33
A Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures in France Benedicte Millet-Reyes Department of Finance, Economics and Real Estate, Leon Hess Business School, Monmouth University, West Long Branch, NJ e-mail: [email protected] Ronald Zhao Department of Accounting, Leon Hess Business School, Monmouth University, West Long Branch, NJ e-mail: [email protected] Abstract French companies operate in a unique environment characterized by the strong involve- ment of block shareholders such as families and banks. Furthermore, the French legal system allows firms to choose between a one-tier or a two-tier board structure. This study investigates whether this choice can affect the firm’s operating and stock performance. Our regression results provide strong evidence that ownership and board structures are used together as corporate governance tools. In particular, the agency cost of debt is strongly affected by their interaction when institutional investors are also bank lenders. Our test results show that while family control has a negative impact on corporate governance, French institutional blockholders play a positive role as monitors of one-tier structures. In contrast, they are more likely to misuse the two-tier board system by promoting interlocked directorship, board opacity and their own interests as creditors. Our regression analysis reveals that foreign institutional investors do not have any impact on firm performance, regardless of board structure. Finally, we do not find any inverse relation- ship between board size and efficiency in France. 1. Introduction: The Impact of Board Structure, Institutional Investors and Creditors Corporate governance relies on a variety of institutional factors, such as ownership characteristics and board structure, aimed at aligning the interests of stakeholders. Most countries have adopted only one of the two following board structures: the first is the unitary board of directors used in common law countries, and the second, the two-tier board structure, is used in several code law countries. France is one of the few countries that allow firms to choose between a one-tier or two-tier board The authors want to express their gratitude to Professor Frederick Choi (the editor) and two anonymous reviewers for their constructive comments and helpful suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies. Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting 21:3 2010 r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd., 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.

A Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures in France

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

management

Citation preview

  • A Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-TierBoard Structures in France

    Benedicte Millet-ReyesDepartment of Finance, Economics and Real Estate, Leon Hess Business School, MonmouthUniversity, West Long Branch, NJe-mail: [email protected]

    Ronald ZhaoDepartment of Accounting, Leon Hess Business School, Monmouth University, West LongBranch, NJe-mail: [email protected]

    Abstract

    French companies operate in a unique environment characterized by the strong involve-ment of block shareholders such as families and banks. Furthermore, the French legalsystem allows rms to choose between a one-tier or a two-tier board structure. This studyinvestigates whether this choice can aect the rms operating and stock performance. Ourregression results provide strong evidence that ownership and board structures are usedtogether as corporate governance tools. In particular, the agency cost of debt is stronglyaected by their interaction when institutional investors are also bank lenders. Our testresults show that while family control has a negative impact on corporate governance,French institutional blockholders play a positive role as monitors of one-tier structures. Incontrast, they are more likely to misuse the two-tier board system by promotinginterlocked directorship, board opacity and their own interests as creditors. Our regressionanalysis reveals that foreign institutional investors do not have any impact on rmperformance, regardless of board structure. Finally, we do not nd any inverse relation-ship between board size and eciency in France.

    1. Introduction: The Impact of Board Structure, Institutional Investorsand Creditors

    Corporate governance relies on a variety of institutional factors, such as

    ownership characteristics and board structure, aimed at aligning the

    interests of stakeholders. Most countries have adopted only one of the

    two following board structures: the rst is the unitary board of directors

    used in common law countries, and the second, the two-tier board

    structure, is used in several code law countries. France is one of the few

    countries that allow rms to choose between a one-tier or two-tier board

    The authors want to express their gratitude to Professor Frederick Choi (the editor) and twoanonymous reviewers for their constructive comments and helpful suggestions. The usualdisclaimer applies.

    Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting 21:3 2010

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd., 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.

  • of directors. This study explores the links between board structure,

    ownership characteristics and rm performance in France. Large institu-

    tional investors can improve rm monitoring and mitigate conicts of

    interest with creditors. However, they can also exacerbate agency costs if

    they behave as insiders, and tend to expropriate wealth from small

    investors by concentrating on their xed claims. In this study, we pay

    particular attention to the role of institutional blockholders on the

    agency cost of debt under alternate board structures.

    The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the existing

    literature on corporate governance mechanisms with an emphasis on

    board characteristics, ownership concentration, institutional investors

    and the role of debt. Section 3 concentrates on the specicities of

    corporate ownership and governance in France. We develop our hy-

    potheses and the regression models used for this study in Section 4. The

    data description and our test results are given in Section 5. Concluding

    remarks are provided in Section 6.

    2. Corporate Governance Mechanisms Around the World

    2.1. Agency Versus Stakeholder Theory

    In the United States, corporate governance issues stem mostly from con-

    icts of interests between managers and dispersed shareholders, which

    are usually studied within the framework of principalagent theory.

    However, agency theory has several deciencies, especially in accounting

    for country dierences in corporate governance. First, the theoretical

    assumptions of agency theory do not include the diverse identities of

    stakeholders within the principalagent relationship. Dierent types of

    investors (such as the state, banks, families, etc.) pursue dierent

    interests. Easterbrook (1991) suggests that there are substitute means

    of controlling the agency costs that arise from professional management

    and the separation of ownership from control. Block shareholdings and

    forcing managers to return often to capital markets are two ways to

    reduce these costs. The second limitation of agency theory is that it

    overlooks important interdependencies among corporate stakeholders

    because of its exclusive focus on the bilateral contracts between princi-

    pals and agents. For example, agency theorists treat employment rela-

    tions as exogenously determined by labor markets despite the employee

    voice within corporate boards of many European rms. In a broader

    sense, corporate governance relies on the structure of rights and

    280 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • responsibilities among all the parties with a stake in the rm. This view is

    reected in the principles of corporate governance by the Organization

    for Economic Cooperation and Development (1997), which describes

    corporate governance as a set of relationships between a companys

    board, its shareholders and other stakeholders. This principle forms the

    basis for stakeholder theory that examines corporate governance in terms

    of three major groups: capital, labor and management. It posits that

    successful managers must systematically attend to the interests of these

    stakeholders because, besides shareholders, corporations have duciary

    duties to other constituencies as well, such as creditors and employees

    (McDonnell, 2002).

    Corporate governance mechanisms can be seen as falling into two

    main categories, either internal or external. Internal governance tools

    include the board of directors, subcommittees of the board, compensa-

    tion programs designed to align the interests of managers and share-

    holders and other corporate control systems. External governance

    mechanisms include accounting rules and regulatory reporting require-

    ments, external auditors, the investment community, nancial analysts,

    national laws and the shareholders themselves. Agrawal and Knoeber

    (1996) give a dynamic overview of these mechanisms by examining seven

    approaches to control conicts of interest between corporate stake-

    holders: shareholdings of insiders, institutions, blockholders, outside

    directors, debt policy, the managerial labor market and the market for

    corporate control. The authors nd interdependence among these

    mechanisms, meaning that where one is used less, others may be used

    more, resulting in equally good corporate performance.

    In Europe, the deregulation and globalization of capital markets has

    created the need for corporate governance principles that provide stand-

    ards and accountability to domestic and international investors. The

    protection of minority shareholders against insiders, blockholders and

    creditors has been the main concern for European rms. Our paper

    concentrates on three governance mechanisms (board characteristics,

    institutional ownership and debt nancing) because of their specic

    relevance to the French corporate environment.

    2.2. Evidence on Board Characteristics and Corporate Performance

    Previous research on the eciency of board structure has focused on the

    activity of a unitary board of directors. Empirical studies mainly address

    three issues: the size of the board (Jensen, 1993; Yermack, 1996; Huther,

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 281

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • 1997; Eisenberg et al., 1998); its composition and independence

    (Baysinger and Butler, 1985; Hermalin and Weisbach, 1988; Rosenstein

    and Wyatt, 1997; Bhagat and Black, 1999); and its internal structure and

    functioning (Klein, 1998; Vafeas, 1999). Most of the studies claim to have

    found empirical ties between some features of a unitary board of

    directors and rm performance, but the empirical results are frequently

    contradictory (Andres et al., 2005). From a theoretical point of view,

    few papers have considered endogenous board structure criteria in

    order to achieve the optimal corporate governance system by which

    companies are directed and controlled (Warther, 1998; Hermalin and

    Weisbach, 2003). In particular, little empirical evidence is available on

    board categories (one-tier versus two-tier) because most countries allow

    only one type of board structure.

    The 2007 report on corporate governance in Europe published by

    Heidrick and Struggles provides a good overview of board types in

    Europe. In their classication, the rst board category is limited to two-

    tier structures. It includes the German two-tier system and the French

    legal board structure called conseil de surveillance, the supervisory

    board. Only 22 per cent of companies follow this board structure in

    Europe. The second category is the unitary board structure of the United

    Kingdom and Spain. The third category includes countries like Belgium,

    Italy, Portugal, Sweden and Switzerland, where a system of two boards

    allows some executive board directors to sit on the non-executive board.

