88
"A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics" G.L. Clementi and H.A. Hopenhayn (QJE, 2006) Cesar E. Tamayo Econ612- Economics - Rutgers April 30, 2012 1/21

A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamicseconweb.rutgers.edu/ctamayo/Research/Presentation-Clementi... · "A Theory of Financing Constraints and Firm Dynamics" G.L. Clementi

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

"A Theory of Financing Constraints and FirmDynamics"

G.L. Clementi and H.A. Hopenhayn (QJE, 2006)

Cesar E. TamayoEcon612- Economics - Rutgers

April 30, 2012

1/21

Program

I SummaryI Physical environmentI The contract design problemI Characterization of the optimal contractI Firm growth and survivalI Contract maturity and debt limits

2/21

What they do in a nutshell

I The paper develops a theory of endogenous �nancing constraints.

I Repeated moral hazard problemI The optimal contract (under asymmetric info) determines non-trivialstochastic processes for �rm size, equity and debt.

I This in turn implies non-trivial �rm dynamics even under simple i.i.d.shocks.

3/21

What they do in a nutshell

I The paper develops a theory of endogenous �nancing constraints.I Repeated moral hazard problem

I The optimal contract (under asymmetric info) determines non-trivialstochastic processes for �rm size, equity and debt.

I This in turn implies non-trivial �rm dynamics even under simple i.i.d.shocks.

3/21

What they do in a nutshell

I The paper develops a theory of endogenous �nancing constraints.I Repeated moral hazard problemI The optimal contract (under asymmetric info) determines non-trivialstochastic processes for �rm size, equity and debt.

I This in turn implies non-trivial �rm dynamics even under simple i.i.d.shocks.

3/21

What they do in a nutshell

I The paper develops a theory of endogenous �nancing constraints.I Repeated moral hazard problemI The optimal contract (under asymmetric info) determines non-trivialstochastic processes for �rm size, equity and debt.

I This in turn implies non-trivial �rm dynamics even under simple i.i.d.shocks.

3/21

Physical environment:

I At t = 0 entrepreneur (E) has a project that requires initialinvestment I0 > M where M in his net worth.

I Borrower (E) and lender (L) are risk neutral, discount future at δ.

I Both agents can fully commit to a long term contract.I At each t � 1, E can re-scale the project by investing additional kt .I Returns are stochastic and equal to R (kt ) if state of nature is H(with prob. p) and zero if state is L (prob. 1� p)

I At the begining of each t, project can be liquidated (αt = 1)yielding S � 0 and resulting in payo¤s Q to E and S �Q to L

I If project is not liquidated, E repays τ to L.

4/21

Physical environment:

I At t = 0 entrepreneur (E) has a project that requires initialinvestment I0 > M where M in his net worth.

I Borrower (E) and lender (L) are risk neutral, discount future at δ.

I Both agents can fully commit to a long term contract.I At each t � 1, E can re-scale the project by investing additional kt .I Returns are stochastic and equal to R (kt ) if state of nature is H(with prob. p) and zero if state is L (prob. 1� p)

I At the begining of each t, project can be liquidated (αt = 1)yielding S � 0 and resulting in payo¤s Q to E and S �Q to L

I If project is not liquidated, E repays τ to L.

4/21

Physical environment:

I At t = 0 entrepreneur (E) has a project that requires initialinvestment I0 > M where M in his net worth.

I Borrower (E) and lender (L) are risk neutral, discount future at δ.

I Both agents can fully commit to a long term contract.

I At each t � 1, E can re-scale the project by investing additional kt .I Returns are stochastic and equal to R (kt ) if state of nature is H(with prob. p) and zero if state is L (prob. 1� p)

I At the begining of each t, project can be liquidated (αt = 1)yielding S � 0 and resulting in payo¤s Q to E and S �Q to L

I If project is not liquidated, E repays τ to L.

4/21

Physical environment:

I At t = 0 entrepreneur (E) has a project that requires initialinvestment I0 > M where M in his net worth.

I Borrower (E) and lender (L) are risk neutral, discount future at δ.

I Both agents can fully commit to a long term contract.I At each t � 1, E can re-scale the project by investing additional kt .

I Returns are stochastic and equal to R (kt ) if state of nature is H(with prob. p) and zero if state is L (prob. 1� p)

I At the begining of each t, project can be liquidated (αt = 1)yielding S � 0 and resulting in payo¤s Q to E and S �Q to L

I If project is not liquidated, E repays τ to L.

4/21

Physical environment:

I At t = 0 entrepreneur (E) has a project that requires initialinvestment I0 > M where M in his net worth.

I Borrower (E) and lender (L) are risk neutral, discount future at δ.

I Both agents can fully commit to a long term contract.I At each t � 1, E can re-scale the project by investing additional kt .I Returns are stochastic and equal to R (kt ) if state of nature is H(with prob. p) and zero if state is L (prob. 1� p)

I At the begining of each t, project can be liquidated (αt = 1)yielding S � 0 and resulting in payo¤s Q to E and S �Q to L

I If project is not liquidated, E repays τ to L.

4/21

Physical environment:

I At t = 0 entrepreneur (E) has a project that requires initialinvestment I0 > M where M in his net worth.

I Borrower (E) and lender (L) are risk neutral, discount future at δ.

I Both agents can fully commit to a long term contract.I At each t � 1, E can re-scale the project by investing additional kt .I Returns are stochastic and equal to R (kt ) if state of nature is H(with prob. p) and zero if state is L (prob. 1� p)

I At the begining of each t, project can be liquidated (αt = 1)yielding S � 0 and resulting in payo¤s Q to E and S �Q to L

I If project is not liquidated, E repays τ to L.

4/21

Physical environment:

I At t = 0 entrepreneur (E) has a project that requires initialinvestment I0 > M where M in his net worth.

I Borrower (E) and lender (L) are risk neutral, discount future at δ.

I Both agents can fully commit to a long term contract.I At each t � 1, E can re-scale the project by investing additional kt .I Returns are stochastic and equal to R (kt ) if state of nature is H(with prob. p) and zero if state is L (prob. 1� p)

I At the begining of each t, project can be liquidated (αt = 1)yielding S � 0 and resulting in payo¤s Q to E and S �Q to L

I If project is not liquidated, E repays τ to L.

4/21

Physical environment:I Assumption: R (�) is continuous, increasing and strictly concave.

I Assumption: R (�) is private information; the state of nature at t isθt 2 Θ � fH, Lg but E reports θt .

I Assumption: E consumes all proceeds R (kt )� τ (i.e. no storage)

5/21

Physical environment:I Assumption: R (�) is continuous, increasing and strictly concave.I Assumption: R (�) is private information; the state of nature at t is

θt 2 Θ � fH, Lg but E reports θt .

