Markus Subsidies

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

About subsidies

Citation preview

  • Getting smart about subsidiesMarkus Goldstein The World Bank

  • Subsidies are all around us Obvious ones such as agriculture, urban transport, fuelBut think about the air we breathe (e.g. subsidies for pollution control), the water we drink (subsidies for water utilities)Not all subsidies are bad, but in order to tell the good from the bad we need to think smart.

  • How do we think smart about subsidies?Think systematicallyWhat are subsidies and why are they important?Why do we subsidize?Who gets the subsidies?How do we implement subsidies?

  • Why are subsidies important?Subsidies are political

  • Why are subsidies important?A lot of money is spent on subsidiesIn 2005, the EU was spending 2 euros per cow, per day (puts them above the poverty line)Egypt spent an estimated 6.9% of GDP on fuel subsidies and 1.6% on food subsidies in 2005/6Subsidies can have big policy effectsMalawi removed all primary school fees, enrollment went up by 1 million children over 6 years, and the enrollment gap between rich and poor closed

  • We often view subsidies too narrowlyThe tendency is to think in terms of producer subsidies (e.g. agriculture) but they apply to both supply & demandA subsidy is when the price is lower than the cost, where the government provides the fundsAnd a tax is a negative subsidy

  • Why subsidize?

  • Do we know why we subsidize?Take the case for subsidizing primary health care:Some would argue its a right, so we do it for equity reasonsOthers would argue market failure, e.g. incomplete informationStill others would argue that it is an externality healthier people are better able to participate in societySo the answer is both yes and no we can see a set of justifications, maybe even more than one for a given subsidyTo understand whether a subsidy is working or not, we need to know why -- the main reason why -- we did it in the first placeUnderstanding why a subsidy is in place, also provides grounds for taking the debate into the political realm and dealing with fiscal constraints

  • So why do we actually subsidize?Markets arent working right efficiencyWe care about the poor equityThere may (or may not) be tradeoffs across theseThese are tempered by the hard facts of real constraints, in particular:Fiscal constraintsPolitics

  • Making markets work right Externalities e.g. government subsidies to identify and treat tuberculosis Special case of externalities is public goodse.g. government funds (100% subsidy) national defenseMarket failures due to information issuese.g. the rationale for subsidizing microcredit

  • Promoting equityBest option: give the poor the cash. But:Administration costs are too highPossible political constraintsSo we subsidizeBut we need to consider what we mean by equity

  • An equity/efficiency tradeoff? Often, but not alwaysReasons there might not be an equity/efficiency tradeoff:When correcting market failure is not possible or too costly, some redistribution can improve efficiency e.g. think about subsidizing education, Psacharopoulos (1994) estimates returns to primary education of 24 percent in Africa and 20 percent in Asiawe could try to create a credit market to pay for primary education but this is really not feasible.

  • Not always a tradeoff -2 Getting rid of some kind of subsidies can improve both equity and efficiencye.g. In Japan, the average farm hh income is 110% of average hh income, yet over 2000-2 producers received $47.5 bn in subsidiesBetween 1996-2000, the US government mailed farm subsidy checks to 31 addresses in Beverly Hills and 803 in Washington D.C.

  • For better or worse, equity and efficiency run into politics and real budget constraints

  • 3 questions to assess the political constraintsWho are the winners/losers and who will they vote for (if they vote)?Who are the interest groups around this issue and how much power do they have?What is the time horizon of policy makers? Outcome need not be fair nor efficient

  • Politics in action: food subsidies in Sri LankaFood subsidy, almost universal from independenceMaintained by govts of different ideology in the name of political stability and equityBroad based political support, particularly from organized laborSubsidies to producers as well to keep them happy

  • And making things better could make them worse1978-9 large devaluation, new govtImplemented means test the pop.Change from rations to food stamps and froze new issues and nominal budget allocationRemoved price subsidiesProtected wage earners who were no longer getting subsidies through inc. wages (interest groups)But then, benefits erode with inflationpolitical constituency? (time horizon of policy makers, beneficiaries did not have enough voting power)