    The improvement in corporate governance among the top 300 rms of

    this study is revealed by the fact that 98 per cent of them now have an

    audit committee, 95 per cent have a remuneration committee and 80 per

    cent a nomination committee. The average board size has decreased from

    13.5 in 1999 to 12.8 in 2007. The United Kingdom (unitary board only)

    has an average of 8.3 directors whereas Germany (two-tier board only)

    has an average of 19.1 directors. However, evidence on Germany reveals

    that supervisory boards are often seen as opaque, with an elite group of

    non-executive directors running most of the top companies (Financial

    Times, 9 May 2007).

    The most recent empirical studies on board characteristics usually

    report that large boards are more likely to suer from communication

    and agency problems, which aect corporate performance in a negative

    way. Cheng (2008) provides evidence that larger boards lead to lower

    performance variability because it is harder to reach consensus on drastic

    changes in corporate strategies. As a result, it is easier for the chief

    executive ocer (CEO) to control the decisions of a larger board.

    282 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • Another factor inuencing corporate boards is the existence of large

    blockholders. Dahya et al. (2008) document that countries with weak

    investor protection benet from strong boards because they can oset the

    power of large shareholders. A strong board includes more independent

    directors and leads to less diversion of corporate resources. Last, Devos

    et al. (2009) show that the presence of interlocked directors in U.S.

    boards is associated with poor rm performance and weak governance.

    2.3. Large Shareholders and Corporate Performance

    The impact of large shareholders on corporate performance varies across

    countries. La Porta et al. (1998) report that French-civil-law countries

    have the weakest legal protection of investors and that ownership

    concentration is negatively correlated to the degree of shareholder

    protection. By creating a core of strong insiders, ownership concentra-

    tion modies the interests of minority shareholders. On the one hand,

    blockholders can strengthen monitoring and reduce conict of interests.

    Historically, this has been the role of bank owners in countries like

    Germany, France or Japan. Empirical evidence shows that these institu-

    tional investors provide useful internal monitoring, improve access to

    debt and mitigate conict of interest between shareholders, creditors and

    managers. Shleifer and Vishny (1997) report a positive association

    between institutional ownership and rm value. Banks may own blocks

    of equity and exercise proxy votes for their clients. They are perceived as

    long-term, active and informed investors who oversee corporate invest-

    ments and organize internal capital markets. Also, rms with bank

    owners often benet from lending relationships and privileged access to

    capital markets. On the other hand, critics argue that banks enlarge

    agency problems when they have large shareholdings, control access to

    external capital markets and issue loans to the rm (Wenger and Kaserer,

    1998). Their role as providers of debt may then conict with the interests

    of minority shareholders.

    Ownership concentration may also be detrimental to minority share-

    holders because large blockholders, such as family owners, are liable to

    misuse their inside power. Expropriation by insiders can take the form of

    stealing prots, asset stripping, unqualied management and excessive

    consumption of perquisites. In their study of Finnish rms, Maury and

    Pajuste (2005) show that corporate value is increased when voting powers

    are distributed more equally, especially when family-controlled rms

    have a nancial institution as a second largest shareholder. La Porta

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 283

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • et al. (1999) provide evidence that reducing the expropriation of minority

    shareholders can lead to higher market values. They show that rms

    operating in countries with better investor protection (measured by their

    anti-director rights and legal system) have a higher Tobins Q. Thomsen

    et al. (2006) study the causality between large ownership and corporate

    performance. Using Granger tests, they nd that block ownership is

    associated with lower subsequent market and accounting value in civil-

    law countries. For bank-based economies, Koke (2004) provides evi-

    dence that concentrated ownership reduces the probability of control

    change. Last, Anderson et al. (2009) study the role of founders and heirs

    in U.S. corporate governance. They nd that entrenchment activities

    dominate over their role as monitor in-place.

    2.4. Institutional Investors and Creditors: The Role of Debt

    Recent empirical studies have shown that debt ratios can be a good

    measure of the role played by institutional investors and bankers on the

    board. Because large institutional shareholders are often banks who need

    to represent both equity owners and lenders, their eect on corporate

    performance has resulted in mixed interpretations. On the one hand, they

    can be active monitors who use inside information and their role on the

    board to improve rm performance and optimize the cost or level of debt

    nancing. On the other hand, the agency cost of debt may be higher if

    banks use their inside position to expropriate wealth from shareholders.

    Kroszner and Strahan (2001) show that U.S. bankers sit on corporate

    boards only when potential conicts between creditors and shareholders

    are low. Banks tend to be active monitors in large and stable rms with

    high tangible assets that can be used as collateral for debt claims. Byrd

    and Mizruchi (2005) examine the role of board-appointed bankers, and

    nd that the presence of lending bankers on a companys board has a

    negative impact on the rms debt ratio. This is because higher leverage

    may trigger stronger conict of interests between shareholders and

    creditors. Jiraporn and Kimberly (2007) show that U.S. rms adopt

    higher debt ratios when investor rights are restricted. Under such

    circumstances, leverage is used to limit agency conicts between owners

    and managers. However, their ndings also show that the negative

    correlation between debt and shareholder rights disappears in regulated

    industries, suggesting that regulation is an alternative mechanism for

    controlling agency costs.

    284 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • 3. Corporate Ownership and Governance in France

    3.1. Ownership Characteristics in France

    Although France shares some common history with its European

    neighbors, it has experienced a unique form of economic development.

    One of the main factors in dierentiating the French economy from

    others is its traditional dependence on families and French banks (Zhao

    and Millet-Reyes, 2007). The French emphasis on family-owned business

    may explain why French companies went public at a slower rate than

    their British and German counterparts. The states strong role in the

    economy, known as dirigisme, is another main factor aecting govern-

    ance in France. State intervention increased after the formation of the

    Fifth Republic until the 1990s, when the state initiated a new privatiza-

    tion plan, in response to pressure from the European Union and

    criticisms about the inecient functioning of public enterprises (Millet-

    Reyes, 2000). However, the states control over private companies still

    extends indirectly through the banking system. Many of the privatized

    nancial institutions still have government-appointed directors on their

    boards.

    Shareholdings in French companies are highly concentrated. The

    French system of concentrated ownership may be an outgrowth of the

    national tradition of family ownership with company founders retaining

    majority interests in companies, as well as the result of the large owner-

    ship interests by the state and/or banks in private companies. In addition,

    blockholding is also the result of the cross-shareholding structure.

    France has developed a complex system of cross shareholding (the

    verrouillage system), in which shares are parked with friendly com-

    panies, accounting for an estimated two thirds of the shares traded on the

    Bourse (Monks and Minow, 2004). The cross-shareholding structure

    consists of related companies, therefore, diminishing any one companys

    incentive to monitor the behavior of another company. Furthermore,

    companies are often connected by interlocking boards, where a director

    of one company sits on the board of another company, and vice versa.

    This system of interlocking boards encourages collusion among direc-

    tors, as a manager of one company may be reluctant to criticize another

    companys manager when the two sit on each others boards.

    The dening characteristic of the French corporate governance (le

    gouvernement dentreprise) system has long been the absence of a diverse

    investment community because the state, banks and families still hold

    controlling interests in most companies (see Faccio and Lang, 2002).

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 285

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • However, in the wake of corporate scandals in the 1990s, many French

    companies began to extricate themselves from cross-shareholding

    arrangements. Some did so in response to minority shareholder demands

    for greater shareholder value. Others initiated corporate restructuring to

    attract more foreign investors who prefer to provide funds to companies

    with transparent management process. In response to these new investor

    needs, France issued two codes of best practice, Vienot I (1995) and

    Vienot II (1999), which proposed signicant reforms to board structures

    and were aimed at promoting corporate transparency and accountability.

    3.2. Characteristics of One-Tier Versus Two-Tier Board Structures

    3.2.1. Legal dierences. One unique feature of the French corporategovernance system stems from the rms ability to choose its board

    structure. Before 1966, French companies could only be governed by a

    unitary board of directors, as is the case in most common law countries

    like the United States or the United Kingdom. The Commercial Code of

    1966 introduced the option to choose an alternate legal governance

    structure, the two-tier board, which closely resembles the German

    Vorstand/Aufsichtsrat structure. French companies are now allowed to

    choose between a unitary board structure, with a combined chairman

    and chief executive ocer (PDG), and a two-tier structure with a

    supervisory board (conseil de surveillance), management board (direc-

    toire) and separate chairpersons. The role of the supervisory board is to

    oversee the management board that runs day-to-day operations. Em-

    ployees must constitute up to one third of the rms supervisory board,

    depending on the size of the rm. This codetermination structure of two-

    tier boards implies that a sizable fraction of the non-executive directors

    cannot be appointed by shareholders. Thus the uncoupling of control

    rights and cash-ow rights makes codetermination potentially important

    to the extent that the supervisory board controls the important decision-

    making of the rm. Although most companies opt for the single-tier

    system, the two-tier board is currently adopted by a number of large

    French companies and favored by many corporate governance reformers.