I Assumption: E consumes all proceeds R (kt )� τ (i.e. no storage)

5/21

Physical environment:I Assumption: R (�) is continuous, increasing and strictly concave.I Assumption: R (�) is private information; the state of nature at t is

θt 2 Θ � fH, Lg but E reports θt .I Assumption: E consumes all proceeds R (kt )� τ (i.e. no storage)

5/21

Physical environment:

De�nition (reporting strategy)A reporting strategy for E is θ =

�θt�θt�∞t=1 where θt = (θ1, θ2, ..., θt )

De�nition (contract)A contract is a vector σ =

�αt�ht�1

�,Qt

�ht�1

�, kt

�ht�1

�, τt (ht )

where ht =

�θ1, ..., θt

De�nition (feasible contract)A contract σ is feasible if αt 2 [0, 1] , Qt � 0, τt

�ht�1, L

�� 0,

τt�ht�1,H

�� R (kt ) .

De�nition (equity and debt)Expected discounted cash �ows for E is called equity, Vt (σ, θ,ht�1) andfor L is called debt, Bt (σ, θ,ht�1)

De�nition (incentive compatibility)A contract σ is incentive compatible if 8 θ, V1

�σ, θ,h0

�� V1(σ, θ,h0)

6/21

Physical environment:

De�nition (reporting strategy)A reporting strategy for E is θ =

�θt�θt�∞t=1 where θt = (θ1, θ2, ..., θt )

De�nition (contract)A contract is a vector σ =

�αt�ht�1

�,Qt

�ht�1

�, kt

�ht�1

�, τt (ht )

where ht =

�θ1, ..., θt

De�nition (feasible contract)A contract σ is feasible if αt 2 [0, 1] , Qt � 0, τt

�ht�1, L

�� 0,

τt�ht�1,H

�� R (kt ) .

De�nition (equity and debt)Expected discounted cash �ows for E is called equity, Vt (σ, θ,ht�1) andfor L is called debt, Bt (σ, θ,ht�1)

De�nition (incentive compatibility)A contract σ is incentive compatible if 8 θ, V1

�σ, θ,h0

�� V1(σ, θ,h0)

6/21

Physical environment:

De�nition (reporting strategy)A reporting strategy for E is θ =

�θt�θt�∞t=1 where θt = (θ1, θ2, ..., θt )

De�nition (contract)A contract is a vector σ =

�αt�ht�1

�,Qt

�ht�1

�, kt

�ht�1

�, τt (ht )

where ht =

�θ1, ..., θt

De�nition (feasible contract)A contract σ is feasible if αt 2 [0, 1] , Qt � 0, τt

�ht�1, L

�� 0,

τt�ht�1,H

�� R (kt ) .

De�nition (equity and debt)Expected discounted cash �ows for E is called equity, Vt (σ, θ,ht�1) andfor L is called debt, Bt (σ, θ,ht�1)

De�nition (incentive compatibility)A contract σ is incentive compatible if 8 θ, V1

�σ, θ,h0

�� V1(σ, θ,h0)

6/21

Physical environment:

De�nition (reporting strategy)A reporting strategy for E is θ =

�θt�θt�∞t=1 where θt = (θ1, θ2, ..., θt )

De�nition (contract)A contract is a vector σ =

�αt�ht�1

�,Qt

�ht�1

�, kt

�ht�1

�, τt (ht )

where ht =

�θ1, ..., θt

De�nition (feasible contract)A contract σ is feasible if αt 2 [0, 1] , Qt � 0, τt

�ht�1, L

�� 0,

τt�ht�1,H

�� R (kt ) .

De�nition (equity and debt)Expected discounted cash �ows for E is called equity, Vt (σ, θ,ht�1) andfor L is called debt, Bt (σ, θ,ht�1)

De�nition (incentive compatibility)A contract σ is incentive compatible if 8 θ, V1

�σ, θ,h0

�� V1(σ, θ,h0)

6/21

Physical environment:

De�nition (reporting strategy)A reporting strategy for E is θ =

�θt�θt�∞t=1 where θt = (θ1, θ2, ..., θt )

De�nition (contract)A contract is a vector σ =

�αt�ht�1

�,Qt

�ht�1

�, kt

�ht�1

�, τt (ht )

where ht =

�θ1, ..., θt

De�nition (feasible contract)A contract σ is feasible if αt 2 [0, 1] , Qt � 0, τt

�ht�1, L

�� 0,

τt�ht�1,H

�� R (kt ) .

De�nition (equity and debt)Expected discounted cash �ows for E is called equity, Vt (σ, θ,ht�1) andfor L is called debt, Bt (σ, θ,ht�1)

De�nition (incentive compatibility)A contract σ is incentive compatible if 8 θ, V1

�σ, θ,h0

�� V1(σ, θ,h0)

6/21

The �rst-best (symmetric info)

I Since both are risk neutral and share δ, the optimal contractmaximizes total exp. discounted pro�ts of the match (E ,L).

I In equilibrium L provides E with the unconst. e¤cient k in every t:

maxk[pR (k)� k ] (1)

I So that R (�) strictly concave) 9 unique k� � 0 that solves (1).I Assume k� > 0 so that per-period total surplus is:

π� = maxk[pR (k)� k ] = pR (k�)� k�

I And PDV of total surplus is W � = π�1�δ > S by assumption.

I Project is undertaken if W � > I0 and once project is started, �rmdoes not grow, shrink or exit.

7/21

The �rst-best (symmetric info)

I Since both are risk neutral and share δ, the optimal contractmaximizes total exp. discounted pro�ts of the match (E ,L).

I In equilibrium L provides E with the unconst. e¤cient k in every t:

maxk[pR (k)� k ] (1)

I So that R (�) strictly concave) 9 unique k� � 0 that solves (1).I Assume k� > 0 so that per-period total surplus is:

π� = maxk[pR (k)� k ] = pR (k�)� k�

I And PDV of total surplus is W � = π�1�δ > S by assumption.

I Project is undertaken if W � > I0 and once project is started, �rmdoes not grow, shrink or exit.

7/21

The �rst-best (symmetric info)

I Since both are risk neutral and share δ, the optimal contractmaximizes total exp. discounted pro�ts of the match (E ,L).

I In equilibrium L provides E with the unconst. e¤cient k in every t:

maxk[pR (k)� k ] (1)

I So that R (�) strictly concave) 9 unique k� � 0 that solves (1).

I Assume k� > 0 so that per-period total surplus is:

π� = maxk[pR (k)� k ] = pR (k�)� k�

I And PDV of total surplus is W � = π�1�δ > S by assumption.

I Project is undertaken if W � > I0 and once project is started, �rmdoes not grow, shrink or exit.

