Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    1/21

    1

    Piece Rate and Time Rate Payment System in Agrarian Economies:

    A Theoretical Insight on Malaysian Rubber Estate.

    Parthiban S.Gopal

    Abstract

    Wages and its method of payment is a perennial old problem for the rubber tappers in

    Malaysian estates. This paper proposes the method of payments which is prevalent in

    agrarian economies, is widely adopted in Malaysian rubber estates wage structure,particularly for the rubber tappers. The method of payment that becomes the centre of

    contention in this paper is weather the time rated or piece rate payment is appropriate for

    the rubber tappers. Therefore the objective of this paper is twofold: Firstly, to examine theconceptual difference and operational definition of time and piece rated payment in

    Malaysian rubber estates. Secondly, to scrutinize the viability of these mode of payment

    vis-a-vis theoretical interpretation, in the rubber estates. The methodology of this paper isbased solely on document research; that is, peer reviewed journals as well as books and

    articles authored by prominent researchers and scholars on wages and payment structure

    especially in agrarian economies. Finally, the findings of the study would further elucidate

    the importance of this mode of payment as a part of wage determinism mechanism for therubber tappers in the Malaysian rubber plantation sector.

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    2/21

    2

    I. Introduction

    This study investigates the compensation theory that guides the two methods of payments

    widely used in agrarian economies. Piece rates and time rates are the two methods of

    compensation that are commonly employed in agricultural activities. The rubber estates in

    Malaysia are no exception. This crux of this study provides a theoretical perspective of the

    main features of the two systems and the circumstances under which an employer is likely

    to choose one or the other.

    II. Background of the Study

    The earnings of rubber tappers have attracted considerable attention in the literaturei. At

    least two reasons account for this; first, the tapper is not separable from the rubber industry

    that has contributed so much to the prosperity of the Malaysian economy since its

    commercial cultivation in the 1800s. Second, while previous studies have shown that the

    earnings of plantation workers have been low, relative to workers of comparable skill in

    other sectors ( Zulkifly and Ishak, 1998; Selvakumaran and Bala, 1995), it is not always

    realized that even within the plantation sector, the earnings of the rubber tapper have been

    among the lowest. In 1998, the average monthly earnings of a tapper was

    MYR605.00(USD195.00)ii, relative to MYR886.00(USD285) earned by an oil palm

    harvester, RM765.00(USD246.00) earned by a palm oil mill worker (Category II) and

    RM612.00(USD197.00) taken home by a rubber installation worker. The tappers earnings

    generally exceed only those of the field workers whose monthly income averaged

    RM430.00 (USD138.00) (Audong and Tan, 2000: 46; see also Navamukundan and Geetha,

    2003: 325-425). However, not all studies that have commented on the low earnings of

    rubber tappers have explored the underlying payment system because their main concerns

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    3/21

    3

    lay elsewhere. In fact, there is a general paucity of studies devoted solely or primarily to

    wage issues in the plantation sector. The studies by Parmer (1960) and Nijhar (1976) are

    among the few exceptions.

    III. Objective of the Study

    The primary objective of this paper is twofold: Firstly, to examine the conceptual difference

    and operational definition of time and piece rated payment in Malaysian rubber estates.

    Secondly, to scrutinize the viability of these mode of payment as a part of the wage

    structure, in the Malaysian rubber estates.

    IV. Research Methodology

    Since the study focuses on various theoretical features of payment system with regards to

    the rubber estates wage structure, document research deemed suffice and was conducted.

    To ensure reliability of these documents, only established peer reviewed journals as well as

    books and articles authored by prominent researchers and scholars on wage system

    especially in agrarian economies

    V. Methods of Payment: Piece Rate and Time Rate

    Two modes of payment are widely used, especially (though not exclusively) in agriculture.

    They are piece rates and time rates (Lazear, 1986: 405-430; 1998: 98-119). A piece rate

    rewards labour according to some measure of the workers output, whereas a time rate

    compensates a worker based on the number of hours allocated to the job (Borjas, 1996:

    402). Under a time rate, time on the job is used as the unit of measuring input (or as the

    proxy for effort).

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    4/21

    4

    Under a piece rate, compensation of a worker is a function of output or:

    wt =f (qt)

    where wtis compensation for period t,andqt is a workers output in period t.

    On the other hand, compensation under a time rate is a function of input (or effort), usually

    measured by time allocated to the job, or:

    wt =g (Et)

    where wtand Et are compensation and (some measure of) effort in period t, respectively.

