Author
lythuan
View
215
Download
0
Embed Size (px)
1
THE THRESHOLD Newsletter Of The Mergers &
Acquisitions Committee
Volume XIV
Number 2
Spring 2014
FROM THE CHAIR
To All Committee Members:
Welcome to the Spring edition of
The Threshold! And for those of you who
may be reading this at the J.W. Marriott
Hotel, welcome to the Spring Meeting! This
issue is packed with informative articles that
merger practitioners should find both useful
and timely.
We lead off with Ronan Hartys very
interesting interview of FTC Chairwoman
Edith Ramirez that touches on a number of
hot merger topics, including acquisitions of
physician groups, merger retrospective
studies, potential competition mergers,
patent portfolio acquisitions, and
international merger enforcement. Next,
Bruce Hoffman critiques the DOJ remedy in
the American/US Airways merger,
concluding that the remedy inflicts harms
and bestows benefits on passengers that
appear unrelated to any merger effect
CONTENTS
Interview with Chairwoman Edith Ramirez
by Ronan P. Harty 3
Boarding For an Unknown Destination: The
Remedy in the American / USAirways
Merger
by Bruce Hoffman 13
Dead on Arrival: Can Efficiencies Revive an
Otherwise Unlawful Hospital Merger in
Court? by John Matthew Schwietz 30
Navigating the Weeds of Foreign Investment
Review: A Case Study of Archer Daniels
Midland/Graincorp. and BHP Billiton/
Potash Corp.
by Julie Soloway and Leah Noble 41
The EU Merger Simplification Package:
What's New and What Are the
Consequences?
by Gavin Bushell and Luca Montani 55
Future Forecasting in Potential
Competition: Stormy Days or Clear
Visibility Summary of ABA Brown Bag
Program
by George Laevsky 68
International Roudup
by Julie Soloway and David Dueck 75
About the Mergers and Acquisitions 86
Committee
About the Threshold 87
2
alleged in the complaint. John Matthew Schwietz addresses whether efficiency claims can
rescue a horizontal hospital merger that is otherwise dead on arrival in court after challenge by
the FTC; he concludes that recent court decisions do not inspire hope, and that the merging
parties best shot is presenting such claims to the FTC during the investigation phase. Gavin
Bushell and Luca Montani discuss the ins and outs, and the consequences, of the recent EU Merger
Control Simplification Package.
Julie Soloway and Leah Noble discuss the foreign investment review processes in Canada
and Australia that led to rejection of the ADM/GrainCorp and BHP Billiton/Potash Corp.
mergersdespite the fact that the mergers were cleared by the national competition authorities.
Julie is doing double duty for this issue, also collaborating with David Dueck on the International
Roundup, which discusses recent developments concerning the failing firm defense in the EU,
UK, and Australia, and efforts to streamline merger review in Europe, China, and Turkey.
Finally, we have an interesting summary of a recent M&A Committee Brown Bag program on
the current state of potential competition analysis in merger review, prepared by George
Laevsky.
The committee has been hard at work, not only on this issue of The Threshold, but also
on a new edition of the Premerger Notification Practice Manual, a new edition of the Mergers
and Acquisitions book, the soon-to-be completed second request cost study, and several changes
to our committee website, including the update through December 2013 of our invaluable (or so
we think) product market catalogue, the addition of a new resource base of antitrust-related
merger agreement clauses, and the conversion of our website to the ABA Connect platform.
The next Threshold will be out in the Summer. As always, we would be delighted to
publish letters to the editor commenting on any past articles, and we would be doubly delighted
to hear from you about any articles you would like to write yourself.
Enjoy the newsletter!
--Paul B. Hewitt
3
INTERVIEW WITH CHAIRWOMAN EDITH RAMIREZ1
By Ronan P. Harty
What are the principal items on your competition agenda as Chairwoman?
I have focused on the healthcare and technology sectors since I first joined
the Commission in 2010, and those sectors continue to be a priority for me as
Chairwoman. As is well known, these have been important priorities for the
Commission for many years. Let me say a few words about each area.
Healthcare accounts for over 17% of GDP, and study after study tells us
that vigorous competition in healthcare markets reduces costs, improves quality,
and expands access for consumers. The Commission has a great record
promoting competition in healthcare markets. Our Supreme Court victory in the
Actavis case will make it easier to challenge anticompetitive pay-for-delay
settlements. In addition to pressing forward with two ongoing actions, including
Actavis, we continue to look carefully at settlements filed under the Medicare
Modernization Act to determine whether there are other enforcement actions we
should pursue in light of the Supreme Courts ruling. Preventing anticompetitive
provider consolidation is another healthcare priority that has deep roots at the
Commission. While hospital mergers can generate important efficiencies that
benefit consumers, we will continue to look carefully at acquisitions that are
likely to enhance market power.
Promoting competition in high-technology markets is also a priority.
Innovation drives economic growth and expands consumer welfare. Innovation
also plays a central role in the competitive dynamics of high-tech markets. Firms
1 Edith Ramirez is Chairwoman of the U.S. Federal Trade Commission. She was appointed to the
FTC by President Obama and was sworn in as a Commissioner on April 5, 2010. She was
designated to serve as Chairwoman effective March 4, 2013. Prior to joining the Commission,
Ramirez was a partner in the Los Angeles office of Quinn Emanuel Urquhart & Sullivan LLP.
She graduated from Harvard Law School cum laude (1992) and holds an A.B. in History magna
cum laude from Harvard University (1989).
4
in this sector are more likely to compete on the basis of new products and
business models rather than on price. So the risk of harm to competition and
consumers through a lessening of incentives to innovate tends to be more acute.
Consistent with our 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, we will be on the
lookout for transactions in this area that raise competitive concerns. Of course,
evaluating competitive effects in rapidly evolving markets requires the
Commission to make educated predictions about the future. But thats something
we do every day when we evaluate mergers in a variety of industries, and is not
something we can avoid where the competitive landscape is shifting more rapidly.
We will also continue to take a hard look at exclusionary tactics that discourage
entry from nascent rivals. Our staff has a wealth of experience in both merger and
conduct enforcement in high-technology markets, and the Commission has
demonstrated its ability to make tough calls based on the evidence in each matter,
pursuing a challenge against Intel for exclusionary tactics in 2009, while voting
unanimously to close its investigation of Googles product design decisions in
2012.
My policy agenda also tracks these interests. The Commissions unique
advantage as a competition and consumer protection agency rests in part on our
expertise in research and policy analysis, and our authority to collect nonpublic
information to conduct industry studies. We can often accomplish as much for
consumers through policy and advocacy as we can through enforcement. The
Commission, for example, has always taken a leadership role on policy issues at
the intersection of competition and intellectual property, and I hope to build on
that record during my tenure.
Our proposed study of patent assertion entities is one important project in
this area. The available evidence suggests the PAE activity may be affecting
incentives to innovate and compete in ways that we do not yet fully understand.
We know that litigation activity by PAEs is on the rise, but we have little more
than anecdotal evidence on PAE activity outside of the courtroom. Under
Section 6(b) of the FTC Act, we have the authority to collect nonpublic
5
information to conduct industry studies, and last fall the Commission voted
unanimously to issue a Federal Register Notice seeking comment on a proposed
PAE study focusing on the economic costs and benefits of PAE activity. We are
completing our analysis of the nearly 70 comments we received and will soon be
seeking OMB approval to proceed with the proposed study. The Commission is
uniquely positioned to expand the empirical picture on the costs and benefits of
PAE activity. We have a talented and dedicated team of lawyers and economists
working on this study, and I am excited about moving forward with it.
While the Commission has always been active when it comes to hospital
mergers, we are also seeing challenges to physician acquisitions, for example
the Reno consent last year and the St. Luke's litigation. Do you anticipate
continued active enforcement in this area? Many of these types of
acquisitions (physician acquisitions) do not meet HSR thresholds. So, how do
you ensure that you are able to review such acquisitions?
The FTC will continue to carefully review all types of combinations
between healthcare providers. As Ive already noted, we have good evidence that
mergers between providers that enhance market power can increase costs and
reduce quality and access to healthcare services. While these acquisitions can
also generate efficiencies, where we have evidence that a merger is likely to
enhance market power, parties must be able to verify any efficiency claims and
show that the efficiencies are merger-specific and of a character and magnitude
that would outweigh any likely anticompetitive effects in the relevant market.
In the St. Lukes case, the court carefully considered whether efficiencies
provided a defense to the Commissions challenge and concluded they did not.
