Free trade: Good or Bad?

Preview:

Citation preview

Haider 1

Ali Haider

2017-02-0331

Rabia Nafees Shah

SS100-11 Writing and Communication

10 May 2014

Should free trade and labor mobility be allowed?

Why is Italy famous for making footwear and not silicon

chips? Is it simply because Italy looks like a long boot? Why do

we spend joules of thought before picking a shampoo or going for

a movie? How has the famous ‘Oscar selfie’ become popular so

rapidly among people all over the world? The carrier of this

gamut of change, which determines our economic well-being,

envelopes our social lives and is transforming global culture, is

free trade. Free trade is described as the unrestricted purchase

and sale of goods and services between countries without the

imposition of constraints such as tariffs, duties and quotas

(Free Trade Definition Investopedia). The notion of free trade

has its early origins in renowned classical economist, Adam

Smith’s 1776 magnum opus, The Wealth of Nations. It was written

Haider 2

to upend the Mercantilist ideology, which was prevalent in Europe

since 16th century. Adam Smith promulgated the idea that rigorous

pursuit of self-interest and free interplay of market forces work

like an ‘invisible hand’, to determine optimum level of

production and consumption in the market, thereby rendering

interventionist discourse and practices unnecessary and adverse

(Adam Smith). Later, various theories dwelled upon Adam Smith’s

revolutionary idea and became founding principles for modern day

free trade. Proponents of Adam Smith’s invisible hand and strong

supporters of protectionism have had been engaging in various

diatribes over the issue. Over the course of history, it has been

observed that economies which have opened their borders to free

trade have enjoyed rapid and sustainable economic growth. China

has experienced a 10% GDP growth rate on average since it leaned

towards trade liberalization post 1978 (China). Free trade

policies and the resultant free mobility of resources have

debatably had detrimental impact on the diversity of cultures,

national security and have also contributed to marginalization of

developing economies. However, we cannot let the perfectionist

fallacy which protectionists and bourgeoisie espouse, often for

Haider 3

their myopic vested interests, override the greater good which

trade liberalization carries. Free trade should be fostered for

the economic growth, higher incomes, and cultural harmony it

brings about, however, state authorities and global community

should oversee and regulate the trading process to curb market

failures and safeguard national interests and security.

Modern day free trade principles stand tall on a

revolutionizing theory propounded by David Ricardo in his 1817

book, Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. In this book

Ricardo vociferously condemned the 1815 Corn Laws, which were

protectionist and myopically nationalist in spirit, and advocated

the theory of Comparative Advantage (Comparative Advantage).

According to ‘Ricardian’ principle of comparative advantage,

resources are optimally allocated when economies produce those

goods in which they have the lower domestic opportunity cost

ratio. The mathematical illustration and the accompanying

technicalities have been forgone for the sake of focus and

brevity. In a trade arrangement based on Ricardian principles,

trading partners specialize in production of goods, which can

best be produced with their factor endowments. The specialization

Haider 4

generates greater output and both trading partners have enough to

trade goods at a profitable exchange rate. It is established how

Adam Smith’s invisible hand and Ricardo’s principle of

comparative advantage induce a mutually-beneficial trade

arrangement, where resources are put to their best use. It is a

worrying fact that the population mark has crossed seven billion

recently. Pervasively, the problem of scarcity of resources is

growing grimmer. In view of the forgoing, channelization of

resources to their optimal use is critical for sustainability.

Therefore, the neo-liberal argument for free trade holds water

for its utilitarian ends. However, the naysayers tend to disagree

on the grounds that free trade damages national industry by

exposure of foreign competition. This refutation to the free

trade argument is valid to some extent. Detroit’s auto industry’s

decline is a classic example. Import of European and Japanese

cars in the US after mid-1950’s marked a watershed for the Big

Three (General Motors, Ford and Chrysler) and Detroit’s economic

structure. In 1956 sales of imported European cars doubled, while

demand for local cars fell. Subsequently, the Big Three fine-

tuned a part of their portfolio according to the consumers’

