29
ELSEVIER Journa| of Accour.ting and Economics 20 (1995) 125 -153 lllr JOUP~AL G~ Accounting &E nom The information content of losses CarlaHayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine. CA 92717-3125, USA (Received August 1993; final version received December 1994) Abstract Th~s study hypothesizes that because shareholders have a liquidation option, losses are not expected to perpetuate. They are thus less informative than profits about the firm's future prospects. The re~ult~ are cnn.gistent with the hypothesis. They also show that the documented increase in the earnings response coefficient as the cumulation period increases appears to be due exclusively to the effect of losses. The liquidation option effect extends to profitable cases where earnings are low enough to make the option attractive. Alternative explanations for the low informativeness of losses such as mean reversal of earnings are not supported by the tests. Key words: Capital markets; Earnings response coefficients; Losses; Negative earnings J E L classification: M4 I. Introduction A large body of research demonstrates that accounting numbers and, in particular, earnings have information content. Yet, earnings appear to explain only a small fraction of the total variation in returns ( for a summary of this evidence see Bernard, 1989; Lev, 1989). Different explanations for the weak 1 thank Ray Ball (the editor) and S.P. Kothari (the referee) for their insightful comments. I also appreciate the comments of Larry Brown, Robert Freeman, Dan Givoly, Josef Lakonishok, Robert Magee, K. Ramesh, Larry Revsine, Joshua Ronen, K.R. Subramanyan, Amy Sweeny, Greg Waymire, John Wild. and the workshop participants at the University of California at Los Angeles, Emory University, and the University of Southern California. The research supporl of Coopers and Lybrand and the Accounting Research Center at Northwestern University is gratefully acknowledged. 0165-4101/95/$09.50 :~ 1995 Elsev/er Science B.V. All rights reserved SSD! 016541019500397 2

Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

ELSEVIER Journa| of Accour.ting and Economics 20 (1995) 125 -153

lllr

JOUP~AL G~ Accounting &E nom

The information content of losses

Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine. CA 92717-3125, USA

(Received August 1993; final version received December 1994)

Abstract

Th~s study hypothesizes that because shareholders have a liquidation option, losses are not expected to perpetuate. They are thus less informative than profits about the firm's future prospects. The re~ult~ are cnn.gistent with the hypothesis. They also show that the documented increase in the earnings response coefficient as the cumulation period increases appears to be due exclusively to the effect of losses. The liquidation option effect extends to profitable cases where earnings are low enough to make the option attractive. Alternative explanations for the low informativeness of losses such as mean reversal of earnings are not supported by the tests.

Key words: Capital markets; Earnings response coefficients; Losses; Negative earnings

JEL classification: M4

I. Introduction

A large body of research demonst ra tes that account ing numbers and, in particular, earnings have informat ion content . Yet, earnings appear to explain only a small fraction of the total variat ion in returns ( for a summary of this evidence see Bernard, 1989; Lev, 1989). Different explanat ions for the weak

1 thank Ray Ball (the editor) and S.P. Kothari (the referee) for their insightful comments. I also appreciate the comments of Larry Brown, Robert Freeman, Dan Givoly, Josef Lakonishok, Robert Magee, K. Ramesh, Larry Revsine, Joshua Ronen, K.R. Subramanyan, Amy Sweeny, Greg Waymire, John Wild. and the workshop participants at the University of California at Los Angeles, Emory University, and the University of Southern California. The research supporl of Coopers and Lybrand and the Accounting Research Center at Northwestern University is gratefully acknowledged.

0165-4101/95/$09.50 :~ 1995 Elsev/er Science B.V. All rights reserved SSD! 0 1 6 5 4 1 0 1 9 5 0 0 3 9 7 2

Page 2: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

126 c Hayn / Journal of ,4ccounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153

association between earnings and returns have been offered in recent years. It has been suggested, for example, that earnings do not reflect the under- lying economic events in a timely manner and, therefore, are not synchro- n/zed with stock price movements (see, e.g., Beaver, Lambert, and Morse, 1980). 1

Another explanation for the observed weak return-earnings relation is that the earnings contain transitory components that are either value-irrelevant or should have only ~ limited valuation impact (see Givoly and Hayn, 1993; Gonedes, 1975; Hoskin, :'.ugbes, and Ricks, 1986; Ramesh and Thiagarajan, 1993; Ramakrishnan and Thomas, 1993; Ronen and Sadan, 1981). Another, possibly related, measurement problem which may contribute to the weak return-earnings association is that cross-sectional tests fail to recognize the time-series properties of individual firms" earnings, a factor likely to be incorpo- rated by investors in projecting future earnings and returns (see Kormendi and Lipe, 1987). Certain specifications of the earnings variable (levels versus changes, deflation by price or earnings~ etc.) also appear to have an effect on the measured earnings response co¢fificient (see Kofl,.ari, 1992).

The suggested improvements in the measurement of earnings (e.g., removal of transitory items or improving the specification of the earnings measure) result, however, in an earnings response coefficient that is still lower than its predicted value 2 and the explanatory power of annual earnings with respect to annual returns remains fairly w e a k )

In li.ne with the research attempting to identify factors that determine the return-earnings relation, this study posits that reported losses are perceived by investors as temporary. They are thus more weakly associated with returns than profits. Losses are likely to be considered temporary since shareholders can always liquidate the firm rather than suffer from indefinite losses. In other words, equity holders have a put option on the future cash flows of the firm whereby they can sell their shares at a price commensurate with the market value of the net assets of the firm.

:The distinction between timeliness and noise in earnings, however, is not straightforward {see Collins, Kothari, Shanken, and Sloan, 1994).

ZWhen earnings behave as a random walk, the predicted value of the slope coefficient of the return-earnings regression (where the earnings variable is deflated by price and the return includes dividends) is expected to be I + l/r where r is the discount rate used by investors. Plausible values of r lead to expected values for the slope coefficient of 7.0 or higher. For further discussion see Kothari and Zimmerman (1994).

3The R 2 value of the return-earnings regression depends, among other things, on the specification of the earnings variable and the window over which earnings and returns are measured. For the earnings.deflated-by-price specification and a window of one year, R 2 values reported by past research are generally belo• 10%.

Page 3: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153 [27

Assuming an identity between cash flows and earnings and ignoring the liquidation option value, the value of the firm's equity is the higher of the present value of its expected earnings and its liquidation value. This conclusion is independent of the earnings generating function (e.g., random walk or mean reverting). It suggests that when a loss is reported, the stock price will not necessarily drop to zero nor decline proportionally to the change in earnings.

As a result, the inclusio~l of loss cases in the samples used to estimate the earnings response coefficient and the return-earnings correlation should damp- en, perhaps considerably, these measures. In addition, to the extent that there is variation in the incidence of losses across firms and over time, such variation will affect the cross-sectional and the intertemporal variation in the measured earnings response coefficient.

Losses represent only a specific case of a more general situation where the earnings signal indicates future earnings that are sufficiently low (albeit positive) as to make the liquidation option attractive. In these situations, investors do not evaluate firms strictly on the basis of their reported earnings, thus leading to a weak observed return-earnings associati.on. It is, therefore, also of interest to examine the market response to positive earnings that are so low that, if expected to persist, would make the liquidation option preferred.

The notion that the liquidation, or abandonment, option adds to the firm's value has long been recognized in the finance literature (see, for example, Robichek and Van Home, 1967; Myers and Maid, 1990), but has received only limited attention in the accounting literature. In an early stuay, Ronen and Sorter (1973) discuss the importance of the assets" exit value for firm valuation. More recently, Berger, Ofek, and Swary (1993) further develop the concept of the abandonment option and provide evidence of its effect on the value of the finn's equity. The liquidation option also plays a role in the model of the return-earnings relation used by Subramanyan and Wild (1993), who show that the informativeness ofearnings is inversely related to various characteristics that proxy for the likelihood that the firm will be terminated. Dhaliwal and Reynolds (1994) reach a similar conclusion, finding that the strength of the return-earnings association is inversely related to the default risk of the firm's debt.

The main purpose of this paper is to assess the effect of loss cases on the return-earnings relation and its cross-sectional and intertemporal variation. The paper further examines the effect of losses on other phenomena documented by previous research such as the increase in the strength of the return-earnings association as the cumulation period increases.

The results of the paper show that when only profitable firm-years are considered, stock price movements are much more strongly linked to current- period earnings. Excluding loss cases results in almost a triplin~t of both the one-year earnings response coefficient and the explanatory power of annual

Page 4: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

128 C Hayn / Journal of Accounti~¢ and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153

earnings with respect to contemporaneous returns. In contrast, when the estima- tion sample consists only of loss cases, the magnitude of reported losses does not appear to be correlated at all with contemporaneous price movements. These results hold regardless of whether levels or changes are used to form the earnings variable.

The findings of the paper further indicate that the increase in the measured earnings response coefficient as the cumulation period lengthens is due exclu- sively to the effect of loss observations. When losses are excluded, no such pattern exists; further, extending the cumulation period results in a much less dramatic increase in the R 2 of the return-earnings regression.

