553
BOUNDARIES AND DOMINION An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North Dominion Education Ministries, Inc. Harrisonburg, Virginia

An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    5

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

BOUNDARIES AND DOMINIONAn Economic Commentary on Leviticus

Volume 3

Gary North

Dominion Education Ministries, Inc.Harrisonburg, Virginia

Page 2: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

copyright, Gary North, 1999, 2006

This volume is part of a series, An Economic Commentary on theBible. At present, the series includes the following volumes:

*The Dominion Covenant: Genesis (1982, 1987)*Moses and Pharaoh (1985)*The Sinai Strategy: Economics and the Ten Commandments (1986)*Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus (1990)*Leviticus: An Economic Commentary (1994)Boundaries and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus

(Full version of previous book, 1994, 2004) Edition: 6/18/08*Sanctions and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Numbers

(1997)Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Deuter-

onomy (3 vols., 1999, 2003) Priorities and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Matthew

(2000, 2003)Treasure and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Luke

(2000, 2003, 2005)Sacrifice and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Acts (2000,

2003)Cooperation and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Romans

(2001, 2003)Judgment and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on First Corin-

thians (2001)Hierarchy and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on First Timo-

thy (2003)

An asterisk notes a printed volume. These are also available forviewing on www.freebooks.com. The other volumes are in PDF for-mat, and may be downloaded from www.demischools.org. For fulldetails, send an e-mail to [email protected].

Page 3: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Table of Contents

Volume 1

Foreword . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . viiPreface . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xxxviiiIntroduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1

Part I. Sacrifices (Lev. 1–7)Introduction to Part I . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

1. Sacrifice, Stewardship, and Debt (1:1–4) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 492. Priestly Representation (2:1–3) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 843. Leaven and Progressive Sanctification (3:1, 17) . . . . . . . . . . . 964. Corporate Responsibility (4:1–3) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1435. Proportional Payments to God (5:6–7) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2356. Sacred, Profane, and Common (5:14–19). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2627. Guardian of the Civil Oath (6:1–7) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 334

Part II. Cleansing (Lev. 8–16)Introduction to Part II . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 382

8. Wine as a Boundary Marker (10:8–11) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3849. Biblical Quarantine (Lev. 13:45–46) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 410

Part III. Separation (Lev. 17–22)Introduction to Part III . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 437

10. The Promised Land as a Covenantal Agent (18:24–29) . . . 439

Page 4: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

iv

Volume 2

11. Gleaning: Charity Without Entitlement (19:9–10) . . . . . . . 46712. Verbal Bonds and Economic Coordination (19:11–12) . . . . 52013. Protecting the Weakest Party (19:13–14) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54414. Impartial Justice vs. Socialist Economics (19:15) . . . . . . . . 58115. Local Justice vs. Centralized Government (19:15) . . . . . . . 63216. The State’s Monopoly of Vengeance (19:18) . . . . . . . . . . . 67217. The Preservation of the Seed (19:19) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70218. Covenantal Fruit (19:23–25) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75119. Measuring Out Justice (19:33–37) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 78120. Inheritance by Fire (20:2–5) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83721. Inheritance by Separation (20:22–26) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 879

Part IV. Covenantal Acts (Lev. 23–24)Introduction to Part IV . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 900

22. Mutual Self-Interest: Priests and Gleaners . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90223. Blasphemy and Civil Rights (24:14–22) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 922

Volume 3

Part V. Inheritance (Lev. 25–27)Introduction to Part V . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 945

24. The Sabbatical Year (25:1–7) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95325. Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws (25:8–13) . . . . . . . . . 98426. Economic Oppression by Means of the State (25:14–17) . 103827. Food Miracles and Covenantal Predictability (25:18–22) . 107128. The Right of Redemption (25:23–24) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108829. Poverty and Usury (25:35–38) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111830. Promise, Adoption, and Liberty (25:39–43) . . . . . . . . . . . 1142

Page 5: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

v

31. Slaves and Freemen (25:44–46) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117532. Mandatory Redemption Upon Payment (25:47–55) . . . . . 121233. Nature as a Sanctioning Agent (26:3–6) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123134. Limits to Growth (26:9–10) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126835. God’s Escalating Wrath (26:13–17) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129536. The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry (27:2–8) . . . . . . . . . . . 130537. The Redemption-Price System (27:9–15) . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133438. Tithing: Benefit of the Doubt (27:30–33) . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1361

Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1368

AppendixesAppendix A: Sacrilege and Sanctions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1399Appendix B: Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique . . . . . . . . . 1417

Volume 4

Appendix C: Leaven as Exclusively Evil . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1491Appendix D: The Church vs. Socialism . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1516Appendix E: Greek Mythology: The Myth of Classical Politics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1556Appendix F: The Covenantal Structure of Judgment . . . . . . . 1583Appendix G: Rushdoony on “Hybridization”: From Genetic Separation to Racial Separation . . . . . 1611Appendix H: Malthusianism vs. Covenantalism . . . . . . . . . . . 1641Appendix I: Conspiracy, Forgery, and Higher Criticism . . . . . 1692Appendix J: Critics of the Five-Point Covenant Model . . . . . . 1710

Scripture Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1750Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1775

Page 6: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

945

V. Inheritance (Lev. 25–27)

INTRODUCTION TO PART V

And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughoutall the land unto all the inhabitants thereof: it shall be a jubile untoyou; and ye shall return every man unto his possession, and ye shallreturn every man unto his family (Lev. 25:10).

The fifth section of Leviticus begins with Chapter 25, which liststhe laws governing the jubilee year: inheritance inside the land’s boun-daries. The remainder of Leviticus deals with inheritance.

Modern evangelical theologians remain totally hostile to the theon-omists’ principle of biblical interpretation: any Mosaic law not annul-led by the New Covenant is still judicially binding on church, State, orfamily. Nevertheless, prominent evangelical social commentators –though not the theologians – of the far right and the far left remainfascinated with the jubilee laws of Leviticus 25.

This is a very curious phenomenon. The jubilee laws were explicitlytied to the Promised Land. They were laws governing the sale of realestate and people. They were not revealed by God prior to the exodus,and they applied to no region on earth prior to the conquest ofCanaan. Why should evangelical Protestant social commentators whodenounce theonomy’s hermeneutic of judicial continuity also proclaimthe benefits of the jubilee laws? Is there some hidden agenda at workhere?

There are two approaches taken by the evangelical commentators.Right-wing evangelicals argue that the jubilee’s 50-year cycle was re-lated to inherent limits on debt. Thus, we should in some way honorthe jubilee’s principle of debt limits. If we fail to do this through somesort of national bankruptcy law, a built-in economic cycle of economicdepression and bankruptcy will do it for us. Far-left evangelicals arguethat the jubilee law governed ownership in the broadest sense, not just

Page 7: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Introduction to Part V

946

real estate. Mosaic civil law specified that every rural plot be returnedto its original family every 50 years. They conclude from this that themodern State should legislate a massive, compulsory redistribution ofcapital from the wealthy to the poor.

Both groups are wrong. Neither group comes close to the specificsof the jubilee law. Neither group comes close to the meaning of thislaw. This is because neither group actually goes to the actual jubileelaw with the assumption that every aspect of this law as well as itsMosaic judicial context is judicially binding in the New Covenant.Neither suggests a principle of judicial continuity. Each side has aneconomic agenda, and each misuses the texts of Scripture to promotethis agenda.

First, with respect to the right-wing analysis, the jubilee year hadvery little to do with debt limitation except insofar as a 50-year leasefor land is a form of debt. How relevant is it today? Hardly anyonetoday signs a 50-year lease. This law had nothing to do with consumerdebt or business debt for capital equipment, or anything besides Israel-ite bondservants, land outside of walled cities, and Levites’ houses.

Second, with respect to the left-wing analysis, the jubilee law restedlegally on God’s mandate that Israel invade Canaan and wipe out allof its inhabitants. That is to say, the jubilee law rested on genocide.It was an aspect of the original spoils of war. It had nothing to do witha government program of systematic wealth redistribution from therich to the poor. The jubilee law established that the conqueringfamilies of Joshua’s era would permanently retain title to their land.This law was announced four decades before the conquest began. Thereturn of rural land to the heirs of these original families every 50years was not statist wealth redistribution; rather, it was the judicialdefense of original title. It was therefore a defense of privateproperty. God set the original terms of ownership. The civil govern-ment was supposed to uphold this original contract.

Page 8: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Introduction to Part V

947

The Meaning of the Jubilee

The Mosaic law guaranteed that the Israelites would multiply ifthey obeyed God’s law: longer life spans (Ex. 20:12) and zero miscar-riages (Ex. 23:26). But a multiplying population leads to ever-shrinking land holdings. As time passed and the population grew, eachfamily plot in Israel would shrink to the point of near-invisibility.Given the fact that the average family allotment at the time of the con-quest was under 11 acres, a population that doubled every quartercentury (3 percent growth per annum) could not remain an agri-cultural society for very long. Every 24 years, the average family’sshare of the farm would shrink by half. The average allotment wouldhave been down to a little over an acre within a century with a popu-lation growth rate of 3 percent a year.

The jubilee law had nothing to do with the equalization of propertyexcept in the peculiar sense of eventually producing plot sizes so tinythat the value of any given family’s landed inheritance was so smallthat it really did not make any difference. In today’s world, an inher-itance worth two dollars is twice as large as an inheritance worth onedollar, but in terms of what either inheritance will buy, the percentagedifference between them really does not matter.

Then what was the jubilee law all about? First, it was a law thatdecentralized politics: every heir of a family of the conquest couldidentify his citizenship in a particular tribe because every family had aninheritance in the land. Ownership stayed inside the tribes. Second, itrestricted the accumulation of rural land holdings by the Levites, whocould never buy up the land. This geographically dispersed urban tribewould remain dispersed. Third, it kept the State from extending itsland holdings on a permanent basis. Fourth, it kept foreigners frombuying permanent residences outside of walled cities where homes

Page 9: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Introduction to Part V

948

were not under the jubilee law. Fifth, it pressured the nation to moveinto walled cities or emigrate out of Israel when population growthhad its effect on farm size.

There was an overall economic principle at work here: thoseoutside the covenants – civil, familial, and ecclesiastical – should bekept economically and numerically subordinate to those inside thecovenants. This is not discussed by commentators.

If Israel remained covenantally faithful as a nation, the life style ofthe typical Israelite would not remain agricultural. A few generationsafter the conquest, the nation would have become an urbanized centerof commerce. More than this: the old wineskin of the original grant ofterritory to Joshua’s generation could not long hold the new wine ofpopulation growth. The Promised Land’s boundaries would bebreached. The Israelites would spread beyond the nation’s borders.

Having said all this, now I must prove it. But there really isn’t verymuch to prove regarding the fundamental economic aspect of this law.It is simple to comprehend. The economic value of each family’s plotwould have decreased over the generations, as covenant-keepingfamilies multiplied. Yet for over two millennia, the commentators haveignored the obvious: a growing population will eventually fill up theland.

There is a reason for this error: those who write Bible commentar-ies rarely take the Mosaic law seriously. They pay little attention tothe coherence of its details. They refuse to ask themselves the crucialquestion: How did each law actually work in relation to the otherlaws? The liberals assume that the judicial system could not havefunctioned coherently because multiple authors wrote the Pentateuch.A coherent system of law would undermine their presupposition ofjudicial incoherence. They discover what they assume: a patchwork ofuncoordinated laws. They do not seek to discover the meaning of anylaw in terms of the whole. Meanwhile, the conservatives feel justified

Page 10: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Introduction to Part V

949

in ignoring the details of the law because they assume that the Mosaiclaw isn’t relevant under the New Covenant. This almost contemptuousattitude toward the Mosaic law has hampered Christian scholarship.It is time for this contempt to end. It is time to search the law in depthto discover what God expects from us, just as David did (Ps. 119).The jubilee law is a better place than most to begin because it isclearly a coherent series of laws with many ramifications.

A Matter of Holiness

God required the nation of Israel to hallow – set apart – the fiftiethyear. This identified the fiftieth year as uniquely holy. It was the jubi-lee year. It was to be inaugurated by the blowing of the trumpet on theday of atonement (Lev. 25:9). The jubilee year was to be the year forclaiming one’s inheritance: of land, but far more important, of legalstatus as a citizen. Those circumcised men who were heirs of the ori-ginal holy army that had conquered Canaan could not legally be disen-franchised except through the loss of their landed inheritance outsidea walled city, or, in the case of the Levites, of their homes in Leviticalcities.

Citizenship (freemanship) in Mosaic Israel was based on three reli-gious factors: confession, circumcision, and lawful participation inGod’s holy army. One mark of citizenship was ownership of a shareof the land once possessed by a conquering family under Joshua. Thiswas not the only proof of citizenship, but it was the most universal. Aman who had been judicially severed from ecclesiastical participationin the congregation could not retain his family’s landed inheritancebeyond the next jubilee. He became disinherited. His property wouldgo to his next-of-kin: his kinsman-redeemer. He could legally buy titleto a residence in a walled city, since this property was not governed

Page 11: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Introduction to Part V

950

by the jubilee law, but he might have to sell it in a crisis. It was riskyto be excommunicated.

As an excommunicate, he was no longer an Israelite. He was a resi-dent alien. As such, he became subject to the threat of lifetime servi-tude. So did his minor heirs (Lev. 25:44–46). He was no longer afreeman. In an economic crisis, he might also lose his status as a freeman.

If Israel did not honor God’s law, God threatened national disin-heritance (Deut. 8:19–20). This placed every Israelite in jeopardy ofbecoming a slave. Slavery was a permanent sanction. A slave couldnot buy his way out of slavery. There were only three ways for a slaveto escape his legal condition and still remain inside the land: (1)manumission, (2) liberation by an invading foreign army, or (3) adop-tion, either by his owner or some other Israelite.

The legal issue of inheritance is, in the final analysis, the theolo-gical issue of adoption by God (Ezek. 16). So is the legal issue of lib-erty. In this regard, consider the New Testament’s doctrine of adop-tion through God’s grace (John 1:12; Eph. 1:5): an act of the ultimateKinsman-Redeemer, Jesus Christ.

Enforcement

Was the jubilee law actually enforced? It is not clear from the histo-rical sections of the Bible whether or not Israel ever observed thejubilee year. The Bible’s silence indicates that it may not have beenenforced, but we cannot be certain about this. Consider Ahab’s theftof Naboth’s land (I Ki. 21). On the one hand, Naboth refused to sellhis land to King Ahab. This is evidence of one man’s commitment tothe Mosaic law’s principle of jubilee inheritance. On the other hand,the fact that Ahab thought he could permanently steal the land from

Page 12: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Introduction to Part V

951

Naboth by having him executed indicates that the enforcement of thejubilee was sporadic or nonexistent in his day. Surely, Ahab was notNaboth’s kinsman-redeemer. The incident reveals no clear-cut evi-dence with regard to the entire history of Israel.

The Mosaic law provided economic incentives for those whopossessed the authority to declare the jubilee year to do so: the Lev-ites. Because the homes of the Levites in Levitical cities were gov-erned by the jubilee (Lev. 25:32–33), the Levites had an economicincentive to declare the jubilee on schedule twice per century – farstronger than the incentive for them to declare a sabbatical year. Didthey nevertheless defect? If so, why?

Conclusion

The jubilee year was a year of liberty for all the inhabitants of Israel(v. 10). But there was an exclusionary clause in the jubilee law: theenslavement of heathens (vv. 44–46). The best way to avoid slaverywas to become a citizen of the holy commonwealth. Unlike the otherancient nations, citizenship in Israel was open to any resident alien, orat least to his heirs (Deut. 23:2–8). The blessings of liberty could besecured through confession of faith in God, circumcision, and eligibili-ty to serve in God’s holy army. This was the Mosaic law’s incom-parable promise to all resident aliens. But to attain citizenship, a familywould have to remain economically productive until the heirs of thepromise could secure their claim. This promise was conditional:remaining productive and avoiding being sold into servitude.

The jubilee law pointed to the conditional nature of Israel’s veryexistence as a nation: God’s threat of disinheritance, which was athreat of servitude to foreigners. There were conditions attached tocitizenship: covenantal stipulations. The jubilee law’s stipulations

Page 13: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Introduction to Part V

1. Gary North, Treasure and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Luke, 2nd elec-tronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc., [2000]2003), ch. 6.

952

(Lev. 25) – point three of the biblical covenant – were immediatelyfollowed by a list of promised sanctions (Lev. 26): point four.

Every true prophet of Israel came before the nation to bring acovenant lawsuit. This reminded them of the ethical basis of liberty.Israel’s supreme prophet would bring Israel’s final covenant lawsuit.He would declare liberty for the enslaved and slavery for the rebelliousslavemasters. He would serve as the final go’el: the kinsman-redeemerand the blood avenger. He would adopt many and disinherit others.He would bring sanctions. He would announce the final jubilee year:“The Spirit of the Lord is upon me, because he hath anointed me topreach the gospel to the poor; he hath sent me to heal the broken-hearted, to preach deliverance to the captives, and recovering of sightto the blind, to set at liberty them that are bruised, To preach theacceptable year of the Lord” (Luke 4:18–19).1 Fulfilled!

Page 14: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

953

24

THE SABBATICAL YEAR

And the LORD spake unto Moses in mount Sinai, saying, Speak untothe children of Israel, and say unto them, When ye come into the landwhich I give you, then shall the land keep a sabbath unto the LORD.Six years thou shalt sow thy field, and six years thou shalt prune thyvineyard, and gather in the fruit thereof; But in the seventh year shallbe a sabbath of rest unto the land, a sabbath for the LORD: thoushalt neither sow thy field, nor prune thy vineyard. That which grow-eth of its own accord of thy harvest thou shalt not reap, neithergather the grapes of thy vine undressed: for it is a year of rest untothe land. And the sabbath of the land shall be meat for you; for thee,and for thy servant, and for thy maid, and for thy hired servant, andfor thy stranger that sojourneth with thee, And for thy cattle, and forthe beast that are in thy land, shall all the increase thereof be meat(Lev. 25:1–7).

The theocentric meaning of the sabbatical year was God as thesource of productivity. Land owners could rest for a year, yet theywould prosper.

Sabbath and Capital Preservation

This law is a recapitulation and extension of the sabbath laws ofExodus 23:10–12. It was not in origin a law of the jubilee, althoughit was tied to it; it was a law of the sabbath. This leads us to an impor-tant implication: the law of the jubilee was an extension of the sab-batical principle of rest. The sabbatical year law was primary; thejubilee land laws were secondary. The sabbatical year law was morefundamental than the jubilee land laws.

Page 15: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

2. Chapter 10.

3. Gary North, The Sinai Strategy: Economics and the Ten Commandments (Tyler, Texas:Institute for Christian Economics, 1986), ch. 4.

4. Andrew Bonar, A Commentary on Leviticus (London: Banner of Truth Trust, [1846]1966), p. 446.

954

We begin our study of the jubilee laws with a consideration of themeaning of the sabbath: rest for land as well as for man. We need todiscover the meaning of “rest” in the context of the sabbatical year.We also need to recognize that this law was a Mosaic land law: anaspect of the land as God’s covenantal agent (Lev. 18:25, 28).2

The law of God is theocentric. Whatever secondary applications itmay have, a law’s primary application always relates to God. This lawfocused on the mandatory resting of the land of Israel, but its ultimatereference point was the sovereignty of the Creator God of thecovenantal promise.

The Bible introduces the subject of the sabbath in relation to thestory of the creation. God created the world in six days; then Herested (Ex. 20:11).3 Whenever the Israelites observed this law, theywere acknowledging the sovereignty of God as both the Creator andthe original owner. Bonar comments: “It has been well said that by theweekly Sabbath they owned that they themselves belonged to Jeho-vah, and by this seventh-year Sabbath they professed that their landwas His, and they His tenants.”4

God deals with men as an absentee landlord deals with leaseholderswho use his property. He gave Adam an assignment; then He left thegarden. This is a continuing theme in the Bible. The Book of Jobpictures God as normally distant from man. Jesus used the theme ofthe absentee landlord in several of His parables. While God dwells inthe midst of men judicially, especially during ecclesiastical feasts, Hedoes not dwell in their midst physically. The dominion covenant (Gen.

Page 16: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

5. Gary North, The Dominion Covenant: Genesis, 2nd ed. (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1987), ch. 3.