    A unitary board is generally composed of at least three and no more

    than 24 directors, both executive and non-executive, who elect a single

    PDG to act as both chairperson and CEO. Executive directors ordinarily

    participate in the daily management of the company. The board typically

    meets every 2 months. At these meetings board members are primarily

    responsible for authorizing new capital and corporate reorganizations

    286 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • (Caussain and Richard, 1995). Although the law authorizes shareholders

    to appoint members of the unitary board, in practice, the PDG selects

    board members, subject to shareholder approval at the general meeting.

    This results in the prevalence of powerful PDGs and passive board

    members.

    In a two-tier board structure, the directorate consists of three to ve

    members, and each member is appointed to a term of 4 years by the

    supervisory board. The supervisory board also selects a presiding member

    from among the members of the directorate. No member of a directorate

    may sit on more than two corporate boards. The supervisory board

    consists of a minimum of three and a maximum of 24 members, who are

    appointed and dismissed at the shareholder meetings. No more than one

    third of supervisory board members may be employees of the company,

    who are elected to the board by their fellow employees. The supervisory

    board members select a chairperson from their ranks, who is responsible

    for presiding over both board and shareholder meetings. The supervisory

    board meets three to four times a year, and its responsibility is to monitor

    the directorate and report its ndings to shareholders. The members of the

    directorate must submit quarterly reports to the supervisory board.

    3.2.2. Pros and cons of two-tier boards. Aste (1999) summarized theinternal strengths of the two-tier board system as follows. First, there is

    clear delineation of the directors responsibilities between the supervisory

    and management board. Second, the small size of the directorate (three

    to ve members) allows for quick decision-making. Third, the two-tier

    structure helps non-traditional candidates to rise to the ranks of

    directors, creating more diversity in the boardroom. Fourth, the two-

    tier board generally generates good publicity and helps companies to

    attract foreign capital. Last, it can be used to satisfy the interests of

    merging companies by providing each of the former PDGs with leader-

    ship positions (one as the head of the directorate and the other as head of

    the supervisory board). Consequently, international parent companies

    often impose the two-tier board on their French subsidiaries. This is

    especially common among German parent companies, which prefer using

    the familiar Vorstand/Aufsichtsrat structure for their French subsidiaries

    (Berger, 1991).

    The advantages of the two-tier board structure have been acknowl-

    edged in reports by various European organizations, including the

    European Commission (1991) and the Organization for Economic

    Cooperation and Development (1997). However, the two-tier system is

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 287

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • not problem-free. First, interlocking directorship often takes place, with

    members of the directorate and supervisory board of one company

    sitting on those of other companies. The second problem is that

    companies frequently adopt a two-tier structure for political as opposed

    to economic reasons. For example, a director who has to resign from the

    directorate (management board) can be appointed to the supervisory

    board, therefore providing him with a graceful exit. As a result, the

    two-tier board has the potential to be misused as a tool for entrenching

    mangers as opposed to making them accountable to shareholders. Third,

    a company may also alternate between unitary and two-tier board

    structures. For example, when a new generation of directors rises to

    power, the older directors may lack condence in the new directors

    abilities and, therefore, would restructure the company so as to retain a

    formal supervisory role. This may hinder the rms ability to implement

    necessary operating and nancial changes (Aste, 1999).

    4. Hypotheses and Models

    4.1. The Impact of Board Structure on Performance

    A recent study by Larcker et al. (2007) reviews a broad sample of

    structural indicators of corporate governance tested in previous works.

    The authors use principal component analysis to investigate whether

    these indicators are useful in understanding managerial behavior and

    corporate performance. The criteria used fall into seven categories:

    characteristics of the board, stock ownership by executives and board

    members, stock ownership by institutions, stock ownership by active

    holders, debt and preferred stock holdings, compensation mix variables

    and anti-takeover devices. They nd that rms with a greater proportion

    of blockholders, a compensation mix that is weighted toward accounting

    performance, lead directors, smaller boards and fewer busy directors

    exhibit superior future operating performance. They conclude that the

    typical structural indicators of corporate governance in academic re-

    search and institutional rating services have only a modest ability to

    explain accounting manipulation, but exhibit some ability to explain

    future operating and stock performance.

    Our rst hypothesis builds on these ndings to examine the impact of

    board structure (one-tier versus two-tier) on the operating and stock

    performance of French rms. In France, the responsibilities of the two

    organs in a two-tier board structure are intended to be separate and

    288 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • clearly discernible. The directorate executes decisions and manages the

    company under the authority of the CEO. The supervisory board

    monitors decisions and exercises control over the company under the

    authority of the chairperson. We test whether structural dierences

    between one-tier and two-tier boards have a signicant impact on

    corporate performance. Stated in the null form (H0), the rst hypothesis

    is the following:

    H1: The two-tier, versus one-tier, board structure does not generate

    signicant dierences in operating and stock performance.

    We use the following model to test H1:

    Y Family Trading SizeGrowthDebtD1 SizeD1GrowthD1DebtD1 1

    where Y5OCF, ROA and Tobins Q, respectively, OCF5 (Net income

    1Depreciation expense)/Total assets, ROA5Net income/Total assets,

    Tobins Q5Market value of common equity/Book value of common

    equity, Family5 1 (0) if family owns at least (less than) 40 per cent of the

    rm, Trading5 1 (0) if the rm stock is listed for continuous trading

    (auction only), Size5Log of total assets, Growth5 per cent change in

    net income between period t and t 1, Debt5Debt/Total assets ratio,D15 1 (0) if two (one)-tier board structure, Size D1, Growth D1and Debt D1 are two-way interactions.

    Three dependent variables are used to proxy for rm performance:

    OCF (ROA) is a cash (accrual)-based measure of operating performance

    and Tobins Q is a market-based measure of stock performance. OCF

    provides information on shareholders cash-ow rights, whereas the

    dierence between OCF and ROA has implication for accounting

    manipulation. Tobins Q measures the market response to the rms

    equity and investment opportunities. The discrepancy between the

    proxies for operating and stock performance reects the gap between

    shareholders cash-ow and control rights. Two dummy variables,

    Family and Trading, are used to control for major features of the French

    economic system: dominant family ownership of businesses and segmen-

    ted capital markets. The variable Family measures majority ownership

    control at the 40 per cent level. Trading distinguishes between rms listed

    on the continuous trading versus auction markets, with rms listed on

    the former enjoying greater stock liquidity. Size, growth and debt

    ratio are explanatory variables used to measure rms operating,

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 289

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • investing and nancing proles. Following conventional wisdom, we

    expect good corporate governance indicators to be statistically asso-

    ciated with positive performance measures. We expect the board struc-

    ture dummy (D15 0 for one tier, D15 1 for two tier) to be signicant

    across all three performance measures, therefore indicating that board

    type has an impact on the operating and stock performance of French

    rms.

    4.2. Interaction of Ownership and Board Structure

    It is worth noting that four of the seven categories of governance

    indicators surveyed by Larcker et al. (2007) are related to ownership

    structure. This strongly suggests that corporate board choices cannot be

    evaluated independently from stakeholder characteristics. Such a case is

    especially true for France, where the monitoring functions of the board

    are often controlled by large blockholders (Zhao and Millet-Reyes,

    2007). Our second hypothesis tests whether the impact of board structure

    on rm performance varies across ownership structures.

    H2: Block shareholding does not modify the impact of board structure

    on the operating and stock performance of French rms.

    We hypothesize that the impact of a board structure on performance

    will reect whether blockholders monitoring functions dominate over

    their incentives to behave as insiders. In theory, the separation of

    responsibilities between the supervisory and management boards that

    characterizes two-tier board structures should contribute to the indepen-

    dence and eectiveness of board decisions. In the absence of bloc-

    kholders such as families or institutional investors, both tiers of the

    board should be able to execute their prescribed responsibilities in the

    interests of the majority. However, dominant shareholders may have

    incentives to divert corporate resources from other stakeholders by

    exploiting the complexity and opacity of a two-tier board system. Under

    such circumstances, a two-tier board would lose its structural advantages

    and facilitate wealth transferring activities.

    We pay particular attention to a rms debt ratio as a proxy for the

    conicts of interest between shareholders and creditors. Previous re-

    search on U.S. corporate capital structure has emphasized the role of

    agency conicts between managers and shareholders on the rm nan-

    cing decisions and cost of capital (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Stulz,

    1990). In a creditor-oriented market like France, blockholders provide

    290 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • both equity and debt capital to companies and may aect rm perfor-

    mance in dierent ways. If there is a coincidence of interests between

    majority shareholders/creditors and minority shareholders, the former

    will exert a benign inuence and reduce the cost of debt. However, if their

    interests are not aligned, blockholders will dominate at the expense of

    minority shareholders and may increase the cost of debt (Gordon and

    Schmid, 2000). Therefore, a boards ability to protect minority share-

    holders will be constrained by blockholders who inuence the rms

    capital structure and cost of debt.