St. Lukes acquisition of the Saltzer Medical Group would have combined the
largest provider of adult primary care services in Nampa, Idaho with its closest
rival in a very concentrated market. The parties claimed that the merger would
have created valuable efficiencies by permitting more integrated patient care and
greater sharing of electronic medical records. While the court was persuaded that
team-based care and shared electronic records can improve quality and reduce
costs, it concluded that the parties could have achieved those same efficiencies
6
through collaborative arrangements short of a merger. So the court correctly
concluded that the merger was unlawful.
As to your point about reporting thresholds, it is true that small provider
acquisitions often fall below HSR reporting thresholds. However, we typically
learn about potentially problematic mergers from a variety of sources, including
state attorneys general, commercial health plans, others in the marketplace, media
reports, and our own monitoring. And we make sure through publications like
this and other public engagement that our views about the potential
anticompetitive risks of these combinations are well known to all participants in
healthcare markets.
The FTC has a reputation as an agency that works effectively and in a
bipartisan way. Thats not always the case in Washington. Whats the
FTCs recipe for success?
As an independent agency with important law enforcement
responsibilities, we take great pride in our bipartisan and consensus-oriented
culture. While my colleagues and I may at times see things differently, we work
hard to understand one anothers perspectives and always aim for consensus. We
are all committed to protecting consumers and promoting competition, and the
vast majority of our decisions are unanimous. But let me also emphasize that the
FTC has a great reputation mainly due to our talented and hardworking staff. Not
only are they on the front lines in everything we do, but it is also the high quality
of their work that enables informed dialogue among Commissioners, including in
those instances when we dont all agree on the outcome.
Are there any ongoing FTC studies of the effects of your merger enforcement
program in healthcare or other areas?
I think retrospectives are an important tool that can be used to improve the
quality of merger enforcement programs. Done well, retrospectives may be able
to tell us whether we are providing consumers with good value for their
enforcement dollar. They can also help us educate courts. As is well known,
retrospectives helped the FTC reinvigorate its hospital merger enforcement
7
program about a decade ago. Retrospectives that focus on remedies, particularly
whether divestitures are effective in restoring the competition lost through an
otherwise anticompetitive transaction, can also help improve merger enforcement.
The Commissions divestiture policies today are grounded in part on what we
learned from our 1999 divestiture study.
At the same time, merger retrospectives are resource intensive, and it is
not easy to design a study that provides us with unbiased answers to the relevant
enforcement questions. But good retrospectives can make us a more effective
agency and I am working with our Bureaus to identify possible projects.
What are your views on potential competition? Typically, we see potential
competition cases in the pharma and medical device industries but the FTC
recently obtained an enforcement action in the Nielsen/Arbitron matter.
Does that signal that we are likely to see more potential competition cases in
the future?
I think Nielson/Arbitron can be seen as an example of the Commissions
commitment to promoting competition in the high-tech sector. We challenge
mergers where the evidence provides us with a sound basis to believe that
competitive harm is likely, and that was the case in Nielson/Arbitron. Internal
documents and statements from the parties showed that the parties had each
invested significant time and resources to develop an audience measurement
product that covered multiple platforms and were beginning to offer them to
customers. There was broad consensus among media companies and advertisers
that Nielsen and Arbitron were the two firms best positioned to develop a cross-
platform measurement product in the foreseeable future that would satisfy
emerging demand. The evidence also showed that these products would likely
compete directly for business. Taken together, the evidence provided ample
reason to believe the transaction was likely to harm competition, and I was very
comfortable supporting a challenge and settlement in that matter.
8
We have seen a number of transactions in recent years in the IT sector
involving the sales of large patent portfolios. Is there something unique about
the Section 7 analysis when the buyer is a patent assertion entity?
We apply the same basic analytic tools and economic principles to
evaluate mergers irrespective of the business models of the transacting parties.
As always, we are concerned with transactions that enhance market power or
facilitate the exercise of market power. In a situation involving the acquisition of
a large patent portfolio, the relevant question under Section 7 would be whether
the transfer is likely to enhance market power.
For example, with regard to the upstream technology market, we would
want to understand whether the transaction combined important substitute patents,
and whether there were any merger specific efficiencies associated with the
combination. We would also ask if the patents at issue are important to
competition in one or more downstream markets, and, if so, whether the buyers
incentives to license those patents are likely to differ from those of the seller post-
acquisition and how that change would be likely to affect downstream
competition. The downstream product market analysis would follow the same
basic framework we apply to other vertical mergers, such as the GE/Avio
transaction earlier this year.
In some cases, the incentives of PAEs to assert and license patents may
differ from those of operating companies. Operating companies that are
themselves vulnerable to infringement claims may refrain from asserting patents
against entities that could strike back. Since PAEs are not generally susceptible to
countersuit, the transfer of a large portfolio from an operating company to a PAE
might lead to more assertion activity. If PAEs assert these patents against firms
that have already embedded the patented technology in products, the transfer
could also increase the risk of patent hold-up, which may distort incentives to
innovate and reduce consumer welfare.
I am committed to using all of the agencys tools to protect consumers
from harmful PAE activity, including using our antitrust enforcement authority to
9
stop anticompetitive portfolio acquisitions by PAEs. However, it is also
important to understand that antitrust cannot provide a solution to some of the
broader competition policy risks that may be associated with PAE acquisitions.
To reduce the threat of patent hold-up more broadly throughout the marketplace,
policymakers should continue to pursue reforms that improve the patent system.
Much has been said about Section 5 and there appears to be a clamoring
from the bar and others for guidance on what is commonly called the
Commissions standalone Section 5 authority. Does the Commission plan
on issuing a policy statement on Section 5? Why or why not?
The Commission is clearly engaged on this issue and several of us have
explained our views publicly. I favor developing Section 5 enforcement
principles using a common law approach. Congress deliberately drafted Section 5
broadly to provide the agency with the administrative flexibility to address unfair
methods of competition that would have been difficult to define adequately in
advance and that would necessarily change over time with economic learning and
an evolving competitive landscape. Courts have successfully developed the
contours of both the Sherman and Clayton Acts using a case-by-case approach,
and I believe the Commission can and should follow that approach for Section 5.
While I recognize that a predictable enforcement environment promotes
economic growth, an enforcement policy that places too much weight on certainty
has economic costs as well. As I noted in a speech I gave at a recent symposium
at GMU, an approach that is excessively concerned about over-enforcement does
not serve the marketplace as whole. While erring on the side of under-
enforcement may provide certainty to incumbents, it can impose a great deal of
uncertainty on nascent rivals seeking to challenge a dominant firm or business
model.
In my view, our enforcement actions themselves provide useful guidance
for the business community. Our most recent cases show that the Commission
will challenge conduct that courts may conclude falls outside the scope of the
Sherman Act, but only where we have reason to believe the conduct is likely to
10
cause harm to competition and where the harm outweighs cognizable efficiencies.
We applied this very familiar rule of reason approach in our Google/MMI and
Bosley actions last year, and it is the standard that I think ought to be applied in
future actions.
You were in Beijing recently to meet with MOFCOM. What is your
impression of the way in which China is handling merger reviews? Is there
anything you would like to see them change?
We have followed the evolution of MOFCOMs merger review process
with great interest. The FTC, together with the Department of Justice, provided
MOFCOM with input on the merger provisions of the draft Anti-Monopoly Law
through the consultation process prior to adoption of the law in 2007. We have
been in regular contact since that time regarding implementation, and even more
so since 2011 when we entered into a Memorandum of Understanding with
MOFCOM and the other two Chinese competition agencies. I am impressed that,
in just over five years, MOFCOMs Antimonopoly Bureau has built the capacity
to analyze complex merger issues with skill. AMB staff are diligent and appear
eager to learn from the experiences of enforcers around the world.
With that said, I am concerned about some aspects of MOFCOMs review
process. Merger review goes more slowly in China than in most other
jurisdictions with a pre-merger notification program. MOFCOM has reported that
87% of the mergers they review move to a second phase investigation, similar to a
second request here, even though ultimately MOFCOM imposes conditions on
less than 5% of all reported transactions. In most jurisdictions, less than 10% of
reported transactions go to a second stage investigation, with the percentage
below 5% in the United States. These numbers suggest that a large number of
transactions that do not pose competitive issues are subject to a lengthy review in
China, imposing costs on the merging parties and consuming MOFCOMs limited
enforcement resources. Recently, MOFCOM released rules on simple
transactions, which may make it easier for MOFCOM to complete many more
investigations within the initial 30-day review period. I hope these new rules will
11
allow MOFCOM to focus its resources on those mergers that pose genuine
competitive concerns.