955

1:26–28)5 is supposed to be fulfilled by men acting as responsiblemanagers, not as supervised coolies in a field. The managerial modelin the Bible is that of a sharecropper or tenant farmer who pays 10percent of his net income to the landowner.

The Terms of the Lease

Leasing land is a very difficult proposition for a landlord. For anabsentee landlord, it is even more difficult. The problem is to establishleasing terms that preserve economic incentives that achieve threegoals: (1) keeping a competent lessee on the property by allowing himto maximize his income; (2) maintaining or increasing the capitalizedvalue of the land; (3) maximizing the landlord’s lease income. Theabsentee landlord must discover a way to achieve all three goalswithout a great expenditure on local monitors. Inexpensive monitorsare valuable.

God established the laws governing the Promised Land because Hedelivered it into their hands. As its owner, He had the authority toestablish the terms of the leasehold. If the people did not like the termsof the lease, they could live elsewhere. So, one foundation of this lawis God’s ownership. (The other foundation is the principle of sabbathrest.)

The terms of God’s lease are generous to the lessee, who keepsnine-tenths of the net income of the operation. This is the principle ofthe tithe. The tithe must be paid to God’s designated agency of collec-tion, the institutional church. The church acts as God’s accountant andcrop-collector. The payment of the tithe is a public acknowledgment

Page 17: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

6. He never used this phrase exactly as quoted. He wrote of property in general as “life,liberty, and estate.” John Locke, Second Treatise on Government (1690), paragraph 87. Hespoke of “life, liberty, or possession” in paragraph 137. Exactly one century later, EdmundBurke wrote of “property, liberty, and life.” Reflections on the Revolution in France(1790), paragraph 324. The United States Constitution adopted “life, liberty, or property”in Article V of the Bill of Rights (1791), and also in Article XIV:1 (1868).

956

by the lessees of God’s ultimate ownership of the original capital: land(rent) plus labor (wages) over time (interest). This original grant ofcapital is also accurately described by John Locke’s three-foldclassification: life, liberty, and property.6

God’s Land Grant

Consider the grant of capital in the form of developed land. Godgave His people the Promised Land as their inheritance. This was anaspect of the promise given to Abraham (Gen. 15:13–16). Alsoincluded were existing houses and fields. “And I have given you a landfor which ye did not labour, and cities which ye built not, and ye dwellin them; of the vineyards and oliveyards which ye planted not do yeeat” (Josh. 24:13). They inherited the capitalized value of the housesand planted fields of the Canaanites. The Canaanites had unknowinglyserved as stewards of the land, building up its value until the fourthgeneration after Israel’s descent into Egypt (Gen. 15:16).

Having delivered a capital asset into their hands, God specified thatthey must, as a nation, rest the land every seventh year. This was to bea national year of rest. The law applied only to agricultural land. It didnot restrict commerce, manufacturing, equipment repair, or anythingexcept planting and harvesting by owners. Urban occupations werenot under the terms of this law. This law granted a year of rest fromfield work to all those under the household authority of landowners,including hired servants.

Page 18: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

7. By the time of Jeremiah, the Israelites had been in the Promised Land for almost eightcenturies. Of this period, 490 years (70 x 7) had been spent without a sabbatical year.Jeremiah did not say when this period of law-breaking began. I presume that it began 490

957

The year of rest was an acknowledgment of the limits on man’sknowledge. Man cannot know everything about the land. He thereforewas not allowed to treat the land indefinitely as if it were a mine. The“mining” of the soil could go on for six years in seven, but not in theseventh year. He was not allowed to strip the soil of its productivity.The seventh year was a rest period for the land in the broadest sense,including worms, bugs, birds, weeds, and every other living creaturethat dwelled on or in the land. This would preserve the land’s long-run value.

This limitation on the landowner’s extraction of present incomefrom the land was a means of preserving the capitalized value of theland over time. This placed a limit on both man’s greed and ignorance.It forced the landowner to honor the future-orientation of God’scovenant. It preserved the landed inheritance for future generations.God’s sharecroppers in one generation were not allowed to underminethe future value of the land by overproduction in the present. God, asthe land’s ultimate owner, was thereby able to maintain a greaterpercentage of the land’s original capitalized value.

The Israelites did not always enforce the provisions of the sabbathland law prior to the exile. In other words, they did not enforce theterms of the original lease. God allowed this infraction to continue foralmost five centuries. Then He collected payment from a later gener-ation. “And them that had escaped from the sword carried he away toBabylon; where they were servants to him and his sons until the reignof the kingdom of Persia: To fulfil the word of the LORD by themouth of Jeremiah, until the land had enjoyed her sabbaths: for as longas she lay desolate she kept sabbath, to fulfil threescore and ten years”(II Chron. 36:20–21).7 Two generations of sharecroppers then learned

Page 19: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

years before the Babylonian captivity, i.e., sometime late in Saul’s kingship. I am usingJames Jordan’s chronology: “The Babylonian Connection,” Biblical Chronology, II (Nov.1990), p. 1: 3426 Anno Mundi = 586 B.C. The accession of Saul was 2909 AM. Jordan,“Chronologies and Kings (II),” ibid., III (Aug. 1991), p. 2. Computation: 586 + 490 = 1076B.C., i.e., 3426 AM - 490 AM = 2936 AM. David came to the throne in 2949 AM, i.e.,1063 B.C.

8. The Hebrew words translated as “meat” in verses 6 and 7 both can be translated as“food.”

958

a judicial lesson in Babylon: God has a long memory for the details ofHis law. Those who violate it will eventually pay restitution to Him bypaying restitution to their victims. In this case, they paid to the land,which rested.

A Year of Gleaning

There appears to be a problem with the translation in the KingJames Version. Actually, there is no problem, but there is a problemfor interpreters who do not take the text literally. Verse 5 says: “Thatwhich groweth of its own accord of thy harvest thou shalt not reap,neither gather the grapes of thy vine undressed: for it is a year of restunto the land.” Conclusion: someone was prohibited from reaping thefields. The next two verses are translated as follows: “And the sabbathof the land shall be meat for you; for thee, and for thy servant, and forthy maid, and for thy hired servant, and for thy stranger thatsojourneth with thee, And for thy cattle, and for the beast that are inthy land, shall all the increase thereof be meat” (vv. 6–7). Conclusion:the produce of the field served as food for someone. But if theincrease is identified as meat (i.e., food),8 then what about the prohi-bition? “That which groweth of its own accord of thy harvest thoushalt not reap, neither gather the grapes of thy vine undressed.” How

Page 20: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

959

could the increase serve as food if the crop could not lawfully beharvested?

To solve this problem, the New American Standard Version insertsa word in verse 6: products. “And all of you shall have the sabbathproducts of the land for food. . . .” The Revised Standard Versiontranslates it as follows: “The sabbath of the land shall provide food foryou. . . .” None of this is satisfactory. Why not? Because the text ofverse 5 is too specific: “That which groweth of its own accord of thyharvest thou shalt not reap, neither gather the grapes of thy vineundressed.” Someone was prohibited from harvesting. The questionis: Who?

The solution is found in the word thy. The law was addressed tolandowners. It applied to those identified in verse 4: “Six years thoushalt sow thy field, and six years thou shalt prune thy vineyard, andgather in the fruit thereof.” Those who owned the fields and vineyardswere not allowed by God to reap them in the seventh year. Thisprohibition did not apply to their hired servants, strangers in the com-munity, poor people, and the beasts of the field. “But the seventh yearthou shalt let it rest and lie still; that the poor of thy people may eat:and what they leave the beasts of the field shall eat. In like mannerthou shalt deal with thy vineyard, and with thy oliveyard” (Ex. 23:11).The prohibition did not apply to those who did not own the land.

What this law established was a year of unlimited gleaning. Hiredharvesters were not allowed into the fields and vineyards as employeesof the landowners. Instead, they were given free access as independentagents. On the one hand, landowners did not invest any money or timein seeding the fields, pruning the vineyards, or caring for the land. Thiscut their expenses in year six. On the other hand, they reaped nocrops. The crops were reaped in year seven by non-owners. Like theleftovers that were collected by the gleaners annually, so were thecrops that grew by themselves. The land’s rest was specific: rest from

Page 21: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

9. R. J. Rushdoony, The Institutes of Biblical Law (Nutley, New Jersey: Craig Press,1973), p. 140.

10. See below: “The Defection of the Levites.”

960

the activities of its owners, not rest from harvesting by non-owners.

Independence

What was the point? Rushdoony argues that this law was not hum-anitarian, meaning (I give him the benefit of the doubt) uniquelyhumanitarian, because gleaners had access to the fields every year.9

This interpretation is incorrect. This law was obviously a humanitarianlaw, for it singled out the poor and strangers. They would receivesomething from the landowner that otherwise would have been keptby him. A transfer of wealth was involved. The sabbatical land lawwas as much a humanitarian law as the annual gleaning law was. Ittreated the beasts of the fields as if they were gleaners. It treated themas servants on the weekly sabbath. In other words, the sabbatical restforced landowners to let the land alone and allow human and animalgleaners into the fields. The landowners were not allowed to use land,man, or beast for their purposes. Non-owners were allowed by Godto do whatever they wanted: to glean or not to glean. It was not thatthey were required to rest from self-employment as harvesters. Theywere not to be compelled by economic circumstances to work forlandowners. God provided them with a source of income to offset theabsence of wages. This was a compulsory wealth-redistributionprogram: from landowners to non-owners. The question is: Whoimposed the negative sanctions? Answer: the Levites.10

In the sabbatical year, all charitable, morally obligatory, zero-

Page 22: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

11. Gary North, Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Deuteronomy,2nd electronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc.,[1999] 2003), ch. 35.

961

interest loans had to be canceled (Deut. 15:1–7).11 This means that thedebtor who had been forced to labor for another landowner becausehe had gone into debt and then had defaulted on this charitable loanhad to be released from bondage. But this release from bondage didnot relieve him from the personal economic necessity of participatingin the harvesting of the crop of his former creditor and perhaps harv-esting part of his own land’s crop, which was also to lie fallow. Heachieved his release from debt in a year of heavy national dependenceon God. There was not supposed to be any planting in the seasonprior to the sabbatical year. The land was to receive its rest. So, thereleased debtor faced a problem: how to get enough to eat.

He would have faced high demand for food from the free market.If he could harvest anything, he could either consume it or sell it. Hewould possess a valuable asset – food – in a year of above-averagescarcity. This was an advantage for him. But without the landownerto serve as his intermediary, the newly debt-free Israelite would beginto regain his confidence as a free man. He would be forced to learnmarketing in the year that he would plant the eighth-year crop on hisown land, except in jubilee “weeks,” when the law also prohibitedplanting in the year after the sabbatical year. The year of his releasefrom debt or even servitude would also be a difficult year economic-ally. It was a year in which Israelites were supposed to rely on God’sgrace and their own previous thrift. This was why the newly releasedIsraelite had to be liberally provided with food (Deut. 15:13–14): toget him through the sabbatical year. The fruit of his own field wouldbelong to non-owning harvesters and beasts.

The sabbatical year was a system for forcing men to become self-consciously dependent on God’s grace. Dependent on Him, they were

Page 23: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

12. See below, “The Defection of the Levites.”

962

to become dominion-minded. Subordinate to God, they were tobecome active toward the creation. This is the mandated hierarchicalpattern for the dominion covenant: those meek before God will inheritthe earth. The year of debt release was to be the year of open accessto the fields for non-owners. It was a year of hard work for harvesters,for they harvested on their own and for their own. A new master toldthem to do this: the market.

If independent harvesters were given free access to the land’s unas-sisted production one year in seven, they would have had an incentiveto recommend land management practices that would maximizeoutput in the seventh year: crop rotation, fertilization, irrigation, etc.This does not mean that landowners were required to follow thesuggestions of the full-time harvesters, but to the extent that ownersdeferred to harvesters in gathering information and assessing its value,the sabbatical year law encouraged agricultural practices that did notstrip the land of its long-run productivity. This law, when enforced,created a class of preferred workers who had an incentive to act aseconomic agents of the land, and therefore as economic agents of thefuture.

We do not know for certain whether the gleaners would havereceived more income as secondary harvesters in a year following aninvestment of capital or as primary harvesters in a year following aninvestment of zero. As I hope to show, it is likely that the total outputof the fields was greater in a normal harvest year than in a sabbaticalyear.12 We know that when this law was enforced, the land receivedits rest, and the poor had access to the fields. God therefore placedself-interested monitors in the midst of the community. The questionwas: Would these monitors possess sufficient power or influence overlandowners through the priesthood? The answer for 490 years: no.

Page 24: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

13. Ludwig von Mises, Human Action: A Treatise on Economics (New Haven, Connec-ticut: Yale University Press, 1949), pp. 485–90.

14. North, Dominion Covenant, ch. 10.

963

The Pressure on Landowners to Save

When the law was enforced, landowners had considerable econo-mic incentive to plan for a year of no agricultural income. They had tosave enough food to get them through the seventh year. They also hadto realize that the seed corn of the sixth year would be needed at theend of the seventh year in order to provide a crop for the eighth year.This would have to be put aside late in year six to plant late in yearseven. Owners had to plan and organize for six years to prepare forthe sabbatical year. If they did not save enough food to get themthrough the sabbatical year, they would be tempted to eat their seedcorn during the sabbatical year. They had to overcome this tempta-tion. In short, they had to save.

Saving requires future-orientation. Without future-orientation, wewould consume everything today. Societies and communities that arecharacterized by what Ludwig von Mises called high time-preference13

are marked by low amounts of capital and low production. People insuch societies value present goods over future goods so highly thatthey consume almost everything today. No society that is completelypresent-oriented could survive except through charity from outside.The harsh reality of the cursed effects of scarcity (Gen. 3:17–19)14

forces members of every society to plan for the future, to save somepercentage of today’s goods for tomorrow’s needs and wants.

The law of the sabbatical year added another incentive to becomemore future-oriented. Those landowners who neglected to store foodfor a coming year of zero agricultural income would find themselvesin a bind in the sabbatical year. They might be forced to borrow

Page 25: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

15. A civil law is justified biblically because God threatens a society with corporatenegative sanctions for disobedience. These sanctions came: the Babylonian captivity.

16. One possible civil sanction: two years of rest for the land as the victim, i.e., doublerestitution.

964

enough food to feed themselves. They would therefore become debtslaves. They might even be forced by a lease agreement to leave theirfarms until the next jubilee year. They might have to become landlesswage earners or even gleaners. Someone who was more thrifty wouldthen become the land’s administrator. That is, in what was designedby God to be a year of release for Israel, improvident, present-oriented landowners would fall into poverty and servitude. This sab-batical system kept control of the land in the hands of future-oriented,efficient people.

The landowner had to forfeit income in the sabbatical year. Restingthe land was mandatory. Was this a civil law? The text does not say.If it was – and I presume that it was15 – the State was required by Godto act as the land’s agent. Owners were not allowed to oppress theland. So, this civil law suppressed a specific evil action: theexploitation of the land. It brought unspecified negative sanctionsagainst evil-doers.16 But there was another aspect of this law: manda-tory gleaning. The landowner had to allow hired servants and poorpeople into his fields to glean in the sabbatical year. Was this a case ofa civil law that imposed positive sanctions for one group at theexpense of another? Was it a State-enforced welfare program?

To answer this question, we first need to determine if this lawestablished a property right for the local poor. The fruit of the landwas to become the property of the gleaners in the sabbatical year.Which local gleaners possessed an enforceable legal claim? Thejudicial problem – which gleaners would be allowed into which fields– still remained, as it did with everyday gleaning. The law did not give

Page 26: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

965

specific legal claims to specific gleaners. This indicates that the Statewas not the enforcing agency with respect to the gleaners, eventhough it was the enforcing agency with respect to the protection ofthe land. This was not a State welfare program.

What agency was to defend the claims of the gleaners? The priest-hood. Priests had the authority to excommunicate landowners whorefused to allow gleaners into the fields. Priests could lawfully barcovenant-breakers from the Passover. They policed the sacramentalboundaries. The priests could serve as wealth-transfer agents in thiscase – defenders of the poor. It was God’s land, and He wanted Hisdelegated owners to allow gleaners into His fields. Gleaners as a classhad ecclesiastically enforceable legal claims to access to the unplanted,fallow land. But without local agents to enforce these legal claims,specific gleaners could not gain access to land owned by someonewilling to break this law.

This law’s effects were not entirely negative on landowners. First,the long-term productivity of the land was retained by the sabbaticalyear. Second, it did give landowners a year of rest. They could con-centrate on other business ventures, perhaps even going on a mission-ary-trade journey. Third, it increased the economic pressure on land-owners to exercise thrift in years one through six.

The discipline of thrift – future-orientation – is not natural to fallenman. It must be learned. Where it is learned, and where its require-ments become habitual, the individual becomes the owner of a majorcapital asset. The psychology of thrift is a very valuable resource. Inthe category of “human resource” or “human capital,” the habit ofthrift rivals the importance of the famous Protestant work ethic. Infact, thrift is basic to this ethic. Max Weber wrote in 1905 regardingthe Protestant ethic that “Old Testament morality was able to give apowerful impetus to that spirit of self-righteous and sober legalitywhich was so characteristic of the worldly asceticism of this form of

Page 27: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

17. Max Weber, The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, trans. Talcott Parsons(New York: Charles Scribner’s Sons, [1905] 1958), p. 165.

18. Ibid., p. 172.

966

Protestantism.”17 Thrift has been a crucial aspect of this worldlyasceticism, he wrote: “When the limitation of consumption is combin-ed with this release of acquisitive activity, the inevitable practicalresult is obvious: accumulation of capital through ascetic compulsionto save.”18 The sabbatical land law pressured Israelite landowners tomaster the discipline of thrift.

The Threat of Debt

In the seventh year, all charitable, zero-interest loans to poor Israel-ites became null and void (Deut. 15:1). Creditors could not legallycollect from impoverished debtors. Meanwhile, the economy grewtight: reduced food production. Improvident landowners went lookingfor loans to get them through the year. There would have beengreater-than-normal demand for interest-bearing loans, i.e., higherinterest rates. This would have tended to squeeze the weakestborrowers out of the loan market. Lenders prefer to lend to those whoare likely to repay. On the other hand, if an evil man wanted to trap aweak debtor in order to gain control over his labor if he defaulted, theyear of national gleaning would have been an ideal time. The recentlyliberated debtors would have known this. Their memory of theirprevious bondage was to keep them from succumbing to thistemptation. The poor had access to the untilled fields of the land-owners. They were expected to take advantage of this unique situationand stay out of debt. They were not to “return to Egypt” by going intodebt and risking another round of bondage.

Page 28: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

967

Any landowner who had not planned carefully would face a crisisin year seven. Without sufficient thrift in the previous six years, hemight have been forced to enter the debt market to save his business.But he would have come to a lender as a businessman, not as apoverty-stricken brother in the faith. There was no moral pressure onanyone to lend to him. Such moral compulsion to lend applied only toloans to the poor (Deut. 15:7–10). A land-secured loan threatened theborrower greatly: to default the loan meant the forced sale of his landuntil the loan was repaid or until the next jubilee year.

Lenders would have been more ready to lend to landowners thanto most poor men: secure collateral. This gave landowners an advan-tage in the loan markets. But there was great risk for the debtor.There was also the embarrassment of having to mortgage the family’sproperty. The present-oriented landowner would then face the needto repay the loan, making preparation for the next sabbatical year evenmore burdensome. The debt trap loomed much larger to the personwho fell behind. This is the grim reality of debt.

The sabbatical year was therefore a major burden on landowners.There is little doubt that they would have preferred to avoid thisburden. If this law was going to be enforced, there had to be anagency of enforcement that had an economic incentive to do so.Which agency was it? And why did it fail to enforce the law prior tothe Babylonian exile?

The Defection of the Levites

We know that this law was not enforced for centuries prior to theexile. Jeremiah identified their failure to honor the year of release asthe cause of the exile: “At the end of seven years let ye go every manhis brother an Hebrew, which hath been sold unto thee; and when he

Page 29: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

968

hath served thee six years, thou shalt let him go free from thee: butyour fathers hearkened not unto me, neither inclined their ear” (Jer.34:14).