    In H2, we test the roles of two types of blockholders in France:

    families and institutional investors. First, we remove the Family dummy

    from equation (1) and split the whole sample into two groups based on

    whether family ownership is greater or smaller than 40 per cent (majority

    control). Then, we add an institutional ownership dummy (D25 1 for

    French institutional ownership, and D25 0 for no French institutional

    ownership) to equation (1), and run the model on the two subsamples.

    Hypothesis 2 becomes

    Y Trading SizeGrowthDebtD1D2 SizeD1GrowthD1DebtD1 SizeD2GrowthD2DebtD2 SizeD1D2GrowthD1D2DebtD1D2

    2

    where Size D1 D2, Growth D1 D2 and Debt D1 D2 arethree-way interactions. All other variables are as dened in equation (1).

    The interactions terms of D1 with other variables would enable us to

    evaluate how the role of board structure is aected by the ownership

    structure under which it operates.

    4.3. Impact of Foreign Institutional Ownership and Board Size

    We develop H3 to test two new factors that may aect board eective-

    ness: foreign institutional ownership and board size. We investigate

    whether their roles dier between one-tier and two-tier boards based

    on the following rationale. First, foreign institutional investors, as

    opposed to their French counterparts, are often minority shareholders

    rather than insiders. They dier from French institutional investors,

    especially bank lenders, because they do not provide debt nancing to the

    rm. Therefore, their impact on rm performance may be limited

    regardless of board type. Second, studies of unitary board structures in

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 291

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • common law countries suggest an inverse relationship between board size

    and eciency. We examine whether this relationship holds in France

    where blockholders and two-tier boards exist.

    H3: Foreign institutional ownership and/or board size do not generate

    signicant dierences in operating and stock performance.

    We split the sample into two categories based on board type and

    consequently remove the dummy D1 from equation (1). Next, we add

    two new variables: a dummy for foreign institutional ownership (D35 1

    for foreign institutional ownership and D35 0 for no foreign institu-

    tional ownership) plus a continuous variable for Directors (number of

    board members). Hypothesis 3 becomes

    Y Family TradingDirectors SizeGrowthDebtD2D3DirectorsD2 SizeD2GrowthD2DebtD2DirectorsD3 SizeD3GrowthD3DebtD3

    3

    A comparison of the test results for the two groups will indicate if the

    role of foreign institutional ownership and board size diers between

    one-tier and two-tier boards.

    5. Sample Data and Test Results

    5.1. Sample Construction and Descriptive Statistics

    The sample consists of 665 rm-year observations covering 174 French

    companies from 28 industries over the period 20002004. Ownership and

    board structure information was obtained from the database Dafsaliens

    for 2004. Financial data were collected from Bloomberg. The sample is

    based on all non-nancial rms that were publicly traded on the second

    market for the period of 19982004. Table 1a reports descriptive statistics

    on the whole sample and also by board structure categories (one tier

    versus two tier). The sample includes 57 rms with a two-tier board (33

    per cent of the sample). In comparison, 18.3 per cent of the 1,033 publicly

    traded rms in France in 2004 had a two-tier structure. The larger

    proportion of rms with a two-tier board in our sample may be explained

    by the greater number of younger and medium-sized corporations with

    initial public oerings in the late 1980s and 1990s, a period when the two-

    tier board structure regained popularity.

    292 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • Table 1a reports the sample means and quantiles for all dependent and

    explanatory variables used in the regression analysis. Denitions of the

    variables are given below each table. The median number of directors is

    six (the mean is 6.19) for one-tier boards, and nine (the mean is 9.52) for

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 293

    Table 1a. Descriptive statistics for full sample

    Mean 25% (Q1) Median 75% (Q3)

    Number of directorsWhole sample 7.35 5 7 9One tier 6.19 4 6 8Two tier 9.52 7 9 12

    Family own. %Whole sample 47.69 16.4 57.1 72.1One tier 42.28 16.2 57.1 72.3Two tier 48.46 21.1 57.2 72.1

    French own. %Whole sample 5.95 0 0 6.9One tier 6.30 0 0 7.1Two tier 5.28 0 0 6.9

    Foreign own. %Whole sample 1.30 0 0 0One tier 1.41 0 0 0Two tier 1.11 0 0 0

    Total assetsWhole sample 298.9 40.6 92.3 248.0One tier 346.0 38.6 85.7 229.5Two tier 210.3 44.8 96.5 268.2

    Growth NIWhole sample 0.048 0.668 0.021 0.436One tier 0.191 0.709 0.030 0.475Two tier 0.220 0.613 0.011 0.347

    Debt/assetsWhole sample 0.648 0.512 0.644 0.763One tier 0.667 0.516 0.652 0.772Two tier 0.613 0.502 0.629 0.733

    OCFWhole sample 0.076 0.044 0.080 0.117One tier 0.077 0.041 0.078 0.120Two tier 0.073 0.048 0.082 0.113

    ROAWhole sample 0.024 0.002 0.031 0.064One tier 0.023 0.001 0.031 0.064Two tier 0.026 0.007 0.033 0.064

    Tobins QWhole sample 1.415 0.976 1.169 1.535One tier 1.433 0.993 1.183 1.574Two tier 1.380 0.929 1.118 1.495

    Notes: French own. % is the percentage of French institutional ownership.Foreign own. % is the percentage of foreign institutional ownership.Total assets is the log of assets measured in millions of euros.OCF5 (Net Income1Depreciation Expense)/Total Assets.

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • two-tier boards. Statistics provided by Heidrick and Struggles on the

    CAC40, the 40 largest rms traded in France, report an average of 14.3

    directors without distinguishing between one-tier and two-tier board types.

    t-test and non-parametric test were run on the two board cate-

    gories. Two variables were found to be statistically lower at the 5 per cent

    level for two-tier boards: debt ratio and Tobins Q. Ownership character-

    istics were found to be similar across board structures as reected by the

    quantiles for family, French and foreign institutional ownership. Half of our

    sampled rms have family ownership at the 57 per cent level or higher.

    Table 1b splits the sample based on family control at the 40 per cent

    level. Our descriptive statistics show that rms controlled by families are

    smaller and have less French and foreign institutional ownership. Both

    their operating cash ow and Tobins Q are also statistically lower than

    companies with a more dispersed ownership.

    Table 1c presents the mean and median values for four subcategories:

    rms with no French institutional ownership and one-tier board (D15 0,

    D25 0), no French institutional ownership and two-tier board (D15 1,

    D25 0), with French institutional ownership and one-tier board (D15 0,

    D25 1) and with French institutional ownership and two-tier board

    (D15 1, D25 1). Among rms without French institutional ownership

    (D25 0), two-tier structures are associated with larger companies and

    lower debt ratios. For companies with French institutional ownership

    (D25 1), none of the descriptive variables (except the number of

    directors) is statistically dierent at the 5 per cent level.

    5.2. Discussion of Regression Results

    5.2.1. Results of equation (1). Table 2 reports the regression results forthe whole sample (equation (1)) with a board structure dummy (D1).

    Three measurements of rm performance are used: OCF, ROA and

    Tobins Q. The OCF model tests the impact of board type on rm

    operating performance in terms of operating cash ow, whereas ROA is

    an accrual-based measure, with accounting earnings being equal to OCF

    plus accounting accrual. Tobins Q is a widely used measure of rm stock

    performance. Industry dummies have been added to the models in order

    to control for SIC codes, but they are not reported.

    The regression results show that two-tier boards have a signicantly

    positive xed impact on operating performance, but not on stock

    performance. The discrepancy between the measures for operating

    versus stock performance suggests potential agency conicts among

    294 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • stakeholders. The rst control variable, Family, is signicantly negative

    across all three performance measures, indicating that family dominance

    has a negative impact on both operating and stock performance. This is

    consistent with the ndings of Anderson et al. (2009), who report that

    founders and heirs exploit opacity to expropriate wealth from minority

    shareholders. The second control variable, Trading, has a signicantly

    positive impact on Tobins Q, indicating a positive correlation between

    equity liquidity and rm valuation. The negative correlation between size

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 295

    Table 1b. Descriptive statistics by family control

    No family control(217 observations)

    With family control(448 observations)

    Number of directorsMean (n) 8.4n 6.8n

    Median 8.0 6.0Family own. %Mean (n) 8.2n 66.8n

    Median 0.7 69.1French own. %Mean (n) 9.9n 4.0n

    Median 1.9 0.0Foreign own. %Mean(n) 2.7n 0.6n

    Median 0.0 0.0Total assetsMean (n) 605.7n 150.3n

    Median 133.0 70.8Growth NIMean 1.448 0.772Median 0.022 0.021

    Debt/assetsMean 0.667 0.639Median 0.637 0.647

    OCFMean (n) 0.089n 0.069n

    Median 0.082 0.079ROAMean 0.033 0.020Median 0.033 0.031

    Tobins QMean (n) 1.554n 1.347n

    Median 1.270 1.121

    Notes: French own. % is the percentage of French institutional ownership.Foreign own. % is the percentage of foreign institutional ownership.Total assets is the log of assets measured in millions of euros.OCF5 (Net Income1Depreciation Expense)/Total Assets.nindicates that t-tests are statistically signicant at the 5% level.