Haider 5

preferences. Later in 1973, OPEC raised oil prices drastically

for political reasons which rendered the cars produced in the US

unaffordable since they were not fuel-efficient anymore. Soon

the exasperated consumers started importing Japanese cars, which

were highly affordable for their splendid fuel-efficient engines

and compact sizes (Detroit: The New Motor City). Japan played on

its factor endowment, i.e. cheap and skilled labor. Heavy flood

of car imports swept Detroit’s car industry away. The General

Motor’s Flint plant, which employed 100,000 workers in its

heyday, downsized to only 6000 in 2007. Detroit, which was once a

home to people with highest median incomes in the country, is now

called the poverty capital of the US (Schifferes). This tragic

account of Detroit’s fall puts spotlight on the horrid façade of

trade liberalization. However, it must be noted that rigid

adherence to utilitarian pursuit is not only justified on the

grounds of optimal resource allocation and sustainability, but

also for the fact that trade liberalization mechanism carries a

moral high ground since it champions consumer sovereignty and

liberty. State intervention and protection of incompetent

national industries violates the rights of the consumers, who are

Haider 6

bigger stakeholders of the state than the business class. The

role of state should ideally be to monitor free trade and provide

an enabling environment for the industrial sector to grow, rather

than to protect it against competition. It has a key role to play

in inspiring innovation in an economy. It is astonishing to

discover that many of the profound technological breakthroughs

have been made by government assistance. Smartphones owe many of

their key features such as touchscreen, GPS positioning and

voice-activated virtual assistants to the US government which

assisted development of these technologies for the armed forces,

through research funding. The development of Google’s search

algorithm was also heavily funded by the National Science

Foundation in the US (The Entrepreneurial State). It is clear

that by stimulating innovation and setting up research

facilities, a government can allow a country to fully explore its

potential and utilize its factors of production, catalyze the

process of specialization and resultantly enable the economy to

reap fruits of free trade. The government can also enter into

partnership with micro-financing banks and fund growth of

promising and creative infant industries. In Bangladesh, the

Haider 7

state has 25% share in the famous Grameen bank’s ownership, which

has empowered 8.3 million people and has $1.4 billion in its

reserves. These are a few of the areas where public-private

sector partnership can safeguard local industry, especially

infant industries, and protect them against free trade

competition in a constructive way (Wright). In summary, it can be

argued that specialization and free trade arrangement should be

provided a fair opportunity to flower by the state for the

economic growth and consumer welfare it promises. The state

should focus on addressing the possible harms free trade could

bring to national economy by providing an enabling environment

and constructive infrastructural support.

Trade between two countries has proved to be a critical tool

for diplomacy and creating cooperative relationships.

Specialization and adherence to principle of comparative

advantage engenders a relationship of mutual interdependence

between two countries. Renowned French political thinker, Baron

de Montesquieu observed that "Peace is the natural effect of

trade. Two nations who differ with each other become reciprocally

dependent; for if one has an interest in buying, the other has an

Haider 8

interest in selling; and thus their union is founded on their

mutual necessities." (Boudreaux). This ‘reciprocal dependence’

creates a stake in trading partner’s economic stability, makes it

imperative and mitigates antagonism between two countries. A

research conducted by a political scientist at Columbia

University, Erik Gartzke, establishes this correlation between

peace and free trade. Erik ranked countries on an economic-

freedom index and scaled the countries from 1 to 10 (10 being

very open). The countries were observed over the time horizon

between 1816 and 2000. He drew some profound conclusions from

this effort. Countries which ranked second or lower on the scale

were 14 times more prone to political upheavals and military

conflicts. Erik accentuated importance of the role of state in

establishing a sound taxation regime, promoting growth of

businesses and deregulation of markets (Boudreaux). The détente

between US and China due to their growing economic relations is

one example how free trade can bring arch rivals together in a

diplomatic bond. Chinese exports to US stood at $252.3 billion,

while US made exports of whopping $224.7 billion to Chinese

markets, making China the third biggest market for US (Shian).

Haider 9

However, this relationship of mutual interdependence based on

principles of free trade is looked suspiciously by critics and is

seen as static. Famous political economist Ha-Joo Chang in his

book, Kicking Away the Ladder, expressed his concern that the

developed countries like the US, the United Kingdom and Germany

unabashedly and unfairly exploit their power at the Bretton wood

institutes and tend to form a bastion to protect national

interests while preaching ‘Adam Smith’ and ‘David Ricardo’ to

the developing economies. Dependency theorists have traditionally

censured an arrangement which tends to divert wealth and

resources from the periphery of poor nations to core nations,

too. These allegations on free trade scheme are quite pertinent

if we observe how members of the OECD protect its agricultural

industry. Over time, while WTO has encouraged and managed to

remove trade barriers by controlling tariffs and bringing them

down from 40% to 4% over the past 50 years, but tariffs on

agricultural goods stay in the range of 40-50% astonishingly.

