31
Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=recg20 Economic Geography ISSN: 0013-0095 (Print) 1944-8287 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/recg20 Accumulation by Decarbonization and the Governance of Carbon Offsets Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman To cite this article: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman (2008) Accumulation by Decarbonization and the Governance of Carbon Offsets, Economic Geography, 84:2, 127-155 To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1944-8287.2008.tb00401.x Published online: 22 Oct 2015. Submit your article to this journal Article views: 340 View related articles Citing articles: 55 View citing articles

Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

Full Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found athttp://www.tandfonline.com/action/journalInformation?journalCode=recg20

Economic Geography

ISSN: 0013-0095 (Print) 1944-8287 (Online) Journal homepage: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/recg20

Accumulation by Decarbonization and theGovernance of Carbon Offsets

Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman

To cite this article: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman (2008) Accumulation byDecarbonization and the Governance of Carbon Offsets, Economic Geography, 84:2, 127-155

To link to this article: https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1944-8287.2008.tb00401.x

Published online: 22 Oct 2015.

Submit your article to this journal

Article views: 340

View related articles

Citing articles: 55 View citing articles

Page 2: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

This article examines the governance of internationalcarbon offsets, analyzing the political economy of theorigins and governance of offsets. We examine howthe governance structures of the Kyoto Protocol’sClean Development Mechanism and unregulatedvoluntary carbon offsets differ in regulation and incomplexity of the chain that links consumers andreducers of carbon, with specific consequences forcarbon reductions, development, and the ability toprovide “accumulation by decarbonization.” We showhow carbon offsets represent capital-accumulationstrategies that devolve governance over the atmos-phere to supranational and nonstate actors and to themarket.

Adam G. BumpusEnvironmental Change

InstituteOxford University Centre

for the EnvironmentOxford UniversitySouth Parks RoadOxford OX1 3QYUnited Kingdomadam.bumpus@

ouce.ox.ac.uk

Diana M. LivermanEnvironmental Change

InstituteOxford University Centre

for the EnvironmentOxford UniversitySouth Parks RoadOxford OX1 3QYUnited Kingdomdiana.liverman@

eci.ox.ac.uk

Key words:carbon offsetsclimate changeClean Development

Mechanismneoliberalismpolitical economymarket environmentalism

abst

ract

Accumulation by Decarbonization and the Governance of Carbon Offsets

ECO

NO

MIC

GEO

GR

APH

Y84(2):127–155.©

2008 Clark U

niversity.—w

ww

.economicgeography.org

127

Page 3: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

128

Carbon offsets have emerged at the forefront ofdebates on strategies to mitigate climate change. Theyare seen as alternative or supplementary ways forindividuals, organizations, and governments to reduceemissions from their own households, operations, orcountries. The fundamental rationale conveyed by advo-cates of offsets is that paying for greenhouse reductionselsewhere is easier, cheaper, and faster than domesticreductions, providing greater benefits to the atmosphereand to sustainable development, especially when offsetsinvolve projects in the developing world.

The concept of offsets emerged in the KyotoProtocol’s flexible mechanisms (UN FrameworkConvention on Climate Change, UNFCCC 1997), whichallow industrialized countries to meet their emission-reduction targets by purchasing emission reductionsthat are associated with projects in the developing world(the Clean Development Mechanism, CDM) or easternEuropean economies in transition (Joint Implemen-tation). Together with carbon trading, these mechanismsprovide an alternative to more expensive or politicallydiff icult domestic emission reductions. A parallelmarket in voluntary carbon offsets (VCOs) has devel-oped beyond the regulated CDM, whereby individ-uals and organizations can compensate for their green-house gas emissions by purchasing carbon credits thatare generated by emission-reduction projects elsewhere.Thus, frequent fliers can “offset” their aviation emis-sions and companies can offset their energy use bypurchasing carbon credits that are generated by suchprojects as forest planting, renewable energy, biofuels,methane capture, energy-efficient wood stoves, andlighting (see Table 1). In this article, we examine theCDM and VCOs as essentially parallel markets oper-ating under the same conceptual basis, but with differentgovernance structures. These structures have implica-tions for economic geography because carbon emis-sions are emerging as a new and dynamic commoditythat links the global North and South, business enter-prises and consumers, and science and markets incomplex ways.

Offset projects have become a new source of fundingfor development and conservation in the global Southand a rapidly growing business opportunity for thosewho develop and broker projects and credits (Bayon,Hawn, and Hamilton 2007). The Kyoto Protocol’s CDMhas developed into a business that was worth more than$2.5 billion in 2005 and nearly $5 billion in 2006 (deWitt Wijnen 2006; World Bank 2006b, 2007b).International meetings, such as the G8 and Davos,

Acknowledgments

This article was written withthe support of an ESRC/NERC studentship award toAdam Bumpus and as part ofresearch for the TyndallCentre for Climate Change.We thank Emily Boyd, MaxBoykoff, Dan Buck, AmyGlasmeier, Mike Goodman,Heather Lovell, ScottPrudham, Sam Randalls,Timmons Roberts, EmmaTompkins, and two anony-mous reviewers for theircomments.

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Page 4: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

129

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Tab

le 1

Typi

cal T

ypes

of C

arbo

n O

ffset

Pro

ject

s U

nder

the

Cle

an D

evel

opm

ent

Mec

hani

sm (

CDM

) an

d Vo

lunt

ary

Carb

on O

ffset

s (V

COs)

Type

of P

roje

ct

Indu

stri

al g

asre

duct

ion

(e.g

.,H

FC23

,PF

C,N

20)

Met

hane

cap

ture

(CH

4)

Ren

ewab

le

ener

gyEn

ergy

effi

cien

cy

Fuel

sw

itch

Fore

stry

Not

e:D

ata

take

n fr

om U

NEP

-Ris

oe (

2007

);H

arri

s (2

006)

;Tai

yab

(200

5);S

ando

r,W

alsh

,and

Mar

ques

(19

99);

Clim

ate

Car

e (2

007a

);T

CN

C (

2007

).D

ata

are

avai

labl

e on

ly fo

r th

e C

DM

beca

use

of t

he u

nreg

ulat

ed n

atur

e of

the

VC

O m

arke

t at

the

tim

e of

wri

ting

(June

200

7).

Exam

ple

of P

roje

ct

Red

uce

and/

or d

estr

oy in

dust

rial

gas

es w

ith h

igh

glob

al w

arm

ing

pote

ntia

ls (

GW

P) a

sso-

ciat

ed w

ith c

hem

ical

and

man

ufac

turi

ng in

dust

ries

;3 p

erce

nt o

f pro

ject

s an

d 37

perc

ent

of t

otal

em

issi

on r

educ

tions

in C

DM

.

Met

hane

capt

ure,

flari

ng,o

r co

mbu

stio

n (fo

r en

ergy

),in

clud

ing

capt

ure

from

land

fills

,ag

ricu

ltura

l was

te,c

oal b

eds,

and

min

es.M

ostly

CD

M b

ut s

ome

VC

O.

Rep

lace

or d

ispl

ace

carb

on-in

tens

ive

ener

gy g

ener

atio

n (e

.g.,

bunk

er fu

els

in p

ower

stat

ions

) by

win

d fa

rms,

hydr

oele

ctri

c da

ms,

sola

r po

wer

,and

so

fort

h.C

DM

and

VC

O.

In la

rge

pow

er p

lant

s,ho

useh

olds

,and

indu

stry

.CD

M a

nd V

CO

,inc

ludi

ng e

nerg

y-ef

ficie

ntlig

ht b

ulbs

in h

ouse

hold

s an

d co

mm

uniti

es.

Switc

hfr

om h

ighe

r to

low

er c

arbo

n fu

els

(coa

l or

oil t

o na

tura

l gas

or

biom

ass)

,oft

en in

larg

e fir

ms

unde

r C

DM

with

som

e V

CO

.

CD

M is

affo

rest

atio

n an

d re

fore

stat

ion

for

CO

2 se

ques

trat

ion.

VC

O a

dds

fore

stpr

otec

tion.

Prin

cipa

l Geo

grap

hic

Prod

ucer

s

Chi

na,I

ndia

Chi

le,B

razi

l,C

hina

,M

alay

sia,

Indi

a,U

nite

dSt

ates

(V

CO

)In

dia,

Braz

il,C

hina

,M

exic

oBr

azil,

Chi

na,I

ndia

,So

uth

Afr

ica,

Car

ibbe

an,K

azak

hsta

n(V

CO

pro

ject

s)

Braz

il,In

dia,

Chi

na,

Sout

h K

orea

,Sou

thA

fric

a,Eg

ypt

Col

ombi

a,U

gand

a,In

dia,

Chi

na,M

exic

o

Num

ber

of P

roje

cts

(CD

M P

ipel

ine

Onl

y)

56 413

1,19

2

285 69 7

Kilo

tonn

es o

f CO

2eR

educ

ed p

er Y

ear

(CD

M O

nly)

1229

94t/

CO

2e

7227

3t/C

O2e

8214

7t/C

O2e

3988

6t/C

O2e

2446

4t/C

O2e

831t

/CO

2e

Page 5: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

and governments, such as those of the United Kingdom and Germany, are offsettingofficial travel and other operations to make themselves “carbon neutral” (Departmentfor Environment, Food and Rural Affairs, DEFRA 2006). A steady stream of criticalreports by nongovernmental organizations (NGOs) and the press about offsets have emergedover the past few years (Bond and Dada 2004; Lohmann 2001, 2005, 2006; Monbiot 2006;F. Harvey 2007), together with analytical publications on offsets from think tanks andworkshops (Carbon Trust 2006; Clean Air-Cool Planet 2006; International Institute forEnvironment and Development 2006; Kollmuss and Bowell 2006; U.K. EnergyResearch Centre, UKERC 2006) and a barrage of publicity from voluntary offsetcompanies themselves.

The geographic literature on offsets is thin; most academic articles have focused on theCDM and forest offsets (Brown and Corbera 2003; Backstrand and Lovbrand 2006;Jung 2005; Klooster and Masera 2000; May, Boyd, Veiga, and Chang 2004; Repetto 2001)or mentioned offsets or the CDM as part of more general analyses of climate gover-nance (Betsill and Bulkeley 2004, 2006; Bulkeley 2001; Bulkeley and Betsill 2005;Lindseth 2006; Newell 2000; Oels 2005; Paterson 1996, 2001).

However, Bulkeley (2005) showed how new forms of environmental governance arebeing scaled and rescaled through the issue of climate change to include new politics ofscale and the emergence of networks that include management from “state and non-stateactors [that] play a variety of roles” (p. 877). Liverman (2004) identified the commodi-fication of nature and the reworking of environmental governance as including consumers,corporations, environmental groups, and transnational institutions as key research agendasfor geography. Offsets sit at the juncture of these two themes in commodifying the atmos-phere with new governance mechanisms and creating markets among multiple actors, andconsequently pose interesting avenues of investigation in critical work in geography.Studying the creation, consumption, and governance of offsets is also a response to therecent call for an environmental economic geography and for a focus on regulation andnature under neoliberalism (Bridge 2002; Bridge and Jonas 2002; Gibbs 2006;Liverman and Vilas 2006; McCarthy and Prudham 2004).