Rather than reflecting the existence of a liquidation option, the finding of a muted stock price response to losses may be due, at least in part~ to a mean reversal in earnings and to the fact that losses represent extreme realizations from the earnings distribution. While the random walk model has been found to provide a fair description of the time-setqes behavior of firms (see, for example, Ball and Watts, 1972; Albrecht, Lookabill, and McKeown, 1977; Watts and Leftwich, 1977), past research has also shown that under certain conditions, earnings behave as a mean-reverting process. In particular, periods with extreme changes in earnings are found to be followed by periods with earnings changes in the opposite direction (see Brooks and Bookmaster, 1976; Beaver, Lambert, and Morse, 1980; Freeman, Ohlson, and Penman, 1982). Recent studies (see Freeman and Tse, 1992; Das and Lev, 1992) find indeed that, consistent with mean reversal in earnings, the stock price response is nonlinear with the magnitude of the earnings change, with weaker responses associated with extreme earnings observations.

The paper tests the validity of mean reversal, as well as of other competing explanations (such as the higher risk of losing firms or the preponderance of transitory components in loss situations) for the findings. The results suggest that the effect of losses on the return-earnings association is, apparently, not due to the extremity of the loss observations and the mean-reversal of earnings which may follow loss incidents. In fact, the results show that the return- earnings association is weak not only in loss situations but also in profitable cases in which reported earnings fall below the threshold that evokes the exercise of the liquidation option. The other competing explanations are also not supported by the data.

The next section of the paper describes the sample and provides descriptive statistics on the incidence of losses. Section 3 shows the effect of loss cases on the measured relation between earnings and returns. Section 4 examines whether the effect of losses on the return-earnings association is due to the phenomenon of a mean reversal of extreme earnings observations (such as loss incidents). Other competing explanations for the findings are considered in Section 5. Concluding remarks and suggestions for future research are presented in the last section.

Page 5: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C. Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (19951 125-153

2. Data and descriptive statistics

129

2.1. Data

The basic sample consists of all firm-years for which earnings data are available on the 1991 release of Compustat 's Primary, Supplementary and Tertiary active and research files. It contains 85,919 firm years over the 29-year period 1962-1990, representing 9,752 distinct firms. Return information is retrieved from the CRSP database. Certain analyses impose data requirements, such as availability of sufficient return data and a minimal number of years with consecutive earnings data, that result in a reduction of the number of firm-years.

2.2. Frequency o f losses

The earnings variable is defined as income (loss) from continuing operations, before extraordin?ry items, discontinued operations, and the cumulative effect of accounting changes. Table 1 presents the relative frequency of losses. Losses are fairly common, appearing in 19.6% of all firm-years. There is a dramatic increase in the frequency of losses over time, from about 3% in the early 1960"s to over 30% in the late 1980's. The increase is only partially due to the changing composition of firms covered by Compustat. When a constant composition of firms is maintained, as shown in the right-most three columns of Table 1, a similar, although less pronounced, pattern exists. The loss frequency for these firms has increased from an average of 4.2% in the first half of the period to an average of almost 12% in the last half of the period.*

The incidence of losses is shared by almost all firms. As Table 2 indicates, the majority of firms with at least eight years of data (2,547 out of 4,148, or 61.4%) report at least one loss and one-fifth of them have two to three losses during the 29-year sample period.

2.3. Losses and firm size

The loss phenomenon is strongly linked to firm size. Table 3 shows the probability of a loss for ten equal-sized portfolios of firm-years ordered by the market value of the firms' equity, s The results reveal a monotonic relation between firm size and the probability of a loss. The prob~,~;Aity of inc~,mr.g

*A similar increase in the frequency of losses also occurs for the smaller group of firms that existed over the entire 29-year period from 1962 to 1990. STen portfolios are formed each year based on the market value of the firms" equity at the end of the previous year.

Page 6: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

130 C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153

Table 1 Frequency of losses tnegative income from continuing operations) by year

All firms Firms present from 1968 through 1990

Total Total number of Number of % of number of Number of % o f

Year firm-years loss years loss years firm-years loss years loss years

All years 85,919 16,814 19.6 21,114 !,631 7.7 1962-67 ~ 878 31 2.7 1968 ! ,703 95 5.6 918 23 2.5 1969 1,847 ! 26 6.3 918 32 3.5 1970 !,931 233 12.1 918 56 6.1 1971 2~50 231 11.3 918 54 5.9 1972 2,784 207 7.4 918 40 4.4 1973 3,119 184 5.9 918 14 !.5 1974 3,129 341 10.9 918 39 4.2 1975 3,101 394 12.7 918 54 5.9 1976 3,084 292 9.5 918 39 4.2 1977 3~81 268 8.7 918 44 4.8 1978 3,252 257 7.9 918 36 3.9 1979 3,534 399 11.3 918 31 3.4 1980 3,634 517 14.2 918 Z2 4.6 1981 3,904 707 18.1 918 55 6.0 1982 3,949 992 25.1 918 110 12.0 1983 <322 1,117 25.8 918 101 11.0 1984 ~434 1,182 26.7 918 92 1~0 1985 4,445 1,424 32.0 918 124 13.5 1986 4,678 1,546 33.0 918 131 14.3 1987 ~995 1,674 33.5 918 122 13.3 1988 ~,928 1,594 32.3 918 115 12.5 1989 &855 1,616 33.3 918 118 12.9 1990 '.°84 1,233 31.7 918 159 17.3

The mean number of firm-years, the mean number of losses per year. and the mean percentage of losses per year are ~'resented for the subpenod 1962-67.

a loss in a given year is only 2.5% for the largest firms (portfolio 10), compared with 50.8% for the smallest firms (portfolio 1).

The results relating loss frequency tt, firm size suggest that if the presence of losses induces a downward bias in the earnings response coefficf~nt, the magni- tude of that bias must vary by firm size: It should be more pronou~ced for small firms and almost nonexistent for large firms. Therefore, these results may have implications for studies on the effect of firm size on the information content of earnings. 6

°See Collins. Kothafi, and Rayburn (19~7), Collins and Kothari (1989), and Freeman (1987).

Page 7: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153 131

Table 2 Distribution of firms with at least eight years of data, by the number of years with losses tnegative income from continuing operations)

Number of loss years Number of firms % of firms

All firms 4,148 100.0

0 1,601 38.6 i 618 1¢.9 2 450 10.8 3 392 9.5 4 308 7.4 5 243 5.9 6 184 4.4 7 133 3.2 8 86 2.t 9 66 1.6

10 or more 67 1.6

Table 3 Probability of losses by portfolios ordered by firm size, where firm size is measured as the market value of equity at the end of each year

Number of Number of % of loss Portfolio firm-years loss years years

All portfolios 85,919 16,814 19.6

1 (smallest firms) 8,592 4,361 50.8 2 8,592 3,150 36.7 3 8,592 2,486 29.0 4 8,592 2,033 23.7 5 8,592 1,621 18.9 6 8,592 !,191 13.9 7 8,592 830 9.7 8 8,592 512 6.0 9 8,592 418 5.0

10 (largest firms) 8,591 212 2.5

2.4. The distribution o f profits versus losses

Fig . 1 s h o w s the c r o s s - s e c t i o n a l , p o o l e d o v e r t ime , d i s t r i b u t i o n o f t he e a r n - i n g s - p e r - s h a r e to p r i ce (a t t he b e g i n n i n g o f t he yea r ) r a t io . 7 T h e f igure is b a s e d

rAn alternative measure, earnings divided by total assets, has similar distributional properties.

Page 8: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

132 C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125- 153

4

A

t__d 0 - I -

-0.60 -0.40 -0,,9.0 0.00 0.20 0.40 0.60 Ratio

Fig. 1, The distribution of earnings-per-share to price ratio for the period 1963-1990 In = 75,878). Earnings are defined as earnings frc.m continuing operations for year t and the price is that prevailing at the end of year t - 1.

on 75,878 observations for which the price data were available. The distribution of the earnings-to-price ratio is not significantly different from a normal distri- bution (at the 5% significance level, using the Kolmogorov goodness-of-fit test) with a mean ratio of 0.051 (a median of 0.077) and a standard deviation of 0.191. a This is in line with the distribution of other financial ratios (see Foster, 1986, Ch. 4).

Interestingly, there is a point of discontinuity around zero. Specifically, there is a concentration of cases just above zero, while there are fewer than expected cases (assuming the above normal distribution) of small losses (i.e., just below zero). The frequency of observations in both the region just above and that just below zero departs significantly from the expected frequency under the normal distribution at the 1% signi- ficance level using the binomial test. These results suggest that firms whose earnings are expected to fall just below the zero earnings point engage in earnings manipulations to help them cross the "red line" for the year.

aNote that the sloping lower tail of the earnings distribution is inconsistent with the presence of "big-bath" behavior which would have been evidenced by a "fat" lower tail of the distribution.