Japan has outrageous tariffs imposed on its rice import, i.e.

1000%. The member countries of the OECD justify this double-

standard on the pretext of food security and to maintain

Haider 10

political harmony with famers. This adversely affects developing

economies’ current account balance because they are strictly

dependent on exports of cash crops and are likely to incur low

terms of trade (Patches of Light). However, if we observe

precedent, this argument does not hold enough substance to refute

the validity of free trade. We have China, Singapore, Malaysia

and India as paragons, which were agrarian economies initially,

but have successfully remodeled their economic structure by

introducing industrialization, trade liberalization, market

deregulation and investing in research and development. Today,

agriculture accounts only for 9.7% of the China’s GDP while

industry and services account for 90.3%, while in Malaysia, which

was a predominantly a raw material producer before 1970s,

agriculture has been restricted to 11.2 % of GDP (Central

Intelligence Agency). The developing economies, as earlier

suggested, constantly need to invest into research and

development to break free from shackles of dependence on low-

value goods. The state has an important role in facilitating a

structural change of this scale. The way OECD clings to its

vested national interests is not liberal in spirit and must be

Haider 11

condemned. Also, the power structure in WTO is not solely

dependent on the economic power of the nations but also their

political influence. Therefore, the argument made by the

dependency theorists and Ha-Joo Chang fails to defuse the

proposition that free trade is ultimately beneficial for the

sustained development of world economy and is in mutual and wider

interests of all the parties involved.

The ambit of free trade does not only include

transportation of physical goods and services only, but also of

ideas and cultural practices. Manfred Steger calls this process

Cultural Globalization. According to Steger, Cultural

Globalization refers to the intensification and expansion of

cultural flows across the globe (Steger). Cultural practices

escape fixed localities, permeate other cultures, mold them and

embrace them. This element of congregating global cultural values

is central to free trade and reinforces peace and harmony which

it espouses. Language is one of the great barriers which impede

flow of information and restrict exchange of ideas and

innovation. Through free trade and the resultant cultural

globalization this barrier has been pushed far back. Steger notes

Haider 12

that the users of English language have increased phenomenally

from seven million in British colonial era to 350 million in 1990

(Steger). On the contrary, this trend towards confluence of

global cultures is seen as erosion of cultural diversity by some

of the critics of free trade and globalization. George Ritzer, in

his famous theory named The McDonaldization of Society, explained

it as the process by which the principles of the fast-food

restaurant are coming to dominate more and more sectors of

American society as well as the rest of the world (The

McDonaldization of Society). Ritzer’s theory has far-reaching

implications. It looks at how the ubiquity of symbols of cultural

globalization, such as McDonald’s and Nike, has pervasively had a

dehumanizing impact on diversity of global cultures. The

criticism on free trade on these bases is not well-founded.

Although free trade and cultural globalization do have a tendency

towards molding global culture, but, free trade has also enabled

people to stay grounded with their culture. YouTube, Facebook and

the wide array of cooking shows bear testimony to the fact that

free trade and thus free flow of media is allowing people to stay

connected to their roots, irrespective of their geographical

Haider 13

location. In addition to this, free trade has been a source of

enlightenment and has at times helped societies purify themselves

of taboos by creating awareness. “Consider, for example, Thomas

Cahill's description of ancient Athens after that city opened

itself to trade: As these familiar clustered settlements, known

to agricultural societies throughout the world, grew into cities—

with demarcated streets, temples and other official buildings,

marketplaces and other gathering centers, import-export

warehouses, and docks where exotic cargoes and even more exotic

foreigners were unloaded power shifted somewhat from landed

aristocrats to the better-placed urbanites, who controlled trade

and who in the diversity of their experience began to think new

thoughts” (Free Trade and Globalization: More than "Just

Stuff” ). The diversity and cultural enlightenment which free

trade brings accompanies, in addition to the huge economic

benefits, are the reasons why free trade should be promoted.