We examine and compare the governance of carbon offsets as a first step in exploringthe role of offsets in reducing carbon emissions and increasing sustainable development,and the strategies of state and nonstate actors in the international climate regime.1 Weuse the term environmental governance to signify the broad range of political,economic, and social structures that shape and constrain actors’ behavior toward the envi-ronment (Jessop 1998; Levy and Newell 2005). We focus on offsets that involve actorsfrom a developed nation investing in projects in a developing nation and are thus concernedwith CDM and VCO projects that specifically channel finance from the global North tothe global South in return for carbon credits.

The article begins by discussing the origins, history, and emerging geography of carbonoffsets in climate change policy and then assesses some of the key steps and principlesin the commodification and trading of carbon credits. The core of the article is an analysisand comparison of the governance of offsets in the CDM and VCO sector. We then examinewho is able to profit from carbon offsets and the role of the state in regulating thecarbon offset market to ensure its stability and growth. Many of the examples that we citeare from the United Kingdom, which has become the center of carbon trading, hosting

130

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

1 Further analyses of carbon offsets are being undertaken through fieldwork in Honduras by Adam Bumpusand in a study of carbon-offsetting organizations by Diana Liverman and her colleagues at the Tyndall Centrefor Climate Change Research.

Page 6: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

the largest number of VCO companies, managing 50 percent of all capital in the carbonvalue chain (World Bank 2007b).

The article focuses on a structural analysis of relations among capital, the state, andother actors to show how the commodification of carbon has led to the creation of newmarkets that eliminate spatial constraints that are associated with distance, institutions,borders, and emissions reductions. It sets aside a discursive analysis of climate policy andthe associated governmentalities (Backstrand and Lovbrand 2006; Oels 2005), althoughthese approaches clearly provide a fruitful perspective on the issue of offsets. Instead, itis informed by political economy and broadly by critical geographers’ work on gover-nance and neoliberal natures. Climate change can be seen as both a threat to the accu-mulation of capital (from climate risks and expensive mitigation) and a new opportunityfor profit. On the one hand, conventional economics explains the business interest inreducing emissions by internalizing external costs, seeking competitive advantage viainnovation, and responding to the concerns of environmental groups, consumers, andinvestors (Newell 2000; Stern et al. 2006). On the other hand, critical political economyargues that environmental damages, such as those from global warming, undermine theaccumulation of capital and threaten profits (O’Connor 1998) and suggests that capitalturns specific instances of environmental degradation into opportunities for continuedprofit (Buck 2007; Bakker 2005). Critical social theory frames emission reductions as adiscursive and material response to public concern and pressure for regulation (a“double movement” per Polanyi 1944). Corporations are also concerned about scientificdevelopments that make it possible to attribute anthropogenic climate change and asso-ciated damages to the emissions of particular countries and corporations. The prospectof expensive lawsuits would provide yet another threat to accumulation (Allen 2003; Tang2005). Corporations may therefore advocate emissions reductions both as a protectionof their capital and as opportunities for profiting through lower carbon technologies andnew offset markets.

The Origins of Carbon OffsetsCarbon offsets allow carbon to be reduced by compensating for excess emissions in

one location through carbon reductions in another. Countries, companies, and individualshave decided to reduce carbon for reasons that include environmental concern, compet-itive advantage, regulations, and incentives, and they are interested in offsets as a cheaperalternative to expensive or difficult internal reductions. Partly because carbon offsetsare created by various individuals within companies and communities for reasons thatrange from pure profit motives and leadership aspirations to care for the planet andelimination of poverty, there is no consensus on the technical components or a generaldefinition of a carbon offset.

Creating Offset Markets: The Kyoto Protocol and the CDMCarbon offsets emerged from a market logic that has created a demand for and supply

of carbon reductions that can be priced and exchanged within the international climateregime through the binding targets and flexible mechanisms of the Kyoto Protocol orthrough the parallel market that links those who voluntarily want to compensate fortheir emissions by paying for emission reductions elsewhere. In generating a price forcarbon, it is argued, an incentive is created to reduce emissions as efficiently as possible(Ekins and Barker 2001; Weyant 1999). Rather than control emissions through command-and-control mechanisms, market instruments are seen as the most effective way to reduceemissions in line with the targets of the Kyoto Protocol. On the basis of U.S. convictions

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

131

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Page 7: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

that “cap and trade” had succeeded in reducing sulphur emissions and acid rain in NorthAmerica, the Kyoto proposal included an option for those who were able to meet andexceed their targets to sell excess reductions to those who were not able or willing to makethe reductions domestically (Liverman forthcoming). Carbon trading became the newestarena for a market environmentalism that assumes that the way to protect the environ-ment is to price nature’s services, assign property rights, and trade these services withina global market (Anderson and Leal 1991; Liverman 2004; Portney and Stavins 2000).

The formal demand for carbon reductions is driven by the commitments made by signa-tories to the Kyoto Protocol who agreed to reduce emissions from a 1990 baseline by, onaverage, 5.2 percent by 2012. The protocol went into force in February 2005, and inter-national carbon trading agreements have been in operation since the start of Europe-wideemissions trading in January 2005 and earlier voluntary domestic schemes (Johnson andHeinen 2004; Sandor, Walsh, and Marques 2002).

The Kyoto Protocol recognized that emission reductions in the industrial world wouldprobably be more expensive than reductions in the developing world and that if devel-oped countries were forced to meet their emission-reduction targets alone, they wouldface economic impacts because of the high marginal costs of reductions in domestic emis-sions (Gundimeda 2004). The CDM has its origins in the 1995 Activities ImplementedJointly (AIJ)2 pilot phase of the UNFCCC (Dolsak and Dunn 2006), which facilitatedthe first formal carbon offsets under the international regime. The AIJ phase became aplatform for developing carbon forestry and other emissions-reduction activities at a timewhen interest in creating markets for ecosystem services was growing (Corbera 2005).

The CDM formally allows credit for emissions-reduction projects in the developingworld under Article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol, which is the first time that internationalenvironmental law contains both provisions for private entities and actively generates anenvironmental commodity through market mechanisms (Bohringer 2003; Langrock, Arens,and Wiehler 2004). The CDM was designed to work with the private sector to promoteand enhance the transfer of, and access to, environmentally sound technologies [indeveloping countries] (UNFCCC 1997, article 10(c); Haites and Yamin 2000), and industryrepresentatives actively contributed to its design and establishment (International EmissionsTrading Association, IETA 2004; Kiss, Castro, and Newcombe 2002; Moorcroft, Koch,and Kummer 2000). The CDM was originally brought to Kyoto in 1997 as a fund tocompensate developing countries but was transformed into a market mechanism to provideindustrialized countries with carbon credits for investment in carbon reductions indeveloping countries (Liverman forthcoming).

VCOsVCOs emerged as a parallel to the Kyoto Protocol and the CDM, especially for compa-

nies and individuals in countries whose governmental policies were against the KyotoProtocol (e.g., the United States) and for those who wanted to go beyond what govern-ments were willing to do. Many of the first offset companies were nonprofit. Voluntaryoffsetting was seen to arise from frustration with the lack of state action—when govern-mental policies were perceived to be slow, inadequate, or nonexistent. Reflecting thesenotions, the company web sites include such comments as “carbon beyond Kyoto .|.|.Carbon for the Rest of Us” and “helping you help the climate” (V-Carbon News 2006;Climate Care 2007b). The VCO market has grown organically as a response to a perceived

132

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

2 AIJ was launched in 1995 as a “learning-by-doing” exercise for countries to work together on mitigationprojects, although AIJ did not formally provide credits for such activities.

Page 8: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

gap in the market for carbon, with over 61 different organizations and companies in theUnited Kingdom alone in 2007 (ECEEE 2007).

Initial offsets were created through voluntary partnerships between market environ-mentalist-oriented NGOs and large corporate entities (many of which were heavy emit-ters of carbon dioxide) to reduce the “carbon footprint” of investors for philanthropicand marketing reasons (Bayon, Hawn, and Hamilton 2007). The first VCO deal wasbrokered in 1989, when AES Corporation, a U.S.-based electricity company, invested inagro-forestry in Guatemala (Hawn 2005). Other early examples included the Face (ForestsAbsorbing Carbon Dioxide) Foundation, established in 1990 by the Dutch electricity-generating board to finance the growth of forests to sequester carbon dioxide, which werethen sold as credits to finance more forestry projects with carbon and sustainable devel-opment benefits in countries like Ecuador (Bumpus 2004; Face Foundation 2007).

By 2000, the World Bank’s Prototype Carbon Fund had channeled more than $180million into emission-reduction offset projects on behalf of 6 governments and 17 compa-nies (World Bank 2006a). The World Bank saw its role as “catalyzing markets for climateprotection and sustainable development” and now sports 11 different carbon funds thatare worth more than $1.9 billion (World Bank 2007a). Its “oiling of the wheels” hasencouraged ever-increasing involvement from the private-sector financial world in thefinancing, creation, and selling of carbon offset projects and carbon credits in the CDM(Carbon Finance 2006a). The active facilitation of the carbon markets by the WorldBank can be seen as part of the bank’s sustained project to support international flows of“natural capital” through its programs of “green developmentalism” in other natures(Goldman 2005; Kiss, Castro, and Newcombe 2002; McAfee 1999; Young 2002).

The Geography of OffsetsAlthough offsetting can easily occur through local exchange—a firm paying for a wind

farm in the next county, rather than reducing its own transport emissions, for example—the emerging geography of offsetting involves more complex and far-reaching spatial rela-tionships. The geography of offsetting is underpinned by the scientific rationale thatbecause greenhouse gases tend to mix throughout the global atmosphere, carbon reduc-tions may occur anywhere and still reduce overall concentrations with no relation tonational boundaries. Carbon reductions are like many other resources in that they can beexpensive to obtain locally and are often easier and cheaper in the developing world, whereindustrial processes are generally less efficient, forest offsets are more effective, oppor-tunities for implementing “cleaner” energy systems may be less costly, and labor and landare generally less expensive. However, carbon reductions as a resource show specificspatial distribution patterns and practices that are mediated by their particular environ-mental, socioeconomic, and political characteristics. These characteristics are now begin-ning to be explored in more depth (cf. Jung 2006; Sutter and Parreño 2007), but with littleattention to the political economy of where carbon emissions are reduced, how they areconverted to marketable commodities, and where they are consumed.

For companies and individuals who are concerned with sustainable development, offsetsin poorer, tropical countries may provide additional co-benefits, such as biodiversityconservation and community development (also recognized in the CDM). The spatialoutcome is that offset projects move to developing countries, transcending national bound-aries, and forming new networks and flows across space. Under the Kyoto Protocol, theflows were facilitated by pilot projects, the establishment of institutions for approvingprojects and registering credits, and an international regime that promoted trade in carbonby setting emission-reductions targets.

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

133

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Page 9: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

Economically, spatially differentiated emission-abatement costs mean that the KyotoProtocol’s suite of flexible mechanisms has the potential to support a cost-effective finalallocation of climate-change mitigation (Barrett 1998) that will minimize and harmo-nize “marginal abatement costs across space through the use of market-based instruments”(Bohringer 2003, 456; Copeland and Taylor 1994, 206). Carbon trading allows compa-nies to internalize the carbon externalities that may ultimately harm their long-term profitswhile providing opportunities for profit through the use of offsets in new global spaces.The World Bank (2006b, 35–39) reported that “[b]rokers, consultants, carbon procure-ment funds, hedge fund managers and other buyers scoured the globe for opportunitiesto buy credits associated with projects that reduce emissions in developing countries.”