Page 9: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C. ttayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153 133

V = L

(0,o)

~ gg

x - s t ~ x ~ )

Fig. 2. Relation between firm value and earnings in the presence of a liquidation option. L is tbe liquidation value of the firm, k is the earnings multiplier, and X* is the level of earnings that would make liquidation preferable to perpetuation of that earnings level.

3. The incidence of losses and the return-earnings association

3.1. Firm valuation in the presence of losses

Consider the following simple model in which the firm's value, V, is deter- mined by its earnings (time subscripts omitted for ease of exposition):

V = k X for X_>X*,

= L for X < X * , (1)

where X is the expected earnings per period in perpetuity, k is the appropriate earnings multiplier, L is the liquidation value of the firm, and X* is the level of expected earnings below which the liquidation option is triggered, X* = L/k. The value of the firm, so determined, is consistent with a random walk behavior of the earnings series, and is described in Fig. 2.

Earnings informativeness, as captured by the correlation between expected earnings and firm values, is a function of the level of expected earnings. Conditional upon earnings being above (below) X*, there is a perfect (zero) correlation between earnings of the firm and its value. In general, the correlation coefficient between X and V approaches 1 as the probability of triggering the liquidation option approaches 0.

Somewhat similar conclusions are reached from an econometric perspective. Estimating an earnings response coefficient based on a sample pooled across observations from the regions above and below X* (see Fig. 2) is expected to result in a downward-biased estimate of k. The degree of bias depends on the relative frequency of observations in the region below X* and on their

Page 10: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

134 C. Hayn / Journal of .4ccounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-133

extremity. 9 In the same vein, when the true relation is that described in Fig. 2, any regression estimated from the entire range of X and constrained to have a single set of coefficients would result in a lower explanatory power than that of the unrestricted regressions that allow the coefficients to vary across X's regions.

3.2. The effect o f losses on the informativeness o f earnings

The effect of losses on the estimated earnings response coefficient (ERC) and on the information content of earnings (as measured by the R 2 of the return- earnings regression) is assessed through the analysis of different specifications of the regression whose general form is (firm identifier omitted to simplify the notation)

R, = ~t + flX,/ P,_ 1 + ~t, (2)

where R~ is the return over the 12-month period commencing with the fourth month after the end of the firm's fiscal year t - 1.1° Xt, the earnings variable, is, alternately, the level of primary earnings-per-share (EPS) of year t or the change in EPS in that year, and e~ is an error term. The earnings measure is deflated by Pt- 1, the share price at the end of fiscal year t - 1. The regression is estimated for both a pooled sample of firm-years and individual firms. Both the pooled sample of firm-years and the sample of individual firms are partitioned into subgroups in order to examine the effect of losses on the regression estimates. Specifically, the pooled sample is divided into profitable and loss firm-years, and the firm sample is divided into groups of firms according to the frequency of losses in the firm's history. Regression (2) is then estimated for each subgroup, using both the earnings levels and earnings changes specifications.~ 1. t 2

If loss cases have a dampening effect on the measures of the information content of earnings, the following relation between the regression parameters of the subgroups should hold:

ERC(R2)I . . . . < ERC(R2)fun saraple < ERC(R2)profits • (3)

9proof is available from the author. t°'rhis time interval is used to ensure that the return period captures the market response 1o year t's earnings and not to the earnings for year t - 1. 1 ~Similar to other studies on the return-earnings association (see, for example, Collins and Kothari, 1989, Kothari, 1992; Lys, Ramesh, and Thiagarajan, 1993), the earnings variable is truncated. In this study, the deflated earnings variable is truncated at the top and bottom 1% of this variable's distribution. l"Wl~m the pooled sample is used for earnings changes, a loss firm-year is defined as a year in which a loss is reported in either the current or the preceding year. The reason is that ifa loss is perceived by investors as temporary, then a loss in either year t or year t - I would make the earnings change from year t - 1 to year t less informative.

Page 11: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Eco, tomics 20 (1995) 125-153 135

Table 4 Regression results of returns on the earnings/price ratio

R, = a + ~X,/P,_ t + e,, where R: is the return over the 12-month period commencing with the fourth month of fiscal year t, X, is the earnings per share variable in year t (specified as either [¢veh or changes), P,. 1 is the share price at the end of year t - 1, and e~ is an error term.

Specification of the earnings variable

Regression specification Levels Changes

No. of Adj, R e Adj. R z Pooled across firm-years firm-years fl (%) /~ {%)

All cases 75,878 0.95 9.3 0.78 5.8 Loss cases a 14,512 0.01 0.0 0.50 3.7 Profit cases b 61,366 2.62 16.9 2.64 13.7

No. of (Median value of regression parameter Time-series firms of sample firms is reported)

All firms 4,148 2.15 17.4 1.62 6.8 Firms with no losses 1,601 3.35 23.8 3.89 9.2 1 loss 618 2.36 21,6 1.79 8.2 2-3 losses 842 1.63 16.6 1.!5 4.9 4-5 losses 551 0.94 10.0 0.72 3.8 6 or more losses 536 0.63 3.6 0.52 1.4

~Under the earnings-change specification, this group also includes profitable cases in which a toss is reported in the previous year, leading to a total number of 18,919 cases in this group.

bUnder the earnings-change specification, this group excludes cases in which a loss is reported in the previous year, resulting in a total number of cases of only 56,959 in this group.

The main results, summarized in Table 4, show that bo th fl (the E R C ) and R z are considerably depressed by the inclusion of loss cases. The first panel of the table presents the parameters f rom a pooled regression. The coefficient of ,the earnings variable is 0.95 for levels and 0.78 for changes. These values are consistent with the values for E R C repor ted in o ther studies. When only profi table yeais are considered, the E R C increases dramatical ly to 2.62 and 2.64, respectively. Similar increases are obta ined for the adjusted R e of the regression, a statistic often viewed as a measure of the informat ion content of earnings: f rom values of R e for the full sample of 9 .3% (levels) and 5,8% (changes), the R e of the regression increases to 16.9% (levels) and 13.7% (changes). When only loss cases are considered, the associat ion between earnings and returns is extremely low. T h e E R C s are 0.01 (which is insignificant) and 0.50 for levels and changes. The R 2 is close to 0 using bo th levels and changes.

The dampening effect tha t the inclusion of losses has on the E R C and the R e of the re turn-earn ings regression is best illustrated when regression (2) is

Page 12: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

[36 C Hayr. / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153

estimated for individual firms. The second panel of Table 4 shows summary results for regression (2) estimatec: ~ r 4,148 individual firms for which at least eight years of returns and earnings data are available. The E R C and R 2 decline with the frequency of loss years in the firm's time series. For earnings levels, the median E R C for all firms is 2.15 and the median R e is 17.4%. The E R C and the R 2 decline monotonically with the number of years in which the firm experiences a loss. Firms that enjoy only profitable years exhibit the highest estimated values of these parameters (3.35 and 23.8%, respectively), while firms with more than six years of losses experience the lowest values (0.63 and 3.6%, r~pectively). Similar patterns are found when the earnings change specification is used.

3.3. The effect o f losses on the return-earnings relation over long cumulation periods

Previous studies on the information content of earnings show that while the E R C and the R 2 of the annual return-earnings regression are low, cumulating earnings over longer horizons results in much higher values for these parameters (see Easton, Harris, and Ohlson, 1992; Lys, Ramesh, and Thiagarajan, 1993). The increase in the explanatory power of the return-earnings regression is attributed, in general, to the lack of timeliness in reporting the effects of economic events on the financial statements and by the noise reduction resulting from the aggregation of earnings over time. This increase in the slope coefficient as the cumulation period increases is not readily explained, however. As Easton, Harris, and Ohlson conclude: "Unfortunately we know of no easy and direct explanation as to why this pattern occurs ... future research needs to address this isst:e" (ibid, p. 138).

Note, however, that as long as the occurrence of a loss in consecutive periods is not perfectly autocorrelated, longer cumulation periods mean a lower likeli- hood that the aggregated earnings variable is negative. Given the dampening effect of losses on the measured information content of earnings, the increased E R C and R z in longer cumulation periods may simply be explained by the prevalence of profitability over longer periods. To examine this explanation, regression (2) is estimated for cumulation periods rang/ng from one to ten years. 13

13The sample for the n-period cumulation period consists of observations pooled across firms. The observations contributed to the sample by each firm are the cumulative return and cumulative earnings levels (or their n-lagged changes) measured over the n-year overlapping intervals available for the firm's time series. Note that a particular firm's observations for any given cumulation period are not independent because of the overlapping years. While this is not a serious problem given the large number of firms, no attempt is made to draw statistical inferences.