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • and Tobins Q suggests that large and mature rms face a reduced pool

    of new investment opportunities. This is oset by the signicantly

    positive interaction between rm size and two-tier structures, implying

    that two-tier board systems may have a positive eect on rm investment

    opportunities. Last, the test results show that the impact of debt on

    performance diers signicantly based on board structure. Debt has a

    signicantly positive role on both operating and stock performance for

    rms with a one-tier board, but a signicantly negative impact on

    operating performance for rms with two-tier boards. This suggests

    296 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    Table 1c. Descriptive statistics by ownership and board categories

    Category1D15 0 D25 0

    (229observations)

    Category 2D15 1 D25 0

    (113observations)

    Category 3D15 0 D25 1

    (205observations)

    Category 4D15 1 D25 1

    (118observations)

    Number of directorsMean 5.9n 8.9n 6.5n 10.1n

    Median 6.0 8.0 6.0 10.0Family own. %Mean 52.8 56.4 41.1 40.9Median 63.0 71.1 44.6 50.0

    French own. %Mean 0.0 0.0 13.4 10.3Median 0.0 0.0 8.8 6.6

    Foreign own. %Mean 1.0 1.2 1.9n 1.0n

    Median 0.0 0.0 1.0 0.0Total assetsMean 136.2n 195.3n 580.4 224.7Median 72.1 94.0 97.7 103.8

    Growth NIMean 1.58 0.08 1.36 0.35Median 0.02 0.00 0.05 0.01

    Debt/assetsMean 0.66n 0.60n 0.68 0.63Median 0.67 0.60 0.64 0.65

    CF operationMean 0.070 0.072 0.085 0.074Median 0.078 0.082 0.078 0.082

    ROAMean 0.019 0.026 0.028 0.027Median 0.031 0.036 0.030 0.029

    Tobins QMean 1.43 1.51 1.44 1.26Median 1.20 1.17 1.17 1.09

    Notes: D15 0 if one-tier board (5 1 for two-tier).D25 0 if no French institutional ownership (5 1 with French institutional ownership).nindicates that t-test signicance at the 5% level for categories 1 versus 2, and category 3 versus 4.

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 297

    Table2.Wholesampleregression:one-tier

    versustwo-tierboards

    Variable

    OCF

    ROA

    TobinsQ

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    D1

    0.097nn

    2.10

    0.04

    0.090nn

    2.09

    0.04

    0.320

    0.88

    0.38

    Family

    0.019n

    1.92

    0.06

    0.016n

    1.76

    0.08

    0.221nnn

    2.92

    0.00

    Trading

    0.005

    0.41

    0.68

    0.008

    0.75

    0.46

    0.278nnn

    3.21

    0.00

    Size

    0.000

    0.07

    0.95

    0.005

    1.29

    0.20

    0.079nn

    2.26

    0.02

    Growth

    0.001nnn

    5.87

    0.00

    0.001nnn

    4.07

    0.00

    0.001

    0.69

    0.49

    Debt

    0.173nnn

    13.14

    0.00

    0.115nnn

    9.32

    0.00

    0.620nnn

    5.99

    0.00

    SizeD1

    0.015n

    2.09

    0.04

    0.013n

    1.90

    0.06

    0.145nnn

    2.53

    0.01

    GrowthD1

    0.000

    1.00

    0.32

    0.000

    0.27

    0.79

    0.002

    0.20

    0.84

    DebtD1

    0.263nnn

    5.78

    0.00

    0.232nnn

    5.44

    0.00

    0.554

    1.54

    0.12

    F-value

    15.81

    10.13

    5.55

    p4F

    0.001

    0.001

    0.001

    R2

    0.251

    0.171

    0.093

    Notes:D151(0)iftwo(one)-tierboard

    type.

    n,nn,nnnSignicantatthe0.10,0.05and0.01levels,respectively.

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • that conicts of interest between shareholders and creditors are magni-

    ed in two-tier structures.

    Taken as a whole, the test results of equation (1) reject the hypothesis

    that there is no signicant dierence in the performance of rms with one-

    tier versus two-tier boards. However, the results for the key variable, board

    structure (D1), are not consistent across the three models (OCF, ROA and

    Tobins Q), implying that its eect may be inuenced by omitted variables.

    Because of the historical role of French institutional owners as large debt

    providers in France, we include it as a new variable in the test of H2.

    5.2.2. Results of equation (2). The test results of H1 provide evidencethat it is dicult to assess the role of board structure without controlling

    for other governance tools such as ownership structure. In France,

    institutional blockholders are often entrenched shareholders as well as

    providers of debt capital. Consequently, they can control the operations

    of the rm and aect the independence and eectiveness of its board. The

    second hypothesis tests the relationship between ownership and board

    structure by investigating the eect of family control and French

    institutional ownership on rm performance. At this point, we exclude

    foreign institutional ownership, which will be examined in H3. In order

    to avoid using too many xed and multiplicative dummies, we split the

    sample into two parts based on family control and compare the

    coecients between the two categories.

    The considerable increase in the adjusted R2 for equation (2) over

    equation (1) indicates that the inclusion of French institutional owner-

    ship substantially enhances the explanatory power of the model. Table 3a

    shows the results for rms with family control. D1 alone (board dummy)

    is negative for all three dependent variables suggesting that one-tier

    boards work better than two-tier boards in family dominated rms. This

    may be because families can use the organizational complexity of a two-

    tier board to hide their self-serving activities. Next, Table 3a conrms

    that board structure has an impact on the agency cost of debt. However,

    because of full family control in this subsample (over 40 per cent of

    ownership), the statistical signicance of the coecients disappears in

    some of the models.

    Table 3b presents the results for rms without family control. The R2

    of all three models is signicantly improved for this group, suggesting a

    higher degree of transparency when the rm is not under family control.

    The positive Debt D2 is consistent with the existing literature on themonitoring role of institutional blockholders in a one-tier environment.

    298 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 299

    Table3a.Regressionresultsforrm

    swithfamilycontrol

    Variable

    OCF

    ROA

    TobinsQ

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    D1

    0.153nnn

    6.49

    0.00

    0.061

    1.12

    0.26

    0.952n

    1.82

    0.07

    D2

    0.023

    0.52

    0.60

    0.012

    0.27

    0.79

    0.103

    0.25

    0.81

    D1D2

    0.100

    1.18

    0.24

    0.009

    0.11

    0.91

    0.329

    0.41

    0.68

    Trading

    0.007

    0.84

    0.40

    0.005

    0.54

    0.59

    0.324nnn

    3.94

    0.00

    Size

    0.00

    0.01

    0.99

    0.006

    1.33

    0.18

    0.070

    1.51

    0.13

    SizeD1

    0.020nn

    2.25

    0.03

    0.008

    0.94

    0.35

    0.121

    1.44

    0.15

    SizeD2

    0.008

    1.08

    0.28

    0.005

    0.61

    0.54

    0.021

    0.30

    0.77

    SizeD1D2

    0.017

    1.22

    0.22

    0.000

    0.00

    0.99

    0.078

    0.60

    0.55

    Growth

    0.001nnn

    6.97

    0.00

    0.001nnn

    4.29

    0.00

    0.000

    0.27

    0.79

    GrowthD1

    0.001

    0.91

    0.36

    0.000

    0.44

    0.66

    0.004

    0.39

    0.70

    GrowthD2

    0.002nnn

    3.46

    0.00

    0.002nnn

    2.72

    0.01

    0.001

    0.08

    0.94

    GrowthD1D2

    0.003n

    1.88

    0.06

    0.002

    1.19

    0.23

    0.011

    0.62

    0.53

    Debt

    0.184nnn

    6.53

    0.00

    0.175nnn

    6.22

    0.00

    0.440n

    1.66

    0.10

    DebtD1

    0.097n

    1.91

    0.06

    0.035

    0.69

    0.49

    0.816n

    1.70

    0.09

    DebtD2

    0.040

    0.84

    0.40

    0.072

    1.55

    0.12

    0.225

    0.50

    0.62

    DebtD1D2

    0.028

    0.33

    0.74

    0.024

    0.29

    0.77

    1.178

    1.49

    0.14

    F-value

    11.29

    10.91

    3.27

    p4F

    0.001

    0.001

    0.001

    R2

    0.358

    0.361

    0.139

    Notes:D151(0)iftwo(one)-tierboard

    structure.

    D251(0)with(without)French

    institutionalownership.

    n,nn,nnnSignicantatthe0.10,0.05and0.01levels,respectively.