Free movement of goods and services which free trade

motivates includes free movement of labor, since it is a factor

of production. This free movement is fundamental for optimal

Haider 14

resource allocation, economic growth and development. In 2013,

the developing world remitted around $414 billion dollars back to

their homelands. Some of the developing economies such as

Tajikistan have 48% of their GDP composed of remittances (News.).

Pakistan, which has been enjoying considerable inflow of foreign

exchange through remittances, has recently received a total of

$14.9 billion from its nationals working abroad. Clearly, free

flow of cheap and skilled labor, which is highly demanded in

developed countries, is an essential determinant of economic

growth at home. Moreover, free flow of professionals across the

globe enhances productivity as larger numbers of ideas are

shared. For example, the Japanese have introduced lean production

techniques, such as ‘Kaizen’ and Just-in-time production to

western producers and have helped them cut costs in various

industries. Dell Inc. now employs the JIT technique earlier

employed by Toyota motors. Free flow of labor is thus

developmental and productive. However, free mobility of labor is

often disapproved by anti-globalization campaigners and

nationalists on the grounds that it leads to flight of

intellectual capital and professionals from a country. This is

Haider 15

informally termed as ‘Brain drain’. The United Kingdom has been

facing this grave problem recently. In 2012, it was studied that

an estimated 4.7 million people in Britain moved to other

countries (Travis). The exodus of young population, especially

professionals badly affects the productive potential of the

economy, and leaves the aged population behind, which increases

burden of dependency on the rest. The problem is more serious

because public funds are heavily employed in funding scholarships

for students graduating in professional degrees. These students,

upon acquiring professional degree tend to move towards developed

economies in pursuit of lucrative careers prospects. While the

issue of brain drain is relevant and valid, what needs to be done

is that the state should enforce a well-planned migration scheme.

Why? In the absence of a state-regulated migration scheme and use

of stringent laws and regulations by state to hamper labor

movement, even more grave issues might arise. In addition to that

the state would be unable to keep a proper record of migration.

Also migrants without proper documents fail to avail to health

care facilities abroad, in addition to huge suffering. This

problem has quite exacerbated in areas like Botswana, Zambia and

Haider 16

Kenya where unavailability of proper logistics causes serious

problems (Border Point Queues: A Curse for Truck Drivers in

Africa – Video). On a principle level, everyone has a right to

freedom of movement according to the Article 13 of the Human

Rights. An individual must be free to pursue his economic well-

being and also since this pursuit of self-interest is essential

to working of free market forces and optimal allocation of

resources, it should be encouraged. Concisely speaking, although

the issue of brain drain can have dire consequences for a

country, an establishment of a regulated process for migration

can allow a state to have a clearer picture of the situation,

curb issues such as, human trafficking and proliferation of

contagious diseases etc. The state must incline towards

incentivizing the local population, binding students studying on

public expenditure in contracts which prevent exploitation of the

public expenditure and also provide fair opportunity to

individuals to pursue their self-interests.

In view of the forgoing effort, some profound conclusions on

the subject and dynamics of free trade can be made.

Interestingly, no matter which position we take on the issue, or

Haider 17

which degree do we pick on the wide spectrum between free trade

and absolute protection, the process of free trade and the

ensuing globalization is ongoing and so deeply embedded in our

lives that we cannot extricate ourselves from it. Not only that,

we are actually participating in it or endorsing it in one way or

another even if we claim ourselves to be radical and stalwart

protectionists. Free trade, as established above is a fount of

economic growth and development, because it adheres to principles

of free market and ensures optimal allocation of resources.

However, there are certain dimensions to the phenomenon which

pose threat to the best interests of a nation, culture, certain

groups such as developing economies, and so on. As far as the

criticism of the economic disparity which free trade entails, is

concerned, the role of state is critical. The state needs to play

a mildly paternalistic role in monitoring markets, addressing

market failures, and channelizing resources to promote free

trade, mobility and industrial growth. The issue of cultural

globalization which free trade inspires is beautifully addressed

in words of a famous Indian economist, Amartya Sen that, “Even

though contemporary attacks on attacks on intellectual

Haider 18

globalization tend to come not only from traditional

isolationists but also from modern separatists; we have to

recognize that our global civilization is a world heritage- not

just a collection of disparate local cultures” (Sen 85).