  • Three ways to pay the bill1. Tax and redistributee.g. Health in Finland taxes from the state (progressive income and indirect) and municipalitiesPatients pay only 24%, the remainder is financed by local (43%) and national govt (18%) and national health insurance (15%)Over 80% of Finns are satisfied with their health care, against EU average of 41%

  • Paying the Bill (2 )2. Cross-subsidizeCan be within or across sectorGabon: urban electricity subsidizes water and electricity in rural areas and small towns. Ecuador: surcharge on telecom subsidizes water3. Grantse.g. Tajikistan Pamir Power ProjectPoor people, low capacity, irregular supplyConcession put in place, but move to market prices for power immediately not feasible (500% increase required)Mix of IDA, Swiss and IFC funding for 10 year gradual phase out of subsidized prices

  • Some things you need to know to pay the bill:

  • Do we know who we subsidize?

  • Primary education is progressive, but higher education is not

    CountryEarly Childhood, PreschoolPrimarySecondaryTertiaryOverallBolivia (2002)ProgressiveRegressiveRegressiveCambodia (1997)NeutralRegressiveRegressiveCambodia (2002) ProgressiveRegressiveRegressiveNeutralEcuador (1999)ProgressiveBell CurveRegressiveJamaica (2000)ProgressiveProgressiveBell CurveRegressiveNeutralMadagascar (2001)RegressiveRegressiveMexico (2002)ProgressiveProgressiveRegressiveRegressiveNeutralEl Salvador (2002)ProgressiveProgressiveRegressiveRegressiveProgressiveVietnam (1998)ProgressiveRegressiveVietnam (2002)ProgressiveRegressive

  • Health varies

    CountryTypeDistributionBolivia (1999)Social Insurance RegressivePublic Expenditure ProgressiveEcuador (1999)Health Care IESSRegressiveHealth Care MSPRelatively NeutralHealth Care SSCProgressiveMexico (2002)All Public Health ExpenditureRegressive*El Salvador (2002)Hospital CareRelatively NeutralPrimary Health CareProgressiveJamaica (1991-2002)Average Ratio of Poorest to Richest Quintile for Public Hospital Use (Q1/Q5)1.83Jamaica (1991-2002)Average Ratio of Poorest to Richest Quintile for Primary Care Use (Q1/Q5)0.82Jamaica (1991-2002)Average Ratio of Poorest to Richest Quintile for Outpatient Care (Q1/Q5)1.76

  • Infrastructure subsidies are clearly regressiveregressiveprogressive

  • So who do we subsidize?First step is to look at incidence data what share of the benefits go to an income group? But both the benefits and the costs (taxes) to the individual matter

  • At the national level, adding them up is key

    Benefit VAT

    14.60.1

    11.7-0.9

    11.1-1.7

    10.8-2.5

    9.2-3.6

    9.8-5

    9.4-7.1

    8.6-11.1

    8.8-17.7

    5.8-50.5

    Benefits

    Taxes

    Decile

    Percent

    Mexico: Benefits and Taxes

    Net Effect

    81.4

    33.8

    23.1

    16.1

    9.6

    6.9

    2.6

    -2.4

    -6.3

    -15.8

    % Change in autonomous income from current VAT average public expenditure

    Decile

    Mexico: Net Effect

    Sheet1

    DecileBenefitsNet TaxesTaxes% Change in autonomous income from current VAT average public expenditure