I am also concerned about the role that industrial policy plays in
MOFCOMs merger enforcement program. The AML expressly requires that
MOFCOM take economic development into account in merger review. As a
matter of practice, MOFCOM will often consult with other ministries, including
those responsible for designing and implementing Chinas industrial policies. In
my view, antitrust enforcement should focus on promoting competition and
consumer welfare, and should not be used as a tool for industrial policy.
However, where an enforcement agency is obliged to consider other goals, it is
particularly important to the global regulatory environment that the agency do so
in a manner that is transparent.
Are we seeing greater convergence in international merger enforcement?
Does the Commission plan any initiatives in this area?
The FTC has worked hard to reduce the burdens on parties that can be
associated with differences in merger analysis and procedures across jurisdictions,
and I think the trend toward convergence is continuing. The FTC promotes
convergence on sound antitrust principles through our work in multilateral
organizations and our bilateral relations with counterpart agencies around the
globe.
By way of example, as you touched on earlier, I recently participated in
the second FTC/DOJ Joint Dialogue with Chinas three competition agencies, at
which senior officials addressed antitrust policy and practice issues, including
those related to merger review, timing, and remedies. We also just concluded a
trilateral meeting with the Canadian and Mexican competition agencies and held
bilateral meetings over the past year with the European Commission, Japan, and
India at which we discussed merger policy convergence and cooperation.
Additionally, through consultations and cooperation on merger cases under
concurrent review, we have addressed key policy and procedural issues that have
12
helped bring our approaches to merger policy and practices closer. We also
continue to strengthen case cooperation and coordination to reach compatible
results on individual cases of mutual interest. Thermo Fisher/Life Technologies is
a recent example of a case in which we cooperated with antitrust agencies in
many jurisdictions, including Australia, Canada, China, the European Union,
Japan, and Korea to reach compatible results on a global scale. We have also
been active with technical assistance to a broad array of young agencies.
The FTC remains committed to working towards even greater
convergence of competition policy and practice internationally, and we look
forward to working with the Antitrust Section and others to do so.
Justice Brandeis once said, You can judge a person better by the books on
his shelf than by the clients in his office. What books have you been reading
recently?
I hope Judge Brandeis would view me as a good commissioner, as my
daily reading mainly consists of staff memos, white papers and case law. I wish I
had time to read more widely and am always on the lookout for good books. The
last book I read was La Sombra del Viento by Spanish author Carlos Ruiz Zafn,
which I thoroughly enjoyed. Im about to start Quiet by Susan Cain, which I am
looking forward to reading. It was recommended to me a while ago, and I was
finally prompted to buy it after listening to Cain speak at the HLS Celebration
60 conference last fall. Another book that I hope to get to soon is Thanks for the
Feedback by Douglas Stone and Sheila Heen. It relates to an issue that I have
given significant thought to in the past while working with young law firm
associates, and am thinking a great deal about now at the FTC how to ensure
that staff are fully engaged and that those of us who are managers are effective
supervisors and mentors. Thanks for the Feedback was recommended to me as
having useful insights on that subject.
If anyone has any other good reading suggestions, I would love to hear
them.
13
BOARDING FOR AN UNKNOWN DESTINATION: THE REMEDY IN THE AMERICAN /USAIRWAYS MERGER
D. Bruce Hoffman1
On August 13, 2013, the United States, joined by seven States and the
District of Columbia (collectively, DOJ), filed suit to block the proposed
merger of American Airlines and US Airways. The complaint2 made sweeping
allegations that the merger would spur nationwide coordinated price increases and
service reductions, inflict consumer harm on over a thousand routes served by
both American and US Airways, and produce a near-monopoly in slots at Reagan
National Airport (DCA). But a scant three months later, DOJ and the airlines
announced a settlement which was essentially limited to addressing the airlines
slot overlap at DCA, plus a few slots at LaGuardia (LGA) and a handful of
gates and related facilities at a few other airports around the country.3 The
settlement has been harshly criticized for failing to address the harms alleged in
the complaint, and also for requiring that the divested assets go to one set of
competitorsthe so-called Low Cost Carriers, or LCCs, such as Southwest and
JetBlue.
Litigation has consequences: as a result, there is no requirement that a
settlement reached during litigation mirror the allegations of a complaint. But
1 Bruce Hoffman is a partner and head of antitrust at Hunton & Williams LLP. Thanks to Brian
Hauser of Hunton & Williams for extensive assistance with this article, Jeff Ogar for helpful
thoughts about airline mergers and related issues, Ronan Harty for suggestions and (particularly)
patience, and Gil Ohana for editing. The author represented Delta in its acquisition of Northwest
and its slot swap transaction with USAirways, but is not representing Delta or any other airline in
connection with this matter. This article does not purport to represent the views of Hunton &
Williams or any of its clients.
2 This article focuses on the Amended Complaint filed by the United States, the States of Arizona,
Florida, Michigan, Pennsylvania, Tennessee, Texas, and Virginia, and the District of Columbia,
against US Airways Group, Inc. and AMR Corporation, in the United States District Court for the
District of Columbia on September 5, 2013 (Compl.).
3 See Proposed Final Judgment, Competitive Impact Statement, etc., filed on November 12, 2013.
The Competitive Impact Statement is cited as CIS below.
14
here there is a fundamental divergence between the complaint, the remedy, and
the antitrust laws. That divergence could perhaps be reconciledthough with
potential implications for the scope of the remedybut DOJ has not provided the
analysis that would be necessary to do so.
I. The Merger and the Complaint
On February 13, 2013 American Airlines (then in bankruptcy) and US
Airways announced a merger. That merger would combine the third and fifth
largest US airlines to create the largest airline in the world. In the U.S., the four
largest remaining airlinesthe new American, Southwest, United, and Delta
would carry over 80% of domestic passenger traffic.4
On August 13, 2013, the complaint was filed, followed on September 5 by
an amended complaint (on which this article focuses). The complaint is detailed
and lengthy, and a full description of it and the amended complaint is beyond the
scope of this article. But its central themes are easily summarized.
The complaint drew a sharp distinction between so-called legacy
airlines and LCCs. Legacy airlines are the descendants of the nations historic
airlines, and typically operate hub-and spoke networks serving numerous
destinations with mixed fleets of aircraft and multiple classes of service.5 The
complaint alleged that post-merger there would only be three such airlines:
American, United, and Delta.6
LCCs, on the other hand, typically operate point-to-point service with
simple aircraft fleets appealing primarily to leisure travelers, though business
travelers do patronize LCCs.7 Southwest, by some measures the nations largest
airline, is the most prominent LCC. Among the numerous other LCCs are
4 Compl. 36.
5 E.g., Compl. 32.
6 E.g., Compl. 1, 3.
7 E.g., Compl. 17, 32, 47, 93.
15
JetBlue, Spirit, Virgin America, and Allegiance. The complaint alleged that while
LCCs may drive down average prices on routes they serve, they do not presently
offer good substitutes for the legacy airlines, for reasons including their lack of
hub and spoke networks, preferences of many passengers for legacy airlines
offerings, and the LCCs absence from many routes.8
Against this backdrop, the complaint alleged that the merger would result
in three major legacy airlines that, as the DOJ put it, prefer tacit coordination
over full-throated competition.9 The merger would reduce the number of legacy
airlines from four to three, and align the economic incentives of those that remain,
allowing increased coordination on price and service.10
This alignment would
occur by eliminating two forms of maverick competition by the existing legacy
airlines. First, the complaint contended that US Airways (US) is a price
maverick. In essence, according to the complaint, USs hub and route structure
was inherently less lucrative than the other legacy airlines, giving US an
incentive to compete directly with the other legacy airlines on price (particularly
by offering low prices on connecting routes that compete with other airlines
direct routes).11
Second, according to the complaint, American (AA) was
poised to become a service maverick on exiting bankruptcy, dramatically
increasing capacity (and thereby inevitably driving prices down) while the other
legacy airlines had been attempting to reduce industry capacity.12
The complaint also observed that slots at DCAone of the four airports in
the US subject to slot constraintswould be very highly concentrated. Slots are
rights to take-off or land; airports subject to slot limitations are restricted in the
number of take-off or landing operations they can permit in any given day.