7/21

The �rst-best (symmetric info)

I Since both are risk neutral and share δ, the optimal contractmaximizes total exp. discounted pro�ts of the match (E ,L).

I In equilibrium L provides E with the unconst. e¤cient k in every t:

maxk[pR (k)� k ] (1)

I So that R (�) strictly concave) 9 unique k� � 0 that solves (1).I Assume k� > 0 so that per-period total surplus is:

π� = maxk[pR (k)� k ] = pR (k�)� k�

I And PDV of total surplus is W � = π�1�δ > S by assumption.

I Project is undertaken if W � > I0 and once project is started, �rmdoes not grow, shrink or exit.

7/21

The �rst-best (symmetric info)

I Since both are risk neutral and share δ, the optimal contractmaximizes total exp. discounted pro�ts of the match (E ,L).

I In equilibrium L provides E with the unconst. e¤cient k in every t:

maxk[pR (k)� k ] (1)

I So that R (�) strictly concave) 9 unique k� � 0 that solves (1).I Assume k� > 0 so that per-period total surplus is:

π� = maxk[pR (k)� k ] = pR (k�)� k�

I And PDV of total surplus is W � = π�1�δ > S by assumption.

I Project is undertaken if W � > I0 and once project is started, �rmdoes not grow, shrink or exit.

7/21

The �rst-best (symmetric info)

I Since both are risk neutral and share δ, the optimal contractmaximizes total exp. discounted pro�ts of the match (E ,L).

I In equilibrium L provides E with the unconst. e¤cient k in every t:

maxk[pR (k)� k ] (1)

I So that R (�) strictly concave) 9 unique k� � 0 that solves (1).I Assume k� > 0 so that per-period total surplus is:

π� = maxk[pR (k)� k ] = pR (k�)� k�

I And PDV of total surplus is W � = π�1�δ > S by assumption.

I Project is undertaken if W � > I0 and once project is started, �rmdoes not grow, shrink or exit.

7/21

Private information: the Pareto frontier

I L designs a contract that gives her B (V ) and gives E a value V .

I The Pareto frontier of the problem is given by Gr (B(V )) and each(V ,B(V )) implies a value for the match W (V ) = V + B (V ) .

I Begin by �nding the equilibrium of the subgame that starts after Ldecides not to liquidate the project.

I Upon continuation, the evolution of equity is given by:

V = p (R (k)� τ) + δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i(2)

I While the evolution of debt (not in the paper):

B (V ) = pτ � k + δhpB�VH

�+ (1� p)B

�V L�i

I The value of equity e¤ectively summarizes all the informationprovided by the history itself (Spear and Srivastava, 1987; Green,1987) so it�s the appropriate state variable in a recursive formulationof the repeated contracting problem.

8/21

Private information: the Pareto frontier

I L designs a contract that gives her B (V ) and gives E a value V .I The Pareto frontier of the problem is given by Gr (B(V )) and each(V ,B(V )) implies a value for the match W (V ) = V + B (V ) .

I Begin by �nding the equilibrium of the subgame that starts after Ldecides not to liquidate the project.

I Upon continuation, the evolution of equity is given by:

V = p (R (k)� τ) + δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i(2)

I While the evolution of debt (not in the paper):

B (V ) = pτ � k + δhpB�VH

�+ (1� p)B

�V L�i

I The value of equity e¤ectively summarizes all the informationprovided by the history itself (Spear and Srivastava, 1987; Green,1987) so it�s the appropriate state variable in a recursive formulationof the repeated contracting problem.

8/21

Private information: the Pareto frontier

I L designs a contract that gives her B (V ) and gives E a value V .I The Pareto frontier of the problem is given by Gr (B(V )) and each(V ,B(V )) implies a value for the match W (V ) = V + B (V ) .

I Begin by �nding the equilibrium of the subgame that starts after Ldecides not to liquidate the project.

I Upon continuation, the evolution of equity is given by:

V = p (R (k)� τ) + δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i(2)

I While the evolution of debt (not in the paper):

B (V ) = pτ � k + δhpB�VH

�+ (1� p)B

�V L�i

I The value of equity e¤ectively summarizes all the informationprovided by the history itself (Spear and Srivastava, 1987; Green,1987) so it�s the appropriate state variable in a recursive formulationof the repeated contracting problem.

8/21

Private information: the Pareto frontier

I L designs a contract that gives her B (V ) and gives E a value V .I The Pareto frontier of the problem is given by Gr (B(V )) and each(V ,B(V )) implies a value for the match W (V ) = V + B (V ) .

I Begin by �nding the equilibrium of the subgame that starts after Ldecides not to liquidate the project.

I Upon continuation, the evolution of equity is given by:

V = p (R (k)� τ) + δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i(2)

I While the evolution of debt (not in the paper):

B (V ) = pτ � k + δhpB�VH

�+ (1� p)B

�V L�i

I The value of equity e¤ectively summarizes all the informationprovided by the history itself (Spear and Srivastava, 1987; Green,1987) so it�s the appropriate state variable in a recursive formulationof the repeated contracting problem.

8/21

Private information: the Pareto frontier

I L designs a contract that gives her B (V ) and gives E a value V .I The Pareto frontier of the problem is given by Gr (B(V )) and each(V ,B(V )) implies a value for the match W (V ) = V + B (V ) .

I Begin by �nding the equilibrium of the subgame that starts after Ldecides not to liquidate the project.

I Upon continuation, the evolution of equity is given by:

V = p (R (k)� τ) + δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i(2)

I While the evolution of debt (not in the paper):

B (V ) = pτ � k + δhpB�VH

�+ (1� p)B

�V L�i

I The value of equity e¤ectively summarizes all the informationprovided by the history itself (Spear and Srivastava, 1987; Green,1987) so it�s the appropriate state variable in a recursive formulationof the repeated contracting problem.

8/21

Private information: the Pareto frontier

I L designs a contract that gives her B (V ) and gives E a value V .I The Pareto frontier of the problem is given by Gr (B(V )) and each(V ,B(V )) implies a value for the match W (V ) = V + B (V ) .

I Begin by �nding the equilibrium of the subgame that starts after Ldecides not to liquidate the project.

I Upon continuation, the evolution of equity is given by:

V = p (R (k)� τ) + δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i(2)

I While the evolution of debt (not in the paper):

B (V ) = pτ � k + δhpB�VH

�+ (1� p)B

�V L�i

I The value of equity e¤ectively summarizes all the informationprovided by the history itself (Spear and Srivastava, 1987; Green,1987) so it�s the appropriate state variable in a recursive formulationof the repeated contracting problem.

8/21

Recursive formulation upon continuation

I The optimal contract upon continuation maximizes the value for thematch W (Vc ), subject to LL, IC and PK constraints.