    114.6-0.10.181.4

    211.70.9-0.933.8

    311.11.7-1.723.1

    410.82.5-2.516.1

    59.23.6-3.69.6

    69.85-56.9

    79.47.1-7.12.6

    88.611.1-11.1-2.4

    98.817.7-17.7-6.3

    105.850.5-50.5-15.8

    99.8100149

    Sheet2

    Sheet3

    Sheet4

    Sheet5

    Sheet6

  • To estimate the net effect of public subsidies - tax

    Benefit VAT

    14.60.1

    11.7-0.9

    11.1-1.7

    10.8-2.5

    9.2-3.6

    9.8-5

    9.4-7.1

    8.6-11.1

    8.8-17.7

    5.8-50.5

    Benefits

    Taxes

    Decile

    Percent

    Mexico: Benefits and Taxes

    net effect

    81.4

    33.8

    23.1

    16.1

    9.6

    6.9

    2.6

    -2.4

    -6.3

    -15.8

    net effect, % of hh income

    decile

    % of hh income

    Mexico: Net Effect

    Sheet1

    DecileBenefitsNet TaxesTaxesnet effect, % of hh income

    114.6-0.10.181.4

    211.70.9-0.933.8

    311.11.7-1.723.1

    410.82.5-2.516.1

    59.23.6-3.69.6

    69.85-56.9

    79.47.1-7.12.6

    88.611.1-11.1-2.4

    98.817.7-17.7-6.3

    105.850.5-50.5-15.8

    99.8100149

    Sheet2

    Sheet3

    Sheet4

    Sheet5

    Sheet6

  • How do we implement subsidies?

  • The rationale for the subsidy tells us where to startIf we are doing subsidies for equity reasons we need to target both:Access Affordability

    If subsidies are justified for efficiency concerns, we need to target:Overcoming/reducing a market distortionChanging behavior

  • And what we need to knowKnow your poor in order to achieve access and affordabilityKnow your markets (including public goods) when trying to remove distortionsKnow your elasticity when trying to change behavior

  • We have some (potentially) powerful toolsKnow your poor (access and affordability)poverty assessments, poverty maps Know your markets (remove distortions)Market assessments, CEM, PSIA, WTP studiesKnow your elasticities (change behavior)Market assessments, ESW, WTP studiesData is key household, investment climate, market SURVEYS

  • But what about the constraints? (1)Political economyKnow your polityPSIAKeep in mind the political economy can be an opportunity, not only a constraintUse politics to put subsidies on the table and in perspective:e.g. Andhra Pradesh: introduced metering so that subsidy was visible, transparente.g. Punjab: free power, but part of a fixed agricultural budget

  • What about the constraints (2) FiscalKnow your budget, know your incidence (dont forget the taxes)CEM, PERFor equity: think about real tradeoffs, balance inclusion/exclusion

  • What can make subsidies go wrong (or right)?

  • We need to avoid bad designBadly designed Information was inadequate/wrongWithin the relevant market:e.g. Cote dIvoire waterLack of attention to other marketse.g electricity/irrigation in IndiaQuestion of providerKeep in mind subsidies are about govt finance, not provision

  • And the environment matters tooConstraints change (good design initially)BudgetPolitical economye.g. Sri Lanka foodBudget constraints tighten Possible opportunity to narrow targetingOr political economy binds and benefits erode

  • In the end good design can have a powerful impact The Bangladesh secondary school stipendTuition and stipend subsidy for girls for educational costs, supplies, uniforms and transport. Good design: priced well (~1/2 of costs), tied to attendance. The subsidy was put very close to the good it was aimed at.Covered 1.9 million girls in 2004, for around $25 millionResulted in enrollment increases of 8-12 percentage points.

  • To take stock:Not all subsidies are bad Bad subsidies are bad.To separate the good and the bad, think systematicallyUnderstand why we have this subsidyWho is the subsidy for, who is getting it?How is this subsidy improving access, affordability, reducing distortions, or changing behavior. Is this the best feasible way?Benchmark on the counterfactual of no intervention make an informed decision

  • Now how do we decide what to do?

  • Why?EquityEfficiency

  • EquityWill a lump sum transfer work?yesNo subsidynoSubsidy for whom?Identify target poorAccessAffordability Identify targeting mechanism Identify political constraints and opportunities Identify fiscal constraints & tradeoffs

  • EfficiencyBehaviorReduce market distortionsExternalities & other MFPublic Goods govt funds these assess optimal level of provision know elasticities identify closest and least distortionary policy handle know markets identify closest and least distortionary policy handle identify funding mechanism, fiscal constraints and tradeoffs

  • This is a PREM taskSubsidies are everywhere PREM economists have a central role in thinking about them systematicallyUnderstanding within sectorAdding up across sectors and taxesHelping identify tradeoffs for the govtWe have an existing set of tools that allow us to tackle these issues