8 Compl. 93; see also CIS at 5-6.
9 Compl. 3.
10 Id.
11 Comp. 5-6.
12 Compl. 8-9.
16
Without slots, airlines cannot serve a slot-constrained airport, and limits on slots
constrain airlines ability to expand service. 13
The complaint then alleged two relevant antitrust markets, both consistent
with longstanding DOJ precedent:
1) Scheduled air passenger service between cities (city-pairs), such
as Washington-Chicago. Also consistent with DOJ practice, the complaint
observed that in some cases consumer preferences and price
discrimination may support smaller relevant markets involving service
between particular airports, such as between DCA (highly preferred by
business travelers) and other airports. This allegation put into play well
over 1000 relevant markets.14
2) Slots at DCA. Slots are bought and sold, and since they are
necessary for flight operations at slot-controlled airports, the DOJ has in
the past contended that slots at particular airports are relevant markets.15
However, while slots were alleged to be a relevant market, the complaint
and other filings in the case generally described the competitive effects
related to slot concentration in terms of their effects on downstream
competition, i.e., the effect of slot holdings on city-pair concentration and
the ability of competing airlines to enter city-pair routes originating or
terminating at the slot-controlled airport.
The complaint began its analysis of effects by alleging a structural case
based on concentration in each set of relevant markets.16
It claimed that the
merger would increase the HHI beyond the level at which anticompetitive effects
13 Compl. 10. The other slot-constrained US airports are all in the New York area: JFK,
LaGuardia, and Newark.
14 Compl. 24-29, 38; see also CIS at 4-5.
15 Compl. 30-31; see also CIS at 5.
16 See Compl., 36-40.
17
are presumed likely in over 1000 city-pairs. It further alleged that the merger
would substantially increase HHI in the already highly-concentrated market for
DCA slots, again resulting in a structural presumption of increased prices
(apparently for air service using those slots).
The complaint operationalized the structural presumption through what
appeared to be two theories. First, the complaint alleged a theory of coordinated
interaction on price and service among the remaining legacy airlines.17
By
reducing the number of legacy airlines and eliminating two mavericks, the
complaint alleged that the merger would generally increase price and service
coordination, elevating price and reducing service. The complaint noted that the
LCCs would not constrain this effect because of the difference between their
products and customers and those of the legacy airlines.18
Second, the complaint appeared to allege a unilateral effects theory in
numerous markets where the merger would eliminate competition between AA
and US, particularly markets involving routes originating or terminating at
DCA.19
This included seventeen nonstop direct overlaps (traditionally, the
greatest area of DOJ concern), and included lost competition on routes DOJ
alleged the airlines had planned to fly prior to the merger, such as planned entry
by US on DCA-MIA. But it also included over 1000 other overlaps, including
connecting routes, on which DOJ alleged prices would rise due to the loss of
competition between AA and US. Finally, the DOJ alleged that US used its large
slot holdings at DCA inefficiently, and was hoarding them to block entry (noting
that competition from JetBlue had reduced fares on the limited routes it had been
able to fly after obtaining slots at DCA, notably DCA-BOS).
17 See Compl., 41-81; see also CIS at 5-6.
18 Compl. 47, 93; see also CIS at 5-6.
19 See Compl. 82-90; see also CIS at 6.
18
Thus, the complaint alleged sweeping theories of anticompetitive effects
extending across the nation to over 1000 city-pair relevant marketseffects
which the numerous LCCs allegedly would not constrain.
II. The Settlement
The settlement, announced just three months later, painted a different
picture.
The settlement itself involved relatively modest relief. The merged airline
(NewAA) would divest 104 slots at DCAeffectively eliminating any increase in
slot concentration there.20
It would also shed 34 slots at LaGuardia (LGA), one of
the three slot-constrained New York airports.21
And it would divest
accompanying gate and other ancillary ground facilities at DCA and LGA, as well
as two gates each plus ancillary facilities at Chicago OHare (ORD), Los Angeles
International (LAX), Boston (BOS), Miami (MIA), and Dallas-Love Field
(DAL).22
The DOJs competitive impact statement explaining the effects of the
settlement conceded that [t]he proposed remedy will not create a new
independent competitor, nor does it purport to replicate Americans capacity
expansion plans or create Advantage Fares [allegedly disruptive low connecting
fares used by US on certain routes] where they might otherwise be eliminated.23
Instead, DOJ argued that the divestitures in the settlement would create network
opportunities for the purchasing carriers that would otherwise have been out of
reach for the foreseeable future. Those opportunities will provide increased
incentives for those carriers to invest in new capacity and expand into additional
20 CIS at 2.
21 Id.
22 CIS at 2-3.
23 CIS at 8.
19
markets.24
This set of divestitures, the DOJ contended, promises to impede
the industrys evolution toward a tighter oligopoly by requiring the divestiture of
critical facilities to carriers that will likely use them to fly more people to more
places at more competitive fares. In this way, the proposed remedy will deliver
benefits to consumers that could not be obtained by enjoining the merger.25
By
carriers that will likely use [slots] to fly more people to more places at more
competitive fares, DOJ meant LCCs, to whom it required the divestitures be
made, to the exclusion of the legacy airlines.26
III. The Criticism and DOJs Response
Under the Tunney Act, Section 2(b) of the Antitrust Procedures and
Penalties Act, 15 U.S.C. 16, following the filing of a propose settlement of a
DOJ antitrust case any person may file comments with the United States, after
which the court determines whether entry of the final judgment called for by the
settlement is in the public interest.27
The settlement attracted numerous comments. Criticism of the settlement
was extensive and harsh.28
Some of the key themes in the critiques include the
following:
24 Id.
25 Id.
26 CIS at 9-10.
27 15 U.S.C. 16(e)(1).
28 See, e.g., February 7, 2014 letter from the American Antitrust Institute, the Airline Passengers
Organization, the Association for Airline Passenger Rights, the Business Travel Coalition, the
Consumer Travel Alliance, and FlyersRights.Org to William H. Stallings (the AAI Comments);
January 9 2014 Comments and January 16, 2014 Supplemental Comments of the Wayne County
Airport Authority Concerning Potential Anti-Competitive Impacts of the Proposed DOJ
Settlement (Wayne County Comments); Comments of Delta Air Lines, Inc. Concerning
Proposed Final Judgment As To Defendants US Airways Group, Inc. and AMR Corp., January 21,
2014 (Delta Comments); Tunney Act Comments of Relpromax Antitrust Inc., February 7, 2014
(Relpromax Comments); and Response of Plaintiff United States to Public Comments on the
Proposed Final Judgment, filed March 10, 2014 (DOJ Resp.) at 2 and n. 1.
20
(1) The remedies did not address the overwhelming majority of
alleged harms. As the American Antitrust Institute (AAI) pointed out, the
divestitures at best would address only eighteen of the one hundred city-
pair routes where concentration post-merger would be highest.29
Numerous commentators made similar points.30
(2) Given the complaints insistence that LCCs cannot presently
check coordinated interaction among the legacy airlines, there was no
apparent reason to believe that divesting slots to LCCs would address the
coordination theories described in the complaint.31
(3) The remedy would fail to address, and in fact inflict harm on,
consumers, including those flying from DCA to small airports that would
likely lose service as a result of NewAAs net loss of slotsservice LCCs
would be extremely unlikely to replace.32
This criticism seems to be
29 AAI Comments at 5, n. 7.
30 See, e.g., Delta Comments at 6-8; Relpromax Comments at 7-8. AAI also argued that DOJs
approach violated the legal principle that harms and benefits be considered only on a market-by-
market (here, city-pairs) basis (the out of market efficiencies rule). AAI Comments at 4, 11.
However, AAI appears to have misunderstood this principle, for two reasons. First, as the DOJ
and FTC have long recognized, the principle does not apply when out-of-market efficiencies are
inextricably intertwined with a mergers benefits. United States Department of Justice and
Federal Trade Commission, 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines, n. 14. Even assuming that city-
pairs are relevant markets, that is nearly always the case in airline mergers, because harms in
particular city-pairs cannot be specifically remedied by divestitures, and the benefits of airline
mergers (which are often extensive but were given little discussion in any of the public analyses of
the merger) likewise typically cannot be isolated and preserved. Taken to its logical conclusion,
AAIs argument would likely require prohibiting any airline merger with any overlap on any city-
pair: that is to say, effectively any airline merger. Second, the cases casting doubt on out-of-
market efficiencies relied heavily on the fact that the benefits of the mergers at issue flowed to
entirely different people than those affected by the harms. See, e.g., Kottaras v. Whole Foods
Market, Inc., 281 F.R.D. 16, 25 (D.D.C. 2012 (a merger that substantially decreases competition
in one placeinjuring consumers thereis not saved because it benefits a separate group of
consumers by creating competition elsewhere.) (emphasis added). However, in airline mergers
that frequently is not the case. For example, passengers living in Dallas or Charlotte might lose
some competition on particular routes from this merger (such as Dallas-Phoenix, or Charlotte-
DCA), but the exact same passengers might benefit from the increased connectivity out of Dallas
or Charlotte provided by the mergers combination of the two airlines networks. The limited case
law on out-of-market efficiencies does not address this scenario.