The enforcing agents, the Levites (gleaning law) and civil magis-trates (land law), did not assert their authority. Why not? We do notknow. This may be one of those cases in which they had a short-termincentive not to enforce the law. In a normal year, they were entitledto tithes and taxes from landowners and gleaners. In a sabbatical year,only the gleaners paid. The landowners harvested nothing for theirown account. Perhaps the collectors of tithes and taxes did not consi-der the soil’s long-term output, allowing landowners to plant and har-vest.

I conclude that the total output of the land in a normal year wasgreater than during a sabbatical year. Levites and civil magistratesreceived a larger tithe in non-sabbatical years. Thus, they had lessshort-term economic incentive to see that the sabbatical year law wasenforced. They had to enforce the law because God required them todo so, not because they were paid to do so. The tribe of Levi was tocooperate with the local monitors: hired hands, the poor, and stran-gers. Levites were required to see to it that the sabbath year’s gleaninglaw was enforced. They refused. They forfeited their position as sanc-tioning agents on this issue. As a result, the nation went into captivity.After their return, Israel honored this law (I Macc. 6:49, 53). Ezekielhad prophesied that heathen residents in the land would participate ina new allocation of land (Ezek. 47:21–23), but we do not know if thejubilee laws were honored.

The Poorest of the Poor

Which gleaners fared best? It is understandable that the hired

Page 30: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

969

harvesters were content with their arrangement during normal years.They were paid to work. They probably would have preferred to workfor landowners in the sabbatical year had the owners planted the cropsin year six. The poorer members of the community, however, probablyfared better comparatively during the sabbatical years. Perhaps thetotal harvest going to them would have been larger in sabbatical yearsthan with conventional gleaning in normal years, despite the fact thatno one would have planted crops in year six. We cannot know forsure. What we do know is that this law was not enforced for half amillennium. The land was not given its rest.

There were no monitors in positions of authority with a clear-cuteconomic incentive to see that the law was enforced. Those whomight have had this incentive would have been the poorest membersof the community, or, in the case of strangers, non-citizens: men withlittle authority. So, the law went unenforced until after the return fromBabylon. Only after God had demonstrated that He would bringnegative sanctions through a foreign invasion did Israel obey the law.In the days of the Maccabees, they still honored it. It was their fear ofGod and His negative historical sanctions, not positive economicincentives, that changed their behavior.

In Search of an Explanation

We now come to a comment made by Robert North, a liberal Jesuitscholar, whose voluminous study of the jubilee law is as unreadable asit is theologically perverse. He cites Germanic sources throughout,and he imports their presuppositions. He even invokes the classicassertion shared with equal enthusiasm by theological liberals and neo-evangelicals: the Bible is not a textbook of [ ]. “Though thePentateuch was not meant as a textbook of economics, still if a

Page 31: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

19. Robert North, Sociology of the Biblical Jubilee (Rome: Pontifical Biblical Institute,1954), p. 115.

20. Ibid., p. 116.

21. Ibid., p. 117.

22. Ibid., p. 118.

23. Ibid., p. 119.

970

universal fallow can be shown to have been economically impossible,then according to sound hermeneutic principles it is legitimate to seeksome other explanation for the text.”19 He then cites a page and a halfof Germans who have concluded that fallow land on a national basiscould not have taken place in the same year. He adds that “a fallowwithout plowing would be useless and positively detrimental; . . .”20

If this interpretation is correct, then God was clearly being a bit of atyrant for having sent the heirs of these people into bondage for theirhaving neglected to do what was not only economically impossible butagriculturally detrimental. This sounds like an unwise conclusion, evenfor a theologically liberal Jesuit.

He cites another German – there are always plenty of Germanacademics to cite in support of any argument – that perhaps there wassufficient agricultural productivity for the Israelites to save enoughfood to feed themselves in the seventh year.21 He then moves from adiscussion of thrift to a discussion of the need for miraculous cropyields, either annually or in the sixth year, to produce this surplus.22

He never says which theory he prefers.The real goal of the sabbatical year, he says, was care for the poor.

This means that a policy of rotating one-seventh of the crop wouldhave met this criterion.23 (This highly practical suggestion comes froma rarity in his text, an American scholar.) Of course, this would notinclude the number-one criterion of the text: a national year of rest.

Page 32: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

24. Idem.

25. Ibid., p. 120.

26. Clyde Haberman, “The Rabbis’ Almanack of Seventh-Year Farming,” New YorkTimes (Dec. 10, 1992). The year 1992 was the sixth year in the cycle.

27. Israel Shahak, Jewish History, Jewish Religion: The Weight of Three Thousand Years(Boulder, Colorado: Pluto Press, 1994), p. 43.

971

He admits as much: “Obviously our interpretation runs counter to thesurface-sense of certain expressions of the sacred text, though formany of these we have already defended an acceptable alternative.”24

Conclusion: there was no true fallow; it was a rotating fallow.25

Modern Israel’s Version of Obedience

The modern State of Israel pretends to honor this law, and hassince the 1880’s. Every seventh year, the farmland of the nation istransferred by the Minister of Internal Affairs to the Chief Rabbinate,which sells title to an anonymous gentile, usually an Arab, who retainsformal ownership for one year. Then he sells it back. By Rabbinic law,he is outside the sabbatical year’s requirements, so he does notenforce this law. He sells back the land to the Chief Rabbinate at theend of the sabbatical year, which in turn returns formal ownership tothe de facto owners. “If we were to stop marketing our products toEurope even for one year, we’d be finished,” according to theDirector General of the Ministry of Agriculture.26 Non-ZionistOrthodox Jewish rabbis refuse to go along, however, since by Jewishlaw, Jews are not allowed to sell land in Palestine to gentiles.27 Theyorganize special shops in sabbatical years that sell fruits and vegetables

Page 33: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

28. Ibid., p. 108, n. 17.

29. Ibid., p. 45.

972

grown by Arabs on Arab land.28

(A similar strategy is used during Passover week. The law requiresall leaven to be removed from every Jewish household. This makes itdifficult for grain merchants. Solution: observant Jews sell all of theseprohibited substances to the local rabbi, who sells them to the ChiefRabbinate, which sells them to a gentile for a week. Then he sells themback. By a special dispensation, these multiple sales are presumed toinclude the leavened substances of non-practicing Jews, too.)29

New Testament Applications

The jubilee laws are important for Christians because of Jesus’ firstpublic announcement concerning the nature of His ministry:

And there was delivered unto him the book of the prophet Esaias. Andwhen he had opened the book, he found the place where it was written,The Spirit of the Lord is upon me, because he hath anointed me topreach the gospel to the poor; he hath sent me to heal thebrokenhearted, to preach deliverance to the captives, and recovering ofsight to the blind, to set at liberty them that are bruised, To preach theacceptable year of the Lord. And he closed the book, and he gave itagain to the minister, and sat down. And the eyes of all them that werein the synagogue were fastened on him. And he began to say untothem, This day is this scripture fulfilled in your ears (Luke 4: 17–21).

Jesus’ application of Isaiah’s language of liberation indicates that

Page 34: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

30. Gary North, Treasure and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Luke, 2nd elec-tronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc., [2000]2003), ch. 6.

31. This is the suggestion of Robert North, Sociology of the Biblical Jubilee, pp. 87–90.

32. A. Löwy, A Treatise on the Sabbatical Cycle and the Jubilee (New York: Hermon,[1866] 1974), pp. 3–4.

973

He saw His ministry as the fulfillment of the jubilee year.30 This isconsistent with the New Testament’s judicial theology of rest. Jesus’work in history is the judicial foundation of man’s sabbatical rest; Hiskingdom is the definitive basis in history for man’s future rest (Heb.4:1–11).

There is a great deal of confusion in modern Christian circles, bothfundamentalist and liberationist, regarding the applicability of thejubilee laws in the New Covenant era. Furthermore, Christians cangain little from a study of the rabbinical sources dealing with thejubilee, since very few of these texts deal in detail with these post-temple applications of the jubilee laws. There is no treatise on the jubi-lee in either the Mishna or the Talmud, perhaps because the rabbisconsidered the jubilee laws abrogated from the era of the Babylonianexile until the coming of the Messiah.31 This is not to say that theTalmud does not mention the jubilee. It does. So did the Geonim, theprincipals of the Jewish academies in Babylonia in the medieval era.But the information they conveyed is not consistent.32

The question arises: Is the sabbatical year law still in force? This isanother way of asking: What in the New Testament may have annulledit?

First, the model for the sabbatical year was the weekly sabbath: aday of rest at the end of the week. In the New Covenant, the locus ofauthority of sabbath enforcement has shifted from the State andchurch to the individual. This is the judicial basis for the annulment of

Page 35: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

33. Gary North, The Sinai Strategy: Economics and the Ten Commandments (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1986), ch. 4. Revised edition: 2006.

34. Ibid., Appendix A: “The Economic Implications of the Sabbath.”

974

the death penalty for violating the weekly sabbath (Ex. 31:14– 15).33

Second, the law in Israel established a national sabbatical yeargoverning both agriculture and charitable debt. This was possible toimpose because the Israelites had entered the land as conquerors at aspecific point in time. That historical starting point no longer exists.

The absence of a fixed sabbatical year could be changed todaythrough civil legislation, but is there biblical justification for this? Onlyin the name of ecology. The individual is to enforce the weeklysabbath, not the State.34 The same is true of any seventh-year sabbath.Is the individual still duty-bound by God to honor the sabbatical year?Does God threaten negative sanctions, corporate or individual, againstthose who refuse to honor its provisions? Or was the sabbatical yearlimited to the Mosaic Covenant?

Were the sabbatical year laws exclusively part of the jubilee system?No. The law was given first in Exodus 23:10–11. It was givenprimarily for the benefit of the poor in the land and secondarily for thebeasts of the field (v. 11). The context was the sabbath in general (v.12), not the jubilee system.

The identification of the beasts of the field as recipients of thebenefit of rest leads to the broader question of just which beasts Godhas in mind. Did He mean domestic animals only? Or is the wild beast also included? What about the worm and the insect?

Ecology

Man has creaturely limits on his knowledge. He is not omniscient,

Page 36: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

975

nor will he ever be. He can harm land through mono-crop agricultureand other techniques that can prove to be exploitative over time.Overuse of pesticides in modern times may prove to be a cause ofmajor ecological damage. Scientists do not presently agree on this.Eventually, a majority of them may agree, although it may take a crisisto produce such agreement, or else generations of additionalagricultural productivity. The question is: Is a compulsory year of restfor the sake of the land established by God’s law? Should the Statecompel the owner of every farm, every garden, and every vineyard tocease cultivating his land one year in seven – not necessarily allenterprises in the same year, but each enterprise one year in seven?Alternatively, should land-use enforcers be sent out to police everyfarm, determining that one-seventh of each plot under cultivation beleft fallow each year? The regulatory nightmare that would resultfrom either interpretation suggests an answer: no. But is the potentialcost of regulation a sufficient reason for abandoning this law? No.There has to be a judicial reason for ignoring any of God’s Old Cov-enant laws, not mere pragmatism or presumed convenience. The fam-iliar refrain is not sufficient: “God’s Old Testament laws applied onlyto an ancient agricultural economy.” That is an invalid objectioncovenantally; it is also weak in this instance. This happens to be anagricultural law. If the law’s primary goal was ecological – rest for thecreatures of the field and soil – then the New Covenant can be said tohave changed this law’s validity only if it established a new relation-ship among God, man, and the land. Did it? Yes. The land ceased tobe a judicial agent of God.

Sanctions and Sanctification

First, we have already considered one major change in relation to

Page 37: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

35. Chapter 17.

36. Julian L. Simon, The Ultimate Resource (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton UniversityPress, 1981), ch. 1; Simon and Herman Kahn (eds.), The Resourceful Earth: A Responseto ‘Global 2000’(New York: Basil Blackwell, 1984); E. Calvin Beisner, Prospects forGrowth: A Biblical View of Population, Resources, and the Future (Westchester, Illinois:Crossway, 1990), ch. 7.

37. The erosion school is best represented in the United States by the tabloid Acres, USA;the conventional view by the United States Department of Agriculture and universityagricultural schools.

38. If the nanotechnology revolution ever becomes a reality, as I believe it will,mankind’s food supply will be able to be produced by microscopic machines usingmolecular raw materials. K. Eric Drexler, Engines of Creation (Garden City, New York:

976

the land’s function as a judicial agent for God. The Promised Landvomited out the Canaanites (Lev. 18:28). This judicial act is now per-formed by Jesus Christ (Rev. 3:16).35 The land no longer serves as thejudicial agent of God. Second, the curse of the land was definitivelyovercome by the New Covenant. Men are no longer polluted rituallyby the land. This is why foot-washing is no longer ritually mandatoryin the post-resurrection, post-temple era. Progressive sanctification,individually and corporately, steadily removes the restraints of theland’s scarcity. This has been happening rapidly for at least two cen-turies. The price of agricultural commodities compared to the price oflabor has steadily dropped as the jurisdiction of the free marketeconomy has advanced.36

The exploitation of the land, net, may still be going on. We may befacing an agricultural calamity as a result of our techniques ofagricultural production and land management. Or we may not. Theecological evidence is unclear; well-informed people can be found onboth sides in this debate.37 The price evidence, however, is clear: noagricultural calamity is foreseen by those whom we reward to forecastsuch possibilities. The industrial revolution has also been an agricul-tural revolution.38

Page 38: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

Anchor/ Doubleday, 1986). The debate over a looming agricultural productivity crisis willprobably shift from the misuse of the land to the misuse of “free” resources, mainly movingfluids that cannot easily be assigned to owners.

39. Gary North, Cooperation and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Romans, 2ndelectronic edition (West Fork, Arkansas: Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 2002),ch. 14.

977

The covenantally significant question is: Can we legitimately attri-bute a supposedly looming agricultural calamity to our failure to restthe land? Had we required a year of national rest for the land, wouldthis have offset all the other commercial farming practices thatsupposedly erode the land’s long-term productivity? There is no wayto know. We are comparing a conjectural future (famine) with a con-jectural past (the rate of land erosion under the sabbatical year). So,in order to understand the sabbatical land law in the Mosaic economy,we have to decide in terms of biblical judicial issues, not ecology.

This is not to say that resting the land will not prove to be a meansof increasing long-term agricultural output, and therefore income, butthe test must be profit and loss under free market conditions. Thegeneral law of the New Covenant sabbath must prevail: the decisionof each individual landowner operating under the sovereign jurisdic-tion of his conscience. We dare not move from the annulled jubileeyear laws to the sabbatical land law in New Covenant times, nor darewe move from the New Covenant sabbath to a national year of rest.This leaves the landowner in charge. Paul wrote: “One man esteemethone day above another: another esteemeth every day alike. Let everyman be fully persuaded in his own mind. He that regardeth the day,regardeth it unto the Lord; and he that regardeth not the day, to theLord he doth not regard it” (Rom. 14:5–6a).39 The same covenantalprinciple of individual jurisdiction also applies to the sabbatical yearof rest.

Page 39: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

978

Conclusion

The judicial foundations of the sabbatical year of rest were two-fold: (1) the sabbath rest principle; (2) God’s original ownership of theland. At the time of the conquest, God transferred control over theland to families that held legal title on a sharecropping basis, operatingunder specific terms of the original leasehold agreement. The leaseprovided a payment to God (the tithe), i.e., a high percentage returnto God’s authorized sharecropper-owners (90 percent before taxes),and a provision for the maintenance of the long-term capital value ofthe land (the sabbatical year). Those residents in Israel who did notown the land had legal title to the output of the land: unrestrictedharvest in sabbatical years. The legal title of the gleaners was to beenforced by the Levites and priests on land owners.

The judicial issue of the sabbatical year was rest: rest for the land,hired workers, and animals. This also included release from therequirement to repay charitable debts (Deut. 15). By “rest,” the lawmeant a respite for the landless from the requirement to work for thelanded. This law governed agricultural land and those who worked it.There is nothing in the Bible to indicate that it governed any nonagri-cultural occupation.

This law pressured landowners to plan and save for the sabbaticalyear. They had to store up both food corn and seed corn. When thislaw was enforced, it forced them to develop the habit of thrift, i.e.,future-orientation. The law also required landowners to forfeit theautomatic (though not “natural”) productivity of the land in the sev-enth year. The poor, the stranger, the field animals, and the regularharvesters all had a legal claim on this production, if they were willingto do the work to glean it.

The Levites were the enforcers of this law as it applied to thegleaners’ lawful access to the fruits of the land. The Levites refused.

Page 40: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

979

This indicates they had little or no short-term economic incentive toenforce it. This in turn indicates that their tithe income was greaterwhen the land was planted and harvested. Finally, this indicates thatthere was less net agricultural output in the seventh year than in theother six.

This law was good for the land and all the creatures great and smallthat inhabited it. Owners were restrained in their use of God’s land.Agricultural practices that overworked the land were restrained by thislaw. The land, as God’s judicial agent, deserved its rest. This law man-dated it. If this land-protecting aspect of the law was enforced by theState, as I believe it was, it rested on the legal status of the land asGod’s judicial agent, not on the State as an agency of wealth redistri-bution to the gleaners. This law is no longer in force in the New Tes-tament era because the land ceased to be a covenantal agent in A.D.71.

The sabbatical year law was enforced after the Babylonian exile.The fear of God is a great incentive. During the exile, God had substi-tuted His negative sanctions in history for the failure of the priesthoodand the State to enforce the sabbatical year law. Exile was God’spartial disinheritance of Israel. It warned Israel of comprehensivedisinheritance, should the nation continue to rebel. The exile alteredland tenure: a new distribution replaced the original distribution underJoshua. The exile severed the judicial link between each family’s plotand the conquest generation. The jubilee land laws had been estab-lished by genocide, but genocide was neither authorized by God norpossible after the exile. The jubilee’s heathen-slave laws remained inforce, but the residents who participated in any post-exilic distributionwere to become immune to the threat of permanent servitude byIsraelites

The sabbatical land law was an extension of the law of the sabbath.It was not a subset of the jubilee land laws. On the contrary, the jubi-

Page 41: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

980

lee land laws were temporary applications of the sabbath law’s prin-ciple of rest. If there are any New Testament applications of the sab-batical year of rest for the land, they are based on ecology or the gen-eral authority of sabbath rules, not on the jubilee’s military conquest.This transfers the locus of authority to the landowner: individual, notcorporate.

Summary

The jubilee laws begin with a consideration of the sabbath.The sabbatical year of rest was more fundamental than the jubilee

land laws.The resting of the land is mandated in terms of God’s creation (Ex.

20:11).As the owner of the Promised Land, God had the authority to

establish the leasehold arrangements.Leasing land long-term requires a carefully designed leasehold

arrangement.An absentee landlord should design a contract that does not require

expensive local monitoring on his part.The Bible pictures God as an absentee landlord.The dominion covenant does not treat men as supervised coolies in

the field.The lease is basically a sharecropping contract: 90 percent remains

with the leaseholder.The land was the inheritance of the Israelites (excluding Levites).Agricultural land had to be rested every seventh year.Planting late in year six and in year seven and field work by

landowners and their agents in year seven were prohibited.The sabbatical rest forced man to acknowledge limits on his knowl-

Page 42: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

981

edge: unknown consequences of overworking the land.This law helped to preserve the land’s productivity.The Israelites did not enforce the law for 490 years prior to the

exile.God sent them into captivity in order to give the land its accumu-

lated rest.The landowners were prohibited from harvesting their land.Non-household hired servants, the poor, and strangers were allow-

ed to harvest whatever grew of its own accord.Beasts were allowed to eat of the crop.The sabbatical year was a year of unlimited gleaning; the whole

field was considered as leftovers or corners.This was a humanitarian law.Hired servants and beasts were left alone in the sabbatical year: free

from the authority of land-owning taskmasters.Season-long gleaning replaced wages.Newly debt-free servants had to learn marketing skills without the

landowner as their intermediary.They had to beware of falling into debt to men whose goal was to

put them back into bondage.Hired workers had an incentive to recommend and obey rules that

would increase the land’s fertility.These workers acted as economic agents of the land and of the

future.They served as God’s local monitors, but they possessed little

authority.This law created an incentive for landowners to save.Saving requires future-orientation.Landowners had to save if they were to survive the sabbatical year

without going into debt.The law was a form of compulsory wealth redistribution, to be

Page 43: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 24 . . . Leviticus 25:1–7

982

enforced by the Levites.Habits of thrift must be learned.The psychology of thrift is a valuable resource.Interest rates probably would have risen in sabbatical years.This was a threat to improvident landowners and newly released

bondservants.The sabbatical land law was a major economic burden on land-

owners.The Levites rebelled, refusing to enforce the law.Levites had a financial incentive to ignore this law: reduced tithe

income in the short run.The total output of the unplanted land was less in sabbatical years.Because the Levites defected, God sent the nation into captivity.After the exile, Israel honored the seventh year.The jubilee land laws ended forever with the exile, for exile severed

the plots’ judicial links with the conquest.The jubilee’s heathen slavery laws did not cease with the exile.The language of jubilee liberation describes Jesus’ ministry (Luke

4:17–21).The New Testament has transferred the locus of authority to

enforce the weekly sabbath to the individual.The common national year of rest was based on Israel’s conquest

of the land.There is no unified national or international church today, i.e., no

agent of enforcement.The sabbatical year laws originally were announced in Exodus

23:10–11.Ecology is relevant: beasts of the field.The New Testament changed man’s relationship to the land. The land is no longer God’s judicial agent.The land no longer pollutes man ritually; hence, no foot-washing.