Page 13: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

c. Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153 |37

For each cumulation period, the regression is estimated separately for cases with positive and negative cumulative earnings, t4

The results are reported in Table 5. The first three columns show the results from estimating regression (2) for all cases, regardless of the sign of the cumulative earnings. The results are consistent with those reported by pre- vious research - both the E R C and the R e increase as the cumulation period increases. The E R C increases from 0.95 for the one-year period to 2.29 for the ten-year cumulation period; respective values for the R e are 11.3% and 63.4%.

The next three columns of Table 5 show the results for cumulation periods for which the aggregate earnings are positive and the last three columns present the results for cumulation periods over which aggregate earnings are negative. The table shows that the likelihood of a cumulative loss declines with the cumulation period. The probability of a loss in the one-year cumulation period is 0.144 (8,825/61,452).1 s This probability declines monotonically to 0.081 (2,024/25,049) for the ten-year cumulation period.

The most interesting finding that emerges from t.he tahl,~ i~ that the no,~itive

association between the magnitude of the E R C and the length of the cumulation period is due only to the decreasing likelihood of incurring a cumulative loss as one extends the cumulation window. When the analysis is restricted to cumula- tion periods with aggregate profits, the E R C is, as expected, high. Furthermore, it is fairly constant and appears to be independent of the length of the cumula- tion period. Panel A {levels specification) shows that the E R C for positive earnings cases is quite high {2.39) for the one-year cumulation period - a magni- tude that is reached only for the ten-year cumulation period when all cases (including losses) are considered. In contrast, the E R C for every cumulation period with an aggregate loss is close to 0 or even negative. The effect of losses on the R 2 of the regression is also evident, yet less pronounced than their effect on the ERC. The increase in R e as one moves from one- to ten-year cumulation period is 4.6|-fold [(63.4-11.3)/11.3] for all cases and only 2.57-fold [(67.8 - 19.0)/19.0] for cases with aggregate profits. The R z values of the regressions estimated for cumulation periods with aggregate losses are alI close to 0. Similar results occur when the change specification of earnings is used (see panel B of the table).

~To ensure some stability in the composition of the sample firms as the cumulation period increases, only firms with at Eeast eight years of data participate in this analysis. Note that the resuhs for the different aggregation periods are not independent since the shorter periods are subsumed by ~he lon~:.'r ones. t SThis probabi|ity is lower than the probability of a loss reported in Tabte 1 ~0.196) due to the fact that the resuhs in Table 5 are based on a subset of the full samp[e (i.e.. firms with at [east e/ght years of earnings and return data~.

Page 14: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

Tab

le 5

R

egre

ssio

n re

sults

of

retu

rns

on t

he e

arni

ngs/

pric

e ra

tio,

eat

imat

ed f

or d

iffe

rent

cum

ulat

ion

peri

ods,

by

the

sign

of

cum

ulat

ive

earn

ings

R,

= •

+

flX

,/P

,-

1 +

c,,

whe

re R

, is

the

retu

rn o

ver

the

12-m

onth

per

iod

com

men

cing

wit

h th

e fo

urth

mon

th o

f fi

seal

yea

r t,

X~

is th

e ea

rnin

gs p

er s

hare

va

riab

le in

yea

r t

(spe

cifi

ed a

s ei

ther

lev

els

or c

hang

es),

P,_

i is

the

sha

re p

rice

at

the

end

of y

ear

t -

1, a

nd e

~ is

an

erro

- te

rm.

Cas

es w

ith

posi

tive

Cas

es w

ith n

egat

ive

Cum

ulat

ion

All

case

s cu

mul

ativ

e ea

rnin

gs

cum

ulat

ive

earn

ings

pe

riod

(y

ears

) n

fl

R 2

(%)

n fl

R

2 (%

) n

fl

R 2

(%)

(A)

Lev

els

1 61

,452

0.

95

11.3

52

,627

2.

39

19.0

8,

825

0.06

0.

0 2

57,1

54

1.20

21

.2

48,3

85

2.3

! 31

.4

8,76

9 -

0.02

0.

0 3

52,8

88

1.40

31

.0

45,0

38

2.20

40

.6

7,85

0 -

0.12

0.

0 4

48,6

52

!.58

38

.7

41,7

23

2.19

46

.5

6,92

9 -

0.21

1.

1 5

44,4

56

1.73

44

.5

38,4

84

2.24

51

.4

5,97

2 -

0.29

1.

8 6

40,2

87

1.87

50

.2

35,3

12

2.29

56

.2

4,97

5 -

0.31

2.

0 7

36,1

46

1.94

54

.1

32,0

94

2.30

59

.0

4,05

2 -

0.37

2.

8 8

32,0

29

2.04

57

.4

28,8

19

2.36

62

.2

3,21

0 -

0.37

2.

8 9

28,3

69

2.22

60

.6

2578

16

2.51

65

.2

2,55

3 -

0.54

4.

2 10

25

,049

2.

29

63.4

23

,025

2.

54

67.8

2,

024

- 0.

57

3.0

(B) C

hang

es

1 61

,452

0.

74

2.2

49,2

82

2.98

7.

3 12

,170

0.

31

2.1

2 52

,888

1.

34

8.0

41,5

79

3.22

17

.5

11,3

09

0.44

4.

7 3

44,4

56

!.78

14

.2

35,4

21

3.23

23

.9

9,03

5 0.

45

5.6

4 36

,146

3.

27

24.0

29

,491

5.

21

36.6

6,

655

0.63

4.

6 5

28,3

68

3.00

21

.8

23,8

34

4.34

29

.6

4,53

4 0.

42

2.4

6 22

,070

3.

13

26.8

19

,005

4.

24

34.4

3,

065

0.36

!.

7 7

16,9

89

3.04

29

.8

14,8

33

3.84

35

.3

2,15

6 0.

56

4.1

8 12

,945

2.

90

35.9

11

,345

3.

48

40.7

1,

600

0.31

2.

1 9

%40

2 2.

81

36.0

8,

336

3.00

35

.7

1,06

6 0.

60

5.4

10

6,48

8 3.

56

46.1

5,

778

3.72

45

.2

710

1.21

13

.8

Page 15: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C. Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153 139

3.4. Losses and the intertemporal variation in the earnings response coefficient

In line with the findings of previous research, t6 there is a drop in the ERC between the 1960"s and the 1980"s. For this sample (consisting of 75,878 obser- vations), the ERC for earnings levels drops from an annual mean of 2.43 in the 1963-1972 decade to 0.99 in the following decade and to 0.81 in the years 1983-1990. A similar drop in the ERC is registered when earnings changes are used. The variations in the frequency of losses over time (as reported in Table 1) may explain, in part or in full, the decline in the earnings response coefficient and the information content of earnings over years.

To test the association between the frequency of losses and the decrease in the earnings response coefficient, the following time-series regression is estimated:

ERCt or RSQ, = ~o + 61FREQt + cot, I4)

where ERC, and RSQ are, respectively, the earnings response coefficient (//) and the R z from regression (2) estimated for year t. FREQt is the relative frequency of losses in year t and co, is an error term.

The results obtained from regression (4) (not shown) confirm the above expectation that the earnings response coefficient is a function of the prevalence of losses. The slope coefficients of regression (4) are negative (i.e., the higher is the frequency of losses in the year, the lower is the ERC and the R 2 for that year) and significant at the 1% significance level. Further, the variation in the frequency of losses over the years appears to explain over a third of the intertemporal variability in the ERC.

The increased frequency of losses, however, does not fully explain the decline in the ERC (and R z) over time since this decline is also observed when only profitable firms are considered in the estimation each year.t7 Thus, while the variability in the frequency of losses explains some of the intertemporal vari- ation in the ERC, the decline in ERC over time is not fully explained by this study's findings. ~s

t6See Beaver, Lambert, and Ryan 11987), Board and Walker 11990), Rayburn 11986), Easton and Harris (1991), and Ramesh and Thiagarajan (1994). A related finding, a gradual decline over the last 40 years in the relative magnitude of the permanent component of earnings, is reported by Ramakrishnan and Thomas (1993~.

t :For profitable fi.,~ns using the levels specification, the mean ERC is 5.23 in the 1963-72 subperiod, 2.41 in the 1973-82 subperiod, and 2.96 in the years 1983-1990.

~Slt has also been suggested that the ERC has declined due to the increase in the cross-sectional variability of earnings {see Ramesh and Thiagarajart, I994}. While both a decline in the ERC and an increase in earnings variability are observed over the last three decades, there are some sub.periods over which the ERC declines while the earnings variability increases. "l'hus the increase in earnings variability does not provide a complete explanation for the decline in the ERC over time.