    Piece rates are often viewed as incentive pay because earnings are dependent on individual

    output (Seiler, 1984: 363-376), whereas time rate earnings are solely a function of hours

    worked. The International Labour Organization (ILO) offers a different perspective: time

    rates are payments to employees who are redeemed hourly, daily, weekly or monthly, while

    piece rates are paymenst for workers who complete specific steps in the production

    process (ILO, 1984: 1-164 and Sajhau 1986: 79). The piece rate system is now more

    popularly referred to as payment by results (PBR). In short, a piece rate and a time rate

    represent a payment by output and a payment by input respectively (Dobb 1959: 50-55;

    Paarsch and Shearer, 1997: 1-2; Shearer, 2003: 1-3)

    V.1 Piece Rates or Time Rates?

    Output based pay has several advantages (Lazear, 1998: 98-119). First, the inherent

    strength of an output based pay system is that it discourages unproductive workers from

    applying for the job and induces inefficient workers to leave. This can be illustrated by

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    5/21

    5

    examining the choice faced by a tapper in deciding between an estate offering payment on

    the basis of output (piece rate) and one that pays a fixed monthly salary (time rate). This

    two payment systems are reflected by schedules B and A respectively in Figure 1 (Refer

    Appendix).

    Schedule A represents a time rate payment while schedule B represents a piece rate

    payment. Assume that MYR0.60 sen (USD0.20 cents) is paid for each kilogram of latex

    collected under scheme B. Under scheme A (the time rate wage scheme), the weekly salary

    is fixed at MYR180.00 (USD58.00), regardless of the amount of latex collectediii

    . What

    would be the workers choice?

    If the worker is able to tap and collect more than 300kg of latex eachweek, he will opt for

    the piece rate scheme since his takings will exceed MYR180 (USD 58.00) per week. On the

    other hand, a less productive job-seeker who is unable or unwilling to tap and collect at

    least 300kg of latex a week will choose the time rate scheme that offers a fixed weekly

    income of MYR180.00(USD58.00). The piece rate scheme, therefore, attracts more

    productive or better motivated workers. The less motivated and less productive workers

    will seek employment with employers offering a time rate paying scheme.

    However, Baland et. al (1999: 445-461) express a slightly different view. While they agree

    that a piece rate contract attracts the most able workers, they point out that it draws the least

    able ones as well. Only workers with medium level ability opt for the time rate. A highly

    able worker can choose his own level of effort, under the piece rate, to earn a higher level

    of earnings per day than is possible under a time rate contract. By the same token, a less

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    6/21

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    7/21

    7

    If the payment for each unit of output produced is given by w, the marginal revenue (MR)

    from each unit of output will be constant and equal to w. The horizontal line labeled MR in

    Figure 2 (refer Appendix) shows this.

    The marginal cost of producing output (MC) is the disutility suffered in allocating time

    away from other pleasurable activities to work. The MC of effort will rise as more output is

    produced because more leisure is sacrificed in favour of work. Furthermore, the MC of

    effort of a more able worker (MC A) will be lower than the MC of a less able worker (MC)

    as shown in the Figure 2 (refer Appendix) .

    The utility maximizing worker will choose that level of output (effort) where the MR from

    the additional output is equal to the MC of producing the output. For the less able worker,

    this is given by the level of output q* whereas the more able worker will produce a larger

    output (q able).

    Thus, a piece rate system not only attracts more productive workers, but also motivates the

    more able among them to produce a higher output than the less able ones.

    Let us now examine the time rate system. How much effort will time rate workers allocate

    to their jobs? Assume that in order to earn a fixed rate of pay, a minimum level of output

    (q*) is required of them. The worker will thus, be motivated to produce this minimum

    output level and no more. The worker will be terminated if he does not meet this minimum,

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    8/21

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    9/21

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    10/21

    10

    the employers monitoring costs and reduce the attractiveness of the piece rate systems to

    the employer.

    The fact that earnings can fluctuate considerably under a piece rate system also undermines

    its attraction to workers. For example, in the rubber estates, the amount of latex collected

    depends on weather conditions, the age of the tree, the terrain and others. These factors,

    outside the control of the tapper, can affect his earnings significantly even if there is no lack

    of effort on his part. This uncertainty in earnings level is absent under the time rate mode.

    A related question is: who should bear the risk of any fluctuation income? If pay is output-

    based, the worker assumes the risk and a risk-averse worker will avoid working under such

    an arrangement. On the other hand, under a time rate system, the firm assumes the risk and

    it will attract risk-averse workers.

