012) leading to an evolutionary pathway that is distinct from new entrants in an industry. This

observation is germane to settings such as fuel cell technology development that involve both new

entrants and incumbents from related industries such as automobiles and power generation. We controlled

for the number of innovators engaged in fuel cell technology development in a given year to account for

the potential for alliance formation.

External portfolio characteristics. The average duration of alliances in the external portfolio

accounts for the number of years since the alliances were formed which could influence the learning and

associated reconfiguration. The proportion of equity alliances in the external portfolio indicates the

governance mechanism in the portfolio. External portfolios in which the majority of alliances involve

equity investments should require greater commitment and coordination between the firm and the partners

and hence, involve higher asset specificity and task interdependence than external portfolios in which the

alliances are structured as arm’s length type of transactions (Gulati and Singh 1998, Nagarajan and

Mitchell 1998). Similarly, the proportion of repeated ties, calculated as the number of partners with which

the focal firm had established at least one alliance prior to the currently observed portfolio (Gulati 1995),

could influence the commitment and reconfiguration of external portfolios. To account for the possibility

that partners possessing technologically valuable inventions may alter the scope of the portfolio, we

included partners’ technological value as the ratio of citations to partners’ patents relative to all fuel cell

patent citations up to the observation year. Geographical diversity in the external portfolio provides the

firm access to partners located in different countries. Such diversity, allows the firm to tap into the

scientific and human resources offered by various national innovation systems, and access multiple

markets. Moreover, since technologies tend to develop in the context of local demand conditions, labor

supply, and government policies; geographical diversity allows the firm access to idiosyncratic, novel, or

specialized technologies (Lavie and Miller 2008). The geographical diversity of partners was calculated

analogously to technological diversity, except that ni now represented the number of partners located in

country i, and N represented the total number of partners in the portfolio. A partner was assigned to the

Page 16: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

16

country in which it conducted the bulk of its fuel cell innovation. In all cases this corresponded to the

partner’s home country.

The firm fixed effects accounts for time-invariant factors at the firm level. The year fixed effects

accounts for unobserved variations across years. These fixed effects are especially helpful in ruling out

sources of endogeneity based on stable but unobserved factors that are likely to explain the technological

diversity of a firm’s internal and external portfolios.

Method

In this study the outcome of interest is the technological diversity of firms’ internal and external

portfolios, which is a continuous variable bounded between the values of zero and one. Our hypotheses

suggest that the external portfolio diversity has a curvilinear relationship with the firm’s technological age

after controlling for firm and portfolio variables. We express this equation below, where the external

portfolio diversity in time t for firm i (EDit), is a function of the firm’s age (FAit), a vector of covariates

(Xit) and an error term εit.

EDit = β1FAit + β2FAit2 + β3 Xit + εit

Similarly, firm’s internal portfolio diversity (IDit), is a function of the firm’s age (FAit), and a vector of

covariates (Xit) and an error term εit.

IDit = β1FAit + β2FAit2 + β3 Xit + εit

Since the contemporaneous error terms associated with the firm’s internal and external portfolio diversity

are likely correlated we use a seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) model using maximum likelihood

estimates (Zellner 1962, Cameron and Trivedi 2005). The SUR regression implemented in STATA 11

provides joint estimates of firm’s internal and external portfolio technological diversity. The explanatory

variables in both equations however differ.

We present the findings based on this model, and conduct a variety of supplementary analysis as

reported below to demonstrate the robustness of our findings to alternative specifications.

--Insert Figures 1 (a) and 1(b) and Figure 2 here--

--Insert Tables 1(a) and 1(b) and Tables 2 and 3 here--

Page 17: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

17

Results

Figures 1 (a) and (b) illustrate the observed evolutionary path of the firms engaged in fuel cell technology

development included in our sample. As can be seen from these graphs, in the early stages of their

technological lifespan, firms’ internal portfolios tend to be less technologically diverse than external

portfolios. At the same time, internal portfolios demonstrate a faster increase in their technological

diversity compared to external portfolios and are less elastic as evidenced from the continuously

increasing technological diversity compared to external portfolios. These observed evolutionary patterns

of internal and external portfolios, suggest preliminary support for Hypotheses 1 and 2.

Tables 1(a) and 1(b) provide the summary statistics and correlations for the model variables. Both

a firm’s internal and external portfolio technological diversity are positively correlated with its

technological age, but the technological diversity of a firm’s internal portfolio has a larger correlation

with age (0.66) compared its external portfolio diversity (0.14). Internal and external portfolio

technological diversity are also positively correlated with one another.