Page 16: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

140 C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) t25-153

4. Liquidation option vs. mean reversal as an explanation for the effect of losses on the return-earnings association

The fact that shareholders have a liquidation option is a plausible explanation for the effect of losses on the measured information content of earnings. Yet, this effect could also be due to the mean reversal of earnings. Previous studies suggest a mean-reverting tendency of earnings, particularly after large earnings changes (see, for example, Brooks and Buckmaster, 1976; Freeman, Ohlson, and Penman, 1982). Past research also finds a nonlinear return-earnings association and, in particular, a muted market response to extreme earnings changes (see Das and Lev, 1992; Freeman and Tse, 1992; a less pronounced nonlinearity is reported by Beneish and Harvey, 1994). Losses represent extreme observations of the earnings level distribution (see Fig. 1), while an earnings change in the loss year may represent an extreme observation of the earnings change distribu- tion. ~9 The finding of a lower E R C during loss years (under both the level and change specifications) could thus be due to the extremity of loss observations rather than to the liquidation option held by shareholders.

Several tests are conducted to assess the validity of the liquidation option explanation. First, the results for the sample of losses are compared with those obtained for profits of the same extremity as the loss cases. Second, the p r o x i m ity to the exercise price of the losing firm is added as an explanatory variable in regression (2). Finally, the validity of the liquidation option explanation is evaluated by examining the extent to which it can also explain the stock price response to profits that are sufficiently low so as to trigger the exercise of this option. These tests are not designed to determine the exact relative contribution of each alternative explanation for the effect of losses on the return-earnings association. Such a determination requires a more accurate specification of the mean-reverting process than is currently available.

The tests and their results are described below. The main thrust of the results is that, while the mean-reversal phenomenon contributes to the effect of losses on the measured information content of earnings, the maior explanation for this effect is the presence of the liquidation option.

4. I. Effect o f mean reversion

To assess the extent to which mean reversion is behind the findings of Table 4, regression (2) is estimated for losses and profitable cases of the same degree of "extremity'. The degree of extremity of a profit observation is determined by its standardized distance from its firm's mean earnings, expressed in terms of

tgThc absolute magnitude of the earnings change variable (e.g., the change in earnings standardized by price~ is much larger for loss cases than for profit cases. The median and the third quartile values of this magnitude are, respectively, 0.044 and 0.117 for losses and 0.026 and 0.073 for profit cases.

Page 17: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (i 995) 125-153 | 4 |

number of standard deviations, z° Eight "equal-extremity" portfolios are created and regression (2) is estimated separately for the loss and the profit cases in each portfolio. In addition, regression (2) is estimated for two pooled samples, one consisting of all loss cases and the other consisting of profitable observations selected so that their distribution across extremity portfolios is identical to that of the sample of losses.

If mean reversal is behind the lower information content measures observed for loss cases, we should expect to find

ERC(R2h ..... = ERC(R2)¢quaily . . . . . . . profi . . . . pie- (5 )

The results reported in Table 6 show that, in line with the findings of earlier studies cited above on the nonlinearity of the return-earnings association, the ERC (and the R z) of the extreme cases is considerably lower than that of the entire populat ion presented in the first panel of Table 4. (In this and the following tables, the results are presented only for the level specification; results for the change specification are similar.)

More important to the issue at hand, however, is the finding in Table 6 that the low informativeness of losses is not due to their extremity. The ERC and R z for profitable observations are much larger than for loss observations, within each extremity portfolio. In fact, the ERC for loss observation~ is insignificantly different from 0 for every portfolio, regardless of its extremity level. The same conclusions are drawn from the results from estimating regression (2} for the sample of pooled losses and the equal-extremity sample of profitable obser- vations, which are reported in the last line of Table 6.

4.2. The information conlent o f losses as a function o f the likelihood o f liquidation

In the presence of a iiquidation option, losses will not be allowed to perpetu- ate. Nonetheless, as long as the current stock price is above the net liquidation value of the firm, a reported loss may reasonably be expected to recur for some time without evoking liquidation. That is, a reported loss is likely to trigger a price reaction whose extent depends on the likelihood of exercising the liquidation option, with an upper bound equal to the excess of the stock price (at the beginning of the response period) over the liquidation value of the firm per share. This observation a!so holds for cases of sufficiently low, but positive, levels of earnings.

To examine the extent to which the likelihood of exercising the liquidation option affects the information content of losses, two proxies for the (unobserv- able) likelihood of liquidation are used. One is based on the rating of the firm's

2°Two alternative measures of extremity were used, E/P and the absolute distance of the earnings observation from the regression of current on lagged earnings-per-share. The results from using these measures are very similar to those based on the standardized distance measure.

Page 18: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

Tab

le 6

R

egre

ssio

n re

sult

s of

ret

urns

on

the

earn

ings

/pri

ce r

atio

, by

por

tfol

ios

orde

red

by t

he e

xtre

mit

y of

the

ear

ning

s ob

serv

atio

n

R~

= ~

+ p

X~/

P~_

~ +

~,

whe

re R

t is

the

retu

rn o

ver

the

12-m

onth

per

iod

com

men

cing

wit

h th

e fo

urth

mon

th o

f fi

scal

yea

r t,

X~

is t

he e

arni

ngs

per

shar

e va

riab

le i

n ye

ar t

(sp

ecif

ied

as e

ithe

r le

vels

or

chan

ges)

, Pf

_ ~

is t

he s

hare

pri

ce a

t th

e en

d of

yea

r t

- I,

and

e~

is a

n er

ror

term

. R

esul

ts f

or t

he l

evel

s sp

ecif

icat

ion

of t

he e

arni

ngs

mea

sure

are

pre

sent

ed.

Ext

rem

ity

of t

he

All

fir

m y

ears

P

rofi

tabl

e fi

rm y

ears

L

oss

firm

yea

rs

obse

rvat

ion

mea

sure

d by

th

e st

anda

rdiz

ed d

iffe

renc

e A

dj.

R:

Adj

. R

: A

dj.

R"

from

the

mea

n, D

IFF

a n

/I

(%)

n P

(%

) n

~ (%

)

All

fir

m y

ears

b 52

,583

1.

14

12.0

48

,176

2.

17

18.7

4,

407

0.01

0.

0 0

< D

IFF

< 0

.25

(lea

st e

xtre

me)

!1

,032

2.

30

18.0

10

,880

2.

36

18.6

15

2 -

0.65

5.

1 0.

25 <

DIF

F <

0.5

0 10

,208

2.

19

16.8

9,

877

2.40

18

.4

331

- 1.

34

3.8

0.50

< D

IFF

< 0

.75

9,61

5 1.

64

12.8

9,

141

2.27

17

.0

474

- 0.

29

1.3

0.75

< D

IFF

< 1

.00

7,81

2 1.

57

13.3

7,

292

2.29

17

.2

520

- 0.

01

0.0

1.00

< D

IFF

< 1

.25

4,91

4 !.

68

18.0

4,

345

2.41

21

.9

569

- 0.

19

0.2

1.25

< D

IFF

< 1

.50

2,98

9 1.

18

14.3

2,

533

1.89

21

.0

456

- 0.

27

0.6

1.50

< D

IFF

< 2

.00

3,48

8 0.

64

11.4

2,

698

1.69

19

.5

790

- 0.

07

0.4

DIF

F >

2.0

0 2,

525

0.60

18

.2

1,40

9 1.

53

25.6

I,

I 15

0.04

0.

1 (m

ost

extr

eme)

A p

ortf

olio

of

prof

itab

le a

nd

loss

yea

rs o

f eq

ual

extr

emit

y 9,

980

0.58

9.

6 5,

573

1.85

21

.7

4,40

7 0.

01

0.0

aD

IFF

= I

EP

S, -

M

ean

(EP

S)[

/Std

.(E

PS

) fo

r ea

ch y

ear.

bFir

ms

wit

h ne

gati

ve M

ean

(EP

S)

are

excl

uded

fro

m t

he a

naly

sis.

Page 19: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C. Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (I 995) 125-153 | 43

public debt. The other is the gap between the firm's current share price and its estimated liquidation value, expressed in terms of the number of standard deviations of earnings. The latter measure yields the magnitude of the earnings drop (expressed in terms of number of standard deviations of earnings) that would (according to the prevailing P/E ratio in the firm's industry) bring about a decline in the share price and cause the liquidation option to be "in the money'. The greater is the drop, the lower is the probability of liquidation.

The first proxy is based on the Standard & Poor's Corporate Bond Rating applicable to the firm-year. The variable, Lt, receives values ranging from 1 (corresponding to the lowest grades, CCC + to D) to 6 (corresponding to the highest grades, AAA to AA - ).

The second proxy, Lz, is measured as

L2 = [( P - A)/PEIND]/Std, (6)

where P is the price per share, A is the liquidation value per share measur~J as the market value of the firm's assets 2! less its liabilities, PE~Nn is the median price-to-earnings ratio in the firm's industry, and Std is the standard deviation of the firm's earnings per share. P, A, and PE~ND are measured at the beginning of the period. Deflating (P - A) by PE~ND transforms the excess of the price over liquidation value into an earnings dimension. Dividing t'ds ratio by the stand- ard deviation of the earnings per share yields the magnitude of the earnings drop (expressed in terms of number of standard deviations of earnings) that is needed (based on the PiE ratio in the firm's industry) to bring about a decline in the share price from P to A.