31 E.g., AAI Comments at 4-11; Relpromax Comments at 8-9.
32 E.g., Wayne County Suppl. Comments at 1-2; Delta Comments at 25-30.
21
proving to be correct. For example, NewAA has eliminated or reduced
service to numerous cities from DCA and LGA as a result of its net loss of
slots, and it does not appear that the recipients of those slots have replaced
much of that lost service.33
The DOJ filed a detailed response to the criticisms. Much of that response
focused on legal points explaining why the attacks on the settlement fell short of
the demanding standard for rejecting a settlement under the Tunney Act, or
addressing comments not clearly related to Tunney Act issues (such as claims of
political pressure on DOJ).34
The DOJs substantive defense of its remedies,
while quite detailed, boils down to two simple propositions. First, the DOJ
conceded that its remedies do not address the mergers increase in concentration
on the overwhelming majority of city-pair routes.35
But the DOJ argued that no
remedy could address that issue, because no divestiture can require an airline to
serve any particular city-pair,36
and its remedy would at least reduce prices on
routes the LCCs choose to serve. Second, while the settlement did not prevent the
effects of the merger that allegedly increased the risk of coordination (the alleged
reduction of legacy carriers from four to three, and the elimination of USs and
AAs incentives to behave like mavericks),37
providing additional slots to LCCs at
DCA and LGA would allow LCCs to expand and, potentially, gain the ability to
33 See, e.g., Wayne County Suppl. Comments at 2. Delta also argued that the DAL divestitures
would harm it and its customers by essentially evicting it from DAL, the closest airport to
downtown Dallas. Delta Comments at 30-34.
34 DOJ Resp. at 15-21, 44-50.
35 See, e.g., DOJ Resp. at 27-30.
36 DOJ Resp. at 29-30, and n. 52. In fact, for virtually all city-pairs, there may not be an asset that
could be divested that relates specifically to that city-pair, because planes can fly anywhere, gates
are rarely if ever in short supply, and even slots cannot generally be restricted to serving particular
routes.
37 DOJ Resp. at 8-9.
22
disrupt that coordination at some point in the future (while providing lower prices
to at least some passengers in the interim).38
IV. Analysis
The settlement is drastically different from the complaint. That, in itself,
is not necessarily cause for concern about a settlement. Cases change when
theyre litigated. The facts and economic analysis dont always turn out as
anticipated, and the parties view of the issues may evolve. The DOJ clearly has
latitude to accept a settlement that reflects the lessons learned during litigation
and the risks of proceeding to trial.
Here, though, there is a fundamental tension between the complaints
allegations, the settlement, and the requirements and limitations of the antitrust
laws under which the complaint was filed. While perhaps not an appropriate
matter for Tunney Act review,39
that tension raises significant issues of antitrust
policy.
To understand this issue, its necessary to go back to the legal foundation
of merger enforcement: section 7 of the Clayton Act, 15 U.S.C. 18. That statute
prohibits mergers where in any line of commerce or in any activity affecting
commerce in any section of the country, the effect of such acquisition may be
substantially to lessen competition, or tend to create a monopoly.40
In other
words, merger enforcement is intended to preclude substantial competitive harm
in relevant markets. And, accordingly, merger remedies should address the
identified harms in the identified markets.41
38 DOJ Resp. at 9-15, 23-30.
39 E.g., DOJ Resp, at 21-22.
40 15 U.S.C. 18.
41 Antitrust Div. Policy Guide to Merger Remedies, 2-4 (June 2011).
23
The theories of harm identified in the complaint cannot be reconciled with
the settlement that purports to remedy them.42
Why is this so? Because in order
for the DOJs remedy to work, LLCs have to be competitive constraints on legacy
airlines and relevant markets cannot be city-pairs. If those two conditions hold,
the remedy might work but the complaint would be wrong. If either of those
conditions does not hold, the complaint might be right, but the remedy does not
work. In other words, based on the information provided to the public, the
complaint and the remedy cant both be right.
As described above, the complaints basic theories were (1) the merger
would increase the risk of coordinated interaction by reducing the number of
legacy airlines from four to three, and (2) the merger would directly harm
consumers by reducing the number of competitors on over 1000 city-pairs, which
would result in price increases on those city pairs. For those harms to be
remedied by slot divestitures at two airports to LCCs who are not likely to use the
slots to fly the routes affected by the merger, it must be the case that (1) LCCs
constrain coordinated interaction by legacy airlines, and (2) prices on
concentrated routes must be affected by competition on other routes, i.e.,
competition must occur at a network level, not a city-pair level.43
The complaint, however, alleged precisely the opposite. And, if LCCs
constrain coordination by legacy airlines, or if competition is not on a city-pair
basis, the complaint simply fails to allege a viable theory of anticompetitive harm
sufficient to justify challenging the merger.
First, if LCCs constrain coordination, rather than a 4-3 merger this merger
was more like an 11-10 merger (with the addition to the market of LCCs
42 As noted above, DOJ has urged that a challenge to the merits of the original antitrust case is not
permissible under the Tunney Act.
43 Otherwise, there is no justification under Clayton 7 for divesting a slot to an LCC to use that
slot to fly a route not affected by the merger for the benefit of passengers unharmed by the merger,
unless relevant markets are broader than particular city-pair routes, or perhaps under the
inextricably intertwined principles discussed earlier.
24
Southwest, JetBlue, Allegiant, Alaska, Frontier, Spirit, and Virgin America along
with US, AA, DL, and UA).44
Moreover, the remaining competitors are not
small, fringe firms. They include Southwest, arguably the largest airline in the
U.S., and a number of the fastest-growing, lowest-priced, highest-service airlines
in the business (e.g., Spirit and Allegiant on price, and JetBlue and Virgin
America on service), none of whom face any material obstacles to entry or
expansion at the overwhelming majority of airports and on the overwhelming
majority of affected city-pairs, and each of whom offer differentiated service
under different business models than the legacy airlines.45
Coordinated
interaction theories are not normally considered plausible under these sorts of
market conditions.
Second, if city-pairs are not relevant markets, the concentration indices
and price effects described in the complaint would be erroneous and irrelevant.
Moreover, if there were price disparities between concentrated and
unconcentrated city-pairs, if city-pairs are not relevant markets, those effects
would likely caused by factors other than market power, and thus would be
neither a concern of merger enforcement nor capable of being remedied by such
enforcement.
Assuming, however, that the complaint was not fundamentally wrong, the
settlement not only fails to remedy the harms identified in the complaint, but
inflicts harms and bestows benefits on consumers without regard to any merger
effectsand that is not what the Clayton Act requires.46
44 Entry and exit are not uncommon in the airline industry, so this list could be subject to change
or debate, but by any definition, the number of competitors is large.
45 See supra. See also John Kwoka, Kevin Hearle, and Phillippe Allepin, Segmented Competition
in Airlines: The Changing Roles of Low-Cost and Legacy Carriers in Fare Determination
(February 6, 2013), available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2212860 or
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2212860, at 4-6, and generally.
46 Once again, with the possible exception of inextricably intertwined efficiencies.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2212860
25
First, as noted above, with perhaps a handful of exceptions the divestitures
do not address harms on routes where concentration is increased by the merger.
For example, a passenger formerly able to choose between AA and US in flying
between Charlotte and Miami will lose that choice with no new choice to replace
it. Thus, if the relevant markets are city-pairs, the remedy does not address the
harm alleged from the merger.
Second, if LCCs do not restrain coordination by legacy carriers,
divestiture of slots to LCCs will not address the increased coordination allegedly
caused by the merger. This is true both on the city-pair level (since the complaint
articulates no theory by which LCCs could constrain coordination on routes they
do not fly) and more generally. Neither the complaint, nor the CIS, nor the
DOJs response to the criticisms of the merger provide any argument explaining
how the divestitures would address coordination on capacity or service (and if
city-pairs are markets, there is no reason to think they would, except where LCCs
that acquire divested slots and facilities actually enter). To the contrary, by
arguing that LCCs cannot address such coordination now, the DOJ essentially has
ruled out any claim that enabling relatively modest expansion by some LCCs
(limited to flights to or from a handful of airports) could have any effect on the
alleged legacy airline coordination, at least in the foreseeable future.