Offsets can be seen as a “spatial f ix” in organizing costly emission reductionsthrough a geographic expansion of markets that provides cheaper alternatives in the devel-oping world as well as creative opportunities for some investors. Political economistswould argue that the use of this spatial fix to find cheap emissions reductions parallelsother ways that capital avoids economic crises under neoliberalism and enlists the devel-oping world in the pursuit of further accumulation as locally specific nature is incorpo-rated as new revenue streams (D. Harvey 2005; Jessop 1998; Katz 1998; Smith 1990,2007).

Issues in Commodifying CarbonFor carbon credits to be exchanged and generate revenue, carbon reduction must be

turned into a tradable commodity. Carbon markets are one more case in a long line ofconversions of parts of nature into tradable commodities, including water (Bakker2005), biodiversity (McAfee 1999), fish (Mansfield 2004), and wetlands (Robertson2004). Offsets are generally commodified into saleable units through the developmentof specific emission-reduction projects, the outputs of which can be quantified, owned,and traded. Examples include the growth of forests specifically to sequester carbon, theimplementation of micro-hydroelectricity to displace diesel generators, and the reductionof industrial gases in hydrofluorocarbon plants (see Table 1). The commodity “chain” caninclude owners of the land or facility where the project occurs, project developers andtheir local organizational partners, financial institutions and brokers who may hold thecarbon credits, and individual consumers, corporations, or countries who purchase thecredits.

Carbon relies on large amounts of scientific and political input for its commodifica-tion to take place. Carbon illustrates how “the power of bundling of nature into tradablebits of capital should not be underestimated, but nor should it be exaggerated. The neolib-eralization of nature is far from complete, not without its obstacles, and is anything buta smooth process” (Smith 2007, 21).

Despite differences in the governance structures of the CDM and voluntary offsets, thefundamental principles for creating carbon as a commodity are similar, although proj-ects vary considerably in the practical and material forms in which carbon credits arecreated in different places and converted into chunks of nature for sale (Castree 2003).3

The fundamental principles are that carbon reductions should be additional to a baselinelevel of emissions and should be abstracted and converted into units of carbon that canbe owned and traded.

134

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

3 A more detailed discussion of commodifying carbon is found in the papers from the June 2007 workshopon the Ethics of Commodifying Carbon (Environmental Change Institute, Oxford University, availableonline: http://www.eci.ox.ac.uk/publications/downloads/commodifycarb-report.pdf).

Page 10: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

Principles Underpinning Offsets: Additionality and BaselinesAs we mentioned earlier, there is no consensus on a general definition of a carbon

offset. However, in this article, we define a carbon offset as occurring when one actor(individual, company, NGO, or state) invests in a project elsewhere that results in a reduc-tion of greenhouse gas emissions that would not have occurred in the absence of theproject (WBCSD and WRI 2005). Carbon offsets therefore rely on “baseline-and-credit” trading systems that “create” assets (carbon credits) that represent the additionalcarbon reductions from a baseline of emissions and focus investment on emission-reduction projects that would not have otherwise taken place (Yamin 2005, 30). This isthe fundamental notion of “additionality,” which differentiates the emissions reductionsproduced by an offset project from the “business-as-usual” scenario of baseline emissionswithout the project (Michaelowa 2005).

The reductions achieved in carbon dioxide or other relevant greenhouse gases aredescribed as tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent (tCO2e).4 It is the ability to measure abaseline scenario against a “with-project” scenario that is essential, and it is this differ-ence (the “emissions reduction” in Figure 1) that allows the calculation of emissions reduc-tions created by the project. For every tonne of emissions that is reduced, a carbon creditworth a tonne of reduced carbon can be claimed. This calculation is essential if offsetprojects are to sell the carbon reductions (as carbon credits) from their activities.

Methodologies for understanding carbon reductions through baseline calculations areextremely complex. For example, it is difficult to determine accurately the amounts andsequestration of carbon in forests because of problems that include weather variations andmonitoring (Andersson and Richards 2001; Grace 2006; Richards and Andersson 2001).It is also difficult to estimate the carbon savings in projects that involve many small actions,such as the distribution of improved stoves or efficient light bulbs, because of differ-ences across households in successful uptake and the ability to monitor carbon reductions.

The additionality criteria for offsets are also controversial (Michaelowa 2005; Woerdman2000). Projects must be environmentally additional (they must reduce greenhouse gasemissions below what they would have been) and investment or economically additional

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

135

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Figure 1. Simplified principle of the baseline (adapted from Michaelowa 2005). The emissionsreduction gives the calculation for the amount of CO2e reduced as a result of the implementa-tion of the project.

4 Strictly speaking, tonnes are measured as tCO2e; however, common notation in the jargon of offset andemissions trading is tCO2e. For consistency, this notation is also used here.

Page 11: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

(they would not be financially attractive without the additional carbon finance that theoffset brings; but see Shrestha and Timilsina 2002). Both forms of additionality rely onproject developers describing counterfactual (nonexisting) future scenarios and thus areopen to exaggerated baselines and claims of emissions reductions that have not actuallyoccurred (i.e., no environmental additionality) or the possibility of projects generatingcarbon credits even though they would have happened anyway (i.e., no financial addi-tionality). The difficulty with this issue led the UNFCCC to create an “additionality tool”and many approved methodologies to help project developers negotiate the difficulty increating projects that “would not have happened anyway” and thus be able to generatecredits that are genuine additional emissions reductions (UNFCCC 2007a). Currently,additionality and baselines in the CDM are verified to a higher degree than VCOs, theo-retically producing more effective “conditions of reduction” for greenhouse gas emissions.

It has been claimed, however, that the CDM may fail to lead to additional emissionreductions (Muller 2007). These concerns have spilled over into the voluntary sector asconsumers demand evidence that the money they pay to offset their emissions is producinga real reduction in the risk of climate change with additional benefits to poor communi-ties. Specifically, concerns about the additionality of existing carbon offset projects, theaccounting of actual emissions reductions that are made, and the double counting of carboncredits that are produced (when more than one organization lays claim to the same emis-sions reduction) are key issues that undermine a robust offset strategy (POST 2007) andhave placed VCOs in the limelight for criticisms of carbon offsets.

Abstracting and Owning CarbonFor emissions reductions to be claimed through offsets, tonnes of carbon dioxide that

are reduced need to be assigned rights of ownership so that they can be traded as acommodity. Ownership can take a variety of different forms: a local community may ownand use the wood grown in a forest for carbon sequestration, but a foreign investor orproject developer may own the carbon reductions (as credits) created through the forest.Likewise the emissions from a polluting factory may “belong” to the factory owners,but the emissions equivalent values once reduced may then belong to another companythat implements the reductions as a carbon offset project.

Legal title for carbon reductions is usually provided by an emissions-reduction purchaseagreement (ERPA) signed by a buyer and seller of the tonnes of carbon that legallybinds the future rights of the carbon commodity, including “any right, interest, credit,entitlement, benefit or allowance to emit (present or future) .|.|. in connection with anyGHG [greenhouse gas] Reduction by the [CDM] Project” (IETA 2004, section 3.01). Thisagreement privatizes and discursively abstracts carbon, so that it can be traded as piecesof information (tCO2e) that are essentially its commodity form. In the VCO market, agree-ments may be less formal, with project developers simply claiming the rights to the infor-mation that is used to generate credits. Through projects, carbon is materially created insinks or destroyed in reductions, but eventually becomes a virtual commodity that isabstracted and transferred across space as a tonne of reduced carbon to be “consumed”by an organization that wants to compensate for emissions of equal value or to be placedinto markets for commensurable trading.

Carbon reductions are therefore “created,” given ownership, and abstracted from theirphysical site of reduction using ERPAs. In this way, carbon is individuated (separatedfrom its supporting context) involving a discursive and practical cut into the world inorder to name discrete chunks of reality that are deemed to be socially useful (Castree2003; D. Harvey 1974). An entity—such as a tonne of carbon—is also functionally andspatially abstracted as an individualized commodity that is assimilated to the qualitative

136

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Page 12: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

homogeneity of a broader type of process. For example, once a tonne of reduced carbonbecomes a credit, it is largely assumed to mean the same thing as other tonnes ofreduced carbon, despite the potentially different material circumstances (a forest comparedto a wind farm) in which they were produced. This abstraction of carbon echoes thework of Robertson (2004), who showed how individual wetlands are labeled as instanti-ations of the generic category of “wetlands.” Consequently, the generic cataloging of theirspecific services and functions acts to sever “the characteristic being measured from themessy uniqueness of the physical site” (p. 473).

Carbon is then also subject to valuation, to make it commensurable with other commodi-ties and the medium of money. The value of a credit depends on the market dynamics andvaries for CDM and VCO credits as they enter regulated markets and consumer-drivenmarkets, respectively. As with most markets, the price of carbon is mediated by supply anddemand. In the CDM, the demand is driven mostly by emissions-reduction targets thatinclude Kyoto commitments and corporate allocations within the European Union EmissionTrading Scheme (EU ETS—a multicountry, multisector greenhouse gas emission tradingscheme centrally administered by the European Commission), whereas in the voluntarymarket, values vary with transaction and project costs and what the market will bear.

Governing OffsetsThe creation, commodification, and trade of carbon offsets is governed by a series of

institutions and practices that have been established to track, trade, monitor, certify, andprice carbon across space. The governance of carbon offsets differs substantially betweenthose managed by international institutions under the CDM and those developed and soldin the VCO markets (see Table 2).

One important contrast (see Table 2) is the more formal and complex institutional struc-tures of the CDM compared to the VCO market. The CDM has mechanisms to definecredits strictly, establish standards of quality for projects’ design and methodologies(including those for additionality and baselines), and formalize documents to registerthe projects, including ERPAs. The VCO market is much more informal, with no stan-dard definition for credits, several voluntary standards only partially adopted, and indi-vidual contracts.

Table 2 also highlights other differences (described in greater detail later), such as thenature of the actors involved—primarily large companies and projects in the CDMcompared to more local projects that are often managed by NGOs in the voluntary sector.The overall governance structures of the CDM are under the oversight of the inter-governmental framework of the UNFCCC and its bureaucracy, especially the CDMExecutive Board, whereas the VCOs have no formal governance structure. In contrast tothe hierarchical and highly regulated structure of governance in the CDM, VCOretailers tend to rely on horizontal networks and local project implementers to createand sell carbon credits (Climate Care 2007a; The Carbon Neutral Company, TCNC 2007;Taiyab 2005). Table 2 also shows that the average current carbon prices are similar, despitethe higher transaction costs of the CDM. CDM prices have declined and are lower thanother prices in the formal carbon market because projects are considered risky and becauseof uncertainty about the use of carbon markets when the Kyoto Protocol’s commitmentperiod ends in 2012 (Carbon Finance 2006b).