Tables 2 and 3 present the results from the seemingly unrelated regressions that estimate the

firm’s internal and external portfolios’ technological diversity simultaneously. The Breusch-Pagan test

shows significant negatively correlated errors (p<0.001), thereby validating the appropriateness of the

seemingly unrelated regression model. Table 2 which includes only the linear term for technological age

shows that a firm’s technological age has a significant positive effect on its internal technological

diversity, but technological age is not significantly related to the external portfolio’s technological

diversity. Table 3 reports the full model and includes both the linear and quadratic terms for technological

age to account for the non-monotonic relationship between technological age and the portfolio’s

technological diversity. As the results in Table 3 reveal, a firm’s technological age and its squared term

are both significantly related to its internal and external portfolio’s technological diversity. Figure 2

illustrates these results graphically. In particular, at the mean technological age of around 10 years, the

firm’s internal technological diversity is 0.49 which is considerably lower compared to the external

Page 18: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

18

portfolio technological diversity of 0.78. A firm’s internal technological diversity however exceeds that of

the external portfolio when the technological age is one standard deviation above the mean value.

The coefficient for technological age suggests a more positive and significant marginal effect on a

firm’s internal technological diversity compared to its external portfolio diversity. This effect points to the

continued expansion of a firm’s internal technological diversity compared to its external portfolio’s

diversity. The coefficient for the squared term for technological age is negative and significant for both

internal and external diversity, but the relative size of the coefficient suggests a greater inflexion in the

external diversity compared to internal diversity. In particular, as a firm’s technological age increases

from the mean value to one standard deviation above it, its internal technological diversity increases from

0.50 to 0.80, but its external portfolio diversity decreases slightly from 0.78 to 0.77. These results point to

a slower reconfiguration or less flexibility of the internal portfolio compared to the external portfolio.

Together, these findings lend support for Hypotheses 1 and 2.

Turning to the control variables in the model, the results show that a firm’s network characterized

by structural holes that enables access to more novel knowledge in its relationships is associated with

greater internal portfolio technological diversity, but lower technological diversity of its external

portfolio. The size of the industry has a small but significantly negative effect on its internal technological

diversity, suggesting that more competition may spur firms to develop focused approaches internally. The

technological distance between the firm’s internal and external technological capabilities has a significant

negative relationship with both the internal and external portfolio’s technological diversity, thus

illustrating the need to balance technological distance and technological diversity. Firms that had

experience in another industry such as transportation or power generation prior to their entry into the fuel

cell technological domain demonstrated more external portfolio diversity. Similarly, a greater proportion

of repeated alliances associated with greater external portfolio technological diversity, possibly due to less

reconfiguration in such instances. Partner’s technological value and geographical diversity also associated

with significantly greater technological diversity of the external portfolio. The effect of other control

variables was non-significant.

Page 19: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

19

--Insert Tables 4, 5 and 6 here--

Supplementary Tests

Alternative model specifications. To check the robustness of our results, in the seemingly

unrelated regression model reported in Table 3, we estimated models with lagged effects. In the model

estimating the external portfolio’s evolution, we included as predictors a one-year lag of the firm’s

internal portfolio’s technological diversity and a one-year lag of the external portfolio’s technological

diversity. Similarly, in the model estimating the firm’s internal portfolio’s technological evolution we

included a one-year lag of the firm’s internal portfolio’s technological diversity and the external

portfolio’s technological diversity. Including these lagged effects did not change our main findings.

Given that the dependent variable is censored between the values of zero and one, an ordinary

least squares regression may yield inconsistent estimates. Hence, we also estimated the model using a

panel tobit regression with firm and year fixed effects to account for unobserved heterogeneity

(Wooldridge, 2002), which yielded similar results.

Finally, we estimated the firm’s internal and external portfolios’ technological diversity modeled

as independent models with robust standard errors. The results from this model reported in Table 4

remain unchanged from those the seemingly unrelated model reported in Table 3.

Cohort effects. To distinguish between the early and late cohort of firms we divided the firms

based on the year in which they entered the industry as determined by their first patent application to the

USPTO. Firms that entered the industry prior to 1990 were considered as early entrants, and firms that

entered in subsequent years were grouped as late entrants. The order of entry could alter the evolutionary

pathways because the technological uncertainty encountered by the firms in the early cohort is likely

greater than that for firms in the late cohort.