Third, as commentators have noted, the remedy harms passengers who
likely would not have been harmed by the merger. Stripping the merged airline of
slots at DCA and LGA has resulted in the termination of service on less-profitable
routes that were served by either US or AA premerger, but not both. To the
extent those routes are relevant markets, passengers traveling them would not
have been affected by the merger. But the settlement has caused them to lose
service they previously enjoyed.
DOJs defense of its remedy increases the tension with the Clayton Act.
In essence, DOJ argues that it is threading a competitive needle that will allow it
to stitch together a superior industry structure sometime in the future. According
26
to DOJ, while it is true that the LCCs today or immediately post-remedy can
neither constrain legacy airline coordination nor prevent the vast majority of price
increases on particular city-pairs, the remedy will help them acquire the assets and
size to do so someday. And, in the meantime, the remedy will produce lower
prices on the routes the LCCs receiving slots choose to fly for the passengers who
choose to use those routes (and, potentially, for connecting itineraries involving
those routes).
The primary thrust of this remedysetting the stage for more robust
future competition by strengthening selected competitorsseems quite
speculative. As complaint alleges, the LCCs are ill-suited to address the harms
alleged at any time in the near future. DOJ has not provided any timeline by
which its hoped-for industry reconfiguration will occur, or by which the LCCs
will achieve sufficient scale to challenge the legacy airlines in the arenas in which
the legacy airlines allegedly coordinate. Given Southwests size, it is unclear
what more DOJ might believe is needed, or even if it is attainable. The remedy
here, though, seems a Lilliputian step in that direction.47
Further, DOJs professed reasons for favoring LCCs amount to preferring
their current business models and hoping that theyll continue to pursue them.
But nothing in the settlement requires any LCC to do so. Moreover, the
complaint provides some evidence that it is unlikely LCCs will ever constrain
alleged coordination among legacy airlines. The complaint alleges that the LCCs
cannot constrain the legacy airlines now because they do not offer the breadth of
service, nor engender the customer loyalty, that the legacy airlines provide with
their far-reaching hub-and-spoke networks. But that implies that in order to beat
the legacy airlines at this game, the LCCs will likely have to look more like
legacy carriers, at least to some extent. And, as some commentators have
observed, doing so would likely require the LCCs to change their structure
which would change their costs, their business model, and might well be expected
47 See Relpromax Comments at 8 (comparing effects of divestiture on relative sizes of LCCs).
27
to cause them to behave like the legacy airlines allegedly do.48
If so, while the
number of competitors in various markets might expandperhaps impeding
coordinationthose additional competitors may not pursue the LCC business
model on which DOJ places considerable weight as an obstacle to coordination.
Finally, DOJs claim of benefits from the reduction of prices on routes the
LCCs choose to enter suffers from two problems. First, as noted above, those
benefits do not directly address either the alleged harms from the merger or the
harms inflicted by the remedy. Second, the hoped-for LCC price reductions
bestow benefits unrelated to the merger on passengers unaffected by the merger.
To illustrate this, consider the example DOJ provides of reduced prices on
Newark-Houston and Newark-St. Louis following the slot divestitures required in
UA/CO.49
While this is difficult to determine with certainty, it appears that prior
to acquiring Continental, United did not fly nonstop between Newark and either
Houston or St. Louis.50
Thus, while DOJs remedy may have benefited
passengers on those routes, they were not going to be harmed by the merger.
They simply received a windfall. Likewise, here passengers benefiting from
increased service between, say, DCA and Orlando will receive windfall benefits.51
Put differently, the professed benefits of the remedy are out-of-market benefits.
To summarize, DOJs complaint, remedy, and the Clayton Act seem
incompatible. If the complaints description of the relevant markets and
competitive harms is correct, the remedy does not appear to be directly related to
any alleged substantial lessening of competition in any line of commerce and
48 AAI Comments at 10; Delta Comments at 20-24, 26-28; Relpromax Comments at 8-9. There is
some evidence that this is already happening. AAI Comments at 8; see also Kwoka, Hearle, and
Alepin at 7-9.
49 CIS at 10.
50 UA may have flown this route via connections, but if airlines behaved then the way the DOJ
alleges they behave now, the UA connections would not have affected the pre-merger price, and
thus the merger likely would not have harmed passengers on those routes.
51 It is true that many of the passengers at issue may be the same people who would be harmed by
increased concentration on city pairs, and that might support DOJs approach to benefits. But
DOJ has not made this argument.
28
does not appear to correct any such lessening caused by the merger. Further, the
remedy appears to bestow benefits and inflict harms on consumers without any
connection to any such lessening of competition. The remedy here more closely
resembles a tax imposed on the transaction, the proceeds of which are then used
by the government to benefit particular preferred competitors in the hopes that
doing so will eventually make the market more competitive. This is a wide-
ranging endeavor that is very difficult to connect to antitrust law. If, on the other
hand, the complaint was fundamentally erroneous, then the justification for
imposing a remedy seems absent, and its connection to any kind of antitrust
theory obscure. Finally, under either scenario, the remedy seems to provide little
more than a hope that things may improve in the future, without any clear path to
that desired outcome.
There are two other possibilities. First, it could be that in airline mergers
there simply are no practical remedies for competitive harms from mergers, and
the best that can be done is to weigh total harms and benefits in deciding whether
to approve a merger. The DOJ hints at this in the CIS and its response to the
comments on the settlement. But if this is the correct reading of events, it would
be greatly beneficial if DOJ would be far more explicit on this point. DOJs
filings to date fail to describe the benefits that would offset the harms DOJ
continues to assert, and provides no means for industry participants, practitioners,
or the public to assess and weigh those harms and benefits. Further, this still
leaves unanswered the deeper question raised by DOJs remedies here. In the
past, the DOJ seems to have sought to block airline mergers when the aggregate
harms exceeded benefits (e.g., the proposed United/US Air merger, which the
United States sued to stop in 2001), or cleared them without conditions when the
reverse was true (e.g., Delta/Northwest). But here the DOJ has done something
different. It imposed remedies that harm some consumers and benefit others in
what could be an attempt to address the total welfare effect of the transaction,
without clearly explaining what it was doing. Whether DOJs approach was
correct is a serious issue that is difficult to assess absent more explanation from
DOJ.
29
Second, it is possible DOJ simply concluded it could not win the case and
took whatever remedy it could get. That often happens in litigation between
private parties with only their own economic interests to consider. But should the
DOJ engage in such a practice? Or should it either litigate and, if necessary,
loseor simply drop cases that turn out to be unmeritorious? And, in any event,
if DOJ is simply extracting the most from what turned out to be a bad hand, it
would be beneficial to the public if it provided more information explaining that
that is what it was doing.
Conclusion
The DOJs challenge to the AA/US merger was comprehensive. It
described sweeping nationwide harms, as well as harms in an enormous array of
narrow antitrust markets. The settlement, however, leaves the alleged harms
largely unaddressed. It instead transfers assets from the merging firms to another
set of firms to facilitate the recipients development as future competitors. In so
doing, the remedy inflicts harms and bestows benefits on passengers that appear
unrelated to any merger effect. Whether this was in fact what DOJ intended is
unclear, but there is not enough information provided to conclude otherwise.
And, if that is what the settlement is intended to do, further public debate may be
merited on whether market engineering of this nature is an appropriate role for an
antitrust enforcer applying Section 7 of the Clayton Act, as opposed to an industry
regulator.
30
DEAD ON ARRIVAL: CAN EFFICIENCIES REVIVE AN OTHERWISE UNLAWFUL HOSPITAL MERGER IN COURT?
John Matthew Schwietz1
Efficiencies have come a long way with respect to their recognition in
merger analysis. Historically, courts have deliberately disregarded efficiencies or
treated them with hostility until it eventually became economically irrational to
do so.2 The increased recognition of efficiencies is also apparent in each
successive publication of the United States Department of Justices and Federal
Trade Commissions (Agencies) Horizontal Merger Guidelines, which
progressively reflect the Agencies willingness to consider efficiencies during
merger review.3
A major concern when analyzing efficiencies is whether or not the merger
at hand will produce efficiencies that are likely to reverse its potential
anticompetitive effects.4 Courts use a sliding scale approach when balancing
claimed efficiencies against potential anticompetitive effects.5 This approach
requires that, if a mergers potential harm is substantial, the parties must produce
extraordinarily great cognizable efficiencies to survive.6 The Agencies
specifically recognize that efficiencies in hospital merger context present both
1 John Matthew Schwietz is J.D. Candidate, University of Minnesota Law School (2014)
2 See Thomas B. Leary, Commr, FTC, Efficiencies & Antitrust: A Story of Ongoing Evolution,
Remarks at the ABA Section of Antitrust L., 2002 Fall Forum (Nov. 8, 2002), available at
http://www.ftc.gov/speeches/leary/efficienciesandantitrust.shtm) (hereinafter Leary Remarks)
(citing Williamson, Economics as an Antitrust Defense, 58 Am. Econ. Rev. 18 (1968).