Figure 2 illustrates the movement of carbon finance through the institutions and organ-izations that implement carbon offset projects, flows of carbon finance and carbon creditsthrough the CDM and VCO structures, and the resultant credits that are formed and chan-neled back through certain institutions to northern consumers of the credits. It shows the

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

137

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Page 13: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

138

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Table 2

Summary Table of Characteristics and Difference Between CDM and VCO Projects and Governance

Component of Offset

Type of credit

Overarching governancestructure

Standards

Legal structure anddocumentation

Retiring of credits (notto be resold)

Additionality and base-lines

Project implementationand actors

Transaction costs

Sellers of credits

Buyers of credits

Average price per tonneof CO2 equivalent

Note: Data were taken from Harris (2006);World Bank (2007b); Clean Air-Cool Planet (2006); and from semistruc-tured interviews with actors in the market during the course of fieldwork for the author’s DPhil on carbon offsetsconducted at the University of Oxford. Prices for CDM and VCO credits were taken from the World Bank (2007b)and Clean Air-Cool Planet (2006), respectively, and are accurate as of June 2007.

Clean Development Mechanism (CDM)

Certified Emissions Reduction (CER)

Kyoto Protocol, 1997, coordinated by theUNFCCC and its CDM Executive Board,which registers methodologies, projects,and third-party verifiers, and issues andtracks the movement of credits in theInternational Transaction Log.

Standards in the CDM are mandated andapproved by the UNFCCC. The supple-mentary premium standard includes theGold Standard with higher sustainabledevelopment attributes.

Standard Emissions Reduction PurchaseAgreements (ERPAs) contract forwardpurchases of CERs. Required ProjectDesign Documents (PDDs) describemethodologies for emission reductionsand calculate actual emissions reductions.ERPAs are normally private contracts,PDDs and methodologies are public onthe UNFCCC web site.

CERs are submitted to be retired forcompliance under the rules governing theKyoto Protocol and the EU ETS.

Detailed in PDD using guidance from theCDM Executive Board to show how theproject “would not have occurredanyway.”

Mostly large multinational companies(dedicated developers of carbon offsetprojects or companies with a specificunderstanding of a technology, e.g., windor hydro power).

Higher: complex paperwork and validationand verification of projects to attainCDM registration.

Project development companies, interme-diary brokers (carbon traders, banks, andfinancial institutions), developing-countrygovernments (e.g., China).

Governments and large-scale private-sectoremitters with commitments to the KyotoProtocol and/or the EU ETS, brokers andtraders, carbon funds, someNGOs/companies. Some credits beingsaved for the first commitment period ofthe Kyoto Protocol in 2008–2012.

$10.90

Voluntary Carbon Offsets (VCO)

No standardized definition. Terms includeVerified Emission Reduction,VoluntaryEmission Reduction, and VoluntaryCarbon Unit.

No formal or general structure. Overallgovernance of each offset project isdecided upon by the actors that imple-ment the project, including NGOs,companies, and individuals.

No mandated standard. The VoluntaryCarbon Standard and voluntary GoldStandard are not used by all projectdevelopers. An optional code of practiceis available from the U.K. government.

Private contracts link project developersand credit buyers. Although similar toERPAs, contracts vary due to the smalleror more informal nature of VCOs.

PDDs sometimes used, but VCOs do notneed to document their methodologies,carbon-accounting procedures, orproject designs transparently.

The retirement of credits is set and moni-tored by individual offset companies orthrough optional registries.

Additionality and baselines may or may notbe explicitly described in project docu-mentation.

Projects implemented by local companiesor NGOs working in developing coun-tries with financial and technical assis-tance and onward sale by northerncompanies.

Lower: no formal registration requirement,no need to use officially accredited third-party verifiers.

Voluntary offset retailers, some larger-scalefunds (e.g., Climate Wedge).

Companies not covered under the KyotoProtocol or EU ETS regulation (e.g., inthe United States), companies andgovernments going beyond formal obliga-tions, individuals, community organiza-tions, NGOs.

$10.00

Page 14: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

geographic and institutional connections across space and the connections that consti-tute the multilevel governance of offsets through a variety of scales and actors (cf.Betsill and Bulkeley 2006). Figure 2 is conceptual and only hints at the detailed link-ages and connections of governance that differentiate the two types of offsets, to whichwe now turn.

Governing the CDMThe arrows in Figure 2 show how the governance of offsets in the CDM is mediated

by national and supranational institutions and is hierarchical. CDM projects must be regis-tered at the supranational level of the UNFCCC, and carbon finance can be channeledthrough private-sector or World Bank carbon funds, which then finance offset projectsin the developing world. Projects are created in developing countries either by interna-tional companies that specialize in developing projects, local companies that may tap intonew sources of carbon f inance, or a combination of the two. For a country to beinvolved with the CDM, it must be a signatory to the Kyoto Protocol. Developing coun-tries must set up a governmental institution (called a Designated National Authority, DNA),that certifies in writing that a CDM project “assists in achieving sustainable development”

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

139

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Figure 2. A conceptual diagram to illustrate the flows of financial capital from developed coun-tries to developing countries and the resultant flows of carbon credits from developing todeveloped countries. The shaded arrow running through the global areas of the figure repre-sents finance for the CDM, while the clear arrow running through the same area represents CERsgenerated by the CDM.The shallower arrows represent VCO carbon finance and resultant credits.This diagram does not represent all of the linkages among organizations or the fact that someorganizations (such as development or carbon offset NGOs may span both developing countries),but it illustrates the differences in complexity that carbon finance/credits flow through for CDMand VCO projects.

Page 15: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

under UNFCCC treaty requirements (Kenber 2004; UNFCCC 1997, 2001). Countriesthat want to facilitate the flow of carbon finance may interpret the sustainable develop-ment criteria loosely (Liverman forthcoming).

Once the offset project is up and running (e.g., a hydroelectric plant starts generatingelectricity), the resultant carbon credits (CERs) are then listed in the InternationalTransaction Log (ITL, which is due to be fully operational by April 2009; Carbon Finance2007a), hosted by the UNFCCC, and recorded into funds (like the World Bank’s) and theninto holding accounts of northern governments that can use the credits as compliance withemissions reductions under the Kyoto Protocol. The ITL is critical to the successful transferof credits across the world from developing to developed countries and from nationalregistries into holding accounts for buyers (Howard 2005). It represents a supranation-ally imposed “customs check” on the movement of credits and was created to provide atransparent and efficient mechanism to “move” virtual credits in the form of informa-tion and to safeguard the “integrity of Kyoto Protocol accounting” (Howard 2005) toand from accounts across space. The ITL is a representation of the regulatory hold thatis taken over the CDM and its credits to ensure that the system is not defrauded and tomaintain the market’s value.

Although the CDM was set up as an intergovernmental structure under an internationaltreaty, nonstate private-sector actors are critical to its governance and functioning throughthe creation and third-party validation and verification of CDM projects and the creditsthey produce. A host of companies have stepped up to take advantage of the commodi-fication of carbon to obtain new revenue streams from the identification, monitoring, andtrading of carbon project credits. However these companies, integral to the process ofcalculating emissions reductions and commodifying carbon, do not operate within a regu-latory vacuum. Instead, they are highly regulated by the CDM Executive Board and ulti-mately the intergovernmental decision-making forum of the climate change convention:the Conference of the Parties to the Climate Change Convention and the Meeting of theParties to the Kyoto Protocol.

As one example, the El Canada hydroelectric project in Guatemala used the WorldBank Prototype Carbon Fund to channel investment from the Kyoto Protocol signatoriesCanada and the Netherlands to a local company (Generadora de Occidente) that wasreplacing fossil fuel with hydro-generated electricity at a rate of about 100,000 tCO2eper year. The UNFCCC accredited company, Det Norske Veritas, verified the environ-mental and developmental benefits, and a letter of approval was provided by the Guatemalangovernment. Although some local actors and international NGOs questioned the addi-tionality of the project (claiming it was already under way), the overall project was acceptedfor CDM registration (Vasudev, Godinez, and Telnes 2005) and submitted to the UNFCCC,to be used for compliance with the Kyoto Protocol between 2008 and 2012.

Thus, the CDM exhibits multilevel governance structures that incorporate private-sectorand supranational actors that govern both in the movement of finance across space to fundprojects and in the tracking of carbon credits back to the developed-country financiersof the offset projects.

Governing the VCO MarketThe governance of the VCO market, in contrast to the CDM, is much more horizontal

and network oriented in its implementation. Companies or NGOs sell carbon credits asoffsets to consumers and companies that are currently outside formal emissions-reduc-tion regulation. To source credits, VCO retailers form networks across space to environ-ment and development NGOs or companies that may be able to produce projects locallyto reduce emissions (Clean Air-Cool Planet 2006). Some offset providers put out calls for

140

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Page 16: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

carbon projects and offer carbon finance as a reward for the best projects in developingcountries (Climate Care 2007a), while some project developers work across both devel-oping and developed world spaces, sourcing credits for both the CDM and VCOs(TCNC 2007). With growing awareness of opportunities for carbon finance, local commu-nities and NGOs may seek out VCO providers and suggest projects. Unlike actors workingwithin the structure imposed by the CDM market, VCO developers or retailers can useflexible practices through horizontal networks across space to obtain projects and ulti-mately generate credits (Taiyab 2005). VCO projects commodify carbon and send thecredits as pieces of information (the amount of CO2e reduced) back through the networksthat provided the carbon finance to fund the project.

These more horizontal networks are illustrated in Figure 2 by the shallower arrows thatlink carbon finance from consumers and developed-country VCO retailers to organiza-tions in developing countries and generate carbon credits flowing back to the developedcountry through the same (or similar-level) organizations. The more direct and horizontallinks are one of the main differences between the structure and regulation in the twodifferent markets listed in Table 2: VCOs operate without reference to higher institutionallevels of governance and free themselves from national boundaries or spatial constraintsas they transmit carbon finance and then carbon credits (as information) through nonstateactors outside any formal regulatory environment.

For example, the VCO company, Climate Care, provides finance to an Indian NGO,the Prakratik Society, for biogas digesters to convert cow dung to cooking gas, thus reducingcarbon emissions from burning wood and with side benefits in reduced air pollution andlabor time. Records are kept by another local NGO (Women for Sustainable Development),which provides data to Climate Care, which then calculates the emission reductions andsells the carbon credits to the U.K. Cooperative Bank (Climate Care 2007b).

Thus, carbon finance and information flow across the world to “generate” credits in anetwork of often-small private organizations and NGOs without reference to national orsupranational bodies or “higher levels” of administration (cf. Arts 2004). VCO relation-ships are a complex reciprocal interdependence of projects that are managed by partnersin Europe and Africa, Latin America and Asia. The governance of VCOs could thereforebe seen as a form of horizontal linking through heterarchy whereby institutions and systemsare operationally autonomous from one another, yet structurally coupled because of theirinterdependence (Jessop 1998) through carbon finance and the production of carbon credits.

Accumulation by Decarbonization and Carbon Offsets:Who Benefits?