As shown in Table 5, a comparison of firm’s internal and external portfolios for the early cohort

shows that when technological uncertainty is higher internal portfolios demonstrate an increasing and

then decreasing technological diversity, while the external portfolio’s technological diversity is not

significantly affected by the firm’s technological age. For the late cohort, which experiences relatively

Page 20: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

20

less technological uncertainty, the external portfolio demonstrates an increasing and then decreasing

technological diversity in the predicted manner, while the internal portfolio demonstrates the reverse

pattern of decreasing and then increasing technological diversity. Late entrants might learn vicariously

from the experience of early entrants and engage in less experimentation. At the same time, late entrants

may be able assemble more diverse portfolios because of a greater range of technological opportunities

created by firms that preceded them. These effects suggest that early and late entrants differ in their

evolutionary pathways.

Discussion

In this study, we applied the basic tenets of evolutionary theory (Nelson and Winter 1982, Nelson 1994)

and combined it with insights from behavioral approaches and organizational learning (Cyert and March

1963, Levitt and March 1988, Cohen and Levinthal 1990) to arrive at two alternative evolutionary

pathways: ‘inside-out’ and ‘outside-in’ characterizing firms’ internal and external portfolios, respectively.

In particular, we find that the extent of technological diversity and the rate at which the transition from

diversity to focus occurs varies across firms’ internal and external portfolios. Our evolutionary approach

recognizes that although firms encounter heterogeneity in their resource endowments and face constraints

in identifying the optimal mix of capabilities under uncertain conditions, firms need not own or control

the requisite resources and capabilities; they can access valuable capabilities externally through alliances.

Moreover, the distribution of resources and capabilities within an industry does not remain fixed or static,

but instead continues to evolve as firms learn and gain experience.

By accounting for the capabilities that reside in firms’ partners, our perspective takes an

ecological view wherein the resources and capabilities that firms need for survival in an uncertain

environment reside not only inside the firm but also in the firms’ portfolio of external relationships

(Barnett 1990, Barnett and Carroll 1987). In this vein, our work extends previous studies in strategic

management that have recognized the role of external capabilities for adapting to a changing

technological and competitive landscape (e.g. Nagarajan and Mitchell 1998, Karim and Mitchell 2000,

Anand et al. 2010). It is worth pointing out that the mechanism that drives fitness in the population and

Page 21: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

21

leads to the selection of the requisite capabilities for firms’ survival is their ability to learn from their

internal and external search processes. Such a learning ability is intrinsic to what scholars have previously

labeled ‘dynamic capabilities’ (Teece et al. 1997, Helfat and Peteraf 2003).

Our findings confirm that even though internal and external capabilities are inter-linked through

knowledge flows, differences persist in their starting and ending levels of diversity, and the rate of change

and peaks across firms’ internal and external portfolios. Taking a contingent view of organizational

search, Siggelkow and Levinthal (2005) similarly showed that the pattern of variation, selection, and

retention of alternatives can vary across different organizational structures, such as centralized versus

decentralized arrangements.

These differences have important implications for firms’ innovatory performance. Importantly, a

longer exploratory span for the internal portfolio means that firms must expend considerable time and

effort to continue to sift through opportunities. Conversely, in the case of external portfolios, firms appear

to make their bets early in their lifecycle. Although such an approach has its benefits in terms of

compressing the locus of experimentation (March 1991), early bets can prove costly: as an illustration, the

early models of small cars introduced by the auto makers in response to the oil crises of the 1970s turned

out to be inferior products (Bresnahan and Ramey 1993). Thus, given that the optimal scope of search is

not easily determined, our findings show that firms’ can offset this difficulty by pursuing different levels

of scope and pace of reconfiguration in their internal and external portfolios. This insight corroborates

prior works on how firms can move into new domains by gradually redeploying their resources

strategically (Anand and Singh 1997, Anand et al. 2010, Baumann and Siggelkow 2013).

While our study takes a step towards delineating the evolutionary pathways of firms’ internal and

external portfolios, our findings must be interpreted in light of its limitations and boundary conditions.

The implications we have discussed so far are tempered by the fact that we only focus on the evolutionary

path in the context a radical technological development, but do not assess the performance consequences

of the evolutionary path. Such an endeavor however, becomes challenging because a continuing state of

flux precludes firms from emulating the better performing firms that have survived in the population

Page 22: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

22

(March and Simon 1958, Hannan and Freeman 1989), and herd towards a dominant design (Abernathy

and Utterback 1978, Levinthal 1997).