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • 300 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    Table3b.Regressionresultsforrm

    swithoutfamilycontrol

    Variable

    OCF

    ROA

    TobinsQ

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    D1

    0.133

    0.68

    0.50

    0.239

    1.30

    0.19

    3.691nn

    2.21

    0.03

    D2

    0.125

    1.16

    0.25

    0.220nn

    2.16

    0.03

    0.332

    0.36

    0.72

    D1D2

    0.315

    1.33

    0.18

    0.399n

    1.80

    0.07

    3.019

    1.49

    0.14

    Trading

    0.014

    0.49

    0.62

    0.006

    0.24

    0.81

    0.334

    1.38

    0.17

    Size

    0.021

    1.19

    0.24

    0.014

    0.83

    0.41

    0.096

    0.65

    0.52

    SizeD1

    0.007

    0.25

    0.80

    0.014

    0.58

    0.56

    0.310

    1.37

    0.17

    SizeD2

    0.029

    1.51

    0.13

    0.012

    0.67

    0.50

    0.038

    0.23

    0.82

    SizeD1D2

    0.003

    0.08

    0.94

    0.010

    0.35

    0.73

    0.156

    0.58

    0.56

    Growth

    0.002

    0.63

    0.53

    0.001

    0.59

    0.56

    0.028

    1.25

    0.21

    GrowthD1

    0.001

    0.21

    0.83

    0.000

    0.04

    0.97

    0.001

    0.02

    0.99

    GrowthD2

    0.001

    0.34

    0.73

    0.001

    0.35

    0.73

    0.024

    1.05

    0.30

    GrowthD1D2

    0.001

    0.16

    0.87

    0.002

    0.31

    0.75

    0.003

    0.07

    0.94

    Debt

    0.169n

    1.78

    0.08

    0.252nnn

    2.81

    0.01

    0.188

    0.23

    0.82

    DebtD1

    0.146

    0.60

    0.55

    0.269

    1.17

    0.25

    3.919n

    1.86

    0.06

    DebtD2

    0.416nnn

    4.31

    0.00

    0.436nnn

    4.79

    0.00

    1.010

    1.22

    0.22

    DebtD1D2

    0.476n

    1.71

    0.09

    0.537nn

    2.04

    0.04

    4.715nn

    1.97

    0.05

    F-value

    10.71

    6.88

    2.62

    p4F

    0.001

    0.001

    0.001

    R2

    0.536

    0.426

    0.220

    Notes:D151(0)iftwo(one)-tierboard

    structure.

    D251(0)with(without)French

    institutionalownership.

    n,nn,nnnSignicantatthe0.10,0.05and0.01levels,respectively.

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • The signicantly positive sign for Debt D1 suggests that two-tierboards without institutional blockholders would also result in a lower

    agency cost of debt. The positive eects of Debt D1 and Debt D2are consistent with the ndings of Agrawal and Knoeber (1996) that

    substitute means of improving corporate governance can be used inside

    the rm. However, the potential for institutional blockholders to

    expropriate wealth from minority shareholders is clearly shown in the

    results linked to the debt variable Debt D1 D2. The statisticallynegative coecient of the three-way interaction in all three models

    implies that, when French institutional blockholders (mostly banks)

    participate in a two-tier board without family control, they are likely

    to put their interests as creditors above those of shareholders. These

    results demonstrate the multi-dimensionality of stakeholders interests in

    French rms. While a two-tier board structure may alleviate one kind of

    agency cost (e.g., improved labor relationship), it may lead to the

    exacerbation of other kinds of conict (e.g., creditors versus equity

    holders, blockholders versus outside shareholders). Overall, our test

    results strongly reject H2 by providing empirical evidence on the

    interdependence of ownership and board structures.

    5.2.3. Results of equation (3). In order to test H3, the whole sample issplit into two groups based on board structure categories (one tier versus

    two tier). Table 4a (4b) reports the results for rms with a one (two)-tier

    board. Two new variables are added to the model; a dummy variable for

    foreign institutional ownership (D3) and a continuous variable for number

    of board members (Director). A comparison of the two panels identies

    the following signicant between-group similarities and dierences.

    First, we see that French institutional ownership (D2) plays a negative

    (signicantly positive) role under one (two)-tier board structure. However,

    foreign institutional ownership (D3) does not have any statistical signi-

    cance in either table, reecting the fact that foreign investors usually have

    minor stakes in the rm.

    Second, the number of directors (board size) is not signicant in both

    panels, indicating that there is no inverse correlation between board size

    and rm performance both within and between the two groups. This result

    provides empirical evidence that size is not a determinant of board

    eciency in France. The positive interaction of DirectorD2 suggeststhat directors appointed by French institutional blockholders are likely to

    play a more independent and eective role in protecting minority share-

    holders interests. The lack of signicance of DirectorD3 implies that

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 301

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • 302 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    Table4a.Regressionresultsforone-tier

    board:withforeigninstitutionalownershipandnumber

    ofdirectors

    Variable

    OCF

    ROA

    TobinsQ

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    D2

    0.170nnn

    3.16

    0.00

    0.166nnn

    3.28

    0.00

    0.510

    1.26

    0.21

    D3

    0.022

    0.23

    0.81

    0.009

    0.11

    0.92

    0.801

    1.15

    0.25

    Family

    0.000

    0.01

    0.99

    0.006

    0.46

    0.64

    0.206nn

    2.06

    0.04

    Trading

    0.008

    0.58

    0.56

    0.004

    0.29

    0.78

    0.310nnn

    2.81

    0.01

    Director

    0.001

    0.22

    0.82

    0.001

    0.37

    0.72

    0.021

    0.68

    0.50

    DirectorD2

    0.007

    1.20

    0.23

    0.011nn

    1.93

    0.05

    0.084nn

    1.93

    0.05

    DirectorD3

    0.009

    0.09

    0.28

    0.004

    0.56

    0.58

    0.001

    0.02

    0.99

    Size

    0.007

    0.90

    0.37

    0.013n

    1.79

    0.07

    0.044

    0.74

    0.46

    SizeD2

    0.028nnn

    2.70

    0.01

    0.028nnn

    2.82

    0.01

    0.189nn

    2.40

    0.02

    SizeD3

    0.026

    1.45

    0.15

    0.020

    1.19

    0.23

    0.118

    0.88

    0.38

    Growth

    0.001nnn

    4.43

    0.00

    0.001nnn

    2.79

    0.01

    0.000

    0.13

    0.90

    GrowthD2

    0.002nn

    2.29

    0.02

    0.001n

    1.76

    0.08

    0.001

    0.11

    0.91

    GrowthD3

    0.002

    0.93

    0.35

    0.001

    0.77

    0.44

    0.002

    0.14

    0.89

    Debt

    1.172nnn

    4.15

    0.00

    0.186nnn

    4.76

    0.00

    0.468

    1.50

    0.13

    DebtD2

    0.392nnn

    9.02

    0.00

    0.343nnn

    8.37

    0.00

    1.216nnn

    3.71

    0.00

    DebtD3

    0.108

    1.10

    0.27

    0.103

    1.11

    0.27

    1.105

    1.49

    0.14

    F-value

    13.83

    9.20

    4.85

    p4F

    0.001

    0.001

    0.001

    R2

    0.395

    0.294

    0.164

    Notes:D251(0)with(without)French

    institutionalownership.

    D351(0)withforeigninstitutionalownership.

    n,nn,nnnSignicantatthe0.10,0.05and0.01levels,respectively.

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • foreign institutional investors do not have a voice in the appointment of

    directors.

    Third, the test results demonstrate again the impact of board structure

    on the agency cost of debt. In Table 4a, the coecient on Debt is

    signicantly negative, but its interaction with French institutional owner-

    ship is signicantly positive for rms with one-tier boards, which is

    consistent with the results of Table 3b. These results conrm the positive

    monitoring role and reduced agency cost of debt associated with French

    institutional investors who participate in one-tier boards. However, under

    a two-tier board structure (Table 4b), the interaction of debt with French

    institutional ownership is signicantly negative, verifying again that

    French banks increase the agency cost of debt by behaving as creditors

    at the expense of equity holders. Two-tier board structures allow dominant

    institutional blockholders with substantial voting control to appoint their

    agents to the supervisory board of related companies. This allows them to

    exert pressure on both the supervisory and management boards in order to

    serve the interests of rms in which they own both stock and debt

    (Cremers and Nair, 2005). In such instances, two-tier boards may lose

    their integrity as has happened in some of the Vorstand/Aufsichtsrats in

    Germany. In both Tables 4a and b, the interaction of foreign institutional

    ownership with debt is not statistically signicant, conrming the role of

    foreign institutional investors as minority shareholders.