I In recursive form, the program to be solved upon continuation is:

W (V ) = maxk ,τ,V H ,V L

pR (k)� k + δhpW

�VH

�+ (1� p)W

�V L�i

s.t.

V = p (R (k)� τ) + δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i(PK)

τ � δ�VH � V L

�(ICC)

τ � R (k) , VH � 0, V L � 0 (LL)

I Authors show that V 7! W (V ) is increasing and concave.I Solving this problem yields policy functions k (V ) , τ (V ), VH (V )and V L (V ) .

9/21

Recursive formulation upon continuation

I The optimal contract upon continuation maximizes the value for thematch W (Vc ), subject to LL, IC and PK constraints.

I In recursive form, the program to be solved upon continuation is:

W (V ) = maxk ,τ,V H ,V L

pR (k)� k + δhpW

�VH

�+ (1� p)W

�V L�i

s.t.

V = p (R (k)� τ) + δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i(PK)

τ � δ�VH � V L

�(ICC)

τ � R (k) , VH � 0, V L � 0 (LL)

I Authors show that V 7! W (V ) is increasing and concave.I Solving this problem yields policy functions k (V ) , τ (V ), VH (V )and V L (V ) .

9/21

Recursive formulation upon continuation

I The optimal contract upon continuation maximizes the value for thematch W (Vc ), subject to LL, IC and PK constraints.

I In recursive form, the program to be solved upon continuation is:

W (V ) = maxk ,τ,V H ,V L

pR (k)� k + δhpW

�VH

�+ (1� p)W

�V L�i

s.t.

V = p (R (k)� τ) + δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i(PK)

τ � δ�VH � V L

�(ICC)

τ � R (k) , VH � 0, V L � 0 (LL)

I Authors show that V 7! W (V ) is increasing and concave.

I Solving this problem yields policy functions k (V ) , τ (V ), VH (V )and V L (V ) .

9/21

Recursive formulation upon continuation

I The optimal contract upon continuation maximizes the value for thematch W (Vc ), subject to LL, IC and PK constraints.

I In recursive form, the program to be solved upon continuation is:

W (V ) = maxk ,τ,V H ,V L

pR (k)� k + δhpW

�VH

�+ (1� p)W

�V L�i

s.t.

V = p (R (k)� τ) + δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i(PK)

τ � δ�VH � V L

�(ICC)

τ � R (k) , VH � 0, V L � 0 (LL)

I Authors show that V 7! W (V ) is increasing and concave.I Solving this problem yields policy functions k (V ) , τ (V ), VH (V )and V L (V ) .

9/21

Recursive formulation before liquidation decision

I If project is liquidated, E receives Q while L receives S �Q. Ifproject is not liquidated, they get Vc ,B (Vc ) .

I Pure strategies may not be optimal for some values of V soα 2 [0, 1] and L o¤ers a "lottery" to E .

I Thus, in recursive form, the program to be solved prior to liquidation:

W (V ) = maxα2[0,1],Q ,Vc

�αS + (1� α) W (Vc )

s.t. : αQ + (1� α)Vc = V (PK)

: Vc � 0, Q � 0 (LL)

I Notice that W (�) preserves the properties of W (�) .

10/21

Recursive formulation before liquidation decision

I If project is liquidated, E receives Q while L receives S �Q. Ifproject is not liquidated, they get Vc ,B (Vc ) .

I Pure strategies may not be optimal for some values of V soα 2 [0, 1] and L o¤ers a "lottery" to E .

I Thus, in recursive form, the program to be solved prior to liquidation:

W (V ) = maxα2[0,1],Q ,Vc

�αS + (1� α) W (Vc )

s.t. : αQ + (1� α)Vc = V (PK)

: Vc � 0, Q � 0 (LL)

I Notice that W (�) preserves the properties of W (�) .

10/21

Recursive formulation before liquidation decision

I If project is liquidated, E receives Q while L receives S �Q. Ifproject is not liquidated, they get Vc ,B (Vc ) .

I Pure strategies may not be optimal for some values of V soα 2 [0, 1] and L o¤ers a "lottery" to E .

I Thus, in recursive form, the program to be solved prior to liquidation:

W (V ) = maxα2[0,1],Q ,Vc

�αS + (1� α) W (Vc )

s.t. : αQ + (1� α)Vc = V (PK)

: Vc � 0, Q � 0 (LL)

I Notice that W (�) preserves the properties of W (�) .

10/21

Recursive formulation before liquidation decision

I If project is liquidated, E receives Q while L receives S �Q. Ifproject is not liquidated, they get Vc ,B (Vc ) .

I Pure strategies may not be optimal for some values of V soα 2 [0, 1] and L o¤ers a "lottery" to E .

I Thus, in recursive form, the program to be solved prior to liquidation:

W (V ) = maxα2[0,1],Q ,Vc

�αS + (1� α) W (Vc )

s.t. : αQ + (1� α)Vc = V (PK)

: Vc � 0, Q � 0 (LL)

I Notice that W (�) preserves the properties of W (�) .

10/21

Regions for V (Propositions 1 & 2)

The domain of V can be partitioned in three regions:

I Region I: When 0 � V � Vr , liquidation is posible and randomizingis optimal with α (V ) = (Vr � V ) /Vr

I Sketch of argument: α = 1) W (V ) = S while α = 0) W (V ) =W (V ). Now W � > S ) 9! Vr and α 2 (0, 1) s.t.V � Vr impliesthat αS + (1� α) W (Vr ) > max

�S , W (V )

.

I Intuition: As V ! Vr expected value W (V ) rises above S and Lliquidates with low probability (draw graph).

I Region III: When V � V � = pR (k�) / (1� δ) the total surplus isthe same as under symmetric information (�rst-best), i.e.,W (V �) = W �.

I Intuition: equivalent to E having a balance of k�/(1� δ) in thebank at interest rate (1� δ) /δ that is exactly enough to �nance theproject at its optimum scale. Then L advances k� and collects τ = 0every period.

11/21

Regions for V (Propositions 1 & 2)

The domain of V can be partitioned in three regions:

I Region I: When 0 � V � Vr , liquidation is posible and randomizingis optimal with α (V ) = (Vr � V ) /Vr

I Sketch of argument: α = 1) W (V ) = S while α = 0) W (V ) =W (V ). Now W � > S ) 9! Vr and α 2 (0, 1) s.t.V � Vr impliesthat αS + (1� α) W (Vr ) > max

�S , W (V )

.

I Intuition: As V ! Vr expected value W (V ) rises above S and Lliquidates with low probability (draw graph).

I Region III: When V � V � = pR (k�) / (1� δ) the total surplus isthe same as under symmetric information (�rst-best), i.e.,W (V �) = W �.