    In terms of the air we breathe you can think about fuel subsidies ranging from subsidies for oil extraction to subsidies for consumers (not charging the full price and we can also think of subsidies for clean air (e.g. in New Delhi, as part of the switch to compressed natural gas as a fuel for public transport, the conversion of engines for motorized rickshaws was subsidized)

    In terms of the water we drink in high-income countries, only 50 percent of water utilities charge tariffs high enough to cover more than operation and maintenance cost. In low-income countries, barely 3 percent of water utilities were able to achieve this level. Komives, et. al. (published version) pp20-22Heres the outline for the talk:-what is a subsidy, here the main thing is that the definition tends to be too narrow-

    Politics these pictures come from subsidies related protests, on the left is fuel subsidy protests in Indonesia (2005) when the government announced that the subsidy would be cut and fuel prices would rise (BBC Sat Oct 1 2005) and on the right are german farmers protesting proposed cuts to farm subsidies Eu figure comes from Deutsche Welle article of 6/22/2005 "The EU spends two euros a day per cow," Britain's new minister for European affairs, Douglas Alexander, recently summed up the situation. Egypt figures come from IMF Country report n0 06/253, July 2006 (they are projections)

    Malawi example from Al-Samarrai and Zaman, forthcoming Education Economics. On page 6 Primary school fess were completely abolished in the 1994/95 school year. This led to a surge in primary enrolment from 1.9 million students in 1993/4 to 2.9 million in 1999/00In 1990/91 the primary gross enrollment rate for the richest quintile was almost double that of the poorest quintile. By 1997/98 this gap in enrolment had been virtually eliminated.In terms of narrow definitions, a good example is the IMF international financial statistics:Subsidies are current unrequited payments that government units make to enterprises on the basis of the levels of their production activities or the quantitiesor values of the goods or services they produce, sell, export, or import. Subsidies may be designed to influence levels of production, the prices at which outputsare sold, or the remuneration of the enterprises.

    Subsidies are payable to producers only, not to final consumers, and are current transfers only, not capital transfers. Transfers that government unitsmake directly to households as consumers and most transfers to nonprofit institutions serving households are treated as either social benefits (27) or miscellaneousother expense (282) depending on the reason for the payment. Most transfers made to general government units are included in grants (26).10 Paymentsto enterprises to finance their capital formation, to compensate them for damage to nonfinancial assets, or to cover large operating deficits accumulated overtwo or more years are miscellaneous other capital expense (2822).

    Source: Government Finance Statistics Manual 2001 http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfs/manual/pdf/ch6.pdf

    Some other examples of narrow/parochial definitions:from Princetons website: a grant paid by a government to an enterprise that benefits the public; "a subsidy for research in artificial intelligence" from the Customs centre in Austrailia:An economic benefit granted by a government to producers of goods, often to strengthen their competitive position. The subsidy may be direct (a cash grant) or indirect (low-interest export credits guaranteed by a government agency, for example)

    On the definition point: note that the government provides the funds but the service they subsidize may in fact be provided by the private sector or an NGO (in addition to the government).

    On the tax point an interesting example comes from the effort to improve the air quality by switching to compressed natural gas in New Delhi. Here the government subsidized the owners of motorized rickshaws to convert their vehicles and fined (taxed) bus owners who did not convert their vehicles.

    Princeton ref is http://wordnet.princeton.edu/ (cognitive science)customscentre.canberra.edu.au/glossary/glossary-S.htmlIts a basic right, so it must be an equity issueThe hard headed economist says no, its a market failure due to incomplete information on the clients, or maybe a discount rate issuesThe not-so hard headed economist says no, its an externality healthier people will be better able to participate in society something we dont take into account when making our individual, private health care choices

    This slide presents a road map for the next section of the discussion the why subsidize questionWhat do we do when markets are not working right (i.e. not efficient)?Government intervenes. One of our common tools is a tax and a subsidy is a tax with a different sign. Here we start our discussion of what the particular market imperfections are that motivate subsidies.

