24
A DISNEYLAND DILEMMA: TWO-PART TARIFFS FOR A MICKEY MOUSE MONOPOLY

Three sections Section 1 Discriminatory two-part tariff Section 2 Uniform two-part tariff Section 3 Applications of two-part tariff Volume

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

A DISNEYLAND DILEMMA:

TWO-PART TARIFFS FOR A MICKEY MOUSE

MONOPOLY

Page 2: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Overview

Three sections Section 1

Discriminatory two-part tariff Section 2

Uniform two-part tariff Section 3

Applications of two-part tariff Volume Surcharge for IBM Marginal price discounts (like those used in public

utilities)

Page 3: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

So, what is a two-part tariff

A two-part tariff is one in which the consumer must pay a lump sum fee for the right to buy a product

Examples: Disneyland: entrance fee + price per ride Bar: cover charge + price per drink Rate structures of utility companies

Against: Standard pricing for the monopolist: single

price where MC=MR

Page 4: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

A discriminating two-part tariff

AKA first degree price discrimination To globally maximize profits by extracting ALL

consumer surpluses Assumptions for Disneyland model (apparently

Mickey is a greedy monopolist based on this article) Consumers are to derive no utility from going to the park

itself Utility derived from consuming a flow of rides X per unit

time period

Problems: difficult and ILLEGAL

Page 5: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Mathematically…

Consumer’s budget equation

XP+Y=M-T [if X>O] Y=M [if X=O]

M=incomeY= good; price set equal to 1

Page 6: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Utility = U=U(X,Y)

If the consumer does not want to pay the tariff, T, they will have the following utility:

U(X, Y,) = U(O, M,)

**without entering the park, the consumer cannot consume the good, X

** Tax, T, allows Disneyland to extract the consumer’s income in order to turn it into Mickey Mouse’s profits (Mickey loves money)

Page 7: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Now, if the consumer has a demand for rides, they will have the following demand function:

X=D(P, M-T) P is price per ride M is income T is admission

This can be interpreted as follows: and increase in the lump sum tax will decrease consumption of the rides, x with respect to a consumer’s given level of income.

Page 8: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Not a fan of math…

Total profits are given by:п=XP+T-C(X) where C(X) is the

total cost functionAnd differentiating with respect to T we get:

Interpretation: Assume that Y is a normal good.

An increase in T will increase profits Forces consumer to move to lower indifference curve because

they cannot consume more rides due to a decrease in their budget

However, the monopolist extracts more of the consumer’s budget by employing this pricing strategy

Page 9: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

There is a point T* where the consumer will not purchase this entrance fee and use their income to purchase other goods

Therefore T* is the consumer’s surplus enjoyed by the consumer

Page 10: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

To show the following:

The larger the T* Disney can charge while keeping their consumers, the lower the price per ride will be This results in a larger consumer surplus

The equation above represents the area under the constant utility demand curve

And this step allows for us to reduce the following profit function to one variable: price per ride

Page 11: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Here, we differentiate profits with respect to price

Description of what has happened: Changes in the optimal tax, T* due to a

change in P from this equation dT*/dP allows for P to satisfy the necessary condition

Result: P=MC

Page 12: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

After all that math

There is a different lump sum tax, or entrance fee in the case of Disneyland, charged per consumer

Price per ride, which is equal to marginal cost is the same across all consumers

Conclusion: Customers who have larger surpluses for rides

will be charged higher entrance fees or purchase privilege taxes

Ie: admission fees transfer the consumer’s income thus putting them on a lower indifference curve

Page 13: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Section II: Uniform Two-Part Tariff

Will look at the process of developing a uniform two-part tariff

Monopolist will want to maximize profit subject to the constraint of the number of consumers N Wants to keep as many consumers in the

market as possible KEY: Tax T will need to be adjusted whenever

the price varies

Page 14: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Total profits =

X – market demand for ridesT=T* -smallest of the N consumer surpluses C(X) – cost function And differentiating with respect to price and

setting equal to zero

Page 15: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

IF:P will exceed c’ if (1- Ns1) >0

(1- Ns1) < 0 means that the price is less than MC

And, if the monopolist chooses to raise the price, the smallest consumer would not purchase this product

With a smaller amount of consumers, a new tariff needs to be found. Due to this, the tax will then increase and there will thus be a lower price charged per ride

Page 16: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

How to derive the new uniform tax

Have consumers n Profits from the lump sum tax: ΠA = nT Profits from the sale of ride: ΠS = (P – c)X

An increase in T means that there will be less consumers buying the product ΠA thus changestherefore profits depends on T

Page 17: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

If the market contracts, meaning there are less consumers because the monopolist increases T.

This gives the monopolist the ability to control the number of consumers in the park Increasing T reduces the number of

consumers This then decreases the price per ride Why do they do this??

To capture the larger surpluses Result: a decrease in profits from sales

Page 18: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

And the final answer is?

The optimum and uniform two-part tariff that globally maximizes profits is reached:

Profits is thus a sum of profits from the tariff and the profit from price per ride

Page 19: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Finally…Section IIIApplications

IBM as an example of volume surcharge or marginal price discounts

Here’s the story for IBM’s case Someone who is renting a machine pays a lump sum

monthly rental: T dollars The tax is for the right to buy/rent machine time The renter gets up to X* hours of machine time with no

additional cost to the lump sum tax If they want to consume more, they are charged an

additional fee of k per hour THUS Larger consumers have a volume surcharge

This captures part of the surplus lost from smaller consumers

Page 20: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

This is optimal when…

MC of machine time is 0 Where the surcharge rate becomes

effective, or the demand after X* is equal to the maximum demand by a smaller consumer

No resale of computer time Rate k is determined by a process that is

similar to a monopolist choosing a single price where MC = MR

Page 21: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Example: public utilities also employ this type of pricing structure (which is like marginal price discounts)

We thus denote the following for prices with respect to varying demand

P1 and demands up to X*P2 for a demand greater than X*

Result of this: Kinked demand curve

Page 22: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Math of kinked demand curve

XP1 + Y = M [ if 0<X<X*]X*P1 + (X-X*) P2 + Y = M [ if X > X*]

So, a marginal price discount can be like a two-part tariff for the larger consumers. We rewrite the second equation as follows:

XP2 + Y = M – T [T = X*(P1 - P2 ) ]

The tax is thus the right to buy X at P2

Page 23: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Results

The monopolist can then receive larger surpluses from the larger consumers from this type of pricing discount.

Monopolist has higher profits

Page 24: Three sections  Section 1  Discriminatory two-part tariff  Section 2  Uniform two-part tariff  Section 3  Applications of two-part tariff  Volume

Conclusion

Charging a two-part tariff instead of a single price by the monopolist

RAISES PRICES AND, it allows for less discrepancy

between marginal rates of substitution in consumption and production