I Intuition: equivalent to E having a balance of k�/(1� δ) in thebank at interest rate (1� δ) /δ that is exactly enough to �nance theproject at its optimum scale. Then L advances k� and collects τ = 0every period.

11/21

Regions for V (Propositions 1 & 2)

The domain of V can be partitioned in three regions:

I Region I: When 0 � V � Vr , liquidation is posible and randomizingis optimal with α (V ) = (Vr � V ) /Vr

I Sketch of argument: α = 1) W (V ) = S while α = 0) W (V ) =W (V ). Now W � > S ) 9! Vr and α 2 (0, 1) s.t.V � Vr impliesthat αS + (1� α) W (Vr ) > max

�S , W (V )

.

I Intuition: As V ! Vr expected value W (V ) rises above S and Lliquidates with low probability (draw graph).

I Region III: When V � V � = pR (k�) / (1� δ) the total surplus isthe same as under symmetric information (�rst-best), i.e.,W (V �) = W �.

I Intuition: equivalent to E having a balance of k�/(1� δ) in thebank at interest rate (1� δ) /δ that is exactly enough to �nance theproject at its optimum scale. Then L advances k� and collects τ = 0every period.

11/21

Regions for V (Propositions 1 & 2)

The domain of V can be partitioned in three regions:

I Region I: When 0 � V � Vr , liquidation is posible and randomizingis optimal with α (V ) = (Vr � V ) /Vr

I Sketch of argument: α = 1) W (V ) = S while α = 0) W (V ) =W (V ). Now W � > S ) 9! Vr and α 2 (0, 1) s.t.V � Vr impliesthat αS + (1� α) W (Vr ) > max

�S , W (V )

.

I Intuition: As V ! Vr expected value W (V ) rises above S and Lliquidates with low probability (draw graph).

I Region III: When V � V � = pR (k�) / (1� δ) the total surplus isthe same as under symmetric information (�rst-best), i.e.,W (V �) = W �.

I Intuition: equivalent to E having a balance of k�/(1� δ) in thebank at interest rate (1� δ) /δ that is exactly enough to �nance theproject at its optimum scale. Then L advances k� and collects τ = 0every period.

11/21

Regions for V (Propositions 1 & 2)

The domain of V can be partitioned in three regions:

I Region I: When 0 � V � Vr , liquidation is posible and randomizingis optimal with α (V ) = (Vr � V ) /Vr

I Sketch of argument: α = 1) W (V ) = S while α = 0) W (V ) =W (V ). Now W � > S ) 9! Vr and α 2 (0, 1) s.t.V � Vr impliesthat αS + (1� α) W (Vr ) > max

�S , W (V )

.

I Intuition: As V ! Vr expected value W (V ) rises above S and Lliquidates with low probability (draw graph).

I Region III: When V � V � = pR (k�) / (1� δ) the total surplus isthe same as under symmetric information (�rst-best), i.e.,W (V �) = W �.

I Intuition: equivalent to E having a balance of k�/(1� δ) in thebank at interest rate (1� δ) /δ that is exactly enough to �nance theproject at its optimum scale. Then L advances k� and collects τ = 0every period.

11/21

The borrowing constraint region (Propositions 1 & 2 cont.)

I Region II: When Vr � V < V �:

(a) There is no liquidation in current period and V 7! W (V ) is strictlyincreasing and,

(b) The optimal capital advancement policy is single-valued and s.t.k (V ) < k� (the �rms is debt-constrained)

I Sketch of argument: suppose that the optimal repayment policy forregion II was τ = R (k) implying that the ICC binds (see below theproofs for both of these results). Then:

R (k) = δ(VH � V L)

which implies that increasing k is only incentive compatible ifVH � V L also increases. But W (V ) concave implies that doing sois costly! (draw graph)

12/21

The borrowing constraint region (Propositions 1 & 2 cont.)

I Region II: When Vr � V < V �:(a) There is no liquidation in current period and V 7! W (V ) is strictly

increasing and,

(b) The optimal capital advancement policy is single-valued and s.t.k (V ) < k� (the �rms is debt-constrained)

I Sketch of argument: suppose that the optimal repayment policy forregion II was τ = R (k) implying that the ICC binds (see below theproofs for both of these results). Then:

R (k) = δ(VH � V L)

which implies that increasing k is only incentive compatible ifVH � V L also increases. But W (V ) concave implies that doing sois costly! (draw graph)

12/21

The borrowing constraint region (Propositions 1 & 2 cont.)

I Region II: When Vr � V < V �:(a) There is no liquidation in current period and V 7! W (V ) is strictly

increasing and,(b) The optimal capital advancement policy is single-valued and s.t.

k (V ) < k� (the �rms is debt-constrained)

I Sketch of argument: suppose that the optimal repayment policy forregion II was τ = R (k) implying that the ICC binds (see below theproofs for both of these results). Then:

R (k) = δ(VH � V L)

which implies that increasing k is only incentive compatible ifVH � V L also increases. But W (V ) concave implies that doing sois costly! (draw graph)

12/21

The borrowing constraint region (Propositions 1 & 2 cont.)

I Region II: When Vr � V < V �:(a) There is no liquidation in current period and V 7! W (V ) is strictly

increasing and,(b) The optimal capital advancement policy is single-valued and s.t.

k (V ) < k� (the �rms is debt-constrained)

I Sketch of argument: suppose that the optimal repayment policy forregion II was τ = R (k) implying that the ICC binds (see below theproofs for both of these results). Then:

R (k) = δ(VH � V L)

which implies that increasing k is only incentive compatible ifVH � V L also increases. But W (V ) concave implies that doing sois costly! (draw graph)

12/21

Optimal repayment policy (proposition 3)

I The optimal repayment function satis�es τ = R (k) for V < V � andτ = 0 for V � V �.

I Intuition:

I We know that maxV 2V W (V ) = W � and from props 1&2 we knowthat W (V �) = W �.

I Now, at given t, L delivers promised utility Vt either by allowingτ < R (k) or by promising higher future value.

I Risk neutrality and common δ ) V ! V � in the shortest timepossible is optimal.

I Limited liability then implies τ = R (k) until V = V �

13/21

Optimal repayment policy (proposition 3)

I The optimal repayment function satis�es τ = R (k) for V < V � andτ = 0 for V � V �.

I Intuition:

I We know that maxV 2V W (V ) = W � and from props 1&2 we knowthat W (V �) = W �.

I Now, at given t, L delivers promised utility Vt either by allowingτ < R (k) or by promising higher future value.

I Risk neutrality and common δ ) V ! V � in the shortest timepossible is optimal.

I Limited liability then implies τ = R (k) until V = V �

13/21

Optimal repayment policy (proposition 3)

I The optimal repayment function satis�es τ = R (k) for V < V � andτ = 0 for V � V �.