    The definition of an externality is when the action of an agent affect at least one other through mechanism(s) other than price.An important thing to note about externalities is that they create a difference between marginal social cost (benefit) and private cost (benefit)

    Public goods are an externality because individuals do not take into account the marginal benefit (cost) to other individuals when deciding how much of a public good to purchase. Public goods are which are non-rivalrous and non-excludable Talk about non-rivalrous, non-excludable hard criteria to meet, few pure examples you might think roads are a public good, but technically they are not (e.g. they are rivalrous look at traffic). There are a large set of goods which have some aspects of public goods (they are either non-rivalrous or non-excludable. Here the simple logic for government provision breaks down (witness the debate over toll roads). Well come back a bit to considering those types of goods/services and how much to subsidize them towards the end of the presentation.

    On market failure due to information issues: Here the big examples are insurance and credit markets e.g. part of the logic for microfinance is that the information costs for very small borrowers is often prohibitive for standard institutions and some form of subsidy is needed. In many cases, when you include technical assistance and the cost of funds, subsidies continue.

    When the goal is equity (and not market failures) we want to redistribute income. The best way to do this is just to give the poor a lump sum transfer. But this may involve prohibitive administrative costs (identification, delivery, etc) and there also may be political obstacles (for example, its possibly a lot more politically obvious to transfer a chunk of money to the poor than to lower the price they pay for a given good).

    Given these, we turn to subsidies as a tool for redistribution. (Keep in mind that these subsidies can be in kind (usually altering the price of a good or service that the poor consume) but it could also be in cash with restrictions (e.g. PROGRESSA and other conditional cash transfers, where there is a cash transfer conditional on certain consumption pattern) .

    Now that we have decided to subsidize, the first question (which incidentally also applies to the lump sum case) is what we mean by equity who gets how much. Ultimately this is about some kind of social welfare function which will tell us what weights different types of individuals in society have (for example, everyone, poor or not, could be weighted equally or we might want to give more weight to the poor). Equity is a broad and politically charged concept and the subject for another, longer, discussion (see for example the WDR 2006). In the end, weights in society will be determined by the institutions and the process by which these institutions make decisions

    Having looked at equity and efficiency as logic for subsidies we can turn to a sometimes used third reason merit goods. Merit goods are not only used for museums but sometimes used to justify a host of basic social services primary education, clean water and the like. This may be the case, but we need to unpack the definition a bit 1)individuals cannot correctly perceive their own welfare is paternalism, the state knows best; 2) society may wish for an equitable distribution of these goods is equity; and 3) consumption of certain goods contribute to the formation of values upon which society is based is an externality (e.g. in education one of the justifications is that better educated people make better citizens/voters and this is something we dont take into account much when choosing education. In the end, we may decide that this is a good reason to subsidize (e.g. most every country has government subsidized museums) but we need to be explicit about it and we need to clearly separate it from equity and efficiency arguments. Too often merit goods are used as a sort of catch all explanation.

    Psacharopoulos from World Development 22 (9): 1325-1343. More recent estimates from Knowles and Behrman (Jan 2005 HNP working paper) find that formal schooling for youth has rates of return that are at least as high as are those for many investments in other sectors for the small number of cases where they can consistently estimate this. Other fun US farm subsidy fact: what do Scottie Pippen, Larry Flynt, and and Bernard Ebbers all have in common? Ans: they all benefited from US farm subsidies.

    Japanese data comes from Aksoy and Beghin, Global Agricultural Trade and Developing Countries, a World Bank book.. US data comes from Goodwin, et. al. Landowners Riches: The Distribution of Agricultural Subsidies on the NBER website.

    Examples of these kind of subsidies arent confined to developed countries. Take the case of electricity in Andhra Pradesh. Getting rid of this subsidy would, arguably, be both efficiency and equity enhancing. Efficiency enhancing because due to subsidies the government has to roster the electricity (i.e. give farmers electricity at pre-announced and restricted hours). But due to energy shortages the quality, amount and voltage of electricity is unreliable. This leads to unpredictability of supply which can cripple yields and periodic blow outs of pump motors and transformers. Furthermore, since farmers are charged a flat rate on electricity, the marginal cost of pumping more water is 0. This leads to over use of groundwater. This is critical in AP, especially in the drought prone areas. This flat rate also indicates the equity improvement this is a regressive subsidy.