We find that important deviations from the predicted evolutionary pathways can arise when we

consider the early and late cohort of firms that are exposed to different levels of uncertainty characterized

by more radical versus incremental technological changes (Henderson and Clark 1990). Further research

could examine such differences in greater depth, by employing contingency theory for instance, which

suggests that firms’ organizational characteristics correspond to the features of the environment to which

they are exposed (Lawrence and Lorsch 1967). Firms that enter the industry in its nascent stages, are

exposed to greater levels of uncertainty and may, therefore, respond in markedly different ways compared

to the late entrants. A variant of this thinking suggests that the uncertainty may filter through the firm’s

institutional context such that governments may intervene to coordinate and alter resident firms’

technological trajectory (Spencer et al. 2005, Vasudeva 2009).

In conclusion, as firms seek to compete in new markets and technologies globally, a dynamic

perspective on how firms’ capabilities are reconfigured becomes a central issue worthy of further

investigation. Our study contributes to this effort by identifying two alternative evolutionary pathways

and applying this theoretical insight for understanding the joint evolution of firms’ internal and external

portfolios of capabilities.

Page 23: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

23

REFERENCES

Abernathy, W.J., J. Utterback. 1978. Patterns of industrial innovation. Technology Review, June-July 40-

47.

Aggarwal, V.A., D.H. Hsu. 2009. Modes of cooperative R&D commercialization by start-ups. Strategic

Management J., 30(8) 835-864.

Ahuja, G. 2000. Collaboration Networks, Structural Holes, and Innovation: A Longitudinal Study. Admin.

Sci. Quart., 45(3) 425-455.

Anand, J., H. Singh. 1997. Asset redeployment, acquisitions and corporate strategy in declining

industries. Strategic Management Journal. 18(S1) 99-118.

Anand, J., R. Oriani, R.S. Vassolo. 2010. Alliance activity as a dynamic capability in the face of a

discontinuous technological change. Organization Science. 21(6) 1213-1232.

Avadikyan, A., P. Cohendet, J. A. Héraud. 2003. The economic dynamics fuel cell technologies. Springer

Verlag.

Lavie, D., L. Rosenkopf. 2006. Balancing exploration and exploitation in alliance formation. Acad.

Management J. 49(4) 797.

Barnett, W. P. 1990. The organizational ecology of a technological system. Administrative Science

Quarterly 31-60.

Barnett, W. P., G.R. Carroll. 1987. Competition and mutualism among early telephone

companies. Administrative Science Quarterly, 400-421.

Barney, J. B. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. J. Management, 17(1) 99-120.

Baumann, O., N. Siggelkow. 2013. Dealing with complexity: integrated vs. chunky search

processes. Organization Science. 24(1) 116-132.

Beckman, C. M., P. R. Haunschild, D.J. Phillips. 2004. Friends or strangers? Firm-specific uncertainty,

market uncertainty, and network partner selection. Organ. Sci. 15(3) 259-275.

Benner, M. J., M. Tripsas. 2012. The influence of prior industry affiliation on framing in nascent

industries: the evolution of digital cameras. Strategic Management Journal. 33(3) 277-302.

Bresnahan, T. F., V. A. Ramey. 1993. Segment shifts and capacity utilization in the US automobile

industry. The American Economic Review. 213-218.

Burt, R. S. 1992. Structural holes: The social structure of competition. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University

Press.

Cameron, A. C., P.K. Trivedi. 2005. Microeconometrics: methods and applications. Cambridge University

Press.

Cohen, W. M., D.A. Levinthal. 1990. Absorptive Capacity: A new perspective on learning and

innovation. Admin. Sci. Quart. 35(1) 128-152.

Page 24: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

24

Cohen, W. M., A. Goto, A. Nagata, R. R. Nelson, J. P. Walsh. 2002. R&D spillovers, patents and the

incentives to innovate in Japan and the United States. Res. Policy. 31(8-9) 1349–1367.

Cyert, R.M., J.G. March. 1963 A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

Freeman, L. C. 1979. Centrality in social networks conceptual clarification. Social Networks. 1(3) 215-

239.

Goerzen, A. 2007. Alliance networks and firm performance: The impact of repeated partnerships.

Strategic Management J. 28(5) 487-509.

Griliches, Z. 1990. Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey. J. Econom. Lit. 28(4) 1661–1707.

Gulati, R. 1995. Social structure and alliance formation patterns: A longitudinal analysis. Administrative

Science Quarterly. 619-652.