Haider 19

Works Cited

"Adam Smith." Investopedia. N.p., n.d. Web. 10 May 2014.

<http://www.investopedia.com/articles/economics/09/adam-

smith-wealth-of-nations.asp>.

"Border Point Queues: A Curse for Truck Drivers in Africa –

Video." Theguardian.com. Guardian News and Media, 19 Oct.

2012. Web. 12 May 2014. <http://www.theguardian.com/global-

development/video/2012/oct/19/border-queues-truck-drivers-

africa-video>.

Boudreaux, Donald J. "Want World Peace? Support Free Trade." The

Christian Science Monitor. The Christian Science Monitor,

n.d. Web. 11 May 2014.

<http://www.csmonitor.com/2006/1120/p09s02-coop.html/%28page

%29/2>.

Haider 20

Central Intelligence Agency. Central Intelligence Agency, n.d.

Web. 10 May 2014.

<https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-

factbook/>.

"China." Overview. N.p., n.d. Web. 10 May 2014.

<http://www.worldbank.org/en/country/china/overview>.

"Comparative Advantage." : The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics.

N.p., n.d. Web. 11 May 2014.

<http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/ComparativeAdvantage.htm

l>.

"Detroit: The New Motor City." Detroit: The New Motor City.

Stanford University, n.d. Web. 11 May 2014.

<http://www.stanford.edu/class/e297c/poverty_prejudice/cityp

overty/hdetroit.htm>.

"The Entrepreneurial State." The Economist. The Economist

Newspaper, 31 Aug. 2013. Web. 11 May 2014.

<http://www.economist.com/news/business/21584307-new-book-

points-out-big-role-governments-play-creating-innovative-

businesses>.

Haider 21

"Free Trade and Globalization: More than "Just Stuff"" Donald J.

Boudreaux,. N.p., n.d. Web. 11 May 2014.

<http://www.econlib.org/library/Columns/y2010/Boudreauxgloba

lization.html>.

"Free Trade Definition Investopedia." Investopedia. Investopedia,

n.d. Web. 10 May 2014.

<http://www.investopedia.com/terms/f/free-trade.asp>.

"The McDonaldization of Society." About.com Sociology. N.p., n.d.

Web. 11 May 2014.

<http://sociology.about.com/od/Works/a/McDonaldization-of-

Society.htm>.

"News." Migrants from Developing Countries to Send Home $414

Billion in Earnings in 2013. N.p., n.d. Web. 12 May 2014.

<http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2013/10/02/Migrant

s-from-developing-countries-to-send-home-414-billion-in-

earnings-in-2013>.

"Patches of Light." The Economist. The Economist Newspaper, 09

June 2001. Web. 11 May 2014.

<http://www.economist.com/node/646484>.

Haider 22

Schifferes, Steve. "The Decline of Detroit." BBC News. BBC, 19

Feb. 2007. Web. 11 May 2014.

<http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/6346299.stm>.

Sen, Amartya. The Argumentative Indian: Writings on Indian

History, Culture, and Identity. New York: Farrar, Straus and

Giroux, 2005. 85. Print.

Shian, Zhong. "U.S.-China Trade Is Win-Win Game." U.S.-China

Trade Is Win-Win Game. N.p., n.d. Web. 11 May 2014.

<http://www.china-embassy.org/eng/xw/t675646.htm>.

Steger, Manfred. Globalization: A Very Short Introduction by

Manfred Steger. N.p.: Oxford, n.d. N. pag. Print.

Travis, Alan. "British 'brain Drain' of Professionals Raises

Concerns over Skills Shortages." The Guardian. Guardian News

and Media, 07 Nov. 2012. Web. 10 May 2014.

<http://www.theguardian.com/global-development/2012/nov/06/b

ritish-brain-drain-skills-shortages>.

Wright, Tom. "Yunus Says Borrowers Are Core of Grameen Bank." The

Wall Street Journal. Dow Jones & Company, n.d. Web. 11 May

Haider 23

2014.

<http://online.wsj.com/news/articles/SB100014240527487044381

04576219731267941622>.