    Lazear (1998: 119) argues that other things being equal, it is better to have the firm bear

    the risk. This is because firstly, firms are generally in a better position to diversify the risk

    by pooling it with other projects or by selling it to a third party through the capital market.

    Apart from diversifying, firms can also conduct arbitrage to protect themselves from wild

    fluctuations in output or in the prices of their input and output.

    Second, workers find it more difficult to deal with the risk. Workers, particularly those with

    low wages, have liabilities such as food, housing, clothing and other expenses that are

    relatively fixed. Hence, any variation in their income is likely to cause significant

    difficulties for them and their families. But highly paid executives or big companies have

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    11/21

    11

    substantial savings to cushion any decrease in workers wages. As a result it is generally

    better to have the firm bear the risk. The problem, however, is that when the firm bears the

    risk and the worker feels insured, his incentive to work is reduced. Thus, there is a trade-

    off: More risk-taking by the worker means more effort and higher average compensation.

    However, more risk-taking also means more variable pay. Lazear (1998) suggests that, in

    general, the rule should be high productivity workers whose average compensation is high,

    should bear a greater proportion of the risk than low productivity workers.

    A fundamental principle missed by Lazear (1998) is that since capital keeps the profit, it

    must be prepared to take the risk. After all, profit is a reward for risk-taking. On the other

    hand, if capital wants to share the risk with labour, it must be prepared to share profits as

    well!

    Borjas (1996: 407), on the other hand, suggests that firms will have to find means to

    compensate workers for the disutility caused by fluctuations earnings. This compensating

    differential, however, will reduce the employers profits and fewer firms will choose to

    offer piece rates.

    Finally, imbedded in the piece rate system is the so-called ratchet effect (Borjas, 1996:

    407). If a worker produces high output, the management may interpret this to mean that the

    job was not quite as difficult as originally conceived and lower the piece rate in the next

    period. This forces labour to work

    harder just to keep even. The ratchet effect discourages workers from accepting piece rate

    jobs.

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    12/21

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    13/21

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    14/21

    14

    3. Piece rate contracts may be supplementary contracts that coexist with time rate

    contracts because the benefits of piece rate contracts are achieved at some cost to

    the employer in terms of task quality.

    4. Piece rates and time rates for the same task may coexist, especially in periods of a

    slack in the demand for labour. During such periods, the time rate is rigid

    downwards and cannot be brought down, leading to involuntary unemployment.

    The coexistence of time rates allows the absorption of unemployed workers on

    piece rate contracts. A dual labour market thus emerges where time rate

    employment is rationed and piece rate work is competed for.

    5. Finally, piece rates are also becoming popular as a means of avoiding statutory

    regulations covering time rate workers whose employment is more formalized.

    Piece rates are being used as a device to implement the casualization of labour

    employment.

    Apart from market structure,our earlier discussion suggeststhat the piece rate contract may

    be made more attractive over the time rate in several situations where:

    1. the cost of measuring output is low and can be done without too much error.

    2. the value of the alternative wage is high in relation to the average output at the

    current firm.

    3. workers ability levels are heterogeneous.

    4. there is the need to attract the most able workers.

    5. only workers of poor ability are available because payments are made based on

    acceptable results.

    Of course, where these conditions are not met, the time rate will be the better alternative.

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    15/21

    15

    VI. Conclusion

    The study evaluated the strengths and weaknesses of the piece and time rate systems of

    payment. The piece rate system had several advantages that make it a logical choice,

    particularly in agrarian settings. It attracts the more productive workers, motivates the more

    able workers to produce more, ties pay directly to performance, requires minimal

    supervision in some circumstances and increases the firms productivity. Time rate, on the

    other hand, has persisted because it de-emphasizes quantity at the expense of quality, and is

    useful in situations where output is difficult to measure, or is attributed to a particular

    worker. A time rate also minimizes the risk of fluctuating incomes and is therefore,

    preferred by risk-averse workers. The wage system that evolved in the estates began with a

    piece rate payment and later incorporated elements of a time rate. Understanding the

    theoretical underpinnings of these two systems helps us evaluate the arguments for and

    against this gradual modification.