The emerging literature on the ethics and economics of the climate and carbontrading regime suggests that the costs and benefits of climate policies may not beequally distributed (Adger, Paavola, Huq, and Mace 2006). The Kyoto negotiations inthemselves benefited certain countries that were able to meet their commitments fairlyeasily because of industrial restructuring (such as the United Kingdom and Germany) orto negotiate stable or increased emissions (such as Russia and the countries of EasternEurope). Russia gained enormous potential for windfall projects in signing the KyotoProtocol with a zero emission-reduction commitment and because economic declinefollowing the collapse of the Soviet Union brought a 38-percent drop in emissions thatcould provide more than $10 billion in tradable carbon credits (Victor, Nakićenović, andVictor 2001; Point Carbon 2006). Similar benefits were obtained by European compa-nies that were given generous permits to emit carbon dioxide in the EU ETS and wereable to sell any excess over required reductions (European Climate Exchange 2006).

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

141

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Page 17: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

These profits from carbon trading are examples of the accumulation possibilities offeredby the new carbon economy, not only through the sales of lower carbon technologies,but in the particular ways in which permits to emit carbon have been negotiated and theconditions for its exchange have been regulated.

Offsets provide further opportunities for accumulation under the CDM because theCDM allows emission reductions to be made more cheaply by investing in other coun-tries. In effect, capital can achieve higher rates of accumulation under carbon tradingbecause it needs to invest less in domestic emission reductions. Credits created by theCDM are valued less than those created in the industrialized North because of the perceivedrisks and costs of creating carbon in the developing South. Although logical accordingto finance and investment markets, this valuation can also be seen as a form of unequalexchange in which commodities that are produced in the South are priced at less thanthose in the North (D. Harvey 2006). The North–South exchange within the CDM andVCO markets, while economically rational to some, can be seen as a case of unfairterms of trade and of powerful countries and carbon traders extracting the low-hangingfruit of cheap carbon reductions from the developing world.

Carbon offsets may be seen as an example of what D. Harvey (2005) called the redis-tribution of wealth through “accumulation by dispossession,” based on earlier models ofthe conversion of collective property, such as common land to private ownership and colo-nial takeover of natural resources facilitated by the state through law and military authority.New forms of dispossession, according to Harvey, include patent rights and bioprospectingand privatization of public utilities through four key steps: privatization and commodifi-cation, financialization (especially through speculative trading fees), the management ofcrises in the interests of the private sector, and the state acting as the agent of redistrib-ution and regulation.

Given the considerable profits to be made from trading in carbon reductions, offset-ting and other profits from emission reductions can be seen as a form of “accumulationby decarbonization.” In the case of offsets, it is the rights to emit carbon (pollution permitsgiven to industrial countries and companies under the Kyoto Protocol and the EU ETS)and carbon reductions (through CDM carbon projects) that become commodified andprivatized, traded with transaction fees, and allocated and regulated by international andstate institutions under conditions of unequal exchange between developed and devel-oping countries, northern companies and southern communities (Roberts and Parks 2007).In what some see as the unequal distribution of rights to pollute the atmosphere (Agarwaland Narain 1991) and in creating a system that provides credit for low-cost carbon-reduc-tion projects in the developing world, the international climate regime may be seen tofollow the pattern of accumulation by dispossession. Communities in the South are crit-ical of offsets and emissions trading because of unequally distributed benefits from offsetprojects, neocolonial approaches to property rights, and the sense that the North willcontinue to consume and use the South as a pollution dump (SinksWatch 2004a; Lohmann2006).

Carbon trading through the CDM created new investment opportunities for thedevelopment and brokering of projects that would generate carbon credits and accumu-lation for new carbon entrepreneurs. Enthusiasm for the carbon markets is increasinglydriven by market actors who see possibilities for both direct investment in offset proj-ects and indirect opportunities for commodification in secondary markets, such asverification of reductions, derivatives, and insurance associated with trading in emis-sions (Paterson 2005; Stern et al. 2006). This enthusiasm can also be found in thedeveloping world by governments that are keen to attract investment to their countriesand by environmental groups that are seeking funds to protect forests and provide renew-

142

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Page 18: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

able energy.5 The commodification of carbon and the generation of carbon credits throughthe CDM and voluntary carbon offsets have resonance with other projects, such as debt-for-nature swaps, eco-tourist ventures, and organic agriculture, that have demonstratedthat the principles of market environmentalism can be realized empirically in a range ofdeveloping world circumstances (Castree 2003).

Accumulation by decarbonization is present in both the CDM and VCO, with the WorldBank (2007b) estimating that the value of carbon trading was almost $30 billion in2006, three times greater than the previous year. The design and implementation of newCDM projects has spurred the creation of successful companies that are dedicated entirelyto the CDM portion of the carbon market that transacted $2.7 billion in 2005 and morethan $5 billion in 2006 (World Bank 2007b; see Figure 3). The voluntary market for reduc-tions by corporations and individuals also grew to an estimated $100 million in 2006(World Bank 2007b). The geographic locus of the carbon economy is in Europe, with 86percent of all CDM investments registered; the United Kingdom and the Netherlandsled the market with nearly 50 percent and 28 percent of project-based volumes in June2007, respectively (UNFCCC 2007b; World Bank 2007b). The City of London has becomea focal point for the world of carbon trading (World Bank 2007b), with existing finan-cial institutions opening trading desks specifically to profit from emerging and existingcarbon markets.

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

143

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Figure 3.Tonnes of CO2e reduced through CDM and VCO projects over time, 2004–2012. CDMCER volumes are from the World Bank (2006b, 2007b). Estimates for 2012 CER volumes arefrom UNFCCC data and relate to projects that were registered as of June 2007 (total expectedCERs from projects in the pipeline in June 2007 will amount to more than 1,900 million tonnesby 2012; UNFCCC 2007).VCO volumes were taken from Hamilton, Bayon, Turner, and Higgins(2007) and refer to survey data including and excluding extreme values in VCO mean and VCOmean excluding extremes, respectively.

5 This point was highlighted by representatives from Kenya’s Green Belt Movement at a Tyndall Centre debateon carbon offsets (Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research 2007).

Page 19: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

The economic logic of offsets means that investment in the CDM follows the avenuesto the most profitable geographic locations. As Jung (2006) noted, the scope of cheapemissions reductions, the institutional capacity of a host country to process CDM deals,and the climate of that country for foreign investment all affect the attractiveness of CDMinvestors to specific countries. Although the United Nations’ (UN’s) Marrakech Accordsemphasize the importance of an “equitable geographic distribution of CDM project activ-ities at regional and sub regional levels” (UNFCCC 2001), Asia and Latin America domi-nate inward investment in the mechanism, holding 68.8 percent and 27.5 percent of thetotal CDM projects, respectively, while Sub-Saharan Africa attracted only 1.3 percent ofthe total number of projects in June 2007 (UNEP-Risoe 2007). As a result of this distri-bution, the second objective of the CDM, to promote sustainable development in devel-oping countries, has not been effective in including the least-developed countries.

The VCO market has grown organically in response to the increased demand for carboncredits outside the Kyoto Protocol systems (V-Carbon News 2006). The VCO sector iscurrently guided by a number of for-profit and not-for-profit organizations in the UnitedStates and Europe (Harris 2006; Sterk and Bunse 2004) that invest in carbon-reductionprojects mainly in the developing world and then sell the resultant emissions credits toconsumers in the developed world (see Figure 2). Investment in VCOs depends solelyon the spatiotemporally volatile nature of consumer demand.

Despite this potential volatility, the VCO market is growing at an exponential rate.Harris (2006) reported that the annual growth in the market is 150 percent and othershave noted that volumes may reach 390 to 1,296 MtCO2e by 2012 (Hamilton, Bayon,Turner, and Higgins 2007; see Figure 3). The earlier not-for-profit organizations arenow being joined by private-sector, for-profit organizations (Bayon, Hawn, and Hamilton2007), including institutional investors in VCOs (Molitor 2006) and companies like aLondon taxi firm that secured $6.4 million (£3.2 million) worth of business for going“carbon neutral” through offsets in 2005 (Nunan 2005). Organizations are positioningthemselves to take advantage of the commodification of carbon because the creation,transfer, and sale of carbon, even without the threat of regulation, make money.Accumulation by decarbonization is the fundamental rationale for the increasing marketparticipation in offset mechanisms.

Of course, local companies and residents in the developing world may also benefit fromoffset projects through employment opportunities (e.g., planting trees and work on renew-able projects), direct payments (e.g., for forest carbon services), and savings and healthbenefits from more efficient stoves and lights. But others may be losing rights to the useof land and water and lack information or skills to allow them to demand high prices fortheir carbon reductions.

The carbon markets and the CDM show that with strong state interventions and theinternalization of harmful environmental externalities, capital can continue to accumu-late from reducing levels of carbon in the atmosphere (de Witt Wijnen 2006; World Bank2007b). The way in which the rights to carbon emissions and reductions have beenallocated provides enormous benefits to some—industrial countries and firms with highlevels of pollution in 1990 and easily achieved efficiencies, for example—but disad-vantages others who were more efficient or less powerful in negotiations or were willingto assign their carbon rights to others at a low cost—such as forest owners in the developingworld.

144

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Page 20: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

Regulating CarbonCarbon offsets follow the logic of other privatizations and commodifications in requiring

state intervention to establish and regulate new markets and stabilize capital investmentsin nature (Bakker 2005). Carbon offsets may be seen as a case of neoliberal environmentalgovernance in which the management of an environmental problem is partly devolved tothe market and to the individual but in which the state eventually establishes the rulesunder which markets operate.

The CDM can be seen as a good example of what Peck and Tickell (2002) called rolloutneoliberalism, in which the state intervenes to allocate and secure private propertyrights, provide scientific knowledge, or create stable market institutions (Bakker andBridge 2006; Brenner and Theodore 2002; McCarthy and Prudham 2004; McCarthy 2005;Tickell and Peck 2003, 19–20). For the CDM, the role of the state unfolds at a range ofgeographic scales, from local governance at project-implementation sites in developingcountries to transnational trades of carbon in Europe. Such rollout neoliberalism alsooccurs in a variety of institutional sites, such as in the DNAs that approve the sustainable-development value of projects, in the spaces for local comment on projects, in the insti-tutional carbon funds (World Bank 2007a), and in the international governing bodies ofthe UN.

Rollout neoliberalism in the CDM operates in the Executive Board as representativesof state-led negotiation processes help determine the allocation of emissions reductionsto various actors (state and nonstate). Similarly the Methodologies Panel provides scien-tific input to individual CDM projects (UNFCCC 2007a). Both are aimed at stabilizingthe market to allow its continued functioning. The CDM therefore also represents a rescalingof governance to “glocalized” sites, where local and nonstate actors take control of thelocal implementation of projects, and supranational governmental organizations set upmechanisms and ensure credibility and effective functioning. Regulation of the CDMimposes rigor on the quantification and commodification of carbon reductions, attemptingto ensure that “what you see is what you get” for market buyers.