I Intuition:I We know that maxV 2V W (V ) = W � and from props 1&2 we knowthat W (V �) = W �.

I Now, at given t, L delivers promised utility Vt either by allowingτ < R (k) or by promising higher future value.

I Risk neutrality and common δ ) V ! V � in the shortest timepossible is optimal.

I Limited liability then implies τ = R (k) until V = V �

13/21

Optimal repayment policy (proposition 3)

I The optimal repayment function satis�es τ = R (k) for V < V � andτ = 0 for V � V �.

I Intuition:I We know that maxV 2V W (V ) = W � and from props 1&2 we knowthat W (V �) = W �.

I Now, at given t, L delivers promised utility Vt either by allowingτ < R (k) or by promising higher future value.

I Risk neutrality and common δ ) V ! V � in the shortest timepossible is optimal.

I Limited liability then implies τ = R (k) until V = V �

13/21

Optimal repayment policy (proposition 3)

I The optimal repayment function satis�es τ = R (k) for V < V � andτ = 0 for V � V �.

I Intuition:I We know that maxV 2V W (V ) = W � and from props 1&2 we knowthat W (V �) = W �.

I Now, at given t, L delivers promised utility Vt either by allowingτ < R (k) or by promising higher future value.

I Risk neutrality and common δ ) V ! V � in the shortest timepossible is optimal.

I Limited liability then implies τ = R (k) until V = V �

13/21

Optimal repayment policy (proposition 3)

I The optimal repayment function satis�es τ = R (k) for V < V � andτ = 0 for V � V �.

I Intuition:I We know that maxV 2V W (V ) = W � and from props 1&2 we knowthat W (V �) = W �.

I Now, at given t, L delivers promised utility Vt either by allowingτ < R (k) or by promising higher future value.

I Risk neutrality and common δ ) V ! V � in the shortest timepossible is optimal.

I Limited liability then implies τ = R (k) until V = V �

13/21

Evolution of equity when V < V �

I From prop. 3 we know that τ = R (k) for Vr � V < V � is optimal.

I Next, notice that τ = R (k) implies that the ICC binds (lemma 2).

I To see this, recall that from prop. 2, V < V � ) k (V ) < k�. Thus,suppose that the optimal k is s.t. the ICC is slack:τ = R (k) < δ

�V H � V L

�. Then one could increase k thereby

increasing the total surplus without violating the ICC, contradictingoptimality.

I Next, ICC binding ) R (k) = δ(VH � V L). Recall that from prop.2 Vr � V ) α (V ) = 0. Summarizing:

V = αQ + (1� α)Vc = Vc = δhpVH + (1� p)V L

iI And we obtain the policy functions:

V L (V ) =V � pR (k)

δ, VH (V ) =

V + (1� p)R (k)δ

14/21

Evolution of equity when V < V �

I From prop. 3 we know that τ = R (k) for Vr � V < V � is optimal.I Next, notice that τ = R (k) implies that the ICC binds (lemma 2).

I To see this, recall that from prop. 2, V < V � ) k (V ) < k�. Thus,suppose that the optimal k is s.t. the ICC is slack:τ = R (k) < δ

�V H � V L

�. Then one could increase k thereby

increasing the total surplus without violating the ICC, contradictingoptimality.

I Next, ICC binding ) R (k) = δ(VH � V L). Recall that from prop.2 Vr � V ) α (V ) = 0. Summarizing:

V = αQ + (1� α)Vc = Vc = δhpVH + (1� p)V L

iI And we obtain the policy functions:

V L (V ) =V � pR (k)

δ, VH (V ) =

V + (1� p)R (k)δ

14/21

Evolution of equity when V < V �

I From prop. 3 we know that τ = R (k) for Vr � V < V � is optimal.I Next, notice that τ = R (k) implies that the ICC binds (lemma 2).

I To see this, recall that from prop. 2, V < V � ) k (V ) < k�. Thus,suppose that the optimal k is s.t. the ICC is slack:τ = R (k) < δ

�V H � V L

�. Then one could increase k thereby

increasing the total surplus without violating the ICC, contradictingoptimality.

I Next, ICC binding ) R (k) = δ(VH � V L). Recall that from prop.2 Vr � V ) α (V ) = 0. Summarizing:

V = αQ + (1� α)Vc = Vc = δhpVH + (1� p)V L

iI And we obtain the policy functions:

V L (V ) =V � pR (k)

δ, VH (V ) =

V + (1� p)R (k)δ

14/21

Evolution of equity when V < V �

I From prop. 3 we know that τ = R (k) for Vr � V < V � is optimal.I Next, notice that τ = R (k) implies that the ICC binds (lemma 2).

I To see this, recall that from prop. 2, V < V � ) k (V ) < k�. Thus,suppose that the optimal k is s.t. the ICC is slack:τ = R (k) < δ

�V H � V L

�. Then one could increase k thereby

increasing the total surplus without violating the ICC, contradictingoptimality.

I Next, ICC binding ) R (k) = δ(VH � V L). Recall that from prop.2 Vr � V ) α (V ) = 0. Summarizing:

V = αQ + (1� α)Vc = Vc = δhpVH + (1� p)V L

i

I And we obtain the policy functions:

V L (V ) =V � pR (k)

δ, VH (V ) =

V + (1� p)R (k)δ

14/21

Evolution of equity when V < V �

I From prop. 3 we know that τ = R (k) for Vr � V < V � is optimal.I Next, notice that τ = R (k) implies that the ICC binds (lemma 2).

I To see this, recall that from prop. 2, V < V � ) k (V ) < k�. Thus,suppose that the optimal k is s.t. the ICC is slack:τ = R (k) < δ

�V H � V L

�. Then one could increase k thereby

increasing the total surplus without violating the ICC, contradictingoptimality.

I Next, ICC binding ) R (k) = δ(VH � V L). Recall that from prop.2 Vr � V ) α (V ) = 0. Summarizing:

V = αQ + (1� α)Vc = Vc = δhpVH + (1� p)V L

iI And we obtain the policy functions:

V L (V ) =V � pR (k)

δ, VH (V ) =

V + (1� p)R (k)δ

14/21

Evolution of equity when V < V �

I The authors show that V L (V ) ,VH (V ) are nondecreasing.

I Moreover, starting from any equity value V0 2 [Vr ,V �) after a �nitesequence of good shocks V0 ! V �.

I Likewise, after a �nite sequence of bad shocks V0 ! Vr or below,triggering randomized liquidation.

I There is an asymmetry between change in equity following good andbad shocks: if p, δ large ) V � V L > VH � V

15/21

Evolution of equity when V < V �

I The authors show that V L (V ) ,VH (V ) are nondecreasing.I Moreover, starting from any equity value V0 2 [Vr ,V �) after a �nitesequence of good shocks V0 ! V �.