Each of the two proxies for the likelihood of liquidation is alternately introduced in regression (2) as an additional interactive independent variable to form the following regression:

R, = • + [¢X,/P,~-, + 7(X, /P,- ~)L, + ~h, (7)

where R, X, and P are as defined earlier, L assumes either the LI or the Lz definition, and ~/, is an error term. Under the 'liquidation-option" explanation, ,/is expected to be positive. That is, a more pronounced stock price response to a reported loss is expected when the likelihood of exercising the liquidation option is smaller.

The results from estimating regression (7) are reported in Table 7. The coefficient 7 is positive and very significant for both versions of the interactive variable. (Note that the different magnitude of the 7 coefficient under the two versions reflects only the different dimension in which L1 and L2 are expressed.) These results are consistent with the liquidation option having an effect on earnings informativeness.

Z tThe procedure used to estimate the market value of the firm's assets is described in the Appendix.

Page 20: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

144 C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125--153

Table 7 Regression results of returns on the earnings/price ratio and its interaction with the likelihood of liquidation, estimated for loss observations

R, = • + [3Xt/ P,_ ~ + 7(X,/P,- ~ ) L, + ~,, where R, is the return over the 12-month period commen- cing with the fourth month of fiscal year t, X, is the earnings per share variable in year t (specified as either levels oz changes), P,_ ~ is the share price at the end of year t - I, and e, is an error te~m. L, takes on the values of L, and Lz described in the footnotes. Results for the levels specification of the earnings measure are presented.

Likelihood of liquidation Adj. R 2 proxied by: n ~ 7 (%)

Lt : Bond rating ~ 1,208 0.02 0.10 3.4 (1.45) ¢ (4.42)

Lz: Estimated distance from 6,462 0.03 1. i 8 0.5 liquidation option b (1.20) 16.03)

~Ln is the bond rating expressed as a number ranging from 6 (best rating) to i (poorest rating). The six rating groups a r e A A A t o A A - , A + t o A - , B B B + t o B B B - , B B + t o B B - , B + to B - , a n d CCC + to D.

bLz is c:,!culated as [(P - A)/PE~ND]/Std, where P is the price per share, A is the liquidation value per share ,,aeasured as the market value of the firm's net assets, PEIND is the median price-to-earnings ratio in the firm's industry, and Std is the standard deviation of the firm's earnings per share.

~The t-values are provided in parentheses.

4.3. The r e tu rn -earn ings associat ion in cases o f " temporari ly depressed" earnings

As discussed in Section 3.1, if the ' l iquidat ion-opt ion ' explanat ion for the low informat ion conten t of losses holds, it should also extend to cases where earnings, while positive, are too low to be reasonably expected to be al lowed to recur. In this si tuation, repor ted earnings would be so low as to make the l iquidat ion of the firm (and the realization of its exit value) a preferred al terna- tive to the perpe tua t ion of the current ly repor ted earnings level.

To explore the similarity between the two si tuat ions (a loss and ' temporar i ly depressed" earnings) in terms of the strength of the re tu rn-earn ings relation, regression (2) is re-estimated for a sample of firm-years ~ i th positive, but depress- ed, earnings. Cases of "temporarily depressed' earnings are defined as those where the estimated exit value of the firm exceeds the value that investors would have assigned to it had they naively applied the earnings multiple of the firm's industry to the firm's repor ted earnings. The exact p rocedure used to identify ' t emporar - •ly depressed" earnings is explained and illustrated in the Appendix.

The results are reported in Table 8. The table shows that both the ERC and the R 2 of regression (2) are higher for firm-years with 'normal' profits (that is, firm-years with positive, nondepressed earnings) than for those with tempoiarily depressed

Page 21: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153 145

Table 8 Regression results of returns on the earnings/price ratio for firms with positive, temporarily depressed earnings

R, = • + flX,/P,_ ~ + ~,, where R, is the return over the 12-month period commencing with the fourth month of fiscal year t. X, is the earnings per share variable in year t {specified as either levels or changes), P,_ ~ is the share price at the end of year t - !, and e, is an error term. Results for the levels specification of the earnings measure. :re presented.

No. of Adj. R 2 cas~s /1 {%)

Profitable years classified as:

"Normal" {nondepressed) earnings 29,34 i 3.08 21.4

Temporarily depressed earnings 19,025 2.20 18.2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Temporarily depressed earnings years classified by 0: ~ 0.75 < 0 < 1.00 5,257 2.51 19.7 0.50 _< 0 < 0.75 5,934 2.14 17.4 0.25 < 0 < 0.50 5,552 2.06 1 !.6

0 < 0.25 2,282 1.65 9.3 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .

Loss years 13,622 0.01 0.0

~0 is the ratio of the product of reported earnings times the mean PiE in the firm's industry, to the liquidation value of the firm. The likelihood of liquidation is a decreasing function of 0. {When the earnings-chang~ specification is used, the 0 value used to assign the firm-year to one of the 'depressed earnings" groups is the lower of the 0 values received by either EPS, or EPS,_ t.)

earnings. W h e n the level specification is used, the E R C for 'normal" prof i table

f i rm-years is 3.08 and the R 2 is 21.4%. The c o r r e s p o n d i n g values for f i rm-years

with ' t empora r i ly depressed" earn ings are 2.20 and 18.2%. Fu r the rmore , the E R C

and, to a lesser degree, the R z decline as the extent o f the earn ings 'depression" (as measured by 0, the ra t io o f the earnings-based value to the es t imated exit value) deepens, with the lowest values o f the E R C and R 2 ob ta ined for loss cases. 22

5. Other alternative explanations for the low informativeness of losses

5. I. F i r m risk

Los ing firms are smal ler (see T a b l e 3) a n d m a y have m o r e volat i le ea rn ings s t r eams and , in ge , e r a l , be r iskier t han prof i tab le firms. Since the d i s coun t ra te

ZZThese findings are not the result of a time-period effect (see Section 3.4). The representation of the different years in each of the groups in the table is similar.

Page 22: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

146 c. Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-~'53

of future earnings increases with firm risk and hence the earnings response coefficient decreases (see, for example, Collins and Kothari, 1989), the lower informativeness of losses could be a reflection of the higher risk of losing firms.

Two tests of the effect of firm risk on the informativeness of losses are employed. In the first, the sample firms are grouped into six portfolios according to ~heir bond rating. Bond ratings, obtained from Standard and Poor's Cor- poration Bond Rating, were available for 8,072 firm-years. Regression (1) is then estimated within each portfolio for all firm-years, and separately for profitable and loss firm-years in each portfolio.

The results of this test are reported in Table 9. They confirm the expectation that losing firms are riskier than profitable firms. The percentage of losses out of all firm-years represented in a given portfolio is a decreasing function of the bond rating of the firms in the portfolio. The frequency of losses in the portfolio consisting of firms with the highest bond rating (Portfolio 1) is only about 1% t22/1,646). This frequency increases monotonically with the riskiness of the portfolio and reaches 68% (338/503) for the portfolio representing the firms with the poorest bond rating.

The table also shows that the E R C declines with risk. Yet, the main result of the table is that, within each risk portfolio, the E R C associated with losses is much lower than that associated with profits. Thus, the higher risk of the losing firms cannot, in itself, explain the low informativeness of losses. The validity of this conclusion hinges on the quality of bond ratings as a proxy for risk. Most empirical evidence, however, is consistent with bond ratings being associated with firm risk (see, for example, Fisher, 1959; Kaplan and Urwitz, 1979; Lamy and Thompson, 1988). Further, the same conclusions of Table 9 are derived when firm risk is proxied by the number of losses incurred by the firm over the sample period of 29 years. The results (not presented) are consistent with those obtained from using the first proxy: namely, the gap between the informative- ness of profits and losses is maintained within each risk group.

5.2. Transitory components in reported losses

A reported loss may be the result of transitory events or accounting accruals, such as write-downs, write-offs, or provisions for losses. In fact, the evidence in the literature concerning 'big bath' beha,'ior (see, for example, Elliot and Shaw, 1988) lends support to this notion. Since some of these earnings components are value-irrelevant or, being transitory, have only limited relevance for firm valu- ation, their preponderance in loss situations may explain the observed low return-loss association. To examine this explanation, the main results of Tables 4 and 5 are replicated using earnings numbers that are devoid of transitory accounting items of the nature described above. The extraction of these items was done by removing from the ordinary earnings number the amount of "special items" (Compustat variable # 17). The results obtained from the use of

Page 23: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

Tab

le 9

R

egre

ssio

n re

sult

s of

ret

urns

on

the

earn

ings

/pri

ce r

atio

, by

ris

k po

rtfo

lios

Rt =

+ p

X~

/P~

_,

+ ~:

, whe

re R

~ is

the

ret

urn

over

the

12-m

onth

per

iod

com

men

cing

wit

h th

e fo

urth

mon

th o

f fi

scal

yea

r t,

X,

is t

he e

arni

ngs

per

shar

e va

riab

le i

n ye

ar t

(sp

ecif

ied

as e

ithe

r le

vels

or

chan

ges)

, P,

~ t

is t

he s

hare

pri

ce a

t th

e en

d of

yea

r t

- 1,

and

e,

is a

n er

ror

term

. R

esul

ts f

or t

he l

evel

s sp

ecif

icat

ion

of t

he e

arni

ngs

mea

sure

are

pre

sent

ed.