Page 44: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Sabbatical Year

983

The jubilee’s sabbatical land law is no longer in force under theNew Covenant.

No agricultural calamity seems imminent; agricultural pricescontinue to fall compared to wages (two centuries).

The ecological evidence on the land’s erosion and productivity ismixed.

Societies must decide the sabbath-year issues in terms of biblicaljudicial issues, not ecology.

The individual conscience of the landowner should rule in this case,not church or State.

Page 45: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

984

25

BOUNDARIES OF THE JUBILEE LAND LAWS

And thou shalt number seven sabbaths of years unto thee, seven timesseven years; and the space of the seven sabbaths of years shall beunto thee forty and nine years. Then shalt thou cause the trumpet ofthe jubile to sound on the tenth day of the seventh month, in the dayof atonement shall ye make the trumpet sound throughout all yourland. And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim libertythroughout all the land unto all the inhabitants thereof: it shall be ajubile unto you; and ye shall return every man unto his possession,and ye shall return every man unto his family. A jubile shall thatfiftieth year be unto you: ye shall not sow, neither reap that whichgroweth of itself in it, nor gather the grapes in it of thy vine undres-sed. For it is the jubile; it shall be holy unto you: ye shall eat theincrease thereof out of the field. In the year of this jubile ye shallreturn every man unto his possession (Lev. 25:8–13).

The theocentric meaning of the jubilee law was God’s ownershipof both the land and the people. He reserved the right to dictate theterms of inheritance to the Israelites. This inheritance included ruralland, heathen slaves, and homes owned by Levites in Levitical cities.It also included citizenship.

The Jubilee Cycle

First, we begin with the problem of identifying the jubilee cycle.Rabbis from at least the completion of the Talmud (c. 500 A.D.)

Page 46: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

1. A. Löwy, A Treatise on the Sabbatical Cycle and the Jubilee (New York: Hermon,[1866] 1974), pp. 7–9. He cited numerous sources.

2. Ibid., pp. 9–10.

3. Ibid., pp. 10–11.

4. Ibid., p. 12.

5. Ibid., pp. 13–16.

6. Gary North, The Dominion Covenant: Genesis, 2nd ed. (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1987), ch. 5: “God’s Week and Man’s Week.”

985

taught that the jubilee year was scheduled every fiftieth year.1 MostChristians have agreed with this view through the centuries, but notall. A few have thought that the forty-ninth year was counted as thefiftieth.2 Among those commentators who accept the fiftieth year asthe jubilee year, there has been debate over the first year in the nextcycle. Most Jewish commentators have argued that the fifty-first yearconstituted the first year in the next cycle. This was the prevailingopinion of the contributors to the Talmud. Maimonides agreed.3 OtherTalmudic Jews have believed that the jubilee year itself counted as thefirst year.4 There have been other theories held by a handful ofscholars.5

The idea that the fiftieth year served as the first year in the nextsabbath cycle suggests a parallel: the shift from the Old Covenant’sseventh-day sabbath to the New Covenant’s eighth-day sabbath, whichitself served as the inauguration of a first-day sabbath, i.e., the shiftfrom the Old Covenant’s week (6–1) to the New Covenant’s week(1–6).6 Jesus’ resurrection took place on the eighth day, i.e., the dayafter the Jewish sabbath, a sabbath that took place on the Sadducees’

Page 47: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

7. Jesus celebrated Passover on Thursday evening, Nissan 14, the Pharisees’ Passover,and was tried and crucified the next day. The Judean dating, used by the Sadducees, wasdifferent. They celebrated Passover beginning on Nissan 15 (Nissan 14, as calculated bythe Sadducees), a sabbath night, so they refused to enter the Praetorium when they tookJesus before Pilate, lest they be defiled for Passover (John 18:28b). They called for theRomans to remove the dead bodies because the sabbath that year corresponded to theJudean Passover (John 19:31). On the distinction between the Pharisees’ and theSadducees’ respective Passover dates, see Harold W. Hohner, Chronological Aspects ofthe Life of Christ (Grand Rapids, Michigan: Zondervan, 1977), ch. 4, especially the charton page 89.

8. Löwy, Sabbatical Cycle, pp. 23–24.

9. Ibid., p. 19.

10. James Jordan, “Jubilee, Part 2,” Biblical Chronology, V (March 1993), p. 1.

986

Passover that year.7 Sunday is the first day of the week for mostChristians: the symbolic equivalent of the eighth day. The theory ofthe fiftieth year as the first year in the next cycle is certainly appealingto the Christian (and also to the Talmud’s Rabbi Jehudah),8 but wecannot appeal to historical records of the jubilee as empirical tests ofthis theory, because there is no biblical record or any other ancientcontemporary record of Israel’s ever having celebrated a jubilee year.9

The Timing of the Jubilee

Second, we need to consider the timing of the day of jubilee. It isnot generally recognized that there were two calendars in ancientIsrael: priestly and kingly, sanctuary and land. They corresponded tothe two shekels: sanctuary (Lev. 27:3, 25) and ordinary. James Jordanbelieves that the two calendars corresponded to two separate govern-ment systems.10 The religious year began in the spring: the firstmonth, Nisan (Esth. 3:7), when Passover was celebrated (Ex. 12). Thecivil year began in the fall: on the first day the seventh month of the

Page 48: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

11. Rosh. Hash., 1:3; cited in “Month,” Cyclopaedia of Biblical, Theological, and Ec-clesiastical Literature, edited by John M’Clintock and James Strong, 12 vols. (New York:Harper & Bros., 1876), IV, p. 547.

12. Jordan notes that the official first year of the reign of a king of Judah ran from thefirst day of the seventh month of the religious year to the last day of the sixth month of thenext religious year.

987

religious calendar (called Tishri in the Talmud).11 This was marked bya day of sabbath rest (Lev. 23:24–25). Ten days later, the day ofatonement took place (Lev. 23:27–28).12 As we shall see, the jubileewas tied to the civil (land) year. This is why the jubilee was a predom-inantly civil event. It launched the next cycle of inheritance. Thisinheritance was predominately civil: a matter of citizenship. Thosewho were heirs of the generation of the conquest were citizens; thejubilee restored them to their judicial tokens of citizenship: their land.On the fifteenth day, the feast of booths or Tabernacles took place(Lev. 23:34–36, 39–43).

In the jubilee year, trumpets were to be blown throughout the landon the tenth day of the seventh month. This marked the great year ofrelease. It was also a day of rest because it was the day of atonement(Lev. 23:28). The next day, men dwelling near the borders of Israelhad to begin their walk to Jerusalem to celebrate the feast of Taber-nacles (Booths). In no more than four days, they had to complete theirjourney. This time requirement restrained any major extension of thegeographical boundaries of Israel. On the day above all other days inIsrael’s life that was tied to geographical boundaries – jubilee’s day oflanded inheritance – the timing of the jubilee and Tabernacles estab-lished tight limits on the size of the nation. Israel could never becomean expansionist territorial empire and still honor the day ofatonement (rest), the jubilee year (inheritance), and the feast of Tab-ernacles (celebration). When the Israelites walked to Jerusalem in thejubilee year, all but the Levites went as rural land owners and citizens,

Page 49: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

13. The reader may think: “This is obvious. What is the big deal?” Try to find any com-mentary on Leviticus that discusses the relationship between the timing of the day ofatonement-jubilee and the growth of empire. The silence of the commentators is testimonyto their unwillingness to take the Bible’s literal texts seriously (theological liberalism) orto take political theory seriously (theological conservatism).

988

even urban dwellers who had leased out their land to others. But theycould never lawfully walk from an inheritance located very far fromJerusalem. If Israel ever became an empire, Israelites living near theouter boundaries would forfeit their inheritance in the original land.13

The Day of Atonement

The year of jubilee was to begin on the day of atonement (yomkippur). The theological significance of this timing is readily apparent:the day of atonement was the day on which the people of Israel madea formal public acknowledgment of their dependence on the grace ofGod in escaping from God’s required punishment for sin. There hadto be an animal sacrifice as part of this formal worship ceremony. Itwas a day of affliction: death for an animal and public humility for theparticipants. No work was allowed on that day. The day of atonementwas a day of rest – the ultimate day of rest in ancient Israel,symbolizing covenant-keeping man’s rest from the curse of sin. It wasa day set apart for each person’s examination of his legal state beforeGod and the self-affliction of his soul.

For on that day shall the priest make an atonement for you, to cleanseyou, that ye may be clean from all your sins before the LORD. It shallbe a sabbath of rest unto you, and ye shall afflict your souls, by astatute for ever. And the priest, whom he shall anoint, and whom heshall consecrate to minister in the priest’s office in his father’s stead,shall make the atonement, and shall put on the linen clothes, even the

Page 50: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

989

holy garments: And he shall make an atonement for the holy sanctuary,and he shall make an atonement for the tabernacle of the congregation,and for the altar, and he shall make an atonement for the priests, andfor all the people of the congregation. And this shall be an everlastingstatute unto you, to make an atonement for the children of Israel for alltheir sins once a year. And he did as the LORD commanded Moses(Lev. 16: 30–34).

Also on the tenth day of this seventh month there shall be a day ofatonement: it shall be an holy convocation unto you; and ye shallafflict your souls, and offer an offering made by fire unto the LORD.And ye shall do no work in that same day: for it is a day of atonement,to make an atonement for you before the LORD your God. Forwhatsoever soul it be that shall not be afflicted in that same day, heshall be cut off from among his people. And whatsoever soul it be thatdoeth any work in that same day, the same soul will I destroy fromamong his people. Ye shall do no manner of work: it shall be a statutefor ever throughout your generations in all your dwellings (Lev.23:27–31).

Once each half century, the day of affliction was to become the day

of liberation. The meaning of the Hebrew verb for “afflict” issubmission or humility. An example of submission is found in theincident in which Hagar had fled from Sarai, and the angel thenconfronted her. “And the angel of the LORD said unto her, Return tothy mistress, and submit thyself under her hands” (Gen. 16:9). Anexample of humility is where God brought low the children of Israelin the wilderness period for their failure to submit to Him: “And thoushalt remember all the way which the LORD thy God led thee theseforty years in the wilderness, to humble thee, and to prove thee, toknow what was in thine heart, whether thou wouldest keep hiscommandments, or no. And he humbled thee, and suffered thee tohunger, and fed thee with manna, which thou knewest not, neither did

Page 51: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

14. Ray R. Sutton, That You May Prosper: Dominion By Covenant, 2nd ed. (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, [1987] 1992), ch. 2.

990

thy fathers know; that he might make thee know that man doth notlive by bread only, but by every word that proceedeth out of themouth of the LORD doth man live” (Deut. 8:2–3). In both instances,the covenantal issue was covenantal subordination: point two of thebiblical covenant model.14

The day of national liberation and family inheritance took place onthe day of formal subordination to God. The imagery is obvious. Onlythrough submission to God can man experience liberation. Autonomyis not liberation. This is why modern humanism’s free marketeconomic theory, which is both agnostic and individualistic, is not thesource of the free society that its defenders proclaim. If we begin oureconomic analysis with the presupposition of the autonomous individ-ual in an autonomous cosmos, we begin with a hypothesis that cannotlead to liberty and maintain it.

A Question of Subordination

The year of jubilee began with the blowing of a trumpet, a trumpetannouncing the day of atonement. The ram’s horn, yobale (Josh. 6: 4–5), is the origin of the English transliteration, jubilee (Lev. 25:10–13). The jubilee year followed a sabbatical year of rest for the land, ayear in which the agricultural poor, the stranger, and the beasts of thefield did not harvest the fields for the fields’ owners; they worked fortheir own direct benefit.

The Hierarchy of God’s Grace

Page 52: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

15. Chapter 27.

991

The sabbatical year temporarily broke the economic hierarchy link-ing the agricultural employer, his employees, and the land. The sab-batical year was to be a year of release for employees from direct andpersonal economic subordination to employers. It was also to be arelease for the land, which was not to be planted in the sixth year. Theowner of the land, God, for one year transferred the fruit of His landto non-owners, i.e., a different set of sharecroppers who could law-fully retain 90 percent of whatever the land, under God’s directadministration, might produce. They became dependent on God’sgrace rather than the owners’ sowing of the fields and care of the land.Like the wilderness that had brought forth manna six days out ofseven, so was the land of Israel to become in the sabbatical year: thevisible arena of God’s grace. God promised to bless Israel with anadded measure of grace: the miraculous sixth-year crop, the “manna”preceding the jubilee year.15

The Hierarchy of Market Competition

Hierarchy is an inescapable concept. There is no escape from sub-ordination. There can be movement from one form of subordinationto another, but not its abolition. The market that governed the agri-cultural employee indirectly through the decisions of his employer sixyears out of seven would, in a sabbatical year, bring its pressures onhim directly. His six years as a subordinate to land-owning masterswere intended to prepare him for a year of service to an impersonalmaster: the competitive market. Consumers bring their judgment uponproducers through the dual sanctions of profit and loss. The employee,when he became the master of his own production unit in the jubilee

Page 53: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

992

year, would have to learn to meet the demands of both nature (foodfor his family) and the market. He would find that he was still underauthority. The system of sabbatical years was designed to give everylandless field hand the opportunity to become familiar with thiseconomic pressure. For one year in seven, he was to learn aboutsubordination to the market.

Then, in the year following the seventh cycle of the sabbaticalweeks of years, the landless employee was to receive his reward: thereturn of his landed inheritance in the jubilee. The day of atonementthat began the jubilee year brought Israelites as individuals under theaffliction of God: voluntary submission. It simultaneously releasedthem from direct economic subordination. In that year, members ofpoor Israelite families repossessed their portion of the larger familyunit’s land. Having submitted to God, they would no longer have tosubmit to landed administrators. They would become landed adminis-trators. They would then have to submit to consumers directly, with-out a land owner above them telling them what to do.

Dominion Through Subordination

The covenantal basis of dominion is formal, oath-bound subordina-tion to God. The jubilee year began with the sound of a trumpet: theaudible symbol of the final judgment. “In a moment, in the twinklingof an eye, at the last trump: for the trumpet shall sound, and the deadshall be raised incorruptible, and we shall be changed” (I Cor. 15:52).The day of atonement was to remind the Israelite nation of its uniquecorporate subordination to God. This ritual subordination was toserve as the foundation, both judicially and psychologically, of eachIsraelite’s tasks of leadership. Humble before God, they were to beaggressive toward the world. This is the meaning of the New Testa-

Page 54: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

16. North, Dominion Covenant, pp. 436–39.

17. Gary North, Political Polytheism: The Myth of Pluralism (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1989).

18. Ludwig von Mises, “Profit and Loss” (1951), in Planning For Freedom, 4thed.(South Holland, Illinois: Libertarian Press, 1980), ch. 9; Frank H. Knight, Risk,Uncertainty and Profit (New York: Harper Torchbooks, [1921] 1965). Cf. North, DominionCovenant, ch. 23.

993

ment’s statement, “Blessed are the meek: for they shall inherit theearth” (Matt. 5:5). They are meek before God, not meek before cov-enant-breaking men.16 To be compelled to be meek before covenant-breaking men is evidence of God’s temporary chastisement of Hiscovenant people. It is to be forced to adhere to an illegitimate civiloath.17

On the day above all other days of the year in which each Israelitepublicly manifested his subordinate position before God, the day ofatonement also served, twice per century, as the day of inheritance,the day on which a man’s inheritance in rural land was returned tohim. He would henceforth regain legal authority over a piece of land.He would then have an opportunity to discover whether he had thenecessary skills and foresight as an entrepreneur – a future-predictingplanner and executor of plans18 – to retain economic authority over hisinheritance as an economic representative of God, his own family, andthe consumers in the marketplace. He became a legal representativeof God as owner, which required economic representation.

Rest and Subordination

The meaning of sabbath rest is subordination. Man, a creature, hadthe whole creation delivered to him by God on the sixth day of thefirst week. Man was to exercise dominion under God: a subordinate

Page 55: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

19. North, Dominion Covenant, ch. 5: “God’s Week and Man’s Week.”

20. Gary North, The Sinai Strategy: Economics and the Ten Commandments (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1986), ch. 4.

994

who was created explicitly to rule. To acknowledge his subordinateposition under God, he was supposed to rest on the seventh day ofGod’s week, which was the first full day of man’s week.19 He rebelledinstead. He illegitimately imitated God by prematurely grabbing forthe robes of authority (Gen. 3:5). One aspect of Adam’s curse was tohave his day of rest postponed. This day of rest is definitively reachedonly through the New Covenant of Jesus Christ. “There remaineththerefore a rest to the people of God. For he that is entered into hisrest, he also hath ceased from his own works, as God did from his”(Heb. 4:9–10). Progressively, rest is attained through covenantalobedience to God: “Let us labour therefore to enter into that rest, lestany man fall after the same example of unbelief” (Heb. 4:11). This restfrom all labor in history is attained only at death: “Rest in Peace,” wewrite on tombstones. Those who die disinherited by God in history dorest from their labors, but they have no peace forever.

Because of the nature of Adam’s transgression, the Mosaic Coven-ant established its mandatory sabbath day as day seven. Old Covenantman was allowed to rest only after his labors were finished for theweek. “Six days shalt thou labour, and do all thy work. But theseventh day is the sabbath of the LORD thy God: in it thou shalt notdo any work, thou, nor thy son, nor thy daughter, thy manservant, northy maidservant, nor thy cattle, nor thy stranger that is within thygates” (Ex. 20:9–10).20 Even as he had to work for his dinner, OldCovenant man had to work for his rest. Having played the rebel in hisquest to become as God, man was made to suffer the burden of cursedwork before his day of rest. This had not been the original design forman’s work week. The six-one pattern of work and rest was a curse,

Page 56: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

21. Ibid., p. 69.

995

even though weekly rest was grace that man does not deserve. Theone-six pattern was the original Edenic model. Man was designed tobegin his week with celebration – a covenant renewal meal – and rest.

Adam rebelled against his assigned day of rest. The mark of coven-ant-breaking man is his assertion of primary sovereignty, meaningautonomy. God did not rest the first day. Imitating God, covenant-breaking man refused to rest on his first day. Instead, he participatedin a satanic communion meal at the forbidden tree.21 Then he sewedfig leaves to cover himself. He became a tailor. Adam’s denial of hisneed for a day of rest was a denial of his subordinate position, meta-physically and judicially, under God.

So it was in Mosaic Israel. To work on the day of atonement – theday of man’s required public acknowledgment of his subordination –was suicidal. It called down the negative sanction of spiritual death,directly imposed by God. “And whatsoever soul it be that doeth anywork in that same day, the same soul will I destroy from among hispeople” (Lev. 23:30). It was therefore an excommunicable offense:the loss of inheritance in the land and therefore also citizenship.

This is the judicial background of the year of jubilee. It wasrequired to be held in the year following the seventh sabbatical year,i.e., year 50. The sabbatical year was a required year of rest for agri-cultural land. It came at the end of six years of harvesting. The year ofjubilee followed the “sabbath” of a “week” of sabbath years. Thisconstituted a second sabbath year: a double rest period. This was adouble testimony to man’s subordination to God.