    In conclusion, the test results cannot reject H3. No additional structural

    indicators of corporate governance, such as foreign institutional owner-

    ship and/or board size, can alter the test results of the previous two

    hypotheses. Test results for all three hypotheses are consistent in showing

    that a two-tier board structure can impact the agency cost of debt and the

    interests of minority shareholders. However, its role is restricted by the

    ownership structure under which it operates. In particular, two-tier boards

    seem to function better when they are not combined with strong control

    rights from families or French institutional investors.

    5.3. Summary of Regression Results

    Table 5 combines the test results for H2 and H3 to facilitate a quick

    comparison of coecients across our sample splits (family control

    and board structure). More specically, Table 5 shows the signicant

    impact of debt on rm performance and its interaction with board and

    ownership structure. One dominant feature of French rms is the inside

    nature of their governance system, which relies on the monitoring of

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 303

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • 304 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    Table4b.Regressionresultsfortwo-tierboard:withforeigninstitutionalownershipandnumber

    ofdirectors

    Variable

    OCF

    ROA

    TobinsQ

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    Coe

    cient

    t-statistics

    p-value

    D2

    0.168nnn

    3.27

    0.00

    0.107nn

    2.09

    0.04

    1.450nn

    2.17

    0.03

    D3

    0.070

    0.47

    0.64

    0.093

    0.62

    0.53

    0.875

    0.45

    0.65

    Family

    0.008

    0.70

    0.48

    0.016

    1.53

    0.13

    0.012

    0.08

    0.93

    Trading

    0.006

    0.46

    0.65

    0.020

    1.58

    0.12

    0.230

    1.39

    0.17

    Director

    0.002

    0.82

    0.41

    0.000

    0.04

    0.97

    0.035

    0.94

    0.35

    DirectorD2

    0.002

    0.61

    0.55

    0.005

    1.30

    0.20

    0.027

    0.52

    0.61

    DirectorD3

    0.004

    0.74

    0.46

    0.000

    0.01

    0.99

    0.112

    1.49

    0.14

    Size

    0.030nnn

    3.65

    0.00

    0.023nnn

    2.79

    0.01

    0.070

    0.65

    0.52

    SizeD2

    0.015

    1.55

    0.12

    0.003

    0.34

    0.74

    0.017

    0.14

    0.89

    SizeD3

    0.034

    1.30

    0.20

    0.022

    0.84

    0.40

    0.329

    0.96

    0.34

    Growth

    0.000

    0.04

    0.97

    0.001

    1.00

    0.32

    0.009

    0.81

    0.42

    GrowthD2

    0.001

    0.47

    0.64

    0.000

    0.16

    0.87

    0.012

    0.82

    0.41

    GrowthD3

    0.001

    0.48

    0.64

    0.001

    0.43

    0.67

    0.003

    0.13

    0.90

    Debt

    0.047

    1.36

    0.18

    0.087nnn

    2.51

    0.01

    1.317nnn

    2.92

    0.00

    DebtD2

    0.099nn

    1.94

    0.05

    0.090n

    1.77

    0.08

    2.082nnn

    3.13

    0.00

    DebtD3

    0.115

    0.79

    0.43

    0.029

    0.20

    0.84

    1.143

    0.60

    0.55

    F-value

    5.72

    6.17

    2.30

    p4F

    0.001

    0.001

    0.002

    R2

    0.301

    0.321

    0.106

    Notes:D251(0)with(without)French

    institutionalownership.

    D351(0)withforeigninstitutionalownership.

    n,nn,nnnSignicantatthe0.10,0.05and0.01levels,respectively.

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 305

    Table5.Summary

    table

    Model2:withversusnofamilycontrol

    OCF

    ROA

    TobinsQ

    With

    No

    With

    No

    With

    No

    D1

    0.153nnn

    0.133

    0.061

    0.239

    0.952n

    3.691nn

    D2

    0.023

    0.125

    0.012

    0.220nn

    0.103

    0.332

    D1D2

    0.100

    0.315

    0.009

    0.399n

    0.329

    3.019

    Trading

    0.007

    0.014

    0.005

    0.006

    0.324nnn

    0.334

    Size

    0.00

    0.021

    0.006

    0.014

    0.070

    0.096

    SizeD1

    0.020nn

    0.007

    0.008

    0.014

    0.121

    0.310

    SizeD2

    0.008

    0.029

    0.005

    0.012

    0.021

    0.038

    SizeD1D2

    0.017

    0.003

    0.000

    0.010

    0.078

    0.156

    Growth

    0.001nnn

    0.002

    0.001nnn

    0.001

    0.000

    0.028

    GrowthD1

    0.001

    0.001

    0.000

    0.000

    0.004

    0.001

    GrowthD2

    0.002nnn

    0.001

    0.002nnn

    0.001

    0.001

    0.024

    GrowthD1D2

    0.003n

    0.001

    0.002

    0.002

    0.011

    0.003

    Debt

    0.184nnn

    0.169n

    0.175nnn

    0.252nnn

    0.440n

    0.188

    DebtD1

    0.097n

    0.146

    0.035

    0.269

    0.816n

    3.919n

    DebtD2

    0.040

    0.416nnn

    0.072

    0.436nnn

    0.225

    1.010

    DebtD1D2

    0.028

    0.476n

    0.024

    0.537nn

    1.178

    4.715nn

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • 306 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    Model3:one-tier

    versustwo-tier

    Onetier

    Twotier

    Onetier

    Twotier

    Onetier

    Twotier

    D2

    0.170nnn

    0.168nnn

    0.166nnn

    0.107nn

    0.510

    1.450nn

    D3

    0.022

    0.070

    0.009

    0.093

    0.801

    0.875

    Family

    0.000

    0.008

    0.006

    0.016

    0.206nn

    0.012

    Trading

    0.008

    0.006

    0.004

    0.020

    0.310nnn

    0.230

    Director

    0.001

    0.002

    0.001

    0.000

    0.021

    0.035

    DirectorD2

    0.007

    0.002

    0.011nn

    0.005

    0.084nn

    0.027

    DirectorD3

    0.009

    0.004

    0.004

    0.000

    0.001

    0.112

    Size

    0.007

    0.030nnn

    0.013n

    0.023nnn

    0.044

    0.070

    SizeD2

    0.028nnn

    0.015

    0.028nnn

    0.003

    0.189nn

    0.017

    SizeD3

    0.026

    0.034

    0.020

    0.022

    0.118

    0.329

    Growth

    0.001nnn

    0.000

    0.001nnn

    0.001

    0.000

    0.009

    GrowthD2

    0.002nn

    0.001

    0.001n

    0.000

    0.001

    0.012

    GrowthD3

    0.002

    0.001

    0.001

    0.001

    0.002

    0.003

    Debt

    1.172nnn

    0.047

    0.186nnn

    0.087nnn

    0.468

    1.317nnn

    DebtD2

    0.392nnn

    0.099nn

    0.343nnn

    0.090n

    1.216nnn

    2.082nnn

    DebtD3

    0.108

    0.115

    0.103

    0.029

    1.105

    1.143

    Notes:D151(0)iftwo(one)-tierboard

    type.D251(0)with(without)French

    institutionalownership.

    D351(0)with(without)foreigninstitutionalownership.

    n,nn,nnnSignicantatthe0.10,0.05and0.01levels,respectively.

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • corporate performance by all interested stakeholders. In countries where

    external control is exercised through the stock market, the threat of

    takeover may act as a disciplinary device for management. In France,

    stakeholders usually take actions to correct management decisions

    through internal channels, leading to a more marked cohesion between

    owners and managers. The choice of a two-tier board should be a signal

    that all stakeholders can exercise their inuence through participation in

    the supervisory board. However, our results clearly show that bloc-

    kholders, especially institutional investors, are in a position to exploit a

    two-tier board system to serve their own interests. In France, banks provide

    long-term nancing to the rm and are often some of its dominant

    shareholders. Their role is enhanced by the practice of proxy voting at

    shareholder meetings on behalf of investors who have deposited their

    shares with banks. The benets of a governance system which relies heavily

    on long-term relationships and on credit as a source of nance seem to be

    that rms have a high probability of surviving and enhanced possibilities of

    growing without having to seek new equity. Our results show that while a

    two-tier board structure can serve as a corporate governance mechanism

    for insiders to monitor and control management performance, it can also

    suer from too much rigidity in protecting the interests of banks as major

    providers of internal nance (Kim, 1995; Jungmann, 2006).

    6. Concluding Comments

    This study provides empirical evidence that signicant dynamics exist

    between ownership and board structures in French corporate govern-

    ance. The operating and stock performance of French rms is aected by

    agency conicts among various stakeholders, such as insiders versus

    minority shareholders, equity owners versus debt holders and family

    versus institutional blockholders. In this context, the option to choose a

    two-tier board structure may be taken as a signal to improve corporate

    governance. But the test results indicate otherwise because blockholders

    are in a position to manipulate two-tier boards. In particular, French

    institutional investors, mostly banks, are likely to misuse their dual role

    as providers of both equity and debt capital when the board structure is

    more complex and less transparent.