'-~

All

fir

m y

ears

P

rofi

tabl

e fi

rm y

ears

L

oss

firm

yea

rs

Ris

k A

dj.

R 2

A

dj.

R 2

A

dj.

R 2

~

' P

ortf

olio

(b

ond

rati

ngP

n

fl

(%)

n fl

(%

) n

~ (%

) ~.

All

fir

m y

ears

A

AA

to

D

8072

0.

58

13.0

68

63

2.01

14

.7

1209

0.

23

4.6

1 A

AA

to

AA

-

1646

1.

43

9.4

1624

1.

61

9.3

22

..

..

2

A +

to

A -

24

41

1.54

15

.2

2344

2.

04

15.8

97

0.

54

3.7

3 B

BB

+

to B

BB

-

1450

0.

91

12.6

12

90

1.90

14

.7

160

0.17

0.

5 ~'

4

BB

+

to B

B -

67

5 0.

90

12.3

54

0 1.

94

14.3

13

5 0.

22

0.4

5 B

+

to B

-

1356

0.

61

12.7

90

3 2.

45

18.6

45

3 0.

24

3.7

6 C

CC

+

to D

50

3 0.

36

13.3

16

5 1.

50

8.6

338

0.18

3.

8

~Bon

d ra

ting

s ar

e ob

tain

ed f

rom

Sta

ndar

d an

d P

oor'

s C

orpo

rati

on B

ond

Rat

ing.

~

Page 24: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

148 c Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153

the "clean" earnings measure (not reported here) are very similar to those reported under the earrfings measure that includes the "special items'. This finding suggests that prevalence of transitory items in situations of reported losses could not explain the low informativeness of losses (and, interestingly, nor could it explain, according to Das and Lev, 1993, the nonlinear earnings-return association).

Further, the evidence shows that a loss, once incurred, persists for several years. The probability of incurring a loss in year t given a loss in year t - 1 is about three times higher than the unconditional probability of a loss. 23 This evidence 3uggests that losses are not induced by one-time accruals, further supporting the liquidation option explanation for the muted market reaction to losses.

5.3. Conservatism in accounting

Conservatism in accounting requires that anticipated losses be incorporated in current earnings whereas anticipated gains be recorded only when reaRzed. In other words, unfavorable information is more likely to be reflected fully in current earnings than favorable information. Since all relevant information is immediately captured in stock prices, the ERC associated with losses would tend to be one whereas that associated with gains would be close to the firm's PiE multiplier. In a recent study, Basu (1994) provides evidence showing that the distribution of earnings and their relation with cash flows and returns are consistent with the presence of conservatism.

A complete examination of this explanation for the results would have to relate the incurrence of losses more closely to the application of the conserva- tism principle. A loss may not be the result of conservatism. Likewise, the application of conservatism does not usually result in a loss. Nonetheless, there are some indications in the data that conservatism is not a primary explanation for the results of this paper. For instance, the evidence on the persistence of losses mentioned in the previous se~,tion calls into question the notion that unfavorable developments are fully incorporated in earnings on a timely basis. Further, as discussed in Section 5.2, even when loss items that are the most typical outcome of applying conservatism to the financial statements (e.g., provisions for future losses, write-offs, and restructuring charges) are excluded from the sample of losses, the results remain intact.

5. 4. The irrelevance of earnings reported by growth companies

For companies in emerging, high-tech, growth industries, current earnings may not be indicative of their future prospects. Not only might current earnings

Z3From Table !, the unconditional probability of reporting a loss is 19.6% for the 1962-90 period. The probability of reporting a loss is 55.2%, given a loss in the previous year. The probability of reporting a loss given a loss in the previous two years increases to 68%.

Page 25: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1095) 125-1~3 |49

fail to convey the future growth potential of these companies but, further, the current earnings of these firms are likely to be distorted by the expensing of large intangible investments. 24 Since these circumstances often lead to losses, it might be argued that the low information content of losses is a reflection of a larger phenomenon, namely the irrelevance of earnings for growth companies, zs

To examine this explanation for the low informativeness of losses, all firms are ordered by their rate of annual growth in sales over the time period for which data exists. The firms are then partitioned into deciles, or portfolios, and regression (2) is estimated for the firm-years in each portfolio. The estimation is clone separately for firm-years with positive earnings and losses. If the 'growth" explanation is valid, the sign of reported earnings (positive or negative) should be equally irrelevant for the stock valuation of high growth companies. The results (not presented) show that the informativeness (measured by the E R C or the R 2) of positive earnings, as well as lo~ses, is not significantly different across growth portfolios. Further, within each growth portfolio, losses are significantly less informative than profits. These results are inconsistent with the growth explanation for the low informativeness of losses.

6. Conclusions

Losses have become very frequent: over 25% of the firms reported a loss in any given year in the last decade. This study hypothesizes that because share- holders hold a liquidation option, the informativeness of losses with respect to future cash flows of the firm is limited. Therefore, pooling profitable and loss observations in samples used by researchers to estimate the information content of earnings leads to a downward bias in :he estimated earnings response coefficient and the return-earnings association.

The results of the study are consistent with this hypothesis. The extent of the bias is considerable: Both the earnings response coefficient and the return- earnings correlation almost triple when loss cases are excluded. Further, the increase in the measured information content of earnings as the cumulation period increases reported by previous studies is related to the reduced frequency of aggregate losses as the measurement period lengthens. The findings of the study also suggest that some of the cross-sectional and intertemporal variation in the earnings response coefficient that is attributed to other factors (such as

Z'~Kim and Ritter { 1994) find tht the earnings of companies that have just gone public are of limited relevance for their stock valuation. Since many of these firms are high-tech, growth companies, the weak relationship between their earnings and stock prices may be a reflection of the earnings suppression experienced by these companies. ZSl thank Amy Sweeney for drawing my attention to this potential explanation.

Page 26: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

150 C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153

firm-size or variability of the firm's earnings) can be traced to the variation across firms and years in the frequency of losses.

These findings are consistent with the results of recent studies on the nonlin- ear relation between earnings and returns. Specifically, the return-earnings association appears to be weaker at the bottom of the earnings distribution. Yet, the weaker response to losses is only partially explained by the fact that losses tend to represent extreme earnings levels. Other explanations of the lower informativeness of losses, such as the higher risk of firms with losses or the presumed prevalence of transitory items in loss situations, are not supported by the data. The main explanation for the low informz.tion content of losses appears to be that shareholders have the option to liquidate the firm when the current losses are projected to perpetuate if the firm continues to operate. This finding is in line with recent research which suggests that the liquidation option is relevant for stock valuation and earnings informativeness.

r,,--, h . . . . . . . ..,b. ;~ ,,.*.*,~.4 to - ~ the extent to which losses and temporar- ily depressed earnings obscure or distort patterns of the cross-sectional variation in the return-earnings relation. More can be learned also about the degree of substitution between earnings numbers and alternative accounting variables in instances of reported losses. Preliminary results (not reported here) show that, in the presence of a reported loss, investors assign more weight to alternative accounting information in their evaluation of the firm's equit."

Finally, two observed phenomena remain without a satisfactory explanation: the increased frequency of losses and the decline in the earnings response coefficient over the last few decades. The intertemporal variation in the earnings response coefficient is only partially explained by the variability in the frequency of losses over time. Structural changes in the economy (resulting from the waves of mergers and acquisitions and the higher leverage levels of firms) and changes in accounting pnnciples (with a greater emphasis on mark-to-market ac- counting) are two possible explanations for these phenomena '_hat might be explored by future research.

Appendix

Estimation of the market value of the firm "s assets and identification of 'temporarily depressed" earnings

Temporarily depressed earnings are defined as positive earnings whose level is likely to be perceived by investors as temporary because their perpetuation is inferior to liquidating the firm. Specifically, earnings are considered temporarily depressed when the liquidation value of the firm exceeds its earnings-based value.

The liquidation value ofthefirm is the excess of the market (exit) value of the finn's assets over the firm's liabilities. The market ralue of the firm's assets is

Page 27: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153 |5i

estimated by adding the book value of current and intangible assets to an approximation of the market value of noncurrent operating assets. The market value of noncurrent operating assets is calculated by finding when these assets were purchased, and adjusting the book value of these, assets for inflation that has occurred since their purchase. The timing of the purchase is derived by taking the difference between the gross and net (after depreciation) balances of noncurrent operating assets, and dividing this difference by the depreciation expense for the year. Adjustment for inflation is made using the GNP deflator. The market value of the liabilities is assumed to be equal to their book value. The earnings-basedfirm value is the firm's earnings multiplied by the mean PiE ratio in the firm's (four-digit SIC code) industry at the end of the reporting year. 26

To illustrate the calculation of these values which are used to determine whether a firm's earnings are "temporarily depressed', consider the following data for Company Z reported for the end of 1991: earnings per share of $1.50, seven million shares are outstanding, the book value of equity is $140 million, the net book value of property, plant, and equipment (PPE) is $50 million, the average age of PPE is estimated to be five years, the cumulative increase in the GNP deflator over the five years from 1987 to 1991 is 32%, and the mean PiE of the company's industry is 14.0.