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    16/21

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    17/21

    17

    Appendix

    Figure 1

    Wage Rate

    The Screening Effect of Output Related Wage

    Source: Lazear (1998: 100)

    Figure 2

    Wage Rate

    The Allocation of Work Effort by Piece Rate Workers

    Source: Borjas (1996:404)

    0

    180(58)

    300 Kgs. of latex tapped

    B

    A

    MYR(USD)/week

    0

    MYR (USD)MC MC able

    MRw

    q* q able Output

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    18/21

    18

    Figure 3

    Wage Rate[RM (USD)

    /week]

    The Sorting Effect of Output Related Wage

    Source: Lazear (1998: 104)

    0

    60(20)

    X

    Y

    300 Kg. of latex tapped

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    19/21

    19

    References

    Arasaratnam, S. (1970)Indians in Malaysia and Singapore.London: Oxford

    University Press.

    Audong, M. and Tan, K.E. (2000) Wages and Labour Scenario in thePlantation Industry: Past, Present and Future.

    Kuala Lumpur: MalayanAgricultural Producers Association.

    Baland, J., Dreze. J. and Leruth, L. (1999) Daily Wages and Piece Rates inAgrarian Economies.Journal of Development Economics.59, pp. 446-

    458.

    Barlow, C. (1978) The Natural Rubber Industry: Its Development,

    Technology and Economy in Malaysia. London: Oxford University Press.

    Beacham, R.H.S. (1979) Pay Systems: Principles and Techniques.London:Heinneman.

    Borjas, G.J. (1996)Labor Economics.New York: McGraw-Hill CompaniesInc.

    Dobb, M. (1959) Wages.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Gamba, C (1962b) The National Union of Plantation Workers, 1948-1958.

    Singapore: Eastern Universities Press Ltd.

    International Labour Organization. (1984) Payment by Results. Geneva,

    International Labour Office.

    Jackson, R.N. (1961)Immigration Labour and the Development of Malaya,

    1786-1920.Kuala Lumpur: Government Printers.

    Lazear, E.P. (1998) Personnel Economics for Managers.New York: John

    Wiley & Sons.

    Lazear, E.P. (1986) Salaries and Piece Rates. The Journal of Business.59

    (3), pp. 405-430.

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    20/21

    20

    Netto, G. (1961)Indians in Malaya: Historical Facts and Figures. Singapore:Self Published.

    Nijhar, K.S. (1976) Wage Structure: A Case Study in Malaysia.Kuala Lumpur:Academic Publishers Sdn. Bhd.

    Navamukandan, A. and Geetha, S. (2003) Decent Work in Agriculture in

    Malaysia. In Naidu, D.P.A. and Navamukandan, A., (eds).Decent Work in

    Agriculture in Asia.Bangkok: International Labour Oganization, pp. 328

    419.

    Paarsch, H.J. and Shearer, B.S. (1997) Fixed Wages, Piece Rates, and

    Intertemporal Productivity: A Study of Tree Planters in British Columbia.

    CIRANO Working Paper, pp. 1-40. Montreal, Canada.

    Shearer, B. (2003) Piece Rates, Fixed Wages and Incentives: Evidence from

    a Field Experiment.CIRANO Working Paper, pp. 1-37. Montreal, Canada

    Parmer, J.N. (1960) Colonial Labour Policy and Administration: A History of

    Labour in the Rubber Plantation Industry in Malaya, 1910-1941.New

    York: J.J. Augustine.

    Ramasamy, P. (1994) Plantation Labour, Unions, Capital and the State inPeninsular Malaysia.

    Kuala Lumpur: Oxford University Press.

    Sajhau, J. (1986) Employment, Wages and Living Conditions in A Changing

    Industry Plantations.International Labour Review. 125 (1), pp. 71-86.

    Sandhu, K.S. (1969)Indian Immigration to Malaya: 1786-1957.London:

    Cambridge University Press.

    Seiler, E. (1984) Piece Rate vs. Time Rate: The Effects of Incentives on Earnings.

    Review of Economics and Statistics.63 (3), pp. 363375.

    Selvakumaran, R. and Bala, S. ( 1995) Plight of Plantation Workers in

    Malaysia: Defeated by Definitions.Asian Survey, 35 (4), pp.394-407.

    Selvakumaran, R. (1994)Indian Plantation Labour in Malaysia.Kuala

    Lumpur: S. Abdul Majeed & Co.

    Zulkifly, O. and Ishak, Y. (1998) The Impact of Unionism on Wages in theManufacturing Sector. In Ishak, Y. and Abdul Ghafar, I., (eds).Malaysian

    Industrialisation Government and the Techinical Change. Bangi:Universiti Kebangsaan Malaysia, pp. 215-226

  • 8/11/2019 Piece Rate and Time Rate(Final) Payment

    21/21