3 See Leary Remarks.
4 Robert F. Leibenhuft, Asst. Dir., Bur. of Comp., FTC, Antitrust Enforc. & Hosp. Mergers: A
Closer Look, text of remarks before the Alliance for Health, Grand Rapids, Mich. (June 5, 1998)
(hereinafter Leibenhuft Remarks).
5 D. Daniel Sokol & James A. Fishkin, Antitrust Merger Efficiencies in the Shadow of the Law, 64
VAND. L. REV. 45, 47-48, 65 (2011) at 64 (hereinafter S/F) (citing id. at 720); see also Merger
Guidelines 10.
6 S/F at 60-61 (citing Merger Guidelines 10 (emphasis added)).
31
ample reasons for skepticism as well as unique opportunities.7 Perhaps the most
unique opportunities efficiencies offer in the context of hospital mergers are
patient care benefits that result from the consolidation of clinical services.8
Typically, efficiencies that yield short-term positive effects and pass savings on to
customers are given the most weight.9 Nevertheless, efficiencies have yet to
revive an otherwise unlawful merger in court.10
This is no longer the case merely
because courts continue to lack the utility to examine difficult economic
problems.11
Instead, parties often-claimed efficiencies are simply not merger-
specific and are notoriously difficult to measure.12
For litigators hoping to revive an otherwise unlawful merger in court, it is
important to note that efficiencies are typically the last factor courts consider.13
In
other words, some mergers may appear to have ended up in court dead on arrival,
requiring extraordinary efficiencies arguments to resuscitate the merger. Two
fairly recent cases broadly illustrate how litigators should (or perhaps, should not)
present efficiencies claims in court: FTC v. OSF Healthcare System, and FTC v.
ProMedica Health System, Inc.14
7 Id.; see Christine A. Varney, Commr, FTC, New Directions at FTC: Efficiency Justifications in
Hosp. Mergers & Vertical Integn. Concerns, text of remarks before Health Care Antitrust Forum
(May 2, 1995) (hereinafter Varney Remarks).
8 See Tenet, 186 F.3d at 1054.
9 Id. at 31 n. 15.
10 John Miles, Analyzing Hospital Mergers-Other Factors-Efficiencies, 3 HEALTH L. PRAC. GUIDE
12:36 (2012). (citing ProMedica, 2011 WL 1219281 (citation omitted)).
11 See U.S. v. Topco Assocs., Inc., 405 U.S. 596, 609 (1972).
12 See id.; Miles (citing FTC v. Univ. Health, 938 F.2d 1206, 1223 (11th Cir. 1991)); FTC v.
Butterworth Health Corp., 946 F. Supp. 1285, 1301 (W.D. Mich. 1996).
13 Debra A. Valentine, Gen. Counsel, FTC, Health Care Mergers: Will We Get Efficiencies Claims
Right?, text of remarks before St. Louis Univ. Sch. of L. (Nov. 14, 1997) (hereinafter Valentine
Remarks); see Varney Remarks.
14 852 F. Supp.2d 1069 (N.D. Ill. 2012); 2011 WL 1219281 (N.D. Ohio).
32
Case Analysis I: The OSF Healthcare System Courts Sliding Scale Required
OSF to Produce Substantial, Non-Speculative Efficiencies.
In the first case, OSF Healthcare System, the FTC challenged the
proposed merger-to-duopoly of St. Anthony Medical Center and Rockford
Memorial Hospital in Rockford, Illinois.15
They were separately owned and
operated by OSF Healthcare and RHS (hereinafter referred to as OSF-RHS).16
Through their negotiations, OSF agreed to acquire RHSs assets; become its sole
corporate member; and combine operations to create a new health care system. 17
In OSF, the applicable primary product markets at issue were general
acute care [(GAC)] inpatient services . . . sold to commercial health plans and
primary care physician services.18
These markets included a broad cluster of
overnight hospital stays, surgical procedures, and emergency and internal
medicine services.19
The court defined the relevant geographic market as the area
within a 30 minute drive-time radius from Rockford, Illinois.20
With respect to
patient admissions and patient days21
, the mergers resulting HHI22
would have
increased 151 and 161 percent, respectively.23
In addition, the new health care
15 See OSF, 852 F. Supp.2d at 1069.
16See id. at 4.
17 Id. at 1072.
18 See id. at 1075-76.
19 Id.
20 See Tenet, 186 F.3d at 1052; id.
21 Def. of Patient Day, http://medical-dictionary.thefreedictionary.com/patient+day, (last viewed
May 17, 2013) (Each day represents a unit of time during which the services of the institution or
facility are used by a patient).
22 See Def. of Herfindahl-Hirschman Index HHI, http://www.investopedia.com/terms/h/hhi.asp
(last viewed May 15, 2013) (A commonly accepted measure of market concentration[ that] is
calculated by squaring the market share of each firm competing in a market, and then summing the
resulting numbers. The closer a market is to being a monopoly, the higher the market's
concentration . . . .)).
23 OSF, 852 F. Supp.2d at 1079.
33
system would have controlled 59 percent of the GAC market based on patient
admissions and 64 percent of that market based on patient days.24
The Court had No Trouble Finding the OSF and RHS Merger
Presumptively Unlawful.
Given the relevant markets at issue, the court had no trouble finding the
proposed merger to be presumptively illegal, as the market concentration
calculations far surpass[ed] the percentages that are regularly deemed illegal.25
To rebut the FTCs case, OSF-RHS claimed its merger would result in substantial
efficiencies, including recurring and one-time capital avoidance savings.26
Specifically, OSF-RHS made five cost-savings claims, including:
(1) $15.4 million in annual, recurring cost savings from clinical and operational consolidation;
(2) $114.1 million in avoiding one-time capital expenditures for building a new bed tower at one of its locations;
(3) $6.4 million through avoiding the replacement of outdated equipment and by purchasing a single, shared
surgical da Vinci Robot;
(4) $7 million based on the replacement cost of a trauma helicopter; and
(5) $7.8 million per year by enhancing clinical
effectiveness.27
The merging parties also argued that their merger would lead to certain
community benefits for the Rockford area such as improved quality of care and
the development of centers of excellence.28
The purported community
24 Id. at 1078.
25 Id. (citing U.S. v. Phila. Natl Bank, 374 U.S. 321, 363 (1963); Univ. Health, 938 F.2d at 1219
(holding that the FTC clearly established a prima facie case of anticompetitive effect when the
merged entity would control approximately 43 percent of the GAC market with three remaining
competitors)).
26 OSF, 852 F. Supp.2d at 1079, 1088-91.
27 Id.
28 OSF, 852 F. Supp.2d at 1093.
34
benefits were alleged to increase the hospitals ability to attract specialists and
develop a residency program.29
With respect to OSF-RHSs cost savings claims, the judge found that a
substantial portion of them were overstated, . . . speculative, [and] inadequately
substantiated.30
This finding was due in part to conflicting expert testimony on
the subject of efficiencies and the uncertainty surrounding whether, and to what
extent, the proposed consolidations would actually occur.31
The court also
summarily dismissed the consolidation arguments after OSF-RHS failed to offer
evidence (and failed to study) the consolidations feasibility, as OSF-RHS had no
specific plans for the consolidations to occur.32
The other examples of capital spending avoidance savings OSF-RHS
identified suffer[ed] from similar infirmities.33
Specifically, these claimed
savings were based solely on the success of service line consolidations, the scope
of which was uncertain.34
[T]o the extent that the proposed savings [we]re
speculative or otherwise not cognizable, these secondary benefits [we]re likewise
speculative or not cognizable . . . .35
As such, the projected savings were deemed
too speculative and the claimed efficiencies were deemed not cognizable.36
With respect to OSF-RHSs community benefits arguments, the court
found that a merger was not necessary to implement graduate education programs
in Rockford.37
The hospitals could have simply implemented a joint-residency
29 Id.
30 Id.
31 Id.
32 Id. at 1090-91.
33 Id.
34 Id.
35 Id.
36 Id. at 1091-92.
37 Id.
35
program via partnerships to accomplish this goal.38
Under the sliding scale
approach, the court found that the private equities were too speculative to revive
the unlawful merger in court.39
Case Analysis II: The ProMedica Court Required ProMedica to Present
Extraordinary Efficiencies.