I Likewise, after a �nite sequence of bad shocks V0 ! Vr or below,triggering randomized liquidation.

I There is an asymmetry between change in equity following good andbad shocks: if p, δ large ) V � V L > VH � V

15/21

Evolution of equity when V < V �

I The authors show that V L (V ) ,VH (V ) are nondecreasing.I Moreover, starting from any equity value V0 2 [Vr ,V �) after a �nitesequence of good shocks V0 ! V �.

I Likewise, after a �nite sequence of bad shocks V0 ! Vr or below,triggering randomized liquidation.

I There is an asymmetry between change in equity following good andbad shocks: if p, δ large ) V � V L > VH � V

15/21

Evolution of equity when V < V �

I The authors show that V L (V ) ,VH (V ) are nondecreasing.I Moreover, starting from any equity value V0 2 [Vr ,V �) after a �nitesequence of good shocks V0 ! V �.

I Likewise, after a �nite sequence of bad shocks V0 ! Vr or below,triggering randomized liquidation.

I There is an asymmetry between change in equity following good andbad shocks: if p, δ large ) V � V L > VH � V

15/21

Dynamics of equity

16/21

Dynamics of equityI Finally, it is easy to see that fVtg is a submartingale with twoabsorving sets: Vt < Vr and Vt > V � 8 t

I Simulations (R (k) = k2/5, p = 0.5, δ = 0.99, S = 1.5):

17/21

Dynamics of equityI Finally, it is easy to see that fVtg is a submartingale with twoabsorving sets: Vt < Vr and Vt > V � 8 t

I Simulations (R (k) = k2/5, p = 0.5, δ = 0.99, S = 1.5):

17/21

Optimal k advancement policy

I We�ve seen that V0 2 [Vr ,V �)) k (V ) < k� (the �rms isdebt-constrained).

I Now, it is di¢ cult to characterize V 7! k (V ) in general (it isnonmonotonic).

I However, simulations show that conditional on success, capital growsat a positve rate, i.e. k(VH )/k (V ) > 1 while k(V L)/k (V ) < 1.

I This contributes to the "cash-�ow coe¢ cient" debate; if Tobin�s q isa su¢ cient statistic for investment, then cash �ows should notmatter.

I But if the optimal contract of this model was the DGP:

1. Cash �ows will matter for investment, k (V ) < k�

2. Cash �ows will matter more, the more constrained is the �rm.

18/21

Optimal k advancement policy

I We�ve seen that V0 2 [Vr ,V �)) k (V ) < k� (the �rms isdebt-constrained).

I Now, it is di¢ cult to characterize V 7! k (V ) in general (it isnonmonotonic).

I However, simulations show that conditional on success, capital growsat a positve rate, i.e. k(VH )/k (V ) > 1 while k(V L)/k (V ) < 1.

I This contributes to the "cash-�ow coe¢ cient" debate; if Tobin�s q isa su¢ cient statistic for investment, then cash �ows should notmatter.

I But if the optimal contract of this model was the DGP:

1. Cash �ows will matter for investment, k (V ) < k�

2. Cash �ows will matter more, the more constrained is the �rm.

18/21

Optimal k advancement policy

I We�ve seen that V0 2 [Vr ,V �)) k (V ) < k� (the �rms isdebt-constrained).

I Now, it is di¢ cult to characterize V 7! k (V ) in general (it isnonmonotonic).

I However, simulations show that conditional on success, capital growsat a positve rate, i.e. k(VH )/k (V ) > 1 while k(V L)/k (V ) < 1.

I This contributes to the "cash-�ow coe¢ cient" debate; if Tobin�s q isa su¢ cient statistic for investment, then cash �ows should notmatter.

I But if the optimal contract of this model was the DGP:

1. Cash �ows will matter for investment, k (V ) < k�

2. Cash �ows will matter more, the more constrained is the �rm.

18/21

Optimal k advancement policy

I We�ve seen that V0 2 [Vr ,V �)) k (V ) < k� (the �rms isdebt-constrained).

I Now, it is di¢ cult to characterize V 7! k (V ) in general (it isnonmonotonic).

I However, simulations show that conditional on success, capital growsat a positve rate, i.e. k(VH )/k (V ) > 1 while k(V L)/k (V ) < 1.

I This contributes to the "cash-�ow coe¢ cient" debate; if Tobin�s q isa su¢ cient statistic for investment, then cash �ows should notmatter.

I But if the optimal contract of this model was the DGP:

1. Cash �ows will matter for investment, k (V ) < k�

2. Cash �ows will matter more, the more constrained is the �rm.

18/21

Optimal k advancement policy

I We�ve seen that V0 2 [Vr ,V �)) k (V ) < k� (the �rms isdebt-constrained).

I Now, it is di¢ cult to characterize V 7! k (V ) in general (it isnonmonotonic).

I However, simulations show that conditional on success, capital growsat a positve rate, i.e. k(VH )/k (V ) > 1 while k(V L)/k (V ) < 1.

I This contributes to the "cash-�ow coe¢ cient" debate; if Tobin�s q isa su¢ cient statistic for investment, then cash �ows should notmatter.

I But if the optimal contract of this model was the DGP:

1. Cash �ows will matter for investment, k (V ) < k�

2. Cash �ows will matter more, the more constrained is the �rm.

18/21

Optimal k advancement policy

I We�ve seen that V0 2 [Vr ,V �)) k (V ) < k� (the �rms isdebt-constrained).

I Now, it is di¢ cult to characterize V 7! k (V ) in general (it isnonmonotonic).

I However, simulations show that conditional on success, capital growsat a positve rate, i.e. k(VH )/k (V ) > 1 while k(V L)/k (V ) < 1.

I This contributes to the "cash-�ow coe¢ cient" debate; if Tobin�s q isa su¢ cient statistic for investment, then cash �ows should notmatter.

I But if the optimal contract of this model was the DGP:

1. Cash �ows will matter for investment, k (V ) < k�

2. Cash �ows will matter more, the more constrained is the �rm.

18/21

Optimal k advancement policy

I We�ve seen that V0 2 [Vr ,V �)) k (V ) < k� (the �rms isdebt-constrained).

I Now, it is di¢ cult to characterize V 7! k (V ) in general (it isnonmonotonic).

I However, simulations show that conditional on success, capital growsat a positve rate, i.e. k(VH )/k (V ) > 1 while k(V L)/k (V ) < 1.

I This contributes to the "cash-�ow coe¢ cient" debate; if Tobin�s q isa su¢ cient statistic for investment, then cash �ows should notmatter.