The Spoils of War

Page 57: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

22. Gary North, Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus (Tyler, Texas: Institutefor Christian Economics, 1990), ch. 27.

996

“In the year of this jubile ye shall return every man unto his pos-session” (Lev. 25:13). This provision applied to rural land. It did notapply to property in walled cities (Lev. 25:29–30). It did not apply tonon-agricultural property.

What was the historical origin of this law? Judicially, it was anapplication of the Mosaic sabbath (Ex. 23:10–12).22 Historically, itwas an aspect of the promised spoils of war. God offered land only tothose families that would participate in the military conquest ofCanaan. Families that refused to join the battle could not participatein the post-conquest distribution of land. This was never stated expli-citly, but we can safely conclude that this was the case because ofJoshua’s dealing with the Reubenites, the Gadites, and half the tribeof Manasseh. These tribes had already inherited property outside thePromised Land, across the Jordan River. This inheritance was anaspect of the spoils of war. Moses had announced: “And when yecame unto this place, Sihon the king of Heshbon, and Og the king ofBashan, came out against us unto battle, and we smote them: And wetook their land, and gave it for an inheritance unto the Reubenites, andto the Gadites, and to the half tribe of Manasseh” (Deut. 29:7–8).However, for them to inherit this recently promised land, Joshuainsisted, they would have to fight the Canaanites alongside the othertribes, despite the fact that they had already fought Sihon and Og fortheir land, and Moses had passed title to them. In short, there wouldbe no transfer of lawful title prior to the final battle. That is to say,there would be no rest for any until after the labor of war was over forall. What had been given to these tribes definitively could not beclaimed by them finally until after the conquest was over.

Page 58: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

23. Robert North’s seemingly exhaustive and mentally exhausting study, Sociology of theBiblical Jubilee (Rome: Pontifical Biblical Institute, 1954), is a good example of modernscholarship. Based on higher critical assumptions and methodology, it never mentions the

997

Then Joshua commanded the officers of the people, saying, Passthrough the host, and command the people, saying, Prepare youvictuals; for within three days ye shall pass over this Jordan, to go into possess the land, which the LORD your God giveth you to possessit. And to the Reubenites, and to the Gadites, and to half the tribe ofManasseh, spake Joshua, saying, Remember the word which Mosesthe servant of the LORD commanded you, saying, The LORD yourGod hath given you rest, and hath given you this land. Your wives,your little ones, and your cattle, shall remain in the land which Mosesgave you on this side Jordan; but ye shall pass before your brethrenarmed, all the mighty men of valour, and help them; Until theLORD have given your brethren rest, as he hath given you, and theyalso have possessed the land which the LORD your God giveth them:then ye shall return unto the land of your possession, and enjoy it,which Moses the LORD’S servant gave you on this side Jordan towardthe sunrising. And they answered Joshua, saying, All that thoucommandest us we will do, and whithersoever thou sendest us, we willgo. According as we hearkened unto Moses in all things, so will wehearken unto thee: only the LORD thy God be with thee, as he waswith Moses (Josh. 1:10–17).

If militarily victorious tribes had to wait for the transfer of title toland already verbally promised – land located across the Jordan andtherefore not part of God’s promise to Abraham – then what of lawfultitle to land within the boundaries of the Jordan? Surely the basis oflanded inheritance inside the Promised Land would also be based onmilitary conquest. Yet it is unheard of for any commentator to discussthe jubilee year in terms of its historical basis: the distribution of spoilsafter the military conquest of Canaan.23 This is why the jubilee

Page 59: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

jubilee in relation to the conquest of the land.

24. Achan and his entire family, including their animals, were executed for his havingthwarted this required burnt offering. See Appendix A: “Sacrilege and Sanctions.”

998

inheritance laws are so frequently misinterpreted, including theirvarious applications to areas completely outside of the jubilee landlaw’s agricultural frame of reference.

Genocide and Burnt Offerings

For the Israelites to inherit the land, they were required to killeveryone who had previously occupied the land. “And thou shalt con-sume all the people which the LORD thy God shall deliver thee; thineeye shall have no pity upon them: neither shalt thou serve their gods;for that will be a snare unto thee” (Deut. 7:16a). Note that the keyissue was theology: the gods of the land’s previous owners. Thepeople of Israel were to be kept away from these alien gods.

God required a bloody burnt sacrifice as the covenantal foundationof the national inheritance: the genocide of the residents of Jericho andthe city’s subsequent burning. This mandatory ritual sacrifice24 was tobe followed by the total annihilation of all other residents of thePromised Land. To the degree that the Israelites in any way pitied theexisting inhabitants, they would thereby compromise their inheritance.They would have to share the land with others.

Recent commentators have attempted to apply the jubilee laws tothe modern world as if these laws had not been grounded in genocide.The original promise had been given to Abraham, but it was condi-tional on the heirs’ continuation of the ritual of circumcision: a bloodyrite symbolizing the cutting off of a man’s biological heirs.

Consider a rate of population growth of 3 percent per annum,

Page 60: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

25. Gary North, “Publisher’s Epilogue,” in David Chilton, The Great Tribulation (Ft.Worth, Texas: Dominion Press, 1987).

999

which was sustained by many agricultural nations in the twentiethcentury. This rate of increase would have doubled the size of thepopulation in a quarter of a century. By the first jubilee, the averagefarm would have been down to just under three acres (11 divided by4). By the second jubilee, the average farm would have been under .7acre. And so on.

This is why the generation of the conquest had to be circumcisedbefore the conquest could begin (Josh. 5). Commentators who do nottrace the origin of the jubilee to the Israelites’ genocidal conquest ofthe land also refuse to discuss the jubilee in terms of the unique, one-time nature of the conquest and the subsequent distribution of militaryspoils. To discuss the jubilee laws without also discussing the God-mandated genocide that implemented these laws is the equivalent ofdiscussing the Christian ideal of heaven without discussing the cross,hell, and the lake of fire. The legal issue is the same: eternal genocideand eternal burnt offerings – not by covenant-breakers; rather, ofcovenant-breakers.25

Dominion, Ownership, and Rest

Notice the phrase, “The LORD your God hath given you rest, andhath given you this land” (Josh. 1:13b). Rest was associated withlawful inheritance. These two and a half tribes had fought and wontheir land outside of the Promised Land, but they would now have tofight and win again in order to seal their lawful inheritance: “Until theLORD have given your brethren rest, as he hath given you” (Josh.1:15a). To seal the tribal promise, there had to be a national victory.

Page 61: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

1000

Only a comprehensive military victory would bring the nation the restthat would become the basis of tribal inheritance. Only on the basis ofmilitary peace can private property be secured. This is an eschat-ological reality: when the implements of war disappear, God’s cov-enant people will then possess lawful title to their property in peace.This can come only when nations universally conform themselves tothe terms of God’s covenant law.

But in the last days it shall come to pass, that the mountain of thehouse of the LORD shall be established in the top of the mountains,and it shall be exalted above the hills; and people shall flow unto it.And many nations shall come, and say, Come, and let us go up to themountain of the LORD, and to the house of the God of Jacob; and hewill teach us of his ways, and we will walk in his paths: for the lawshall go forth of Zion, and the word of the LORD from Jerusalem. Andhe shall judge among many people, and rebuke strong nations afar off;and they shall beat their swords into plowshares, and their spears intopruninghooks: nation shall not lift up a sword against nation, neithershall they learn war any more. But they shall sit every man under hisvine and under his fig tree; and none shall make them afraid: for themouth of the LORD of hosts hath spoken it (Mic. 4:1–4).

There are three primary goals of war: victory (dominion), spoils(inheritance), and peace (rest). The greatest of these is peace, if thepeace is secured on God’s terms. Permanent peace can be attainedonly when the law-order of the victors replaces the law-order of thelosers. Victor’s justice is the only form of justice after the war ends.But without a change in law, there has been no victory. There has onlybeen assimilation by the defeated culture. The classic examples of thisin Western European history were the military victories by the Gothsover Rome. The Goths were steadily assimilated both theologicallyand judicially by the Christian order that had prevailed in Rome. Legal

Page 62: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

26. Harold J. Berman, Law and Revolution: The Formation of the Western LegalTradition (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1983), pp. 19–20.

27. Ibid., p. 20.

28. Ibid., p. 6.

1001

scholar Harold Berman has put it well: without a change in the legalsystem, there is no revolution, only a successful coup or rebellion.26 Ittakes more than one generation to produce a genuine revolution, hesays.27 In Israel, it took two generations: the generation of the exodus,all but two of whom died in the wilderness, and the generation of theheirs, 40 years spent growing up in the wilderness. Because Godordered the total annihilation of the Canaanites, this revolution in lawwas not supposed to take another generation. Canaan could not bepersuaded by the law, so it was to be destroyed by the law’sdesignated sanctioning agent: the land itself, operating through thenation of Israel. God’s grace to the Israelites mandated His wrath tothe Canaanites.

All three goals – victory, spoils, and peace – were encapsulated inthe conquest of Canaan. The conquest of Canaan did not rival theexodus as the archetype of God’s dealings with His people, but it didgovern that most crucial aspect of a rural civilization: the inheritanceof land. The specific terms of land ownership and inheritance in Israel,which in turn established the judicial basis of citizenship, did notderive from the Old Covenant era prior to the exodus, but wereannounced after the exodus and were ratified in history by the con-quest.

Berman quotes Goethe: a tradition cannot be inherited; it must beearned.28 This was surely the case with Mosaic Israel. But before thepromised Abrahamic inheritance could be delivered to the heirs – thefourth generation – there had to be an act of covenant renewal. Theconquest was closely associated with point four: covenant renewal.

Page 63: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

1002

The conquest began with the crossing of the Jordan (Josh. 4): aboundary violation. As had been true of Moses’ crossing out of thewilderness into Egypt with his uncircumcised son (Ex. 4:24–26), thisboundary violation required an act of covenant renewal. Like Moses’son, the sons of Israel had not been circumcised in the wilderness.There followed the mass circumcision at Gilgal (Josh. 5:2–8) and aPassover meal of the corn of Canaan (Josh. 5:11). The manna thenceased; the fruit of the land replaced it (Josh. 5:12).

James Jordan speculates that the entire period constituted a five-point covenantal sequence: (1) the sovereign call out of Egypt byGod; (2) the establishment of a judicial hierarchy (Ex. 18), whichconstituted a judicial sanctuary; (3) the moral development of theinheriting generation for 40 years; (4) the conquest itself, whichbrought mass sanctions against the Canaanites; (5) the occupation ofthe land. Evidence for this is the close association of the conquest withthe oath-signs of circumcision and Passover.

The Demographics of the Jubilee InheritanceLaw

The year of jubilee nullified all existing rural land lease contracts.On what legal basis? Assertion of original title. God, as the primaryowner, transferred the leaseholds back to the heirs of the originalconquering families. God announced in advance of the conquest theterms of His leasehold contracts. These leases were to be periodicallyre-established with members of the families of the original invasionand conquest. There could be no other lawful basis of inheritance inthe Promised Land. Eventually, a future generation of those familieswhose members were unwise enough not to honor these terms wouldfind itself dispossessed through captivity (Lev. 26:33–35).

Page 64: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

29. This included adoption through marriage for women, as the cases of Rahab and Ruthindicate.

30. Chapter 31.

1003

The terms of the leases created a monopoly of family ownership.No foreigner prior to the exile could ever hope to establish a landedinheritance outside of a walled city except by adoption into an Israelitefamily. This law tended to keep foreigners inside cities. They wouldhave been restricted to such occupations as merchants, craftsmen, andbankers. They could become landed heirs outside the cities onlythrough adoption by an existing Israelite family.29 On the other hand,they themselves could become the inherited property of Israelites, forthe jubilee land law established permanent, inter-generational chattelslavery for foreigners (Lev. 25:44–46).30 The jubilee laws thereforemade it difficult for foreigners to achieve a permanent culturalpresence in the land. It kept them as outsiders, except as temporaryleaseholders, hired workers, slaves, and residents of walled cities.

Population Growth

Simultaneously, the jubilee inheritance law created demographicpressure for expansion beyond the boundaries of the Promised Land.No commentator ever discusses this obvious aspect of the jubilee.First, Mosaic law established the possibility of zero miscarriages:“There shall nothing cast their young, nor be barren, in thy land: thenumber of thy days I will fulfil” (Ex. 23:26). It therefore establishedthe possibility of high birth rates. Second, it established the possibilityof longer life spans: “Honour thy father and thy mother: that thy daysmay be long upon the land which the LORD thy God giveth thee”

Page 65: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

31. Gary North, The Sinai Strategy: Economics and the Ten Commandments (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1986), ch. 5.

32. Gary North, Moses and Pharaoh: Dominion Religion vs. Power Religion (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1985), pp. 23–25.

33. Populations do not explode except when bombed. The language of modern growththeory has attached the metaphor of explosives to the metaphor of growth.

34. Alvin Rabushka, Hong Kong: A Study in Economic Freedom (University of ChicagoPress, 1979).

1004

(Ex. 20:12).31 Third, the law allowed the adoption by Israelites ofcircumcised foreigners, a practice that had taken place widely in Egyptbefore the persecutions began.32 This was a covenantal formula forblessings that would produce “explosively” high population growth.33

The rapid population growth they had experienced in Egypt, whichhad so terrified the Pharaoh of the oppression (Ex. 1:7–10), was themodel.

When a high population growth rate is combined with a fixedsupply of land, societies become progressively urbanized and progres-sively engaged in foreign trade. The model in the early modern periodof Europe is the tiny nation of the Netherlands. The twentieth-centurymodel was the even tinier nation of Hong Kong.34 If residents of asmall, formerly rural nation are unwilling to become urbanized, theymust emigrate to less densely populated nations. The land at home fillsup.

Small Farms and Large Families

In ancient Israel, the land was to be transferred back to the originalfamilies. The geographically bounded nation was small when theyinvaded, yet they came in with at least two million people. There were

Page 66: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

35. North, Moses and Pharaoh, ch. 1.

36. The land was no more than 10,330 square miles. Barry J. Beitzel, The Moody Atlasof Bible Lands (Chicago: Moody Press, 1985), p. 25. There are 640 acres per square mile.This means 6,661,200 acres.

37. 6,661,200 acres divided by 601,730 families = 10.98 acres per family. This wascomparable to the 4 to 15 acres owned by the average Roman farmer around 200 B.C.“Agriculture, history of,” Software Toolworks Illustrated Encyclopedia (1990). This isGrolier’s Encyclopedia on a CD-ROM disk.

38. Contrasted with the extended family.

1005

601,730 adult males at the time of the conquest (Num. 26:51), plus23,000 Levites (Num. 26:62). Since this was approximately the samenumber that had come out of Egypt (Ex. 12:37), there had been nopopulation growth for 40 years. This meant that they were repro-ducing at the replacement rate level: 2.1 children per family. (Somechildren do not marry, which is why the replacement rate is not 2.0children.) So, there must have been about 2.4 million people at thetime of the exodus: two adult parents and about two children perfamily.35

They entered a land of about six and a half million acres.36 Thismeant that the average family, had there been no cities, would haveowned about 11 acres.37 Not all of this land was arable. Some of itwas taken up by cities, where the Levites lived. Over time, the numberof acres per “nuclear” family unit38 would have declined as populationrose. If Israel had remained faithful to God’s law, miscarriages wouldhave ceased. The early Egypt-era rate of growth of Israelite nuclearfamilies would have resumed. No nuclear family could have inheritedmore than a declining number of acres as time went on. Eventually, nofarm would have been large enough to support all the heirs. Thiswould have forced the creation of extended family agriculturalcorporations, with one or two nuclear families (or even foreignsharecroppers) running the farm in the name of the extended family’s

Page 67: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

1006

members, most of whom would have moved to cities or abroad. Therewould be no mass exodus back to the original family plots of theconquest era. Only moral rebellion could have kept the land of Israelsufficiently empty of residents to have allowed each family’s return tothe family plot.

Any discussion of this law as if it were a way to maintain smallfamily farms must discuss in detail how very small these farms wouldhave been within a century or two of rapid population growth. Thepoint is, this law did not guarantee the continuation of agricultural lifefor a significant percentage of the population. There was no way forany law to assure such a way of life to a growing population in a verysmall nation. What the jubilee inheritance law did was to cut off allreasonable hope that a family had any economic future in farming,except in those periods in which the nation was in rebellion, when Godwould respond by sending plagues, famines, miscarriages, and othernegative demographic sanctions. But in such deplorable ethicalconditions, it would have been highly unlikely that the jubilee inheri-tance law would have been honored anyway. The system of coven-antal law and covenantal sanctions in Mosaic Israel points to a con-clusion that the commentators never mention: the anti-rural implica-tions of the Mosaic law. It did not despise farming; it simply madeclear that hardly anyone in a God-honoring society is expected to bea full-time farmer. The urban family garden, not the family farm, is thebiblical ideal.

Declining Per Capita Farm Income

The jubilee inheritance law was a way to guarantee every head ofhousehold a small and declining share of income from a family farm.Most heirs would have become urban residents in Israel or emigrants

Page 68: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

1007

to other nations. The promise of God regarding population growth –being fruitful and multiplying – was a guarantee that covenantalfaithfulness would lower the proportion of per capita family incomederived from farming. The law made it plain to everyone exceptmodern Bible commentators that if the nation’s numbers grew as aresult of God’s blessing, Israelites could place little hope in the possi-bility of supporting themselves financially as farmers. Far from beinga guarantor of egalitarianism, the jubilee inheritance law was a lawforcing covenant-keeping people into the cities or out of the nation.This is rarely or never mentioned by commentators. Instead, they talkabout rural Israel and its annulled rural laws, which were cultural.

Real estate located inside walled cities did not come under this law.Neither did property owned or leased outside the boundaries of Israel.This law warned them that a covenantally faithful nation wouldbecome an urbanized nation and/or a nation of emigrants. The lawmade it plain that their lives as farmers could continue only if theywere not faithful to God’s law. If the nation remained primarilyagricultural, this was God’s visible curse against them.

The jubilee land inheritance law was designed to force the Israelitesto plan for a very different future. They were to become city dwellersas a people within the Promised Land, and traders, bankers, andskilled manufacturers outside the land. There could be no legitimatehope in remaining farmers in the Promised Land. The boundaries ofthe land were fixed; their population size was not. There wouldeventually have to be expansion beyond the boundaries of Israel, andthere would have to be a concentration of population in Israel’s cities.Like the garden east of Eden, the family-owned farms of Israel wouldbe temporary dwelling places of preliminary training for worldwidedominion. The faster the population grew, the faster their life asfarmers and animal herders would disappear. What the West hasexperienced since the late eighteenth century is what God had in mind

Page 69: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

39. Gary North, Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Deuteronomy,2nd electronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc.,[1999] 2003), ch. 8.

1008

for Israel from the time of the conquest, namely, rapid growth – ofpopulation, cities, specialization, manufacturing, trade, emigration,and per capita wealth. To the extent that they did not experience this,they would know that they were under God’s national curse.

The jubilee inheritance law was designed to promote emigration outof Israel and into urban occupations inside the land that relied onforeign trade. The rural land inheritance law promoted contact withforeigners. This was an aspect of the dominion covenant. It was toserve as a means of evangelism. The story of Israel, her laws, and herGod was to spread abroad:

Behold, I have taught you statutes and judgments, even as the LORDmy God commanded me, that ye should do so in the land whither ye goto possess it. Keep therefore and do them; for this is your wisdom andyour understanding in the sight of the nations, which shall hear allthese statutes, and say, Surely this great nation is a wise andunderstanding people. For what nation is there so great, who hath Godso nigh unto them, as the LORD our God is in all things that we callupon him for? And what nation is there so great, that hath statutes andjudgments so righteous as all this law, which I set before you this day?(Deut. 4:5–8).39

The Blindness of the Commentators

R. K. Harrison’s comment on the jubilee inheritance law indicateshis concern with what he supposes are its economic effects. He paysno attention to demographics and its effects, which is a common char-

Page 70: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

40. R. K. Harrison, Leviticus: An Introduction and Commentary (Downers Grove,Illinois: Inter-Varsity Press, 1980), p. 229.