Hagedoorn, J., R. Narula.1996. Choosing organizational modes of strategic technology partnering:

international and sectoral differences. J. Internat. Bus. Stud. 27(2).

Hamilton, J. D. 1983. Oil and the macroeconomy since World War II. The Journal of Political Economy.

228-248.

Hannan, M. T., J. Freeman. 1984. Structural inertia and organizational change. American Sociological

Review. 149-164.

Hannan, M.T., J. Freeman. 1989. Organization Ecology. Harvard University Press. Cambridge.

Haveman, H. A. 1992. Between a rock and a hard place: Organizational change and performance under

conditions of fundamental environmental transformation. Administrative Science Quarterly 48-75.

Helfat, C. E., M.A. Peteraf, M. A. 2003. The dynamic resource-based view: capability lifecycles.

Strategic Management J. 24(10) 997–1010.

Helfat, C. E., S. Finkelstein, W. Mitchell, M. A. Peteraf, H. Singh, D. J Teece. S.G. Winter. 2007.

Dynamic capabilities: Understanding strategic change in organizations. Malden, MA: Wiley-Blackwell.

Karim, S. 2006. Modularity in organizational structure: The reconfiguration of internally developed and

acquired business units. Strategic Management Journal 27(9) 799.

Karim, S., W. Mitchell. 2000. Path-dependent and path-breaking change: Reconfiguring business

resources following acquisitions in the US medical sector. Strat. Mgmt. J. 21 (10-11) 1061–1081.

Lavie, D. 2006. The competitive advantage of interconnected firms: an extension of the resource-based

view. Acad. Management Rev. 31(3) 638-658.

Lavie, D., S.R. Miller. 2008. Alliance portfolio internationalization and firm performance. Organ. Sci.

19(4) 623-646.

Lawrence, P. R., J.W. Lorsch. 1967. Differentiation and integration in complex

organizations. Administrative Science Quarterly 1-47.

Page 25: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

25

Leonard-Barton D. 1992. Core capabilities and core rigidities: a paradox in managing new product

development. Strategic Management Journal. 13 (SI) 111-126.

Levinthal, D. A. 1997. Adaptation on rugged landscapes. Management Science. 43(7) 934-950.

Levinthal, D. A., J. G March. 1993. The myopia of learning. Strategic Management Journal. 14(S2) 95-

112.

Levitt, B., & March, J. G. 1988. Organizational Learning. Annual Rev. Soc. 14(1) 319-340.

March, J. G. 1991. Exploration and exploitation in organizational learning. Organization Science. 2(1)

71-87.

March, J.G., H.A. Simon. 1958. Organizations. Oxford, England: Wiley Organizations.

Mitchell, W., K. Singh. 1996. Survival of businesses using collaborative relationships to commercialize

complex goods. Strategic Management Journal. 17(3) 169-195.

Mowery, D. C., J. E. Oxley, B. S. Silverman. 1996. Strategic alliances and interfirm knowledge transfer.

Strategic Management J. 17(1) 77-91.

Nagarajan, A., W. Mitchell. 1998. Evolutionary diffusion: Internal and external methods used to acquire

encompassing, complementary, and incremental technological changes in the lithotripsy industry.

Strategic Management Journal. 19 1063–1077.

Nelson, R. R. 1994. Evolutionary theorizing about economic change. In Smelser, N. J. and R. Swedberg

(eds.), Handbook of Economic Sociology (pp. 108–136). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Nelson, R. R., S.G. Winter, S. G. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA:

Harvard University Press.

Powell, W. W., K. W. Koput, L. Smith-Doerr. 1996. Interorganizational collaboration and the locus of

innovation. Admin. Sci. Quart. 41(1) 116-145.

Priem, R.L, J. E. Butler. 2001. Is the resource-based ‘view’ a useful perspective for strategic management

research? Academy of Management Review 26(1): 22–40.

Rosenkopf, L., P. Almeida. 2003. Overcoming local search through alliances and mobility. Management

Sci. 751–766.

Rosenkopf, L., A. Nerkar. 2001. Beyond local search: Boundary-spanning, exploration, and impact in the

optical disk industry. Strategic Management Journal. 22(4) 287-306.

Rothaermel, F. T., D. L. Deeds. 2004. Exploration and exploitation alliances in biotechnology: A system

of new product development. Strategic Management J. 25(3) 201–221.

Schilling, M. A., C.C. Phelps. 2007. Interfirm collaboration networks: The impact of large-scale network

structure on firm innovation. Management Sci. 53(7) 1113–1126.