I But if the optimal contract of this model was the DGP:

1. Cash �ows will matter for investment, k (V ) < k�

2. Cash �ows will matter more, the more constrained is the �rm.

18/21

Firm growth and survival

I Firm size is captured by k

I Starting frm the same V0 2 [Vr ,V �) simulate many di¤erent shockpaths.

I As seen before, �rms eventually either exit or reach theunconstrained optimum size.

I Since k < k� w/e Vt < V � surviving �rms grow with age; size andage are positively correlated in accordance with empirical evidence.

I Mean and variance of equity growth decrease sistematically.I Conditional probability of survival increases with V . Given that Vincreases over time (for surviving �rms), survival rates are positivelycorrelated with age and size.

I The advantage of this model is that requires little structure on thestochastic process driving �rm productivity; a simple i.i.d. process isenough to generate the rich dynamics described above.

19/21

Firm growth and survival

I Firm size is captured by kI Starting frm the same V0 2 [Vr ,V �) simulate many di¤erent shockpaths.

I As seen before, �rms eventually either exit or reach theunconstrained optimum size.

I Since k < k� w/e Vt < V � surviving �rms grow with age; size andage are positively correlated in accordance with empirical evidence.

I Mean and variance of equity growth decrease sistematically.I Conditional probability of survival increases with V . Given that Vincreases over time (for surviving �rms), survival rates are positivelycorrelated with age and size.

I The advantage of this model is that requires little structure on thestochastic process driving �rm productivity; a simple i.i.d. process isenough to generate the rich dynamics described above.

19/21

Firm growth and survival

I Firm size is captured by kI Starting frm the same V0 2 [Vr ,V �) simulate many di¤erent shockpaths.

I As seen before, �rms eventually either exit or reach theunconstrained optimum size.

I Since k < k� w/e Vt < V � surviving �rms grow with age; size andage are positively correlated in accordance with empirical evidence.

I Mean and variance of equity growth decrease sistematically.I Conditional probability of survival increases with V . Given that Vincreases over time (for surviving �rms), survival rates are positivelycorrelated with age and size.

I The advantage of this model is that requires little structure on thestochastic process driving �rm productivity; a simple i.i.d. process isenough to generate the rich dynamics described above.

19/21

Firm growth and survival

I Firm size is captured by kI Starting frm the same V0 2 [Vr ,V �) simulate many di¤erent shockpaths.

I As seen before, �rms eventually either exit or reach theunconstrained optimum size.

I Since k < k� w/e Vt < V � surviving �rms grow with age; size andage are positively correlated in accordance with empirical evidence.

I Mean and variance of equity growth decrease sistematically.I Conditional probability of survival increases with V . Given that Vincreases over time (for surviving �rms), survival rates are positivelycorrelated with age and size.

I The advantage of this model is that requires little structure on thestochastic process driving �rm productivity; a simple i.i.d. process isenough to generate the rich dynamics described above.

19/21

Firm growth and survival

I Firm size is captured by kI Starting frm the same V0 2 [Vr ,V �) simulate many di¤erent shockpaths.

I As seen before, �rms eventually either exit or reach theunconstrained optimum size.

I Since k < k� w/e Vt < V � surviving �rms grow with age; size andage are positively correlated in accordance with empirical evidence.

I Mean and variance of equity growth decrease sistematically.

I Conditional probability of survival increases with V . Given that Vincreases over time (for surviving �rms), survival rates are positivelycorrelated with age and size.

I The advantage of this model is that requires little structure on thestochastic process driving �rm productivity; a simple i.i.d. process isenough to generate the rich dynamics described above.

19/21

Firm growth and survival

I Firm size is captured by kI Starting frm the same V0 2 [Vr ,V �) simulate many di¤erent shockpaths.

I As seen before, �rms eventually either exit or reach theunconstrained optimum size.

I Since k < k� w/e Vt < V � surviving �rms grow with age; size andage are positively correlated in accordance with empirical evidence.

I Mean and variance of equity growth decrease sistematically.I Conditional probability of survival increases with V . Given that Vincreases over time (for surviving �rms), survival rates are positivelycorrelated with age and size.

I The advantage of this model is that requires little structure on thestochastic process driving �rm productivity; a simple i.i.d. process isenough to generate the rich dynamics described above.

19/21

Firm growth and survival

I Firm size is captured by kI Starting frm the same V0 2 [Vr ,V �) simulate many di¤erent shockpaths.

I As seen before, �rms eventually either exit or reach theunconstrained optimum size.

I Since k < k� w/e Vt < V � surviving �rms grow with age; size andage are positively correlated in accordance with empirical evidence.

I Mean and variance of equity growth decrease sistematically.I Conditional probability of survival increases with V . Given that Vincreases over time (for surviving �rms), survival rates are positivelycorrelated with age and size.

I The advantage of this model is that requires little structure on thestochastic process driving �rm productivity; a simple i.i.d. process isenough to generate the rich dynamics described above.

19/21

Firm growth and survival

20/21

Beyond �rm dynamics (not presented here)

I The authors show that the optimal (long term) contract can bereplicated by a sequence of one-period contracts i¤ it isrenegotiation-proof.

I The contract is renegotiation-proof i¤ collateral S is greater thanthe maximum sustainable debt.

I Risk aversion?I No capital accumulation is WLOG?I General equilibrium?

21/21

Beyond �rm dynamics (not presented here)

I The authors show that the optimal (long term) contract can bereplicated by a sequence of one-period contracts i¤ it isrenegotiation-proof.

I The contract is renegotiation-proof i¤ collateral S is greater thanthe maximum sustainable debt.

I Risk aversion?I No capital accumulation is WLOG?I General equilibrium?

21/21

Beyond �rm dynamics (not presented here)

I The authors show that the optimal (long term) contract can bereplicated by a sequence of one-period contracts i¤ it isrenegotiation-proof.

I The contract is renegotiation-proof i¤ collateral S is greater thanthe maximum sustainable debt.

I Risk aversion?

I No capital accumulation is WLOG?I General equilibrium?

21/21

Beyond �rm dynamics (not presented here)

I The authors show that the optimal (long term) contract can bereplicated by a sequence of one-period contracts i¤ it isrenegotiation-proof.

I The contract is renegotiation-proof i¤ collateral S is greater thanthe maximum sustainable debt.

I Risk aversion?I No capital accumulation is WLOG?

I General equilibrium?

21/21

Beyond �rm dynamics (not presented here)

I The authors show that the optimal (long term) contract can bereplicated by a sequence of one-period contracts i¤ it isrenegotiation-proof.

I The contract is renegotiation-proof i¤ collateral S is greater thanthe maximum sustainable debt.

I Risk aversion?I No capital accumulation is WLOG?I General equilibrium?

21/21