    The reasons we see these kinds of subsidies persisting are political and thus we now turn to take a closer look at political economy issues.

    We now will see the illustration of the first three of these points in an example from Sri Lanka. The subsidy focuses on rice (a staple) but also, at one point or another, covered wheat, flour, sugar, and powdered milk. Also, there were significant balance of payments implications as during most of the universal period, over 50% of food was imported One thing to note is that this government was elected as a liberalizing government, so the initial push for the mandate (reform, overcome the short run view) was there. The means test was a household monthly income threshold (with some marginal allowance for household size) and cut the number of beneficiaries to half the population. In the shift to food stamps, the number of beneficiaries did not fall, but actually started rising. In response the govt fixed the number of beneficiaries and fixed the nominal amount allocated to the food stamp program in the budgetThe government spending on total food (and kerosene) subsidies fell from 15% of govt expenditure (5% of GNP) in the mid 1970s to 5% of govt expenditure (2% of GNP) by 1982. The protection for wage earners came through govt and parastatal wage increases. Note this co-opts one of the powerful interest groups that had been at the heart of earlier protests.An important thing to keep in mind when we talk about tax and redistribution for subsidies is that taxes themselves entail some efficiency cost. In some contexts this can be quite high.

    The national health insurance is mostly payroll deductions so a tax, but has some other sources (returns on assets, etc).

    Health is a significant part of government spending, accounting for 25% of municipal budgets and health, welfare and social security account for about 20% of national government expenditure.

    According to a survey published by the European Commission in 2000, Finland has the highest number of people satisfied with their health care system in the EU: more than 80% of Finnish respondents were satisfied compared with the EU average of 41.3%. These figures come from a WHO Europe report. Finnish tax and spending figures come from the same report. Keep in mind that while a government may face separate fiscal and political economy constraints, they are likely to interact. One such example comes from Sri Lanka:-Early 1950s saw inflationary pressure as rice prices rose.-The government then had overenthusiastic adherence to IMF program subsidies cut-Riots, labor heavily involved-Partial reversal, PM resigns, govt falls, new government and subsidies return fullyNote for the last point that one factor that enabled the new government to return the level of subsidies was the fact that rice prices fell. Keep in mind that this is only one case, but throughout the universal period of the subsidy there was a number of clear cases of fiscal constraints leading to political turnover/turmoil around this subsidy program.

    In terms of tax costs, there may be a bunch of different ways to measure them. Basically, you have to consider the counterfactual to raising the tax, and then cost out the tax (which will include not only the induced changes in behavior but also leakages and administrative costs).

    In terms of cross subsidization, an example of this going awry in Cote dIvoire during 80s:-Put in place free water connections for urban and rural customers-Subsidized by few hundred industrial customers (large surcharges)-Fell apart when industrial customers exited public network

    These data (and the health that follow) come from a review of the 20 PERs done for the last two years (plus an old Cambodia one to get another picture of longitudinal change). Note that only 10 had education expenditure incidence.

    Here we can see that with the exception of Cambodia (in 1997, not 2002) and Madagascar, that primary and preschool spending is progressive. The results at the higher levels, however, show the opposite. In almost all cases secondary and tertiary education are regressive. The exception to this is secondary expenditure in Ecuador and Jamaica where the middle quintiles capture a disproportionate share of the spending relative to the poor and the rich (and hence the distribution has a bell curve shape). Note that the years in parentheses are not necessarily the year of the PER but rather the year that the data used are from. Only five of our 20 PERS had any data on health programs. Here the evidence is mixed, often in ways that are possibly counterintuitive. Take the last three rows which show the data from Jamaica. We can see that outpatient care and hospital care are progressive, while primary care is regressive. On the other hand, in El Salvador we see a pattern similar to education where the higher level care is regressive.