Siggelkow, N., D. A. Levinthal. 2005. Escaping real (non-benign) competency traps: Linking the

dynamics of organizational structure to the dynamics of search. Strategic Organization. 3(1) 85-115.

Page 26: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

26

Sirmon, D. G., M. A. Hitt, R. D. Ireland. 2007. Managing firm resources in dynamic environments to

create value: Looking inside the black box. Acad. Management Rev. 32(1) 273-292.

Stuart, T. E. 2000. Interorganizational alliances and the performance of firms: A study of growth and

innovation rates in a high-technology industry. Strategic Management J. 791–811.

Teece, D. J., G. Pisano, A. Shuen. 1997. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic

Management J. 18(7) 509-533.

Tripsas, M., G. Gavetti. 2000. Capabilities, cognition, and inertia: Evidence from digital

imaging. Strategic Management Journal. 21(10-11) 1147-1161.

Tushman, M. L., P. Anderson. 1986. Technological discontinuities and organizational environments.

Admin. Sci. Quart. 31(3) 439–465.

Vassolo, R. S., J. Anand, T. B. Folta. 2004. Non-additivity in portfolios of exploration activities: A real

options-based analysis of equity alliances in biotechnology. Strategic Management J. 25(11) 1045–1061.

Vasudeva, G., J. Anand. 2011. Unpacking absorptive capacity: A study of knowledge utilization from

alliance portfolios. Academy of Management Journal. 54(3) 611-623.

Wernerfelt, B. 1984. A resource-based view of the firm. Strategic Management J. 5(2) 171-180.

Williamson, O. E. 1991. Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural

alternatives. Admin. Sci. Quart. 36(2).

Wooldridge, J. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge: MIT Press.

Wuyts, S., S. Dutta, S. Stremersch. 2004. Portfolios of interfirm agreements in technology-intensive

markets: Consequences for innovation and profitability. J. Marketing, 68(2) 88–100.

Zellner, A. 1962. An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for

aggregation bias. Journal of the American Statistical Association. 57(298) 348-368.

Zollo, M., S. G. Winter. 2002. Deliberate learning and the evolution of dynamic capabilities. Organ. Sci.

339–351.

Page 27: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

27

Figure 1(a). Internal and External Portfolio Technological Diversity Evolution (Observed—All

Firms)

Figure 1(b). Internal and External Portfolio Technological Diversity Evolution (Observed—Ballard

Power Systems)

0.2

.4.6

.81

0 10 20 30Firm Age

Portfolio Technological Diversity Fitted values

Firm Technological Diversity Fitted values

0.2

.4.6

.81

0 10 20 30Firm Age

Portfolio Technological Diversity Fitted values

Firm Technological Diversity Fitted values

Page 28: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

28

Figure 2 Internal and External Portfolio Technological Diversity Evolution (Estimated)