Computational procedure (1) To determine the liquidation value of the firm, an estimate of the replace-

ment cost (i.e., the estimate of the market value) of the PPE is derived by indexing the original cost of the PPE ($50 million) to the GNP deflator (32%), to yield $66 million.

(2) The adjusted equity value per share is found by adding the increase in the PPE ($16 million) to the book value of the equity (to obtain $156 million) and dividing the result by the number of shares (7 million). The result, $22.29, is the liquidation value per share.

(3) The earnings-based firm value is found by multiplying the EPS ($1.50) by the median PiE in the industry (14.0). This value is $21.

In this example, the earnings-based value of the company falls below its liquidation value. This level of earnings, which is estimated to have a capitalized value of $21 per share, is unlikely to be allowed to perpetuate since the shareholders would be better off liquidating the firm and recovering $22.29 per share from the proceeds. In other words, the earnings reported for 1991 are considered 'temporarily depressed'.

'°The median PiE in the industry was also used with very similar results.

Page 28: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

152 C Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153

References

Albrecht, W.S., L.L. Lookabill, and J.C. McKeown, 1977, The time-series prolyztties of annual earnings, Journal of Accounting Research 15, 226-244.

Ball, R. and R. Watts, 1972, Some time series properties of accounting income, Journal of Finance 27, 663-68 I.

Basu, S., 1994, Conservatism and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings, Working paper (University of Roche'_.ter, Rochester, NY).

Beaver, W.H., R.A. Lambert, and D. Morse, 1980, The information content of security prices, Journal of Accounting and Economics 2, 3-28.

Beaver, W.H., R.A. Lambert, and S.G. Ryan, 1987, The information content of security prices: A second look, Journal of Accounting and Economics 9, 139-157.

Berger, G.P., E. Ofek, and I. Swary, 1993, Investor valuation of firm assets as an abandonment put option, Working paper (University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, PA).

Beneish, M.D. and C.R. Harvey, 1994, The specification of the return-earnings relation, Working paper (Duke University, Durham, NC).

Bernard, V., 1989, Capital market research during the 1980"s: A critical review, Paper presented in honor of the University of Illinois Accountancy Ph.D. Program Golden Jubilee Symposium (University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign, IL).

Board, J.L.G. and M. Walker, I990, Inter-temporal and cross-sectional variation in the association between unexpected accountil~g rates of return and abnormal rates of return, Journal of Ac- counting Research 28, 182-192.

Brooks, L. and D. Buckmaster, 1976, Further evidence of the time series properties of accounting income, Journal of Finance, 31, 1359-1373.

Collins, D.W. and S.P. Kothari, 1989, An analysis of intertemporal and cross-sectional determinants of earnings response co¢ffic/ents, Journal of Accour.ting and Economics 11, 143-i81.

Collins, D.W., S.P. Kothari, and J. Rayhurn, 1987, Firm size and the information content of prices with respect to earnings. Journal of Accounting and Economics 9, 111-138.

Collins, D.W., S.P. Kothari, J. Shanken, and R.G. Sloan, 1994, Lack of timeliness and noise as explanations for the low contemporaneous returns-earnings association, Journal of Accounting and Economics 18, 289-324.

Das, S. and B. Lev, 1992, Nonlinearity in the returns-earnings relation, Working paper (University of California, Berkeley, CA).

DhaliwaL D.S. and S.S. Reynolds, 1994, The effect of the default risk of debt on the earnings response cocffic/cnt, The Accounting Review 69, 412-419.

Easton, P.D. and T.S. Harris, 1991, Earnings as an explanatory variable for returns, Journal of Accounting Research 29, 19-36.

Easton, P.D. and M. ZmijewskL 1989, Cross-sectional variation in the stock market response to accounting earnings announcements, Journal of Accounting and Economics 11, 117-141.

Easton, P.D., T.S. Harris, and J.A. Ohlson, 1992, Accounting earnings can explain most of securities returns: The case of long event windows, Journal of Accounting and Economics 15, 119-142.

Elliot, J.A. and W.H. Shaw, 1988, Write-offs as accounting procedures to manage perceptions, Journal of Accounting Research 26, 91-119.

Fisher, L., 1959, Determinants of risk premiums on corporate bonds, Journal of Political Economy, 217-237.

Foster, G., 1986, Financial statement analysis (Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, N J). Freeman, R.N., t987, The association between accounting earnings and security returns for large

and small firms, Journal of Accounting and Economics 9, 195-228. Frceman, R.N. and S. Ts¢, 1992, A non|inear model of security price responses to unexpected

earnings, Journal of Accounting Research 30, 185-209.

Page 29: Accounting &E nom - Aarhus Universitet · Accounting &E nom The information content of losses Carla Hayn Graduate Sckool of Maria+dement, University of California, Irvine, lrvine

C. Hayn / Journal of Accounting and Economics 20 (1995) 125-153 153

Freeman, R.N., J.A. Ohlson, and S.H. Penman, 1982, Book rate-of-return and prediction of earnirJgs changes: An empirical investigation, Journal of Accounting Research 20, 639-653.

Givoly, D. and C. Hayn, 1993, Transitory accounting items: Information content and earnings management, Working paper (Northwestern University, Evanston, IL).

Gonedes, N.J., 1975, Risk, information and the effects of special accounting items on capital market equilibrium, Journal of Accounting Research 13, 220-256.

Hoskin, R.E., J.S. Hughes, and W.E. Ricks, 1986, Evidence on the incremental information content of additional firm disclosures made concurrently with earnings, Journal of Accounting Research 24, 1-32.

Kaplan, R.S. and G. Urwit~ 1979, Statistical models of bond ratings: A methodological inquiry, Journal of Business 52, 231-261.

Kim, M. and J.R. Ritter, 1994, Earnings, book values and comparable firm multiples in the pricing of initial public offerings, Working paper (University of Illinois, Champaign, IL).

Korn~ndi, R. and R. Lipe, 1987, Earnings innovations, earnings persistence, and stock returns, Journal of Business 60, 323-345.

Kotbari, S.P., 1992, Price-earnings regressions in the presence of prices leading earnings, Journal of Accounting and Econonlics 15, 173-202.

Kotha~ S.P. and J.L. Zimmerman, 1994, Prices and return models, Working paper (University of Rochester, Roc}-~ter, NY).

Lamy, R.E. and G.R. Thompson, 1988, Risk premia and the pricing of primary issue bonds, Journal of Banking and Finance 12, 585-601.

Lev, B., 1989, On the usefulness of earnings: Lessons and directions from two decades of empirical research, Journal of Accounting Research 27, 153-201.

Lipe, R.C, 1986, The information contained in the components of earnings, Journal of Accounting Research 24, 37-64.

Lys, 1"., K. Ramesh, and S.R. Thiagarajan, 1993, The role of aggregate earnings in explaining long-window stock returns, Working paper (Northwestern University, Evanston, IL).

Myers, S.C. and S. Maid, 1990, Abandonment value and project life, Advances in Futures and Option Research, 1-21.

Ramakrishnan, R.T.S. and J.K. Thomas, 1993, Valuation of permanent, transitory and price- irrelevant components of reported earnings, Working paper (Columbia University, New York, NY).

Ramesh, K. and S.R. Thiagarajan, 1993, Estimating the permanent component of accounting earnings using the unobservable components model: Implications for price-earnings research, Journal of Accounting. Auditing and Finance, Fall, 399-425.

Ramesh, K. and S.R. Thiagarajan, 1994. Inter-temporal instability in earnings response coefficients, Working paper (Northwestern University, Evanston, IL).

Rayburn, J., 1986, The association of operating cash flow and accruals with security returns, Journal of Accounting Research 24, 112-133.

Robichek, A. and J. Van Home, 1967, Abandonment value and capital budgeting, Journal of Finance 22, 577-590.

Ronen, J. and S. Sadan, 1981, Smoothing income numbers: Objectives, means and implications (Addison-Wesley, Reading. MA).

Ronen, J. and G.H. Sorter, 1973, Relevant accounting. Journal of Business 46, 258-282. Subramanyan, K.R. and J.J. Wild, 1993, The going concern assumption and the informativeness of

earnings, Working paper (University of Wisconsin, Madison, Wl). Watts, R.L. and R.W. Leftwich, 1977, The time-series behavior of annual accounting earnings,

Journal of Accountirg Research 15, 253-271.