In contrast to the extensive and formal regulation of the CDM, the nonstructure of theVCO market means that a wide variety of organizations provide a variety of credits thathave different types of verification for carbon reductions, ranging from internal self-veri-fication to full third-party verification and monitoring by UN-accredited companies(Bayon, Hawn, and Hamilton 2007; Harris 2006; Taiyab 2005). This nonstructure hasled to a dispersed and nonstandardized market that has had difficulty proving actual carbonreductions and demonstrating the benefits of one retailer over another. The lack of stan-dards, uniformity, transparency, and registration in the voluntary market has led to criti-cism and skepticism that VCO credits may not represent actual environmental andsocial progress, creating a media and public backlash against offsets, posing risks to thereputations of companies that buy carbon credits, and creating financial crises for thosethat sell VCO credits or depend on their income streams (Bayon, Hawn, and Hamilton2007; Lohmann 2001; “Upset with Offsets” 2006; F. Harvey 2007; “CO2onned” 2006;SinksWatch 2004b). As a result, VCO retailers have attempted to legitimize their carbongovernance by forming relationships with respected environmental individuals and steeringgroups (Climate Care 2005; Targetneutral 2006) and by linking with research organiza-tions to define standards and source projects (TCNC 2005).6

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

145

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

6 Both authors have provided some advice to VCO providers, specifically to Oxford-based Climate Care, anda quote from Liverman appears on that company’s web site.

Page 21: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

There has also been a change in cooperation between capitals that are involved in themarket, manifesting itself in the consultation and implementation of self-imposed stan-dards as a form of self-regulation. These standards lay out expectations for both carboncounting and sustainable development, addressing such issues as additionality,excluding the more controversial forest projects, and requiring local input into definingsustainable development.

The creation of a collaborative Voluntary Carbon Standard (VCS) and its consultativeprocess represents a form of collective governing structure that is steering the industryin a direction that is deemed to be mutually beneficial and echoes other patterns of gover-nance under neoliberalism (Jessop 1998, 2002). The process of creating the VCS includes“the full range of stakeholders: project developers, buyers, sellers, financiers, researchers,verifiers and NGOs” and aims to “give confidence to all stakeholders” by providing a“set of criteria that will provide integrity to the voluntary carbon market” (Climate Group2006). Other standards have also been developed, including the Gold Standard, whichprovides a benchmark on sustainable development for the CDM and has a parallel schemefor the voluntary market. A premium price is claimed for buyers or sellers of credits thatexhibit the standard, demonstrating a demand in the market for “boutique” carboncredits (“The Gold Standard for Voluntary Offsets” 2006; UKERC 2006).

As we noted earlier, the United Kingdom is one of the world centers of carbontrading, and the U.K. media have provided some of the most destabilizing critiques ofvoluntary offsets. Just as retailers were attempting to self-regulate, the U.K. governmentstepped in to provide a “code of practice” for the VCO market (DEFRA 2008), proposingthat the only safe carbon credits are those that are created and validated in the CDM orretired from the EU ETS. This proposal created dismay among some voluntaryproviders who believe variously that the CDM does not promote sustainable developmentand is too costly or that the EU ETS is little more than a mechanism for providing wind-fall profits to utilities and other corporations (UKERC 2006). This intervention by theU.K. government to guide voluntary offsetting could be seen as a step toward the furtherstandardization and legitimization of the markets, following a Polanyian notion of callingforth regulation from the state to regulate the unchecked commodification of fictitiouscommodities (Low 2002; Mansfield 2004; McCarthy and Prudham 2004). State media-tion of governance systems can be seen as inherently part of the neoliberal turn toward“the market solution” and partnership-based forms of governance that shape the contextwithin which heterarchies, including partnerships, can be forged (Jessop 2002). Thecode of practice for VCOs, rather than prescribing exact regulation, provides a frameworkwithin which partnerships can develop.

Despite these attempts to manage the market, carbon credits as commodities generatedby offset projects are continually destabilized, even in the markets regulated by the EuropeanCommission or the Kyoto Protocol. One example was the collapse of carbon prices inthe EU ETS when it was revealed that permits had been overallocated, making reductionseasy and reducing the demand for carbon credits. Because of the global links in the carbonmarket, this destabilization caused a consequent drop in the price of CERs that are gener-ated through CDM projects (Carbon Finance 2006b). Political uncertainty about the shapeand role of carbon markets after 2012 also reduces the price of CERs and worries actorsthat are attempting to use the markets for compliance and capital gain (Carbon Finance2006c). CER prices have been reported to be as low as $3 or as high as $24 per tCO2e;however, prices for 2006 averaged $10.90 (World Bank 2007b). Prices for CDM creditsare low because of the risks that are associated with the nondelivery of CERs and thedifficulty in generation and commodification. For example, a number of CDM projectshave failed to deliver the credits they promised owing to unforeseen difficulties (e.g.,

146

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Page 22: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

forests burning down, less methane capture or energy generation than predicted; seeCarbon Finance 2007b). The institutions that govern carbon reductions (from market struc-turing to creating material projects to the marketing and selling of reductions) define thevalue placed on a tonne of carbon that is reduced. However, in this case the economicvalue of the environment is not simply for the resources it provides, but for the protec-tion of the biosphere through a reduction in the risk of climate change as a whole. Thisbroader implication reworks the value of an environmental resource that contributes towider environmental protection and has important ramifications for an environmentaleconomic geography.

The VCO markets are somewhat insulated from the CER price drops because of theirseparate consumer-driven voluntary supply-demand dynamic, but some VCO retailersoffer boutique CERs to rely on secondary benefits, such as high sustainable develop-ment attributes to transcend market fluctuations (Atmosfair 2007). The prices of VCOretailers vary from about $0.50 to $40 per tCO2e, depending on buyers’ preferences forsecondary benefits and small volume premiums (Harris 2006), with VCO retailers relyingheavily on their own reputations to maintain confidence in buyers (Taiyab 2005). Thus,although regulation may provide some protection to prices, fictitious commodities thatare created through offsets, market dynamics, and buyers’ opinions still show that thecarbon-governance systems that are in place are far from stable and constantly requireconscious management to function.

ConclusionsCarbon offsets raise many interesting questions for an environmental economic geog-

raphy in illustrating the creation of a new commodity and market linking the North andSouth and the negotiation of a new set of institutions and regulations to govern the produc-tion and exchange of emissions reductions. We have provided an introduction to theenvironmental economic geographies of offsetting, including an interpretation of theirorigins and the process by which carbon reductions have become commodified and tradedinternationally. Key steps in the process include the definition of baselines and addi-tionality in quantifying a carbon reduction and the allocation of rights, legal contracts,and values in converting carbon reductions to generic tradable carbon.

We suggest that the political economy of offsetting produces highly unequal geogra-phies that link permits to pollute and international treaty commitments and regulationsto opportunities to obtain cheap, compensatory, carbon-reduction projects in the South.A key objective was to explore and compare the emergence of two parallel governancesystems—the formal CDM governed by the UN and the more informal VCO markets.

The CDM is governed by a set of international institutions, including the UNFCCCand World Bank, and is hierarchical, with tight regulatory structures, extensive knowl-edge requirements for achieving greenhouse gas reductions, and higher transaction costs.It is mostly in larger and more industrialized developing countries, such as China andIndia, and involves actors that include nation-states, large carbon project-developmentcompanies, and companies that are formally regulated under the European and other regu-lated trading schemes. VCO governance is more horizontal and networked, with littleregulation and highly varied technical and geographic activities involving individuals,NGOs, and socially responsible firms that are seeking green credentials. These gover-nance systems have created considerable opportunities to reduce concentrations of green-house gasses, to contribute to sustainable development through offsets, and to providepossibilities for accumulation in the profits from the development of carbon projects

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

147

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Page 23: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

and trading in offsets and excess emissions—a process we term “accumulation bydecarbonization.”

Both governance systems rely on the development of cheap carbon reductions in theSouth and claim real reductions in emissions (additionality) and sustainable developmentbenefits. Both also rely on nonstate actors, including businesses (CDM and VCO), NGOs,and individuals (VCO) to achieve climate mitigation under what can be seen as princi-ples of market environmentalism and the neoliberal devolution of governance to supra-national, local, and private actors. The CDM is a more explicit example of rolloutneoliberalism, with extensive state intervention in the allocation, certification, and tradeof carbon credits.

Offsets represent newly created markets that allow actors to transcend traditional barriersand spatial constraints by channeling transactions through supranational organizations (inthe CDM) and by forming partnerships and networks across space (in the CDM and VCO)to create offset projects and transfer and trade carbon finance and resultant carbon credits.These governance structures help to obliterate spatial constraints and nonmarket barriers,largely bypassing the nation-state, and relying on more glocalized forms of governanceboth above and below the national level.

Both systems have been heavily criticized for sloppy definitions of additionality anddevelopment benefits, for neocolonial practices of unequal exchange and the disposses-sion of rights in selling cheap credits to the North obtained from projects in the South,and for the lack of transparency and participatory governance. The response to thesecriticisms includes new regulatory efforts to legitimize and stabilize the offset market,including the creation of the development-oriented, CDM Gold Standard, and similarforms of self-regulation among VCOs to ensure real reductions in emissions and bene-fits of development in the voluntary sector. In the United Kingdom, a media backlash andconfusion among consumers have resulted in the government stepping in to provide guide-lines as a first step in the state regulation of voluntary offsets. Such reconfigurations ofgovernance that incorporate nonstate actors, such as offset retailers, have enormous impli-cations, including the degree to which such actors are accountable to their customers orthe climate when, as some have suggested, they encourage people to offset, rather thanto make behavioral changes to reduce domestic emissions (POST 2007).

Indeed, a more profound critique of offsets argues that paying someone else to reducecarbon is unethical and that all reductions should be made by the individual, company,or country through behavioral and technical changes that reduce consumption or shift tolower carbon technologies. This view contrasts with the economic and ecological argu-ments that faster, cheaper, and larger reductions of equal or greater value to the atmos-phere are possible in the developing world and denies the potential sustainable develop-ment and side benefits of projects in poorer communities and technology transfer to theSouth. A key question is whether offsets can be seen within the more nuanced interpre-tations of development that allow local people to select projects that are consistent withtheir needs and for development to operate within the hybrid landscapes and livelihoodsthat have emerged from the globalization of economies and environmental management(cf. Bebbington 2003).

For economic geographers and others who are concerned with new forms of environ-mental governance and their material benefits, carbon offsets and the larger issue of themitigation of climate change and carbon trading are important and intriguing avenuesfor research. Carbon trading is extremely dynamic, changing in response to evolvingscience, international negotiations, corporate cultures, media attention, and consumerpreferences. An agenda would include detailed empirical studies of carbon reductions inparticular places and through different networks and value chains, and further theoret-

148

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Page 24: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

Adger,W. N.; Paavola, J.;Huq, S.; and Mace, M. J., eds. 2006. Fairness in adaptation to climatechange. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Agarwal, A., and Narain, S. 1991. Global warming in an unequal world: A case of environ-mental colonialism. New Delhi: Centre for Science and Environment.

Allen, M. R. 2003. Liability for climate change. Nature 421:891–92.Anderson,T. L., and Leal, D. R. 1991. Free market environmentalism. Boulder, Colo.:Westview

Press.Andersson, K., and Richards, K. R. 2001. Implementing an international carbon seques-

tration program: Can the leaky sink be fixed? Climate Policy 1:173–88.Arts, B. 2004. The global-local nexus: NGOs and the articulation of scale. Tijdschrift

voor Economische en Sociale Geografie 95:498–510.Atmosfair. 2007. Climate protecting projects. Available online: http://www.atmosfair.deBackstrand, K., and Lovbrand, E. 2006. Planting trees to mitigate climate change: Contested

discourses of ecological modernization, green governmentality and civic environ-mentalism. Global Environmental Politics 6:50–75.