In the second case, FTC v. ProMedica Health System, Inc., the FTC
sought to enjoin ProMedica from further consolidating its operations with St.
Luke's Hospital in Ohio.40
At the time, ProMedica was a dominant, not-for-
profit integrated healthcare system that served Ohios Lucas County.41
This area
includes the City of Toledo and adjacent areas of southeastern Michigan.42
There,
ProMedica operated three GAC hospitals that offered inpatient obstetrics
services.43
Its market share from July 2009 to March 2010 accounted for nearly 50
percent of the GAC services patient days and 71.2 percent of obstetrics services
patient days. 44
Meanwhile, St. Luke's was a non-profit, low-cost, high-quality
GAC community hospital, located in southwestern Lucas County where it
provided a full array of GAC services.45
Like in OSF, this case also presented high market concentration levels.46
The relevant product markets at issue were a cluster of GAC inpatient services
sold to commercial health plans and inpatient obstetrical services.47
Also
similar to OSF, the ProMedica court found that the market shares and HHI levels
38 Id.
39 Id.
40 2011 WL 1219281 at 1 (N.D. Ohio).
41 Id. at 2.
42 Id.
43 Id. at 1-2.
44 Id. at 3.
45 Id.
46 Id. (citing Heinz, 246 F.3d at 72122).
47 Id. at 55.
36
here far exceed[ed] those that regularly establish presumptive illegality.48
Accordingly, the burden to rebut the FTCs prima facie evidence shifted to
ProMedica to present efficiencies that outweigh the mergers anticompetitive
effect.49
In order to revive the merger in court, application of the sliding scale
required that the District Court find ProMedicas efficiencies to be
extraordinary, which it did not.50
The Sliding Scale Approach Effectively Rendered ProMedicas
Speculative Efficiencies Arguments Dead on Arrival.
To support its efficiencies claims, ProMedica produced an economic
report that represented an initial plan, based on preliminary estimates that
were subject to further analysis, revision, and substantiation.51
However, this
tentative sentiment from the report was merely illustrative of the several problems
ProMedica faced, making it improbable the court would ever tip the sliding scale
in its favor.
The first problem ProMedica encountered was that its purported
efficiencies were not clearly cognizable. For example, ProMedica argued that
certain revenue enhancements were efficiencies despite that they merely shifted
revenue among market participants and did not reduce costs or increase inputs.52
Also, the District Court described as suspect ProMedicas capital cost
avoidance claims because ProMedica had no investment plans for the saved funds
that would pass savings onto customers.53
ProMedica also claimed that it might
avoid $100 million in construction and equipment costs for building a new
hospital at its Arrowhead location.54
However, this plan did not convince the
48 Id. at 56 (citing Heinz, 246 F. 3d at 716).
49 See Univ. Health, 938 F.2d at 1218.
50 ProMedica, 2011 WL 1219281 at 3 (citing Heinz, 246 F.3d at 72122).
51 Id. (citation omitted) (emphasis added).
52 Id. at 36.
53 Id.
54 Id.
37
court because, even though ProMedica owned the Arrowhead land for a decade,
it failed to take any recent steps consistent with its intent to build on the site.55
ProMedica also made several unsuccessful cost avoidance arguments and
its other claimed efficiencies were simply speculative, as [v]irtually all of
the[m] contained the caveat that they may be accomplished.56
First, it claimed
it could avoid spending $30 million on constructing an additional bed tower.57
Second, it averred it could save St. Luke's between $7.6 and $15.6 million in
information technology upgrade costs.58
The District Court dismissed both
claims and described them as unsubstantiated because ProMedicas pre-merger
strategic plans never included adding a bed tower in the near future.59
So the
avoided construction costs ProMedica pointed to were not costs that ProMedica
anticipated incurring before the merger.
Like in OSF, the District Court found that ProMedicas arguments
regarding savings from consolidation were insufficient. Because ProMedica failed
to undertake any detailed analysis of its proposed clinical consolidations, its
$1.45 million in consolidation savings claims were unsubstantiated.60
Further,
when ProMedica claimed it could save $1.4 million through lowering post-merger
physician insurance coverage costs, it failed to compare those costs on an apples
to apples basis and based the calculation on a different, less robust type of
insurance coverage.61
Ultimately, the District Court found that ProMedicas
efficiency claims were unsubstantiated and speculative because they lacked
55 Id.
56 Id. at 38 (citation omitted).
57 Id. at 37.
58 Id.
59 Id.
60 Id.
61 Id. at 38 (citation omitted).
38
detail about how prices the hospitals paid differ and omitted analyses of
ProMedica's capacity to absorb St. Luke's volumes.62
Several of ProMedicas Claimed Efficiencies were Not Merger-
Specific.
In addition, several of ProMedicas claims were simply deemed not
merger-specific. For example, the court noted that St. Lukes could achieve a
substantial amount of the claimed efficiencies through affiliation with a
different Lucas County hospital.63
In fact, the court cited a then-recent St. Luke's
Board presentation that described several opportunities such an affiliation could
create, specifically noting that it could provide endless benefits and be just as
valuable as a partnership with ProMedica.64
In addition, ProMedica alleged that it
could save $4.5 million by closing a family practice residency program.65
The
District Court found that this claim was not merger-specific, as ProMedica could
have eliminated one of its residency programs on its own without the
acquisition.66
Likewise, the District Court found the information technology
upgrades claims to be largely overstated because ProMedica failed to account for
certain subsidies that could have substantially lower[ed] St. Lukes overall costs
absent a merger.67
The final asserted revenue enhancement regarded the addition of St.
Luke's to the Paramount provider network.68
Here again, the District Court found
that the alleged efficiencies could be achieved without the acquisition because St.
Lukes was already interested in participating in the network.69
Ultimately, the
62 Id. at 39.
63 Id.
64 Id.
65 Id. at 40.
66 Id.
67 Id.
68 Id.
69 Id.
39
court found that ProMedica failed to prove efficiencies that were: (1) verifiable;
(2) not attributable to reduced output or quality; (3) merger-specific; and (4)
sufficient to outweigh the transaction's anticompetitive effects.70
It Remains to be Seen Whether or Not Real, Cognizable Efficiencies
can Revive an Otherwise Unlawful Merger in Court.
Because the Agencies are charged with the important task of protecting
consumer welfare, it should be no surprise that the few cases that reach the courts
often go in the Agencies favor. As the above cases illustrate, efficiencies are
typically the last factor a court will consider in merger cases. This is especially
the case, as seen above, when parties merely rely on the the impressive-sounding
quantity of unsubstantiated arguments rather than making quality, substantiated
efficiencies arguments.
Practitioners should note that although OSF and ProMedica do not inspire
hope that courts will see efficiencies as a reason to permit an otherwise anti-
competitive hospital merger, the robust efficiencies discussions from these cases
signal that courts are willing to examine proffered efficiencies claims carefully.
Much of the uncertainty regarding efficiencies in these cases appear to be due to
the fact that the sliding scale significantly weighed in the Agencies favor and the
merging parties presented - at best - speculative efficiencies arguments. By the
time the court considered the arguments (regardless of their merit), it was likely a
case of too little, too late the court had already formed the view that the merger
was anti-competitive, and only very concrete and credible efficiencies claims
would cause the court to reexamine that conclusion. The parties in these cases
failed to carry that heavy burden, by failing to take advantage of the unique
opportunities for efficiencies arguments that hospital mergers can present.
While prospective merging parties prepare for Agency challenges, they
must consider how best to develop evidence of efficiencies that the court is likely
70 Id. at 57 (citing Heinz, 246 F.3d at 721; Univ. Health Inc., 938 F.2d at 1223; see also Merger
Guidelines 10.
40
to recognize. Merging parties should recognize that the courts will not consider
efficiencies are merely promises about post-merger behavior.71
Generally,
merging parties must substantiate and support their efficiencies claims to an
extent that allows a court to verify by reasonable means (1) the[ir] likelihood and
magnitude . . ., (2) how and when each will be achieved (and the costs of doing
so), (3) how each will enhance the merged firm's ability and incentive to compete,
and (4) why each one is merger-specific.72
If a hospital merger case does in fact
reach the courts, it would be wise to center these arguments around patient care
benefits, clinical services consolidations, and most importantly, short-term
positive effects regarding customer savings. In other words, merging parties must
demonstrate exactly where they will save money through consolidation and show
the court exactly how those savings will be passed on to patients.
Finally, if merging hospitals sufficiently bolster their efficiencies claims
with cognizable, non-speculative, merger-specific arguments during the
government merger investigation, the Agencies may be less likely to challenge the
mergers to begin with. After all,