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

0 4 8 12 16 20 24 28 32

Tec

hn

olo

gic

al

Div

ersi

ty

Firm Age

Firm Technological Diversity Portfolio Technological Diversity

Page 29: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

29

Table 1(a) Summary Statistics

Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

Internal Portfolio Tech. Diversity 985.00 0.44 0.38 0.00 0.95

Tech. Age 985.00 9.99 8.70 0.00 32.00

Tech. Base 985.00 12.11 24.71 0.00 228.00

Degree 985.00 5.21 7.57 0.82 100.00

Efficiency 985.00 0.90 0.17 0.33 1.00

Total Inventors 656.00 15.48 39.56 0.00 391.00

Total Prior Citations 912.00 8763.08 40379.46 0.00 539320.00

Industry Size 985.00 266.14 119.88 43.00 408.00

Jaffe Dist. 985.00 0.76 0.25 0.10 1.00

Pre-Entry Experience 981.00 0.85 0.36 0.00 1.00

Average Age of Alliances 985.00 2.74 1.26 1.00 5.00

Prop. Equity Alliances 985.00 0.26 0.38 0.00 1.00

Prop. Repeated Alliances 985.00 0.06 0.18 0.00 1.00

External Portfolio Tech. Value 985.00 0.01 0.01 0.00 0.09

External Portfolio Tech. Diversity 985.00 0.77 0.29 0.00 1.00

External Portfolio Geog. Diversity 985.00 0.20 0.32 0.00 1.00

Table 1(b) Correlations

Variable 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16

1 Internal Portfolio Tech. Diversity 1.00

2 Tech. Age 0.66 1.00

3 Tech. Base 0.61 0.48 1.00

4 Degree 0.13 -0.02 0.04 1.00

5 Efficiency -0.10 -0.10 0.00 -0.14 1.00

6 Total Inventors 0.42 0.29 0.67 0.13 0.02 1.00

7 Total Prior Citations 0.21 0.14 0.47 0.13 -0.01 0.61 1.00

8 Industry Size 0.04 0.16 0.07 -0.35 0.01 0.08 0.14 1.00

9 Jaffe Dist. -0.56 -0.45 -0.52 -0.18 0.22 -0.41 -0.34 -0.22 1.00

10 Pre-Entry Experience -0.02 0.15 -0.11 0.02 -0.04 -0.16 -0.21 -0.19 0.04 1.00

11 Average Age of Alliances 0.10 0.13 0.08 -0.06 0.05 0.06 0.02 -0.06 -0.04 0.15 1.00

12 Prop. Equity Alliances -0.15 -0.15 -0.06 -0.07 0.11 -0.06 0.02 0.05 0.11 -0.01 0.00 1.00

13 Prop. Repeated Alliances 0.06 0.12 0.04 0.03 -0.02 0.10 0.11 0.05 -0.05 0.02 0.05 0.09 1.00

14 External Portfolio Tech. Value 0.10 0.03 0.00 -0.03 -0.03 -0.02 -0.05 -0.04 -0.18 0.09 -0.01 -0.10 -0.02 1.00

15 External Portfolio Tech. Diversity 0.21 0.14 0.13 0.04 -0.14 0.10 0.07 0.07 -0.32 0.01 -0.02 0.00 0.05 0.30 1.00

16 External Portfolio Geog. Diversity 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.02 0.10 0.07 0.12 -0.08 0.15 -0.09 -0.04 0.08 0.09 -0.28 0.39 1.00

Page 30: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

30

Table 2. Seemingly unrelated regression estimates of firm internal and external portfolio

technological diversity (linear term for technological age)

Variables Internal Portfolio

Technological Diversity

External Portfolio

Technological Diversity

Firm Characteristics

Technological Age 0.03 (0.01)*** -0.004 (0.01)

Technological Base -0.002 (0.00)* -0.003 (0.00)*

Degree Centrality 0.001 (0.00) 0.001 (0.00)

Efficiency 0.15 (0.05)** -0.25 (0.06)***

Total Inventor Count 0.0009 (0.00)* 0.0004 (0.00)

Total Citations Count -0.00 (0.00) -0.00 (0.00)

Industry Size -0.0001 (0.00) 0.0007 (0.00)

Jaffe Technological Distance -0.33 (0.04)*** -0.53 (0.05)***

Pre-Entry Industry Experience 0.09 (0.14) 1.20 (0.26)***

Alliance Portfolio Characteristics

Average Alliance Duration 0.001 (0.01)

Proportion Equity -0.04 (0.03)

Proportion Repeated 0.05 (0.05)

Technological Value 6.65 (0.71)***

Geographical Diversity 0.60 (0.03)***

Firm Fixed Effects Yes Yes

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes

N 655

Constant 0.01

Breusch Pagan Chi-square test of

Correlated Errors

11.51***

Page 31: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

31

Table 3. Seemingly unrelated regression estimates of firm internal and external portfolio

technological diversity (linear and quadratic terms for technological age)

Variables Internal Portfolio

Technological Diversity

External Portfolio

Technological Diversity

Firm Characteristics

Technological Age 0.064 (0.01)*** 0.008 (0.01) †

Technological Age Sq. -0.0008 (0.00)*** -0.0003 (0.00)*

Technological Base -0.0008 (0.00) -0.002 (0.00)*

Degree Centrality -0.0007 (0.00) 0.0004 (0.00)

Efficiency 0.14 (0.05)** -0.30 (0.06)***

Total Inventor Count 0.0003 (0.00) 0.0002 (0.00)

Total Citations Count 0.00 (0.00) -0.00 (0.00)

Industry Size -0.001 (0.00)* 0.0002 (0.00)

Jaffe Technological Distance -0.31 (0.04)*** -0.52 (0.05)***

Pre-Entry Industry Experience 0.16 (0.13) 1.34 (0.26)***

Alliance Portfolio Characteristics

Average Alliance Duration 0.001 (0.01)

Proportion Equity -0.03 (0.03)