    The case of Mexico is interesting because here we have a fund which is financed by contributions by formal sector employees and their employers. If we net this out, the *net* distribution is neutral, but more on Mexico in a few minutes.

    For Bolivia: Government expenditure is mainly wages and salaries. (central government controls 80 percent of public health expenditure). Municipalities account for around 18percent, which include variable costs of the public health insurance. The remaining 2 percent is managed by Social Investment Fund (FPS) and other public entities. Pg. 107. The public sector also gives an annual subsidy from the public sector to the Health Insurance Funds (which is about 0.2% of GDP), which I believe is the social insurance. (pg. 103)This table is for quantity-based infrastructure subsidies. The targeted performance indicator is share of subsidies that go to the poor over the population share of the poor. So 1 is a neutral subsidy (money dropped from the plane), >1 is progressive, and PSIA on the World Bank website). Willingness to pay/accept (WTP) and contingent valuation studies are key in cases such as determining the right amount of a public good to provide.

    Underlying all of these tools is data. In some cases additional data may need to be collected, in others it is already there. A good place to start for seeing what data is out there is to type data into your browser (if you work in the bank). Not only does this site give you access to some micro and macro data online, it also has Country Statistical Information pages which list the surveys which have been done.

    So weve talked about the main justifications around equity and efficiency and how to approach these. But remember that we have two other factors that shape what is feasible. How do we deal with these in designing subsidies?

    Understanding the political situation is key to understanding what is possible. Ideally, a good PSIA should bring political considerations into the analysis. There will also be a fair amount of informal, unwritten understanding that goes into this analysis. Its important to keep in mind that the political situation can present opportunities as well as problems for example, as we saw earlier in the example of Sri Lanka, there was a significant opportunity to reform a subsidy with the election of a new government.

    Obviously, we have to be able to afford whatever subsidy we are thinking of. So on one level this constraint brings in the issues of knowing your budget envelope and identifying the funding mechanism. This will true for all subsidies. But when we consider equity-justified subsidies, we have to think carefully about targeting which among the poor will get it, and which among the non-poor will get it. (To those of you familiar with the targeting literature, these are the errors of inclusion/exclusion). The budget constraint will dictate how many poor and non-poor can receive this subsidy and this leads to the choice of targeting mechanism. Note that including the non-poor is not always a bad idea for example it can lead to critical political support to continue a subsidy in some cases on the other hand it can also allow for a coarser (and usually cheaper) way of targeting (e.g. target a region rather than individuals).

    On inclusion/exclusion: Recall the earlier slide where we saw that all of the quantity based water and electricity subsidies shown here were regressive. A big contributor to that result is exclusion in many cases the poor (as well as a chunk of the non-poor) are not connected to the water and power grids, and hence cannot receive a tariff subsidy. This points to the fact that you have to consider the exclusion of poor/inclusion of non-poor in light of your budget constraint but adds the twist that in this case it suggests that the intervention is misguided if we want to alleviate poverty we are better off focusing on connection, rather than usage charge subsidies.

    Keep in mind too that the inclusion/exclusion, fiscal constraint and political economy are intertwined. Going back to earlier example of our sri lanka subsidies there was significant leakage in the early 1980s recall it covered 50% of the population but 30% of the lower half of the pop did not get it, while a fair number of those in the upper half did (Edirisinghe p 260. Reforms proposed to fix this in 1985 met with significant protests from current beneficiaries and their elected representatives (Edirinsinghe + Sahn 46)

    To wrap up our discussion of how to implement effective subsidies we need to take a quick look at why subsidies fail. There are two groups here: badly designed subsidies (a lot of which should be avoided with careful thought to the issues we have discussed) and those which were well designed but still went awry. To take a closer look at the badly designed subsidies, we can separate out a few common problems.

    First, we have bad information within the market of concern. We saw that in the case of Cote dIvoire there was an underestimation of the price elasticity of demand of industrial users. As a result, they exited the market when the cross-subsidy surcharge was put in place (for the benefit of poorer households).