Bakker, K. 2005. Neoliberalizing nature? Market environmentalism in water supply inEngland and Wales. Annals of the Association of American Geographers 95:542–65.

Bakker, K., and Bridge, G. 2006. Material worlds? Resource geographies and the “matterof nature.” Progress in Human Geography 30:1–23.

Barrett, S. 1998. Political economy of the Kyoto Protocol. Oxford Review of EconomicPolicy 14(4):20–39.

Bayon, R.;Hawn, A.; and Hamilton, K., eds. 2007. Voluntary carbon markets:An internationalbusiness guide to what they are and how they work. London: Earthscan.

Bebbington, A. 2003. Global networks and local developments: Agendas for develop-ment geography. Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie 94:297–309.

Betsill, M. M., and Bulkeley, H. 2004. Transnational networks and global environmentalgovernance: The cities for climate protection program. International Studies Quarterly48:471–93.

———. 2006. Cities and the multilevel governance of global climate change. GlobalGovernance 12:141–59.

Bohringer, C. 2003. The Kyoto Protocol: A review and perspectives. Oxford Review ofEconomic Policy 19:451–66.

Bond, P., and Dada, R., eds. 2004. Trouble in the air: Global warming and the privatised atmos-phere, Civil Society Energy Reader. Durban, South Africa: Center for Civil Society.

Brenner, N., and Theodore, N. 2002. Cities and the geographies of “actually existingneoliberalism.” Antipode 34:349–79.

Bridge, G. 2002. Grounding globalization: The prospects and perils of linking economicprocesses of globalization to environmental outcomes. Economic Geography 78:361–86.

Bridge, G., and Jonas, A. 2002. Governing nature: The re-regulation of resource access,production, and consumption. Environment and Planning A 34:759–66.

Brown, K., and Corbera, E. 2003. Exploring equity and sustainable development in thenew carbon economy. Climate Policy 3:S41–S56.

149

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008C

AR

BON

OFFSET

S

refe

renc

esical work on the commodification of carbon, the spatial relations of emissions trading,and the role of non-nation-state actors.

Page 25: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

Buck, D. 2007. The ecological question: Can capitalism prevail? In Coming to terms with nature, ed.L. Panitch and C. Leys, 61–70. Monmouth, U.K.: Merlin Press.

Bulkeley, H. 2001. Governing climate change:The politics of risk society? Transactions of the Instituteof British Geographers 26:430–47.

———. 2005. Reconfiguring environmental governance:Towards a politics of scales and networks.Political Geography 24:875–902.

Bulkeley, H., and Betsill, M. M. 2005. Rethinking sustainable cities: Multilevel governance and the“urban” politics of climate change. Environmental Politics 14:42–63.

Bumpus, A. G. 2004. CPR for climate change? Understanding the effective recipiency of a carbonsequestration project as a common pool or privately owned resource in highland Ecuador.Unpublished master’s thesis, Kings College, London.

Carbon Finance. 2006a. Jump in carbon market volumes, values. Carbon Finance, 25 August. Availableonline: http://www.carbon-financeonline.com/index.cfm?section=lead&action=view&id=1120&return=search

———. 2006b. No CDM credits in the EU ETS without ITL-Commission. Carbon Finance, 8 March.Available online: http://www.carbon-financeonline.com/index.cfm?section=lead&action=view&id=933&return=search

———. 2006c. What Montreal did for the CDM. Carbon Finance, 27 January. Available online:h t tp : / /www.carbon- f i nanceon l i ne . com/ index . c fm?sec t ion= fea tures&ac t ion=view&id=10329&return=search

———. 2007a. Market nerves shaken by latest ITL delay. Carbon Finance, 28 November.Available online: http://www.carbon-financeonline.com/index.cfm?section=europe&action=view&id=10884

———. 2007b. AgCert’s share price dives on Morgan Stanley downgrade. Carbon Finance, 1February. Available online: http://www.carbon-financeonline.com/index.cfm?section=lead&action=view&id=10372&return=search

Carbon Trust. 2006. The Carbon Trust three stage approach to developing a robust offsetting strategy.London: Carbon Trust.

Castree, N. 2003. Commodifying what nature? Progress in Physical Geography 27:273–97.Clean Air-Cool Planet. 2006. A consumer’s guide to retail carbon offset providers. Portsmouth, N.H.:

Clean Air-Cool Planet.Climate Care. 2005. Climate Care annual report. Oxford, U.K.: Climate Care.———. 2007a. Climate Care’s projects. Available online: http://www.co2.org/Projects/index.cfm———. 2007b. Biogas digesters in India: Clean cooking in tiger country. Rathambhore, India:

Climate Care. Available online: http://www.climatecare.org/projects/countries/index.cfm?content_id=B4E1FF3C-E43F-29B3-D36ABF70834AAFC7

Climate Group. 2006. The Voluntary Carbon Standard: Proposed version 2 for consultation.Available online: http://www.theclimategroup.org/assets/Voluntary_Carbon_Standard_Version_2_final.pdf

CO2onned. 2006. New Internationalist, July, 46.Copeland, B. R., and Taylor, M. S. 1994. North–South trade and the environment. Quarterly

Journal of Economics 109:755–87.Corbera, E. 2005. Interrogating developments in carbon forestry activities: A case study from

Mexico. School of Development Studies, University of East Anglia, Norwich, U.K.de Witt Wijnen, R. 2006. A shaky regulatory environment. Available online: http://carbon-

financeonline.com/issue/30/feature/131.htmlDepartment for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs (DEFRA). 2006. UK developing government

carbon offsetting fund. London: DEFRA.

150

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Page 26: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

———. 2008. Draft code of best practice for carbon offset providers: Accreditation require-ments and procedures. London: DEFRA. Available online: http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/carbonoffset/pdf/carbon-offset-codepractice.pdf

Dolsak, N., and Dunn, M. 2006. Investments in global warming mitigation: The case of “activitiesimplemented jointly.” Policy Sciences 39:233–48.

ECEEE. 2007. UK calls carbon offset market to order. Stockholm: ECEEE. Available online:http://www.eceee.org/news/news_2007/2007_01_23b

Ekins, P., and Barker, T. 2001. Carbon taxes and carbon emissions trading. Journal of EconomicSurveys 15:325–76.

European Climate Exchange. 2006. Emissions trading: Commission decides on first set of national allo-cation plans for the 2008–2012 trading period 2006 (29 November). Available online:http://www.europeanclimateexchange.com/default_flash.asp

Face Foundation. 2007. Services/projects. Arnheim, the Netherlands: Face Foundation. Availableonline: http://www.stichtingface.nl

Gibbs, D. 2006. Prospects for an environmental economic geography: Linking ecologicalmodernization and regulationist approaches. Economic Geography 82:193–215.

Goldman, M. 2005. Imperial nature: The World Bank and struggles for social justice in the age of glob-alization. New Haven, Conn.:Yale University Press.

Grace, J. 2006. Do trees warm or cool the planet? Guest lecture at the Oxford University Centrefor the Environment, Oxford, U.K.

Gundimeda, H. 2004. How “sustainable” is the “sustainable development objective” of CDM indeveloping countries like India? Forest Policy and Economics 6(3–4):329–43.

Hamilton, K.; Bayon, R.; Turner, G.; and Higgins, D. 2007. State of the voluntary carbon market2007. London: Ecosystem Marketplace and New Carbon Finance.

Haites, E., and Yamin, F. 2000. The clean development mechanism: Proposals for its operationand governance. Global Environmental Change—Human and Policy Dimensions 10:27–45.

Harris, E. 2006. The voluntary retail carbon market: A review and analysis of the current marketand outlook. Faculty of Natural Sciences, Imperial College, London. Copy available from E.Harris, 112 Magdalen Road, Oxford, U.K.

Harvey, D. 1974. Population, resources and the ideology of science. Economic Geography 50:256–77.

———. 2005. A brief history of neoliberalism. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.

———. 2006. Spaces of global capitalism. London:Verso.

Harvey, F. 2007. Beware the carbon offsetting cowboys. Financial Times, 25 April. Availableonline: http://www.ft.com/cms/s/dcdefef6-f350-11db-9845-000b5df10621,dwp_uuid=3c093daa-edc1-11db-8584-000b5df10621.html

Hawn, A. 2005. Horses for courses: Voluntary vs CDM projects in Mexico, ed. R. Bayon. SanFrancisco: Ecosystem Marketplace. Available online: http://ecosystemmarketplace.com/pages/article.news.php?component_id=2509&component_version_id=4039&language_id=12

Howard, A. 2005. International transaction log and CDM registry. In UNFCCC COP/MOP1. Availableonline: http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/getfile.php?docID=1284

International Emissions Trading Association. 2004. CDM emission reductions purchase agreementV2.0. Geneva: International Emissions Trading Association. Available online:http://www.ieta.org/ieta/www/pages/download.php?docID=450

International Institute for Environment and Development. 2006. Can voluntary offsets assist indevelopment?Roundtable Discussions on Offsets. Available online: http://www.iied.org/CC/documents/Notes26OctRoundTableCanVoluntaryCarbonOffsets.pdf

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

151

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Page 27: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

Jessop, B. 1998. The rise of governance and the risks of failure: The case of economic develop-ment. International Social Science Journal 50:29–45.

———. 2002. Liberalism, neoliberalism, and urban governance: A state-theoretical perspective.Antipode 34:452–72.

Johnson, E., and Heinen, R. 2004. Carbon trading: Time for industry involvement. EnvironmentInternational 30:279–88.

Jung, M. 2005. The role of forestry projects in the clean development mechanism. EnvironmentalScience & Policy 8:87–104.

———. 2006. Host country attractiveness for CDM non-sink projects. Energy Policy 34:2173–84.Katz, C. 1998. Whose nature, whose culture? Private productions of space and the “preserva-

tion” of nature. In Remaking reality: Nature at the millenium, ed. B. Braun and N. Castree,46–63. London: Routledge.

Kenber, M. 2004. The Clean Development Mechanism: A tool for promoting long-term climateprotection and sustainable development? In Climate change and carbon markets, ed. F. Yamin,263–88. London: Earthscan.

Kiss, A.; Castro, G.; and Newcombe, K. 2002. The role of multilateral institutions. PhilosophicalTransactions of the Royal Society of London Series A—Mathematical Physical and Engineering Sciences360(1797):1641–52.

Klooster, D., and Masera, O. 2000. Community forest management in Mexico: Carbon mitigationand biodiversity conservation through rural development. Global Environmental Change:Human and Policy Dimensions 10:259–72.

Kollmuss, A., and Bowell, B. 2006. Voluntary offsets for air-travel carbon emissions. Evaluationsand recommendations of voluntary offset companies. Medford, Mass.: Tufts Climate Initiative.

Langrock, T.; Arens, C.; and Wiehler, H. A. 2004. Creating markets abroad: The case of CDM/JIprojects. Available online: http://www.wupperinst.org/uploads/tx_wibeitrag/creating-markets.pdf

Levy, D. L., and Newell, P. 2005. The business of global environmental governance. Cambridge, Mass.:MIT Press.