41. The most famous popular presentation of this ideal was made by British playwrightGeorge Bernard Shaw: The Intelligent Woman’s Guide to Socialism and Capitalism (NewYork: Brentano’s, 1928). The best critical histories of the movement are Margaret PatriciaMcCarren, Fabianism in the Political Life of Britain, 1919–1931 (Chicago: HeritageFoundation, 1954) and Rose L. Martin, Fabian Freeway: The High Road to Socialism inthe U.S.A., 1884–1966 (Chicago: Heritage Foundation, 1966). This is a condensation ofSister McCarren’s privately circulated manuscript, The Fabian Transmission Belt, whichher ecclesiastical superiors ordered her to withdraw in the early 1960's. She was thedaughter of U.S. Senator Pat McCarren, who headed the Senate Internal SecuritySubcommittee in the early 1950’s.

42. Clarence Carson, The World in the Grip of an Idea (New Rochelle, New York:Arlington House, 1979). His book was based on articles he wrote for The Freeman (Dec.1968–July 1969; Jan. 1977–Sept. 1979).

1009

acteristic of virtually all commentators on this law. “An emphasis onhumanitarianism and social justice is a pronounced feature of thelegislation in this chapter, and it should be noted that the tenor of thelaws pursued a middle course between the extremes of unrestrictedcapitalism and rampant communism.”40 A middle course betweencommunism and capitalism? This misreading of the text is so total thatit is difficult to understand how anyone who has read the Pentateuchcould write it. So powerful has been the Fabian socialist ideal41 of theso-called Keynesian “mixed economy” – halfway between capitalismand communism, but with limits always set by the State – that modernBible commentators have read Fabianism’s worldview into biblicaltexts. The condition of most intellectuals prior to the astoundingovernight collapse of both Soviet Communism and socialist ideologyin 1989 was well described in 1979 by historian Clarence Carson: theworld in the grip of an idea.42 That idea was either a variation ofKeynesian economics or outright socialism. This outlook has coloredeven conservative biblical exegesis.

There was no possibility whatsoever of communism under the

Page 71: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

1010

Mosaic Covenant. The jubilee laws were aimed at preserving privateownership, even including the private ownership of foreign-bornslaves. There was no “middle course” between communism and capi-talism, since communism was never an option. The ownership systemwas entirely capitalistic. God, the land’s owner, from the beginningestablished leasehold arrangements with those who would occupy Hisland after the conquest. This is the essence of capitalism: a voluntarycontract between owners and managers or tenants.

What Harrison might have written is that the law promoted a var-iety of rural familism. Yet even this minimal statement would havebeen true only when there was no population growth, i.e., only whenthe nation was under God’s curse. Otherwise, the jubilee inheritancelaw made it clear that the only way for families to derive any meaning-ful economic benefit from their landed inheritance was to create somesort of corporate family ownership with delegated management –something like the modern corporate farm. Farm income would havebeen in the form of dividend payments: a declining percentage offamily income as the families grew in number and their income fromnon-farming sources increased. The terms of the jubilee rural landinheritance law destroyed any hope in rural landed wealth in a societymarked by a growing population. Wealth would have to becomeincreasingly urban in origin, derived from manufacturing, services,foreign trade, and all the other occupations of the modern, distinctlyurban, distinctly capitalist world.

What is astounding to me is that I have yet to read another Biblecommentator or historian of ancient Israel who mentions any of this.I am aware of no commentator who has gone to the passage thatpromises the elimination of miscarriages and then to the passages thatpromise long life spans in his attempt to calculate the demographiceffects of a growing population on rural land tenure. The commenta-tors have systematically ignored those biblical texts that relate to

Page 72: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

43. The Attempt to Steal the Bicentennial, The People’s Bicentennial Commission, Hear-ings Before the Subcommittee to Investigate the Administration of the Internal Security Actand Other Internal Security Laws of the Committee on the Judiciary, United States Senate,94th Congress, Second Session (March 17 and 18, 1976), p. 36.

1011

God’s historical sanctions – in this case the positive sanction of popu-lation growth. Only with anti-covenantal blinders firmly attached dothey begin making observations on the meaning and implications ofthe jubilee laws. This approach to Leviticus 25 is as common amongconservative Bible commentators as among the liberals. The result hasbeen the utter failure of the commentators to make sense of thejubilee.

The Myth of Jubilee Egalitarianism

In the mid-1970’s, Jeremy Rifkin and other humanist radicalsorganized the People’s Bicentennial Commission. This organizationwas set up to take advantage of the national bicentennial celebrationin the United States of the Declaration of Independence (1776).William Peltz, the Midwest regional coordinator of the Peoples Bicen-tennial Commission, at a meeting in Ann Arbor, Michigan, argued thatconservative Christians could be turned into promoters ofrevolutionary politics if radicals would just show them that the Bibleteaches revolution. Peltz cited Leviticus 25 as a key passage in prom-oting compulsory wealth redistribution.43 This theme subsequentlybecame popular among numerous radical Christian groups. It waspromoted heavily in Ronald Sider’s 1977 book, Rich Christians in anAge of Hunger, and also in Sojourners magazine. It has even becomea familiar theme in certain fundamentalist groups.

Those who defend this interpretation have not understood that thejubilee was an aspect of military conquest, an economic incentive to

Page 73: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

44. Ronald J. Sider, Rich Christians in an Age of Hunger: A Biblical Study (Wheaton,Illinois: Inter-Varsity, 1977), p. 88. This book was co-published by the liberal Paulist Press(Roman Catholic). A second edition was published in 1984, one which promised on thecover to respond to Sider’s critics. Inside, there was no reference to David Chilton’srefutation, or to a dozen other published critics. Sider simply stonewalled; his influencebegan to disappear almost immediately. A third edition came out in 1990, a fourth in 1997.In that edition, he reversed himself on many issues, and abandoned his socialist rhetoric.See North, Inheritance and Dominion, Appendix F.

1012

fight that was given to each Hebrew family before Israel invadedCanaan. They also have not recognized that the jubilee was fulfilled inprinciple by Jesus (Luke 4) and abolished historically when Israel asa nation ceased to exist. But, most of all, they have not bothered totell their followers that if Leviticus 25 is still morally and legallybinding, then lifetime slavery is still morally and legally valid, for it isonly in Leviticus 25 that the Hebrews were told that they could buyand enslave foreigners for life, and then enslave their heirs forever(Lev. 25:44–46).

Ron Sider wrote in 1977: “Leviticus 25 is one of the most radicaltexts in all of Scripture. At least it seems that way for people born incountries committed to laissez-faire economics. Every fifty years, Godsaid, all land was to return to the original owners – without com-pensation! . . . God therefore gave his people a law which wouldequalize land ownership every fifty years (Lev. 25:10–24).”44 First, thelaw could not possibly have equalized land holdings; families are notall the same size. The larger the family was, the smaller the individualinheritance was. That Sider ignored this obvious implication of thejubilee law indicates how little attention he paid to the context or thetext of this law. Second, like Harrison, Sider ignored the fact that thislaw did not equalize urban land ownership in walled cities, which iswhere most people would have been living in Israel after a fewgenerations of population growth. Sider went on to note that landedwealth is basic to an agricultural economy. True, but covenantally

Page 74: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

45. Idem.

46. Ibid., p. 89.

1013

irrelevant; Israel was not supposed to remain an agricultural economy.It was to become intensely urban. Sider wrote: “But the means ofproducing wealth were to be equalized regularly.”45 There were twoexceptions to this law of equalization, however: in rural areas and inurban areas. He never mentioned either of these exceptions.

Then Sider got to the point: an attack on private, voluntary charity,and a defense of State-mandated wealth redistribution, which he calledjustice: “That this passage prescribes justice rather than haphazardhandouts by wealthy philanthropists is extremely significant. The yearof Jubilee envisages an institutionalized structure that affects everyoneautomatically. It is to be the poor person’s right to receive back hisinheritance at the time of the Jubilee. Returning the land is not acharitable courtesy that the wealthy may extend if they please.”46 Hemoved without a missing a beat from the jubilee law’s narrow judicialcategory – heirs of the families that had originally received the land aspart of the military spoils system – to the broad economic category of“the poor.” He conveniently neglected to mention three groups –permanent chattel slaves (Lev. 25:44–46), the urban poor, and poorstrangers in the rural communities – none of whom participated in thejubilee law’s inheritance. If the goal was, as he has insisted, the careof the poor, then why not all of the poor? This question points toSider’s problem: the jubilee’s goal was not wealth-redistribution tothe poor. Any explanation of the jubilee law in terms of care of thepoor leads to a dead end. We can partially explain the sabbatical yearin terms of care of the non-urban poor, but not the jubilee year.

Sider then moved from the historical and geographical boundariesof the Promised Land to the modern world. “Actually, it might not bea bad idea to try the Jubilee itself at least once. . . . We could select

Page 75: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

47. Ibid., p. 93.

1014

1980 as the Jubilee year in order to give us a little time for the prelim-inary preparations. In 1980 all Christians worldwide would pool alltheir stocks, bonds, and income producing property and businessesand redistribute them equally.”47 This recommendation, understand,did not come from someone who owned any stocks, bonds, orincome-producing property. It came from a tenured (no risk of beingfired), salaried college professor with a pension plan. At worst, hewould have had to forfeit his pension under his recommended plan tohonor the jubilee year principle. At least he admitted: “There wouldundoubtedly be a certain amount of confusion and disruption.” Suchconfusion of results would be the product of Sider’s confusion ofexegesis.

What he was advocating was the transfer of ownership of non-agri-cultural productive capital to pagans. Christians, he concluded, shouldsurrender their legally valid claims over the productive economicresources of capitalism and become servants without claims: strangersin the land. This program of economic surrender to paganism, Siderargued, is an extension of the jubilee principle. But what was thejubilee principle, as described a few pages earlier by Sider? It was alegal prohibition against the permanent sale of a family’s long-termcapital to someone else, especially strangers (pagans) in the land. Inother words, Sider’s recommended modern application of the jubileeyear principle would produce results exactly opposite of what he haddescribed as the original jubilee year’s goal. Yet Sider’s book soldvery well, and was widely acclaimed in academic Christian and neo-evangelical circles as a model of relevant Christian scholarship.

Sider’s book initially appeared to be based on Mosaic law. This wasan illusion. On the page following his suggested program of economicsurrender to paganism, he wrote: “Still, I certainly do not think that

Page 76: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

48. Ibid., p. 94.

49. Chapter 24.

50. Gary North, Judgment and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on First Corinthi-ans, electronic edition (West Fork, Arkansas: Institute for Christian Economics, 2001), ch.11.

51. Gary North, Hierarchy and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on First Timothy(West Fork, Arkansas: Institute for Christian Economics, 2002), ch. 7.

1015

the specific provisions of the year of Jubilee are binding today.Modern technological society is vastly different from rural Palestine.. . . We need methods appropriate to our own civilization. It is thebasic principles, not the specific details, which are important andnormative for Christians today.”48 This is the standard antinomianargument: the details of God’s revealed law are irrelevant today; letus therefore glean and apply only the principles. But there is a majorproblem with this approach: Without our obedience to the specifieddetails, how can we be confident that our application of the underlyingprinciple is valid? How can we discover the underlying principle if weautomatically toss out the specified applications? In short, what goodare Bible’s case laws without the actual cases? Paul argued that thecase law prohibiting the muzzling of oxen while they labored in thefield (Deut. 25:4)49 can be applied two ways: (1) the Christian haslegitimate confidence in the positive outcome of his labors (I Cor.9:9–10);50 (2) elders are deserving of double honor (I Tim. 5:17–18).51

He did not add, however, that since we now live under the NewCovenant, we can lawfully muzzle our working oxen because we arebound only by the principles of the case laws, not the details thereof.

Aliens and Inalienable Land

Page 77: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

1016

We can discover the fundamental jubilee principle by beginningwith God’s own statement regarding the reason for the jubilee law:“The land shall not be sold for ever: for the land is mine; for ye arestrangers and sojourners with me” (Lev. 25:23). Problem: God ownsall the earth, then and now. “For every beast of the forest is mine, andthe cattle upon a thousand hills” (Ps. 50:10). Yet this very ownershipof the world is what led to the special position of the land of Canaanand its conquerors: “Now therefore, if ye will obey my voice indeed,and keep my covenant, then ye shall be a peculiar treasure unto meabove all people: for all the earth is mine: And ye shall be unto me akingdom of priests, and an holy nation. These are the words whichthou shalt speak unto the children of Israel” (Ex. 19:5–6). It was theIsraelites, and only the Israelites, who were to be owners of rural landin Israel – not the immigrant stranger, and surely not the Canaanite.

Only the Israelites were strangers and sojourners with God. There-fore, for as long as God dwelled uniquely in the land, only His cov-enant people were allowed to remain agricultural owners. They wouldpolice the land’s boundaries, keeping strangers out except on God’sterms: inside walled cities, inside Israelite households as slaves, asleaseholders, and as free agricultural laborers. Far from being so-journers in the sense of “wanderers in the land,” Israelites were tobecome the only permanent owners of rural land. They might bestrangers and wanderers outside the Promised Land, but permanentowners inside. The Promised Land was to serve as “home base” in aworldwide program of trade and evangelism. To be a perfect strangerto the covenant-breaking world outside the geographical boundariesof Israel, one had to be: (1) a covenanted member of an Israelite fam-ily that had participated in the conquest, or (2) an adopted member ofa walled city’s tribe. This was the meaning of “strangers and so-journers with me”: strangers to the world but perpetual land ownersinside rural Israel. Then as now, the concept of stranger was an ines-

Page 78: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

52. This restriction ended after their return from exile (Ezek. 47:21–23). See below,“Land Ownership by Foreigners: Then and Now,” pp. 1029–30.

1017

capable concept. A person was either a stranger with God or a stran-ger from God. The physical mark of circumcision and lawful inher-itance inside Israel identified a man as being a stranger with God.

So, God set apart the Promised Land as His holy dwelling place.He sanctified it. He placed boundaries around it. Thus, thefundamental covenantal principle of the jubilee law was holiness: theseparation of covenantally unequal people from each other.

The Principle of Inequality

God established His people as owners of the land through an histor-ically and judicially unique program of genocide. The covenantalprinciple of the jubilee is simple: those who worshipped false godswithin the geographical boundaries of Israel could not own agri-cultural land. The original Canaanites had to be killed, God insisted,while future immigrants from pagan nations would have to beconfined geographically. For as long as they dwelt within the land’sgeographical boundaries under the terms of the original distribution,Israelites had to keep strangers from inheriting agricultural land.52

Strangers could inherit houses only inside walled cities. The wallswere symbols of the covenantal restraints on them. They could alsolawfully be enslaved on a permanent basis if they ever sold themselvesto an Israelite family. This means that the primary economic concernof the jubilee laws was not the equalization of property, or evenequality of opportunity; it was, on the contrary, the establishment ofthe principle of inequality of opportunity for those outside thecovenant.

Page 79: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

53. They were always subordinate politically: North, Political Polytheism, ch. 2:“Sanctuary and Suffrage.”

54. Idem.

1018

The economic principle is clear: those who did not worship the Godof the Bible, as well as the heirs of those who had not proven theirdevotion to God by participating in national genocide, had to berestricted economically (no landed inheritance) or geographically(inside walls). There was a corollary: the vast majority of the covenan-tally faithful nation would eventually move into walled cities, whichwould have made it less likely that strangers would becomeeconomically influential there. The fundamental economic principleof the jubilee laws was that those outside the covenants – civil,familial, and ecclesiastical – should be kept economically andnumerically subordinate to those inside the covenants.53 Does Siderregard these principles as morally binding today? I think not. (I alsowonder if he believes that they were morally valid during the Mosaicera. I would like to see him write an article defending these principlesas they applied in Mosaic Israel.) But this raises a fundamentalquestion: How can we apply these jubilee principles in New Covenanttimes?

Citizenship

Let me re-write Sider. “Leviticus 25 is one of the most radical textsin all of Scripture. At least it seems this way for people born incountries committed to pluralist democratic politics.” In ancient Israel,citizenship was by formal covenant.54 It was not by propertyownership. The stranger could be circumcised, but he could not inheritrural land. He could therefore not become a judge in the Promised

Page 80: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

1019

Land as a member of the congregation unless he was adopted into anIsraelite tribe (walled city) or family. Only if adopted could he becomeeligible to serve in God’s holy army, which was the mark ofcitizenship.

The strangers’ economic and cultural influence was to be offset bya growing concentration of Israelites living in walled cities. The walledcities were places of refuge for immigrants (as cities become in nationsthat open their borders to immigrants), but walled cities were not tobecome strongholds of foreign influence, either political or economic.Any city in Israel that covenanted with a foreign god was to be totallydestroyed (Deut. 13:12–17).

The interactions between foreign cultures (plural) and domesticculture (singular) would take place mainly in the walled cities of Israeland in the commercial cities of other societies. The kingdom(civilization) of God was to overwhelm the kingdoms of all othergods. Cities would be the places where the confrontation betweenGod’s kingdom and all others would take place. The jubilee inheri-tance law, when coupled with a rising Israelite population, insured thatthere would be a strong and growing presence of covenant-keepers inthe walled cities of Israel.

Geographical Holiness

Jesus spoke of a coming transfer of His kingdom: “Therefore sayI unto you, The kingdom of God shall be taken from you, and givento a nation bringing forth the fruits thereof” (Matt. 21:43). He spokeof new wine in old wineskins: “Neither do men put new wine into oldbottles [askos: leather bag]: else the bottles break, and the winerunneth out, and the bottles perish: but they put new wine into newbottles, and both are preserved” (Matt. 9:17). The New Covenant

Page 81: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

55. David Chilton, The Days of Vengeance: An Exposition of the Book of Revelation (Ft.Worth, Texas: Dominion Press, 1987).

1020

would soon break the limits of the Old Covenant. The church wouldsoon replace national Israel. This is why Paul speaks of the church as“the Israel of God” (Gal. 6:16).

With the fall of Jerusalem in A.D. 70, the Promised Land lost thefinal remnants of its judicial holiness.55 The land of Israel was nolonger uniquely the place of God’s residence. This change in coven-antal administration had been made visible when the veil separating theholy of holies from the holy place was torn at the time of Christ’sdeath. This destruction of the temple’s physical barrier between manand God was immediately verified by the destruction of that mostfundamental of all boundaries in history, the boundary of the grave.“Jesus, when he had cried again with a loud voice, yielded up theghost. And, behold, the veil of the temple was rent in twain from thetop to the bottom; and the earth did quake, and the rocks rent; Andthe graves were opened; and many bodies of the saints which sleptarose, And came out of the graves after his resurrection, and went intothe holy city, and appeared unto many” (Matt. 27:50–53).

This destruction of the key geographical boundary in Israel – God’sset-apart dwelling place in the temple – led to the judicial destructionof the other geographical boundaries: Levitical cities vs. walled cities,walled cities vs. fields, Israel vs. the world. With the end of nationalIsrael’s covenantal holiness came the end of geographical Israel’sholiness. This annulled the jubilee land laws.

The Promise of Sanctuary

The law required that “ye shall return every man to his possession,

Page 82: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

56. The one exception involved the transfer of ownership to a priest (Lev. 27:20–21). SeeChapter 37.

57. It was therefore very risky for foreigners to commit major crimes in Israel. Makingrestitution could lead to his children’s permanent enslavement if the criminal could not buyhis way out before he died.

58. Adult male children of pagans presumably were not sold into slavery with theirparents. Neither were married daughters and aged parents. Adults had already establishedseparate family jurisdictions. But those children who were still under the covenantal juris-diction of alien parents went into bondage with them.

1021

and ye shall return every man unto his family” (Lev. 25:10b). This waswhy it was illegal to enslave an Israelite permanently. The family plotsserved as legal sanctuaries. An Israelite’s legal claim to eventualfreedom and his legal claim to landed inheritance were both aspects ofthe same covenantal grant. An Israelite could not legally alienate hisfreedom, his heirs’ freedom, or his share in the land.56 Civil freedomand rural land ownership were linked. Any unwillingness on the partof the civil magistrates to enforce the jubilee land laws was implicitlya denial of sanctuary to the heirs of the Abrahamic promise and alsoa denial of the original terms of the conquest.