Proportion Repeated 0.08 (0.05)*

Technological Value 6.80 (0.71)***

Geographical Diversity 0.60 (0.03)***

Firm Fixed Effects Yes Yes

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes

N 655

Constant 0.27

Breusch Pagan Chi-square test of

Correlated Errors

16.00***

β coefficient (standard errors); *** p < 0.001; **p<0.01; *p<0.05; †p<0.10; single-tailed tests

Page 32: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

32

Table 4. Fixed effects estimates of firm internal and external portfolio technological diversity as

independent equations

Variables Internal Portfolio

Technological Diversity

External Portfolio

Technological Diversity†

Firm Characteristics

Technological Age 0.06 (0.01)*** 0.02 (0.03)

Technological Age Sq. -0.008 (0.00)** -0.005 (0.00)*

Firm Tech. Diversity -0.22 (0.08)**

Technological Base -0.0008 (0.00) -0.002 (0.00)*

Degree Centrality -0.0007 (0.00) 0.0002 (0.00)

Efficiency 0.14 (0.07)* -0.23 (0.09)**

Total Inventor Count 0.0003 (0.00) 0.0002 (0.00)

Total Citations Count 0.00 (0.00) -0.00 (0.00)

Industry Size -0.001 (0.00) 0.0001 (0.00)

Jaffe Technological Distance -0.31 (0.08)*** -0.59 (0.09)***

Alliance Portfolio Characteristics

Portfolio Tech. Diversity -0.0005 (0.04)

Average Alliance Duration 0.002 (0.01)

Proportion Equity -0.03(0.04)

Proportion Repeated 0.09 (0.10)

Technological Value 6.81 (2.08)***

Geographical Diversity 0.60 (0.05)***

Firm Fixed Effects Yes Yes

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes

Constant 0.38* 1.13*

N 655 655

R-square 0.52 0.40 β coefficient (standard errors); *** p < 0.001; **p<0.01; *p<0.05; †p<0.10; single-tailed tests; robust standard errors

Page 33: Gurneeta Vasudeva Jaideep Anand · improve performance (Lavie 2006, Anand et al. 2010, Vasudeva and Anand 2011). Alliances also allow firms to cope with discontinuities by continuously

33

Table 5. Seemingly unrelated regression estimates of firm internal and external portfolio

technological diversity

Early Cohort (Firms Entering

Industry before or in 1990)

Late Cohort (Firms Entering

Industry after 1990)

Variables Internal

Portfolio

Technological

Diversity

External Portfolio

Technological

Diversity

Internal Portfolio

Technological

Diversity

External

Portfolio

Technological

Diversity

Firm Characteristics

Technological Age 0.13 (0.02)*** 0.004(0.02) -0.02(0.01)* 0.07(0.01)***

Technological Age Sq. -0.0009

(0.00)***

0.00001(0.0002) 0.004(0.001)*** -0.001(0.001)

Technological Base -0.003 (0.00)** -0.003(0.001)* 0.01(0.003)*** -0.002(0.004)

Degree Centrality -0.001 (0.00) 0.004(0.001)* 0.007(0.003)* -0.007(0.004)*

Efficiency 0.06 (0.05) -0.30(0.06)*** 0.17(0.08)* 0.10(0.10)

Total Inventor Count 0.00 (0.00)* 0.0009(0.0005)* 0.008(0.001)*** -0.003(0.002)

Total Citations Count 0.00 (0.00) -0.00(0.00)* -0.00(0.00)* 0.00(0.00)

Industry Size -0.01 (0.00)*** 0.0007(0.001) 0.0005(0.0004) -0.0004(0.000)

Jaffe Technological Distance -0.23 (0.05)*** -0.56(0.05)*** -0.32(0.07)* -0.25(0.09)**

Pre-Entry Industry Experience 0.51(0.23)* 0.78(0.28)** 0.12(0.12) 0.34(0.15)*

Alliance Portfolio

Characteristics

Average Alliance Duration 0.004(0.007) -0.01(0.009)

Proportion Equity 0.06(0.03)* -0.21(0.04)***

Proportion Repeated 0.03(0.05) 0.06(0.09)

Technological Value 6.88(0.82)*** 7.22(1.46)***

Geographical Diversity 0.62(0.03) 0.63(0.04)***

Firm Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes Yes

Constant -0.20 0.52*

N 371 284

Breusch Pagan Chi-square test

of Correlated Errors

2.05† 2.64*

β coefficient (standard errors); *** p < 0.001; **p<0.01; *p<0.05; †p<0.10; single-tailed tests