Lindseth, G. 2006. Scalar strategies in climate-change politics: Debating the environmentalconsequences of a natural gas project. Environment and Planning C—Government and Policy24:739–54.

Liverman, D. M. 2004.Who governs, at what scale and at what price? Geography, environmentalgovernance, and the commodification of nature. Annals of the Association of American Geographers94:734–38.

———. Forthcoming. Conventions of climate change: Constructions of danger and the dispos-session of the atmosphere. Journal of Historical Geography.

Liverman, D. M., and Vilas, S. 2006. Neoliberalism and the environment in Latin America. AnnualReview of Environment and Resources 31:327–63.

Lohmann, L. 2001. Democracy or carbocracy? Intellectual corruption and the future of the climatedebate. In Corner House Briefing 24. Sturnminster Newton, U.K.: Corner House. Available online:http://www.thecornerhouse.org.uk/pdf/briefing/24carboc.pdf

———. 2005. Making and marketing carbon dumps: Commodification, calculation and counter-factuals in climate change mitigation. Science as Culture 14:203–35.

———. 2006. Carbon trading: A critical conversation on climate change, privatisation and power. Vol.48, Development dialogue. Dorset, U.K.: Corner House.

Low, N. 2002. Ecosocialisation and environmental planning: A Polanyian approach. Environment andPlanning A 34:43–60.

Mansfield, B. 2004. Neoliberalism in the oceans:“Rationalization,” property rights, and the commonsquestion. Geoforum 35:313–26.

152

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Page 28: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

May, P. H.; Boyd, E.;Viega, F.; and Chang, M. 2004. Local sustainable development effects of forestprojects in Brazil and Bolivia: A view from the field. London: International Institute forEnvironment and Development.

McAfee, K. 1999. Selling nature to save it? Biodiversity and green developmentalism. Environmentand Planning D: Society and Space 17:133–54.

McCarthy, J. 2005. Devolution in the woods: Community forestry as hybrid neoliberalism.Environment and Planning A 37:995–1014.

McCarthy, J., and Prudham, S. 2004. Neoliberal nature and the nature of neoliberalism. Geoforum35:275–83.

Michaelowa, A. 2005. Determination of baselines and additionality for the CDM: A crucial elementof credibility of the climate regime. In Climate change and carbon markets: A handbook for emis-sions reduction mechanisms, ed. F.Yamin, 305–20. London: Earthscan.

Molitor, M. 2006. Carbon volunteers Part 2. Carbon Finance, January, 19.Monbiot, G. 2006. Paying for our sins. The Guardian, 18 October, 9.Moorcroft, D.;Koch, J.; and Kummer, K. 2000. Clean Development Mechanism: Exploring for solu-

tions through learning-by-doing. Available online: http://www.wbcsd.ch/web/publications/cdm2000.pdf

Muller, A. 2007. How to make the Clean Development Mechanism sustainable—The potentialof rent extraction. Energy Policy 35:3203–12.

Newell, P. J. 2000. Climate for change: Non-state actors and the global politics of the greenhouse.Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.

Nunan, M. 2005. Client case studies—Radio Taxis Group:The Carbon Neutral Company. Availableonline: http://www.carbonneutral.com

O’Connor, J. 1998. Natural causes: Essays in ecological Marxism, democracy and ecology. New York:Guilford Press.

Oels, A. 2005. Rendering climate change governable: From biopower to advanced liberalgovernment? Journal of Environmental Policy & Planning 7:185–207.

Paterson, M. 1996. Global warming and global politics. London: Routledge.———. 2001. Risky business: Insurance companies in global warming politics. Global Environmental

Politics 1:18–42.———. 2005. Contextualizing public-private partnerships: The dynamics and development of

environmental governance. Paper presented at a talk at the Center for Governance, 11 January,Ottawa, Canada.

Peck, J., and Tickell, A. 2002. Neoliberalizing space. Antipode 34:380–404.Point Carbon. 2006. Russia could earn 10 bn USD from ratifying the Kyoto Protocol. Available online:

http://www.pointcarbon.com/article.php?articleID=2325&categoryID=147Polanyi, K. 1944. The great transformation. Boston: Beacon Press.Portney, P. R., and Stavins, R. N. 2000. Public policies for environmental protection. Washington, D.C.:

Resources for the Future.POST. 2007. Voluntary carbon offsets. London: Parliamentary Office of Science and Technology.Repetto, R. 2001. The Clean Development Mechanism: Institutional breakthrough or institu-

tional nightmare? Policy Sciences 34(3–4):303–27.Richards, K. R., and Andersson, K. 2001. The leaky sink: Persistent obstacles to a forest carbon

sequestration program based in individual projects. Climate Policy 1:41–54.Roberts, J. T., and Parks, B. C. 2007. A climate of injustice: Global inequality, North–South politics, and

climate policy. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Robertson, M. M. 2004. The neoliberalization of ecosystem services:Wetland mitigation banking

and problems in environmental governance. Geoforum 35:361–73.

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

153

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Page 29: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

Sandor, R.;Walsh, M.; and Marques, R. 1999. Creating a market for carbon emissions: Gas industryopportunities. Natural Gas, 6. Available online: http://www.envifi.com/Bios/natgas.htm

———. 2002. Greenhouse-gas-trading markets. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society ofLondon Series A—Mathematical Physical and Engineering Sciences 360(1797):1889–900.

Shrestha, R. M., and Timilsina, G. R. 2002. The additionality criterion for identifying CleanDevelopment Mechanism projects under the Kyoto Protocol. Energy Policy 30:73–79.

SinksWatch. 2004a. Climate justice now! The Durban declaration. Available online:http://www.sinkswatch.org/pubs/Durban%20DeclarationSeptember%202006%20leaflet.pdf

———. 2004b. How Plantar sinks the World Bank’s rhetoric: Tree plantations and the WorldBank’s sinks agenda. Available online: http://www.sinkswatch.org/pubs/world%20bank%20and%20sinks%20final.pdf

Smith, N. 1990. Uneven development: Nature, capital and the production of space. 2d ed. Oxford,U.K.: Basil Blackwell.

———. 2007. Nature as an accumulation strategy. Socialist Register (January):1–36.

Sterk,W., and Bunse, M. 2004.Voluntary compensation of greenhouse gas emissions, 2-23. PolicyPaper No. 3/2004, 2-23. Available online: http://www.wupperinst.org/download/1078-compensation.pdf

Stern, N.; Peters, S.; Bakhshi,V.; Bowen, A.; Cameron, C.; Catovsky, S.; Crane, D.; Cruickshank, S.;Dietz, S.; and Edmonson, N. 2006. Stern review: The economics of climate change. London: HerMajesty’s Treasury.

Sutter, C., and Parreño, J. C. 2007. Does the current Clean Development Mechanism (CDM)deliver its sustainable development claim? An analysis of officially registered CDM projects.Climatic Change 84:75–90.

Taiyab, N. 2005. Exploring the market for “development carbon” through the voluntary and retail markets.London: International Institute for Environment and Development.

Tang, K., ed. 2005. The finance of climate change:A guide for governments, corporations and investors.London: Risk Books.

Targetneutral. 2006. Advisory panel. Available online: http://www.targetneutral.com/TONIC/advisorypanel.jsp

The Carbon Neutral Company (TCNC). 2005. Homepage:The Carbon Neutral Company. Availableonline: http://www.carbonneutral.com

———. 2007. Projects overview: The Carbon Neutral Company. Available online:http://www.carbonneutral.com

The Gold Standard for voluntary offsets. 2006. Gold Standard Newsletter 01, ed. M. Schlup. Basel,Switzerland: CDM Gold Standard.

Tickell, A., and Peck, J. 2003. Making global rules: Globalization or neoliberalization? In Remakingthe global economy: Economic-geographical perspectives, ed. J. Peck and H. W.-c. Yeung, 163–81.London: Sage.

Tyndall Centre for Climate Change Research. 2007. Is carbon offsetting a legitimate response tomitigating cl imate change? Available online: http://www.tyndall .ac .uk/research/programme4/carbon_offset_debate.html

U.K. Energy Research Centre (UKERC). 2006. Carbon neutrality and carbon offsets, ed. S. Keay-Bright. Oxford, U.K.: U.K. Energy Research Centre.

UNEP-Risoe. 2007. CDM/JI pipeline overview. Available online: http://www.cdmpipeline.org

United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). 1997.The Kyoto Protocol.Bonn: UNFCCC.

154

ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY

Page 30: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

———. 2001. Decision 17/CP.7—Modalities and procedures for a Clean Development Mechanismas defined in Article 12 of the Kyoto Protocol. United Nations Framework Convention onClimate Change, Bonn.

———. 2007a. Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). Available online: http://cdm.unfccc.int———. 2007b. CDM projects registered. Available online: http://cdm.unfccc.int/Projects/

registered.html———. 2007c. CDM statistics: Expected CERs until end of 2012. Available online:

http://cdm.unfccc.int/Statistics/index.htmlUpset with offsets. 2006. The Economist, 3 August, 26.V-Carbon News. 2006. The ecosystem marketplace’s V-Carbon news. Available online: http://

ecosystemmarketplace.com/pages/newsletter/vc_6.6.06.htmlVasudev, A.; Godinez, G.; and Telnes, E. 2005.Validation report: El Canadá hydroelectric project

in Guatemala. Oslo, Norway: Det Norske Veritas.Victor, D. G.; Nakicenovic, N.; and Victor, N. 2001. The Kyoto Protocol emission allocations:

Windfall surpluses for Russia and Ukraine. Climatic Change 49:263–77.WBCSD and WRI. 2005.The Greenhouse Gas Protocol:The GHG Protocol for project accounting.

Geneva: World Business Council for Sustainable Development and World ResourcesInstitute.

Weyant, J., ed. 1999. The costs of the Kyoto Protocol: A multi-model evaluation. Energy Journal(Special Issue).

Woerdman, E. 2000. Implementing the Kyoto Protocol: Why JI and CDM show more promisethan international emissions trading. Energy Policy 28:29–38.

World Bank. 2006a. Prototype carbon fund. Available online: http://carbonfinance.org/Router.cfm?Page=PCF&ItemID=9707&FID=9707

———. 2006b. State and trends of the carbon market 2006. Washington, D.C.:World Bank.———. 2007a. Carbon finance at the World Bank. Available online: http://carbonfinance.org———. 2007b. State and trends in the carbon market 2007. Washington, D.C.:World Bank.Yamin, F. 2005. The international rules on the Kyoto mechanisms. In Climate change and carbon

markets: A handbook of emissions reductions mechanisms, ed. F.Yamin, 1–74. London: Earthscan.Young, Z. 2002. A new green order?: The World Bank and the politics of the global environment facility.

London: Pluto Press.

CA

RBO

N O

FFSETS

155

Vol. 84 No. 2 2008

Page 31: Adam G. Bumpus & Diana M. Liverman...Mostly CDM but some VCO. Replace or displace carbon-intensive energy generation (e.g., bunker fuels in power stations) by wind farms, hydroelectric

Conditions of use: This article may be downloaded from the Economic Geography

website for personal research by members of subscribing organizations. This PDF

may not be placed on any website without permission of the publisher, Clark

University.