The legal justification for the right of the Israelites to buy residentaliens on a permanent basis (Lev. 25:44–46) was the fact that residentaliens were not citizens of the commonwealth. They could not serveas civil judges or as warriors in God’s holy army. They were outsidethe civil covenant. They were guaranteed sanctuary from pagan lands,but not sanctuary within the land. They could be sold into slavery topay their debts, including especially debts to victims of their crimes.57

Their heirs – the fruit of their loins – were sold with them.58

A family’s original grant of land at the time of the conquest estab-lished a legal claim to sanctuary from permanent enslavement for itsheirs. The land was holy, sanctified by God’s presence. The Israeliteswere holy, sanctified by God’s promise to Abraham and also by their

Page 83: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

59. The promise was obviously conditional.

1022

obedience to the requirement of the covenant: circumcision.59 Thefamily plots were sanctuaries, sanctified by God’s original ownershipof the land and by the terms of his leasehold with Israel at the time ofthe conquest.

When Jesus declared the jubilee fulfilled by Him (Luke 4:18–21),He granted universal sanctuary. The land of Israel would no longerserve as a place of sanctuary in history, sanctified by the specialpresence of God. The kingdom of God has become the New Cov-enant’s place of sanctuary – not merely the institutional church, butthe civilization of God. The whole world of paganism is required byGod to seek sanctuary in Christ’s church. This substitution of a newsanctuary annulled the jubilee land laws, and thereby also annulled thejubilee’s permanent slave law.

The alternative to this interpretation of the New Covenant is thelong-held defense of slavery made by Christian commentators. Theirinterpretation – never explicit but necessarily implicit – is that theannulment of the jubilee land laws did not also annul the slave law.This leads to the conclusion that God’s law no longer makes provisionfor those seeking geographical sanctuary. In other words, whennational Israel ceased to offer sanctuary to the lost or the righteousforeigner, geographical sanctuary ceased in history. The argumentruns as follows: “The Israelites no longer possessed a guarantee ofjubilee liberty; therefore, the liberty announced by Christ must haveconstituted the annulment of Mosaic liberty. God has annulled theland-sanctuary-liberty connection, but nothing has taken its place.Thus, slavery is validated as a universal institution.”

The only New Testament-based alternative to this unpleasantinterpretation is to conclude that liberty has been validated by thework of Jesus Christ, and the mark of this validation is the abolition

Page 84: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

60. David Brion Davis, Slavery and Human Progress (New York: Oxford UniversityPress, 1984).

61. The ultimate immigration barrier is abortion.

62. Gary North, “The Sanctuary Society,” Journal of Libertarian Studies, 13 (Summer1998). http://www.mises.org/journals/jls/13_2/13_2_7.pdf

1023

of slavery in Christian nations. The church has never publiclyacknowledged the abolitionist implications of Jesus’ fulfillment of thejubilee law. His announcement was not, to my knowledge, ever citedby any abolitionist of the late eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. Butafter 1780, pressure to abolish slavery increased within many Anglo-Saxon Protestant churches that were located outside of the slave-owning regions. By the end of the 1880’s, chattel slavery had beenabolished in the West.60

Meanwhile, national sanctuaries for the oppressed and poor wereopened: free emigration and immigration. But, after World War I, thisopen access was steadily closed by legislation. Immigration barrierswere erected everywhere. The modern passport is one of humanism’simportant covenantal marks: a progressive contraction of internationalsanctuaries. Political liberals as well as political conservatives haveaffirmed the legitimacy of these immigration barriers.61 When nationsare no longer covenantally Christian, i.e., when they adopt religiouspluralism and other marks of citizenship besides church membership,and when they replace voluntary charity with welfare Stateentitlements, the Christian evangelist’s call to the lost in the name ofChrist steadily fades. “Come unto me, all ye that labor and are heavyladen, and I will give you rest” is replaced by “Keep out thosewelfare-seeking bums!” Finally, when mandatory identification cardsare issued by the State to every resident in order to “reduce welfarefraud,” all of the remaining sanctuaries tend to disappear: in churches,regions, and families.62

Page 85: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

1024

Citizenship and Land Ownership

Under the initial distribution of the land under Joshua, no non-citizen could own rural land. Not every citizen had to own rural land– most notably, a circumcised immigrant or his heir who was eligibleto serve in the army – but every rural land owner had to be a citizen.This law ended with the exile (Ezek. 47:21–23), when the land vom-ited out the Israelites.

Why should land ownership in any nation be limited to its citizens?If the uses of the land are under civil law – and land can hardly bemoved outside this jurisdiction – then what does it matter who ownsit? The rent will be the same, no matter who owns the property, sinceowners cannot unilaterally establish rent in a free market. Rentpayments are established in terms of competition: owners vs. owners,renters vs. renters. I ask: What is the covenantal justification for civilrestraints on real estate sales to foreigners? Land ownership confersno right to vote – citizenship – to owners. It therefore has nothing todo with the civil covenant. Restrictions on land sales to foreignresidents constitute restrictions against the maximization of an existingland owner’s wealth. Why should the civil government be given suchcontrol over the sale of land? It is not sufficient to cite the jubileeagricultural land laws; these laws applied only to land that had beentransferred by God to the families that participated in the conquest ofCanaan.

The idea that a person can somehow disinherit his heirs merely byexchanging land ownership for the ownership of money is a peculiarnotion. It may be a valid concern in a statist society that places legalrestrictions on the purchase of real estate – “once sold, always sold”– but in a free market social order, the idea is ridiculous. Such a viewis culturally derived, not economically or judicially derived. Disin-

Page 86: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

63. Leni Riefanstahl’s Nazi propaganda film, Triumph of the Will (1935), records theNazi Party conference of 1933. The film has scenes of organized rural residents, spadesused as symbols of the soil, and happy peasant types. On the occult, see Dusty Sklar, TheNazis and the Occult (New York: Dorset, 1977).

64. The agrarian worldview expressed in I’ll Take My Stand, the 1930 manifesto writtenby a dozen American Southern literary figures, remains personal sentiment or personalaesthetic taste unless backed up by civil law. If backed up by civil law, the manifestomeans I’ll Take My Stand Against Economic Freedom – not just “yankee industrialcapitalism,” but the free market a social order. The paganism of the modern “deep ecology”movement is another extension of the myth of the soil. It is deeply hostile to science,progress, and economic freedom. Man’s problem is not his environment, urban or rural;

1025

heritance is surely not limited to land ownership. Neither is inher-itance. To imagine that the sale of land to another family or to a busi-ness, foreign or not, is somehow a means of disinheritance is to adopta magical view of land. Such a view is not a New Covenant view, forthe Mosaic covenant has been abrogated by the New Covenant.

There is nothing either covenantal or magical about land. The once-powerful myths of “blood and soil”– pagan family myths and paganagricultural myths, both of which are pagan fertility myths – have longserved as rival religions to Christianity. The Latin root word for paganmeans villager. Rural areas were where the gospel met its greatestresistance from the beginning of the church. The most recent nationalrevival of these dual myths took place in industrial Germany underNazism: the work of a dictator who had self-consciously adopted thesymbolism of soil and the occult as a tools of public mobilization.63

One of the great benefits of free market capitalism and its consequenturbanization has been the cultural undermining of these fertility myths.In response, the defenders of the old pagan order openly reject theidea of progress as a rival and erroneous myth. This is consistent withancient paganism’s cyclical theory of time.

While there can be legitimate traditional or sentimental feelingsabout the land in some societies, these feelings possess no uniquejudicial authority in a private property-based social order.64 As with

Page 87: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

man’s problem is sin. Delivery from sin is not through a change in the environment.

65. About 18 percent of the population moved residences, 1987–88: Statistical Abstractof the United States, 1990 (Washington, D.C.: Department of Commerce, Bureau of theCensus, 1990), Table 25.

66. Robert A. Nisbet, “The Social Impact of the Revolution,” in America’s ContinuingRevolution: An Act of Conservation (Washington, D.C.: American Enterprise Institute forPublic Policy Research, 1975), p. 80. Nisbet regards the post-Revolution abolition ofprimogeniture and entail as symbolically important, not judicially important.

1026

any scarce economic resource, the land owner must meet the demandsof the highest-bidding consumers or else suffer net economic losses(e.g., forfeited rent). Land ownership is unique only in land’s physicalimmobility. Its uses are easier to control by law. Real estate is also lessliquid economically than other assets, since extensive knowledge of aparticular property’s location and condition is required to assess itsvalue.

Inheritance and Mobility

In a nation such as the United States, in which almost one-fifth ofthe population moves to new residences every year,65 an attempt todefend restricted land ownership in terms of the Bible is most peculiar.Primogeniture (eldest son inherits the family’s land) and entail(prohibition on sale of the family’s land) were never major aspects ofNew England Puritanism, and both faded rapidly in the late eighteenthcentury in Virginia. While laws authorizing both practices were on thebooks in most of the American colonies up until the AmericanRevolution (1776–83), there are few court records indicating thatsuch laws were ever seriously enforced.66 When enforced, these lawsreduced the authority of parents to control their children, especially

Page 88: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

67. Edmund S. Morgan, Virginians at Home: Family Life in the Eighteenth Century(Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press, 1952), pp. 34–35.

1027

with respect to marriage.67 Without the covenantal authority of tribalorganizations to direct the line of inheritance, laws restricting the saleof land restrict both parental authority and social mobility. Thisrestriction on social mobility was also present in Mosaic Israel,although population growth and urbanization would have overcomemuch of this restricted mobility. God placed these restrictions onlanded inheritance for the sake of the promised messianic seed; inA.D. 70, God destroyed the tribes and abrogated the tribal land laws.

The dominion covenant requires mobility: the conquest of societyby the gospel. The ownership of the world was transferred definitivelyto Jesus at Calvary, and from Him to His people in history. The spreadof the gospel is God’s authorized means of progressive conquest –inheritance – by His people. The idea of covenantally restricted landownership is foreign to the idea of mobility (dominion) in NewTestament times. The covenantal threat of land ownership by aforeigner no longer exists under biblical law. Only those nations, suchas the United States, that perversely sanction citizenship based onresidence or birth in the land are threatened by foreign-born ownersof land. There is no covenantal or political threat whatsoever fromownership by foreign corporations.

The tremendous social and economic mobility offered by moderncapitalism cannot be separated from the freedom to buy and sell land.A cry to legislate a policy of limiting land ownership to a nation’scitizens, especially in a large country, indicates the degree to whichvoters are uninformed about (1) economic theory (rent), (2) economicfacts (freedom of contract), and (3) social theory (social mobility). Acry to limit land ownership to citizens in the name of the Mosaicjubilee land laws adds ignorance about the Bible to the three other

Page 89: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

68. The Strait Times (Singapore) (Nov. 23, 1991). The price later fell to $2 million in1991 as a result of the drop in Japanese real estate prices.

1028

forms of ignorance. This raises the question of land ownership byforeigners.

Land Ownership by Foreigners: Then and Now

One misguided idea that began to circulate in conservativeAmerican Christian circles in the late 1980’s was the suggestion thatcitizens and corporations of a foreign nation should not be permittedto buy land in the United States. The theological defense of thissuggestion has been an appeal to the jubilee land laws. The purchaseof American land by foreigners has not been a problem, nor has it beenmuch of a phenomenon, except possibly in Hawaii, where Japanesecompanies have bought land to build golf courses to be used only byJapanese players. Because a single golf course membership in the bestclub in Tokyo cost over $3 million in late 1989 (up from $769,000 in1986),68 plus $4,000 for a member to play one 18-hole game, itbecame cheaper for Japanese golfers to pool their funds, buy aHawaiian golf course or build it, charter a jet over the weekend, fly toHawaii, play two rounds, and fly home. But this “golfing invasion”hardly constituted a threat to American national interests. Tightmoney and a falling stock market in Japan ended speculative golfcourse investments after 1989.

The most prominent American theologian to articulate this view ofrestricted land ownership is Rushdoony, who in most cases is a firmdefender of property rights. But in the case of land ownership, heappeals back to the land laws of Mosaic Israel. He writes that

Page 90: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

69. R. J. Rushdoony, “Ownership,” Position Paper, Chalcedon Report (April 1990), p.17.

1029

“Scripture is very clear about the alien within the country; he must betreated the same as a covenant man, even if an unbeliever. As abeliever, he is free to inter-marry with covenant families. The alienoutside the covenant country has no property rights within the land.Ownership is a form of responsibility, and responsibility within thecovenant land is to the covenant of God; hence, he cannot buy into theland. The first fruits of the earth, and the tithes on agricultural andcommercial increase, belong to the Lord.”69 This was indeed true ofagricultural land in Mosaic Israel, but the land laws of Mosaic Israeldied with the transfer of God’s kingdom to the church in A.D. 70.They were not resurrected. To argue otherwise is to allow the redis-tributionist jubilee theology of Ronald Sider to enter in through theback door, as well as Simon Legree: the re-introduction of inter-generational slavery (Lev. 25:44–46).

The primary legal issue for rural land ownership in Mosaic Israelwas adoption, not confession. Both the confessing resident alien[geyr] and the non-confessing resident alien [nok-ree] could buyinheritable residential real estate inside walled cities. Confession hadnothing to do with urban residential ownership. On the other hand,covenant-keeping converts to the faith had no access to rural landownership apart from their adoption into a family of the conquestgeneration. The resident alien’s orthodox confession had nothing todo with inalienable rural ownership except insofar as such confessionwas likely for adoption into an Israelite family.

Rushdoony’s comment on the lawfulness of land ownership byimmigrants is even less accurate with respect to the post-exilic period.He does not mention the relevant passage, Ezekiel’s prophecy of anew law that would prevail after their return to the land: “So shall ye

Page 91: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

70. North, Inheritance and Dominion, ch. 56.

1030

divide this land unto you according to the tribes of Israel. And it shallcome to pass, that ye shall divide it by lot for an inheritance unto you,and to the strangers that sojourn among you, which shall begetchildren among you: and they shall be unto you as born in the countryamong the children of Israel; they shall have inheritance with youamong the tribes of Israel. And it shall come to pass, that in what tribethe stranger sojourneth, there shall ye give him his inheritance, saiththe Lord GOD” (Ezek. 47:21–23). The prohibition against permanentrural land ownership by the circumcised resident alien ended after theexile. This had nothing to do with marriage to an Israelite. The cir-cumcised stranger was the covenantally faithful resident alien [geyr],from whom it was illegal to take interest (Lev. 25:35–37), not theresident who was not part of the covenant [nok-ree], from whom itwas legal to take interest (Deut. 23:20).70

The civil enforcement of property rights to land in the New Coven-ant era has nothing to do with either theological confession or bodilyresidence. The jubilee land laws of Israel have all been annulled. Theywere never cross-boundary laws; they applied only to the land andheirs of the conquest. No judicial appeal to any of those laws is validtoday. Those who appeal to them risk placing us in bondage: therevival of permanent chattel slavery or the imposition of permanentslavery to the messianic welfare State.

Conclusion

The jubilee year began with the day of atonement. This was a dayof public submission to God, invoking His grace: a positive sanction.The judicial issue of the day of atonement was man’s subordination to

Page 92: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

1031

God. There could be no profit-seeking work on that day. Men had torest contentedly in God’s grace.

The jubilee year was the culmination of the cycle of sabbaticalyears. Sabbatical years were mandated by God in order to train land-less Israelites and poor strangers how to produce for a market. TheMosaic law identified harvesters as landless or impoverished peoplewho worked as harvesters or gleaners in six years out of seven. Insabbatical years, they became dependent on whatever it was that Godwould allow the fields to produce apart from cultivation. In thoseyears, harvesters learned to make decisions without a land owner orhis supervisor ruling over them.

The jubilee inheritance law applied to rural land inside the boun-daries of Israel. It did not apply to houses within the walled cities ofthe nation except Levitical cities (Lev. 25:32–33). It also did not applyto property outside the Promised Land. This law had been given to thepeople by God because He was the owner of the land (Lev. 25: 23).It was part of the terms of God’s lease under which they held rightsof administration as sharecropping tenants, with 10 percent of anyincrease owed to God through the Levites and priests. It was also partof the spoils of war.

A Question of Sanctification

God is owner of all the earth, not just the Promised Land. Why didthe jubilee laws not apply to all other nations? Because these lawsapplied only to His special dwelling place. They were an aspect ofGod’s holiness, which is why the jubilee laws appear in Leviticus, thebook of holiness. The Promised Land was to be kept holy: set apartjudicially from all other nations. How? Initially, this separation beganwith God’s promise to Abraham: definitive holiness, i.e., definitive

Page 93: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

71. It is worth noting that members of Rahab’s family never formally voiced their indi-vidual support of this covenant, but by remaining silent before she made it, when the civilauthorities had questioned her regarding the spies (Josh. 2:3), they became lawful residentsof Israel through their adherence to the external demands of Rahab’s covenant. If theyremained inside their section of the wall, despite the collapse of the remainder of the wall,they could remain in the Promised Land (2:19).

1032

sanctification. The second phase of the process of separation began with the

conquest: progressive holiness, i.e., progressive sanctification. Godcleansed the land of His enemies by means of total war: the annihila-tion of His enemies. He required the extermination of the gods ofCanaan by means of an original program of genocide. He promised todwell in the land that contained the tabernacle and temple; He wouldnot permit any other god to be worshipped publicly in Israel. Thus, thegods of the land had to be removed from public view. To achieve thisinitially, the Israelites were told by God to exterminate or drive outevery person dwelling in the land. Only Rahab and her family wouldbe allowed by God to escape this judgment, for she had established apre-invasion covenant with God.71

Third, His holiness was to be defended by enforcing a law that keptpost-conquest immigrants from ever owning property in Israel exceptinside Israel’s walled cities. The families of the conquest received aninheritable lease that could not be alienated beyond 49 years. Laterimmigrants could sublease rural property if they were sufficientlyproductive, but they could not leave an inheritance beyond the jubileeyear.

Fourth, God established a law that removed from the majority ofthe population any legitimate hope of remaining farmers in Israel if Hisblessings were forthcoming in response to their covenantal faithfulnessas a nation. They surely knew that, as Israel’s population expanded,no branch of any extended family could retain economic control overof a particular plot of rural land apart from the compliance of all the

Page 94: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

72. Chapter 37.

1033

other members of the family, except perhaps as a small recreationalproperty (a consumer good). If they wanted income from the land,they could attain it only through its productivity. Small, isolated plotsare not very productive. If they wanted to maximize their passiveincome from their portion of the extended family’s land, they wouldhave to cooperate with other members of the extended family inselecting representative managers, either from within the extendedfamily or from outside its legal boundaries. If any nuclear family unitwanted to farm all of the original “eleven acres” for the others, itwould have to meet the competition of any other members of theextended family who might offer to serve as the family’s repre-sentatives on the farm.

Fifth, wealthy immigrants and strangers in the land would havetended to dwell in walled cities, where they could own homes. This iswhere the population of the Israelites was intended by God to bechanneled over time. This process was intended to keep strangers andforeigners from gaining too much influence in their 48 cities. Theywould have been outnumbered by immigrants from rural areas.

Sixth, God kept the geographically dispersed family of the Levitesfrom gaining political control through land purchases. Their cross-tribal boundary judicial influence had to be advisory. The jubilee landlaw made it impossible for Levites to centralize land ownership inIsrael. They could only rarely inherit rural land (Lev. 27:20–21).72 Butto make sure that they would not abandon their support of the jubileeyear because of their desire to inherit rural land, they were givenjubilee privileges in the cities: reversion in the jubilee year (Lev. 25:32–33). When enforced, this aspect of the jubilee land laws wouldhave tended to confine their political power to cities, but it alsobalanced the jubilee law’s economic costs and benefits for them. Over

Page 95: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

1034

time, their influence would grow with the population, as more peoplecongregated in cities, assuming that they could find ways of maintain-ing the people’s theological allegiance in a progressively urbanizedculture. Ultimately, cities would have become economically dominant,and therefore politically dominant, just as they have become all overthe world in modern times. But the Levites were not supposed tocentralize political and economic power during the rural phase of theIsraelite kingdom.

The primary covenantal issue of the jubilee laws was holiness. Thejubilee inheritance law had little or nothing to do with assuring econo-mic equality, except in times of national covenantal cursing: stagnantpopulation. The law had everything to do with the mandating ofpolitical and cultural inequality: giving a permanent head start to heirsof the conquest over immigrants, even those immigrants who becamemembers of the covenant through circumcision, but not members ofland-inheriting families. Only through adoption, either directly orthrough marriage (for females), could immigrants gain this advantage.