    As one of the rst empirical studies on the strengths and weaknesses of

    alternative board structures, this paper makes three contributions to the

    literature. First, it broadens the analysis of board eciency from the

    perspective of agency theory to that of stakeholder theory. A comparison

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 307

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • of test results across three performance measures (OCF, ROA and

    Tobins Q) identies areas in which agency conicts are more likely to

    exist. Second, it rejects the common hypothesis that blockholding,

    especially domestic institutional shareholding, always improves corpo-

    rate monitoring. Our test results show that while family dominance

    usually has a negative impact on corporate governance, French institu-

    tional blockholding also plays a negative role when combined with a less

    transparent two-tier structure. Furthermore, we show that foreign

    institutional investors have no eect on rm performance. Third,

    previous ndings on the inverse relationship between board size and

    eciency based on common law countries do not appear to be applicable

    to code law countries. In France, concentrated ownership dominates

    over other structural indicators of corporate governance. Board size is

    not inversely correlated with board eciency for rms with either one-

    tier or two-tier boards.

    This empirical study suggests potential ground for new research on

    rm survival and board structure in code law countries. Control changes

    are the result of poor corporate performance and management, weak

    governance and inadequate ownership stakes. In this context, it will be

    interesting to analyze the role played by the choice of board structure in

    the context of a limited market for corporate control.

    References

    Agrawal, A. and C. Knoeber, Firm Performance and Mechanisms to Control AgencyProblems between Managers and Shareholders, Journal of Financial and QuantitativeAnalysis 31 (1996), pp. 377397.

    Anderson, R., A. Duru and D. Reeb, Founders, Heirs, and Corporate Opacity in theUnited States, Journal of Financial Economics 92 (2009), pp. 205222.

    Andres, P.D., V. Azofra and F. Lopez, Corporate Boards in OECD Countries: Size,Composition, Functioning and Eectiveness, Corporate Governance 13 (2005),pp. 197210.

    Aste, L.J., Reforming French Corporate Governance: A Return to the Two-TierBoard?, The George Washington Journal of International Law and Economics 32(1999), pp. 172.

    Baysinger, R.D. and H.N. Butler, Corporate Governance and the Board of Directors:Performance Eects of Changes in Board Composition, Journal of Law, Economicsand Organization 1 (1985), pp. 101124.

    Berger, D.J., Guidelines for Mergers and Acquisitions in France, The NorthwesternJournal of International Law and Business 11 (1991), pp. 474505.

    Bhagat, S. and B. Black, The Uncertain Relationship between Board Composition andFirm Performance, Business Lawyer 54 (1999), pp. 921963.

    Byrd, D. and M. Mizruchi, Bankers on the Board and the Debt Ratio of Firms, Journalof Corporate Finance 11 (2005), pp. 129173.

    308 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • Caussain, J. and B. Richard, Les Conditions Juridique dune Approche Francaise,LExpansion Management Revue (June 1995), pp. 5273.

    Cheng, S., Board Size and the Variability of Corporate Performance, Journal ofFinancial Economics 87 (2008), pp. 157176.

    Cremers, K.J.M. and V.B. Nair, Governance Mechanisms and Equity Prices, TheJournal of Finance 60 (2005), pp. 28592894.

    Dahya, J., O. Dimitrov and J. McConnell, Dominant Shareholders, Corporate Boardsand Corporate Value: A Cross-Country Analysis, Journal of Financial Economics 87(2008), pp. 73100.

    Devos, E., A. Prevost and J. Puthenpurackal, Are interlocked Directors EectiveMonitors?, Financial Management 38 (2009), pp. 861887.

    Easterbrook, F.H., High-Yield Debt as an Incentive Device, International Review ofLaw and Economics 11 (1991), pp. 183202.

    Eisenberg, T., S. Sundgren and M.T. Wells, Large Board Size and Decreasing FirmValue in Small Firms, Journal of Financial Economics 48 (1998), pp. 3554.

    Faccio, M. and L. Lang, The Ultimate Ownership of Western European Corporations,Journal of Financial Economics 65 (2002), pp. 365395.

    Gordon, G. and F.A. Schmid, Universal Banking and the Performance of GermanFirms, Journal of Financial Economics 58 (2000), pp. 2980.

    Hermalin, B.E. and M.S. Weisbach, The Determinants of Board Composition, RANDJournal of Economics 19 (1988), pp. 589606.

    Hermalin, B.E. and M.S. Weisbach, Boards of Directors as an Endogenously Deter-mined Institution: A Survey of the Economic Literature, Economic Policy Review 9(2003), pp. 726.

    Huther, J., An Empirical Test of the Eect of Board Size on Firm Eciency, EconomicsLetter 54 (1997), pp. 259264.

    Jensen, M., The Modern Industrial Revolution, Exit, and the Failure of Internal ControlSystem, Journal of Finance 48 (1993), pp. 831889.

    Jensen, M. and W. Meckling, Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costsand Ownership Structure, Journal of Financial Economics 3 (1976), pp. 305360.

    Jiraporn, P. and G. Kimberly, Capital Structure, Shareholder Rights, and CorporateGovernance, The Journal of Financial Research 30 (2007), pp. 2133.

    Jungmann, C., The Eectiveness of Corporate Governance in One-Tier and Two-TierBoard systems, European Company and Financial Law Review 3 (2006), pp. 426474.

    Kim, H., Markets, Financial Institutions, and Corporate Governance: Perspectives fromGermany, Law and Policy in International Business 26 (1995), pp. 371406.

    Klein, A., Firm Performance and Board Committee Structure, Journal of Law andEconomics 41 (1998), pp. 275303.

    Koke, J., The Market for Corporate Control in a Bank-Based Economy: A GovernanceDevice?, Journal of Corporate Finance 10 (2004), pp. 5380.

    Kroszner, R. and P. Strahan, Bankers on the Board: Monitoring, Conicts of Interest,and Lender Liability, Journal of Financial Economics 62 (2001), pp. 415452.

    La Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes and A. Shleifer, Corporate Ownership Around theWorld, Journal of Finance 54 (1999), pp. 471517.

    La Porta, R., F. Lopez-De-Silanes, A. Shleifer and R. Vishny, Law and Finance,Journal of Political Economy 106 (1998), pp. 11131155.

    Larcker, D., S. Richardson and I. Tuna, Corporate Governance, Accounting Out-comes, and Organizational Performance, The Accounting Review 82 (2007),pp. 9631008.

    Maury, B. and A. Pajuste, Multiple Large Shareholders and Firm Value, Journal ofBanking and Finance 29 (2005), pp. 18131834.

    Comparison Between One-Tier and Two-Tier Board Structures 309

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • McDonnell, B.E., (2002), Public Law and Legal Theory Research, Research Paper 02-13, University of Minnesota Law School.

    Millet-Reyes, B., The Deregulation of Capital Markets in France, Journal of Multi-national Financial Management 10 (2000), pp. 109132.

    Monks, R.A.G. and N. Minow, Corporate Governance, 3rd ed (Oxford, UK: Blackwell,2004).

    Rosenstein, S. and J.G. Wyatt, Inside Directors, Board Eectiveness, and ShareholderWealth, Journal of Financial Economics 44 (1997), pp. 229250.

    Shleifer, A. and R. Vishny, A Survey of Corporate Governance, Journal of Finance 52(1997), pp. 737783.

    Stulz, R., Managerial Discretion and OPTIMAL Financing Policies, Journal ofFinancial Economics 26 (1990), pp. 327.

    The European Commission (1991), Council Regulation (EC) No. 2157/2001 of 8 October2001 on the status for a European Company (SE).

    The Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (1997), EconomicSurveys: France.

    Thomsen, S., T. Petersen and H.K. Kvist, Blockholder Ownership: Eects on FirmValue in Market and Control Based Governance Systems, Journal of CorporateFinance 12 (2006), pp. 246269.

    Vafeas, N., Board Meeting Frequency and Firm Performance, Journal of FinancialEconomics 53 (1999), pp. 113142.

    Warther, V.A., Board Eectiveness and Board dissent: A Model of the BoardsRelationship to Management and Shareholders, Journal of Corporate Finance 4(1998), pp. 5370.

    Wenger, E. and C. Kaserer, The German System of Corporate Governance, in S.W.Black and M. Moersch (eds.), Competition and Convergence in Financial Markets(Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1998), pp. 4178.

    Yermack, D., Higher Market Valuation of Companies with a Small Board of Directors,Journal of Financial Economics 40 (1996), pp. 185211.

    Zhao, R. and B. Millet-Reyes, Ownership Structure and Accounting Information:Evidence from France, Journal of International Financial Management and Accounting18 (2007), pp. 223246.

    310 Benedicte Millet-Reyes and Ronald Zhao

    r 2010 Blackwell Publishing Ltd.

  • Copyright of Journal of International Financial Management & Accounting is the property of Wiley-Blackwelland its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyrightholder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.