    Second, when seeking to remedy a market failure the designer has to pay careful attention to complementary markets. India subsidized water and power for farmers with the goal of increasing agricultural growth (presumably on some logic of credit constraints or equity) but neglected issues of distortions in the land and agricultural output markets. One of the interesting lessons to observe here is that of the political economy circle -- these subsidies have benefited an increasingly entrenched powerful political constituencies that make them hard to reverse. This is an important lesson: a subsidy mistake can be very hard to undo.

    Finally, one area of design in which subsidies may fail (despite having a sound justification and underlying analysis) is in delivery. As we know from our work on leakages and public service delivery, the government may not all be the best provider of a service look at studies of doctor/teacher abseentism, etc in the public sector. Keep in mind that with subsidies the first question is whether the government should pay for it. Then we ask the question as to whom should deliver this: the govt, NGOs or the private sector. This is basically about inflexibility. Once you set up a subsidy, you create a group of beneficiaries who have a clear stake in the continuation of that subsidy. The budget may change and political conditions may change and these will impact the Throughout this presentation we have seen the travails of the Sri Lanka food subsidy and they embody these problems. At one point in time, the budget constraints tightened, this provided an opportunity for narrowing down the targeting, but at other points in time the real value of benefits eroded as budget constraints, combined with political economy factors prevented changes. This program was initiated by the Government of Bangladesh with World Bank support to boost female enrollment. Its primary component was the Stipend and Tuition Subsidy, which provided monthly stipends to girl students from Grade 6 to Grade 10 for female students 11 to 15 years old. The stipends covered nearly half of a girl's annual direct educational costs, including tuition, textbooks, supplies, uniforms, and transportation during rainy season.*

    To start our wrap up, lets revisit the three big questions

    In a fair number of discussions you hear subsidies as justified as good for the poor. Well, as we have seen, that isnt always the case (remember education primary education subsidies are usually good for the poor, secondary not so much). But even if we accept this justification of good for the poor the question is how are they good for the poor are they good for the efficiency of the markets the poor face or good for redistribution? As we saw this makes a big difference in how we will go about things and how we will ultimately judge a subsidy so understanding WHY is key.

    We need to know who is supposed to be getting it, who is getting it and who is not to begin to understand how we should target a subsidy and then the impacts, intended or not.

    How is where the rubber meets the road we need to seek out a subsidy that does what we intended and not a lot of what we did not intend. We need to identify the best possible mechanism to achieve what the justification mandates. We know economies are complex systems and tweaking one price can have repercussions in many other markets.

    In the end we have to weigh this logic and the potential options against the ways things are now subsidies can make things much better (look at the results we are getting on the results of Mexicos PROGRESA/Opportunidades) but in some cases it may be better to do nothing. Since one of the goals of this discussion is to think systematically about subsidizes, lets recap the logic. We start with the basic question is this subsidy (chiefly) by equity or efficiency concerns? This then takes us down 2 separate pathsFor equity, we have to ask if a lump sum transfer will work first. If not, we move to designing a subsidy. The next question is who we need to know who the poor are. Then we decide how to do it do we need access (e.g. building health centers, connecting households to water) or affordability (do we change user fees for health or water tariffs). We have to figure out how we will target people, what are our political constraints (and/or political opportunities) and what we have to work with on the budget side.In an efficiency justified subsidy we are going to look primarily at changing behavior or reducing market distortions. In the realm of changing behavior, we have to know how much people are going to react to the subsidy, so we need to know the relevant elasticities (these include cross elasticities). We want to find the policy handle that imposes the minimum amount of distortion (lest we end up in the worst choice among second best situations) and the one that is as close as possible to the behavior we want to change.

    In reducing market distortions, it is useful to make a distinction between externalities and other market failures and public goods. For public goods the task is straightforward, figure out how much is needed and figure out how to pay for it there is a clear justification for the government paying for these. But these are rare, we are more likely to find ourselves faced with other types of externalities, including quasi-public goods and information failures (as well as those garden variety externalities). Here we have to know the markets and get the policy handle right. In all of these cases we have to figure out how this will be paid for is it a cross-subsidy, government spending, how? Putting the cost of the various subsidies in perspective will help identify tradeoffs across areas.