Summary

The beginning of a jubilee cycle is difficult to identify: fiftieth yearor 51st year. I believe it was in the fiftieth year.

There were two calendars in Israel: ecclesiastical and civil.The Day of Atonement was jubilee day.This day was tied to the beginning of the civil year.It occurred five days before the feast of Tabernacles (booths).The geographical boundaries of Israel were restricted to about a

four-days’ walk from the tabernacle-temple.This prevented the creation of an empire.The day of atonement was a day of affliction – formal subordination

Page 96: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

1035

– to God.It was a day of rest.The day of national liberation took place on the day of subordin-

ation.Autonomy is not liberation.Modern free market economics begins with the presupposition of

the individual’s autonomy.The sabbatical year removed the land owner from the hierarchy of

access to the crops: God, land, harvesters.The land became like the wilderness: the visible arena of God’s

grace.The harvester was caught between the land and consumers without

an intermediary: the land’s owner.In a pre-jubilee year, this experience was to prepare poor Israelites

for their return to their inheritance.In sabbatical years, the experience was to prepare poor indebted

Israelites for a return, debt-free (Deut. 15:1–7), to their land.The trumpet was symbolic of final judgment.Sabbath rest is linked to subordination to God.Working on the day of atonement brought disinheritance through

excommunication.The Israelites owned the land as the spoils of war.The jubilee land laws were an aspect of total military conquest:

genocide (burnt offerings).Rest – total victory – is associated with inheritance: the jubilee land

laws.The goal of holy war is three-fold: victory (dominion), spoils

(inheritance), and peace (rest).A true revolution is not successful until the legal order is defini-

tively changed.This takes more than one generation.

Page 97: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 25 . . . Leviticus 25:8–13

1036

The conquest began with a boundary violation: entry into the land(point three).

It was sealed with circumcision (point four).The entire conquest era was a five-point covenant sequence.The jubilee’s nullification of leases was an assertion of original title:

God’s and the invading families’ title.This law pressured foreigners to dwell inside walled cities.The shrinking size of landed inheritance in a growing population

would have pushed Israelites into walled cities.The original families owned on average fewer than eleven rural

acres.This means that the families of a faithful commonwealth had no

long-term future in farming.The urban garden, not the family farm, is the biblical ideal.Emigration was also subsidized by the jubilee law.The land’s boundaries were fixed; the population was not.Israel’s political economy was capitalist, not communist.American radicals, 1975–85, used the rhetoric of the jubilee to

promote socialism and compulsory wealth redistribution.The goal of the jubilee was not distributing wealth to the poor.The number-one principle of the jubilee was to emphasize God’s

ownership of the rural land of Israel.The dozen non-ecclesiastical tribes of Israelites were God’s agents

over the rural land.The law was designed to keep foreigners out of the rural areas.Being a stranger with God meant possessing rural land in Israel.Being a stranger from God meant life outside of Israel or inside

Israel’s walled cities: boundaries.The jubilee law was a separation law.Foreign gods could not reign in rural Israel.This manifested a principle of inequality.

Page 98: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Boundaries of the Jubilee Land Laws

1037

Covenant-breakers were to be subordinate to covenant-keepersinside Israel’s borders.

Inside the walls, Israelites were also to outnumber non-Israelites:urbanization and population growth.

After A.D. 70, Israel ceased to be God’s dwelling place.The land’s boundary laws ceased to exist.This began with the tearing of the temple’s curtain at Jesus’ death:

no more separation of the holy of holies.This was emphasized by Jesus’ violation of the ultimate boundary

in history: death.Laws prohibiting foreigners from owning land in any nation are not

based on the Bible.There is not supposed to be anything covenantally unique about

land ownership in the New Covenant era.The biblical goal is mobility – extending dominion – not restrictive

land ownership.Israel’s refusal to enforce the jubilee was in effect a denial of perm-

anent sanctuary status to the sons of Abraham.Jesus’ fulfillment of the jubilee law meant that He granted universal

sanctuary inside His church.The church has replaced the land of Israel as the area of sanctuary

for pagans to flee into.Jesus annulled the jubilee laws governing slavery: household sanc-

tuaries for pagans.The church has never formally acknowledged this abolitionist

aspect of His ministry.Twentieth-century immigration restrictions have contracted the

number of available modern sanctuaries.

Page 99: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1038

26

ECONOMIC OPPRESSION BY MEANS OF THE STATE

And if thou sell ought unto thy neighbour, or buyest ought of thyneighbour’s hand, ye shall not oppress one another: According to thenumber of years after the jubile thou shalt buy of thy neighbour, andaccording unto the number of years of the fruits he shall sell untothee: According to the multitude of years thou shalt increase theprice thereof, and according to the fewness of years thou shaltdiminish the price of it: for according to the number of the years ofthe fruits doth he sell unto thee. Ye shall not therefore oppress oneanother; but thou shalt fear thy God: for I am the LORD your God(Lev. 25:14–17).

The theocentric message of this passage is that God is not anoppressor. Though He is the author of the law, as well as the finaljudge, He does not use His authority to do injustice. He does not seekunfair advantage. Neither should those who act in His name as Hisstewards.

Terms of the Lease

God was the owner of the land of Israel: special ownership asdistinguished from general ownership of the earth. He established theterms of ownership and leasing within Israel’s boundaries. His per-manent sharecropping tenants were required to honor these terms.More specifically, they were required to imitate God: no oppression.The terms governing leaseholds in some unique way reflected God’sdealings with His people. As an aspect of the jubilee land law, this law

Page 100: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

1. If he was being sold to repay a zero-interest charitable loan, his term of servitude couldnot extend beyond the sabbatical year (Deut. 15:12).

1039

was a specific application of the general law prohibiting oppression.In buying and selling, both parties were required to honor the

limiting factor of the jubilee year. This raises important questions.First, what is oppression, biblically speaking? Second, is oppressionhere merely the failure to write contracts whose provisions ended withthe advent of the jubilee year? Third, did this warning refer only torural land sales?

The context indicates that rural land was the thing being bought andsold. But the legal restriction on the leasing of land would also haveapplied to the leasing of men. If, for example, an Israelite was soldinto bondage because of his failure to repay a business debt, his termof servitude could not extend beyond the jubilee year.1 The lawrequired that “ye shall return every man to his possession, and ye shallreturn every man unto his family” (Lev. 25:10b). Business debt couldnot be collateralized by land beyond the jubilee.

The first question is more difficult to answer. What is oppressionin this context? Has it anything to do with pricing? The text indicatesthat it has everything to do with the period of time in which the termsof the contract will apply. Time has something to do with pricing, butwhat? “According to the multitude of years thou shalt increase theprice thereof.” The question arises: Increase the price from what?What were the price floor and price ceiling that governed the pricingof additional years? How were they established? To answer thisquestion in the absence of historical records, we need to understandsomething about modern capital theory.

We need to think very carefully about how prices are formed in afree market society if we are to discuss the meaning of economicoppression. If we do not understand how prices are established in afree market society, we may be tempted to accuse sellers of goods and

Page 101: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

2. Gary North, Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Deuteronomy,2nd electronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc.,[1999] 2003), ch. 44.

3. Jack Douglas, The Myth of the Welfare State (New Brunswick, New Jersey: RutgersUniversity Transaction Books, 1989).

1040

services (i.e., buyers of money) of having oppressed buyers (i.e.,sellers of money). Warning: he who brings a lawsuit against anothershould first determine if an infraction of God’s law has taken place.The Bible is clear: he who testifies falsely against another and issubsequently convicted of having made a false accusation must sufferthe same penalty that his intended victim would have suffered (Deut.19:15–21).2 Historically, there have been a great number of would-beeconomic theorists who have made such accusations against an entireclass of people. There have been politicians and bureaucrats who haveimposed socialistic programs onto society in the name of suchconscience-driven economic analyses. They have shown zeal withoutknowledge. The result has been economic exploitation through Statecoercion on a massive scale, always in the name of economic justiceand frequently in the name of social salvation.3 Where such policieshave been widely enforced, God has brought His curse: low produc-tivity and low income.

Pricing a Factor of Production

The text speaks of the years of the fruits. “According to the num-ber of years after the jubile thou shalt buy of thy neighbour, andaccording unto the number of years of the fruits he shall sell untothee” (v. 15). This is a very important economic concept. Capitaltheory is dependent on it. Land and labor produce fruit over time. This

Page 102: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

4. The simultaneous and independent work of William Stanley Jevons, Leon Walras, andCarl Menger. See The Marginalist Revolution in Economics: Interpretation andEvaluation, edited by R. D. Collison Black, et al. (Durham, North Carolina: DukeUniversity Press, 1973).

5. Gary North, Hierarchy and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on First Timothy(West Fork, Arkansas: Institute for Christian Economics, 2002), Appendix B.

6. Any scarce economic resource with a market price is in part the product of labor. If itis not yet the product of labor, such as a waterfall, it will have to have labor (includingintellectual labor) added to it before its fruits can be appropriated. Before any asset can beappropriated and used by an owner, he must perform some kind of labor.

7. Mark Skousen, The Structure of Production (New York: New York University Press,1990), ch. 2.

8. Ludwig von Mises, Human Action: A Treatise on Economics (New Haven,Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1949), p. 63.

1041

is what makes land and labor valuable. Modern economic theory,beginning with the marginalist (subjectivist) revolution of the early1870’s,4 attempts to explain the relationship between the market valueof the fruits of production and the market value of the economicinputs that produce these fruits.

What does modern economic theory teach? First and foremost, itteaches that all economic value is subjective value. Economic value isimputed, i.e., it is subjectively determined.5 Economic value is not theproduct of labor; on the contrary, labor is valuable because of thevalue of labor’s output.6 Economic value is also not the product ofobjective costs of production. The classical economists, from AdamSmith to Karl Marx and John Stuart Mill, argued for objective valuetheory – labor theory of value or cost-of-production theory of value– but the marginalist or subjectivist revolution rejected this approachto value theory.7 The classical economists did not trace marketexchange, production, and the formation of prices solely to the actionsof consumers. They did not construct a general theory of value.8

Page 103: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

9. The phrase is generally attributed to W. H. Hutt. Hutt, “The Nature of AggressiveSelling” (1935), in Individual Freedom: Selected Works of William H. Hutt, edited bySvetozar Pejovich and David Klingaman (Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Press, 1975),p. 185. Biblically speaking, this sovereignty is delegated from God: hierarchical authority.

10. Ludwig von Mises, The Theory of Money and Credit, 2nd ed. (New Haven, Connec-ticut: Yale University Press, 1953), pp. 102–3.

11. Ibid., p. 103.

12. In another place, I have discussed why value theory in economics requires thedoctrine of an imputing sovereign God in order to avoid the incoherence produced by puresubjectivism’s theory of autonomous man. See Gary North, The Dominion Covenant: Gene-sis, 2nd ed. (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, [1982] 1987), ch. 4.

1042

Consumer Sovereignty9 (Authority)

The subjectivists concluded that economic inputs possess valueonly in relation to the value of their output. The question immediatelyarises: Value to whom? Concluded the subjectivists: value is imputedsubjectively by an imputing agent – the consumer – to the fruits ofproduction. In his Theory of Money and Credit (1912), Ludwig vonMises wrote that “in the last resort it is still the subjective use-valueof things that determines the esteem in which they are held.”10 Inshort, “the only valuations that are of final importance in the determin-ation of prices and objective exchange-value are those based on thesubjective use-value that the products have for those persons who arethe last to acquire them through the channels of commerce and whoacquire them for their own consumption.”11 The persons who are thelast to acquire anything are called consumers. If all potential con-sumers refuse to pay for some asset’s fruits of production, these fruitshave no economic value.12 Neither will the specific factor of produc-tion, assuming that all producers recognize that no future consumerwill pay for this output. Thus, “The consumers determine ultimatelynot only the prices of the consumers’ goods, but no less the prices of

Page 104: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

13. Mises, Human Action, p. 271.

14. Ibid., p. 330.

15. Ibid., p. 335.

16. The classic example is Ford Motor Company’s introduction of the Edsel automobile,1958–60. Ford could not sell enough cars to make a profit.

1043

all factors of production.”13 Regarding capital goods, Mises wrote:“The prices of the goods of higher orders are ultimately determined bythe prices of the goods of the first or lowest order, that is, the con-sumers’ goods. As a consequence of this dependence they are ulti-mately determined by the subjective valuations of all members of themarket society.”14 This is why he concluded: “The pricing process isa social process.”15

But don’t producers have more money than consumers? Can’t theyimpose their will on consumers? On the contrary, producers have farless money than consumers, which is why producers are vulnerable toshifts in consumer demand. Producers own inventories of highlyspecialized consumer goods and even more specialized producergoods (capital equipment). Consumers own the most marketable com-modity, money. They have the competitive advantage. Think of aproducer of shoes. If consumers decide they do not like the style ofthese shoes, what can the producer do with these shoes? Spend a for-tune on advertising to change consumers’ minds? I am in the advertis-ing business; let me assure you, most producers do not have sufficientfunds to change the minds of many consumers.16 All the shoe manu-facturer can do is lower the price of his inventory, even if he does notregain his costs of production. After all, some income is better than noincome. Some money is better than a pile of unsold shoes that must bestored somewhere.

Consumers can buy many things with their inventory of unspecial-

Page 105: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

17. The cost of production is not an aspect of economic cost. What is spent is spent: sunkcosts. Once spent, the producer’s past costs are irrelevant to the crucial question: What canI get for my stock of goods?

18. Frank H. Knight, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit (New York: Harper Torchbooks,[1921] 1965), p. 244.

1044

ized money; producers cannot buy many things with their inventory ofspecialized goods. This is why consumers are economically sovereignover producers, even though consumers and producers are equallysovereign legally. The hierarchy of control under capitalism iseconomic. Consumers “hold the hammer”: money (the most market-able commodity) plus the legal authority to buy or not to buy from anyproducer.

Market theory rests on the insight that the consumer is economic-ally sovereign, even though the owner of a tool of production is leg-ally sovereign. The owner lawfully can do whatever he pleases withhis property, so long as he does not physically injure someone else,but he cannot thwart the consumer at zero cost. If he thwarts thedemand of the highest-bidding consumer by not selling the capitalgood’s final output to him, he thereby forfeits the extra amount ofmoney which that consumer would have paid him. The owner’s inven-tory cost is not just the cost of storage and insurance, but also theforfeited income.17

The free market, with its lure of profit, encourages the specializingof risk-bearing (insurance) and uncertainty-bearing (entrepreneur-ship).18 Capitalism allows consumers safely to transfer to producersboth the risk and the uncertainty of deciding what to produce andwhen, since the legal system places in the hands of consumers theauthority to say “no” to those products and services that they do notwish to buy at the prices offered. The consumers therefore hold thehammer over producers, despite the fact that the producers appearsovereign because they decide what gets produced. What they cannot

Page 106: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

19. Murray N. Rothbard, Man, Economy, and State: A Treatise on Economic Principles(Princeton, New Jersey: Van Nostrand, 1962), pp. 408–9, 554–56. Reprinted by the Ludwigvon Mises Institute, Auburn, Alabama, 1993.

20. Mises, Human Action, p. 333.

1045

control is what gets sold at what price.

Economic Imputation

So far, there is something missing from this explanation of thestructure of capitalist production and distribution. (Note: this is anintegrated system; production is not separate from distribution.)19

What is missing is imputation. We have seen that production takesplace over time. So, a question arises regarding the valuation of capi-tal goods, raw materials, labor inputs, and land. How does the presentvalue of any scarce economic resource relate to the value of its finaloutput? That is to say, how do present prices relate to future prices?

To answer this, we need to apply Mises’ theory of entrepreneurshipto capital goods theory. Producers act as the economic agents offuture consumers. Producers forecast future market demand as wellas they can. They study historical records of previous market demand(perhaps only a few minutes old), and then they guess what futuredemand (consumers) and future supply (their competition) will be.That is, they guess what the market price will be for a particularproduct.20 As Mises wrote in 1922 in his monumental refutation ofsocialism, the capitalist “must exercise foresight. If he does not do sothen he suffers losses – losses that bring it about that his disposition[control] over the factors of production is transferred to the hands ofothers who know better how to weigh the risks and the prospects of

Page 107: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

21. Ludwig von Mises, Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis, translatedby J. Kahane, 2nd ed. (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, [1932] 1951), pp.140– 41. Reprinted by Liberty Classics, 1981. First German edition: 1922.

22. He taught the more famous student, Milton Friedman. He studied under the morefamous teacher, Max Weber, and translated Weber’s 1919–20 lectures: General EconomicHistory.

23. Knight, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, p. 241.

1046

business speculation.”21 University of Chicago economist Frank Knight22 agreed with Mises

on the role of entrepreneurship, although he rejected Mises’ theory ofinterest and capital. Knight understood that the consumer is sovereignunder capitalism, and the entrepreneur-producer is his servant. Henoted the amazing fact that today’s consumer does not know exactlywhat he will want to buy in the future or what he will be willing topay. Therefore, “he leaves it to producers to create goods and holdthem ready for his decision when the time comes. The clue to theapparent paradox is, of course, in the ‘law of large numbers,’ theconsolidation of risks (or uncertainties). The consumer is, to himself,only one; to the producer he is a mere multitude in which individualityis lost. It turns out that an outsider can foresee the wants of amultitude with more ease and accuracy than an individual can attainwith respect to his own. This phenomenon gives us the mostfundamental feature of the economic system, production for a market.. . .”23

In the expectation that a particular piece of capital equipment willproduce something of value to future consumers – something they willpay for – producers today impute value to capital equipment. They dothe same with land, labor, and raw materials. They do this as presenteconomic agents of future consumers. (I keep repeating this becausenon-economists simply do not grasp it, including thousands of non-economists who hold Ph.D.’s in economics.) Mises described land

Page 108: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

24. Mises, Socialism, p. 41.

25. An interesting epistemological question can be asked at this point: If the producer andhis competitors never discover that he could have charged more, has he suffered aneconomic loss? If pure subjectivism is true, and if God’s omniscience is not part of thetheoretical explanation of value, then on what basis can the economist say that the producerhas suffered a loss? If there is no objective value, then there cannot be an objective loss.But if there is no subjective perception on the part of the producer or his competitors thathe has sustained a loss, has he in fact sustained it? This is an unsolved theoretical dilemmaof modern humanistic economics.

1047

ownership by a farmer in a market economy: “He does not controlproduction as the self-supporting peasant does. He does not decidethe purposes of his production; those for whom he works decide it –the consumers. They, not the producer, determine the goal ofeconomic activity. The producer only directs production towards thegoal set by the consumers.”24

Understand, however, that these consumers are not present consu-mers, for production is always aimed at the future. The consumerswho control production are in the minds of the producers. A par-ticular producer – the capitalist entrepreneur – may discover later thatthe actual consumers do not act in the way that his mental consumersdid. He will then suffer losses, either because he has to sell his outputfor less per unit than he planned, in order to unload his inventory, orelse he sells it at the expected price per unit, but then discovers thathe could have charged more.25 In either case, he experiences a loss.

The producer can consult present prices, meaning the most recenthistorical record of publicly published prices. This does not tell himanything secure regarding the future. Mises wrote in Human Actionthat “the prices of the factors of production are determined exclusivelyby the anticipation of future prices of the products. The fact thatyesterday people valued and appraised commodities in a different wayis irrelevant. The consumers do not care about the investments madewith regard to past market conditions and do not bother about the

Page 109: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

26. Mises, Human Action, p. 334.

27. Ibid., p. 634.

28. Ibid., p. 635.

1048

vested interests of entrepreneurs, capitalists, land-owners, andworkers, who may be hurt by changes in the structure of prices. Suchsentiments play no role in the formation of prices. . . . The prices ofthe past are for the entrepreneur, the shaper of future production,merely a mental tool.”26 A good’s present price is only a starting pointfor the producer’s inquiry into the possible range of a similar good’sfuture prices. These prices are set by competition: producers vs. prod-ucers, consumers vs. consumers.

Factors of Production

Land and labor are original factors of production.27 Capital is notan original factor of production; it is the product of land (raw mater-ials) and human labor over time.28 Thus, the producers of capitalequipment (producers’ goods) act as present economic agents offuture buyers and renters of producers’ goods, i.e., future consumersof producers’ goods. The producers of capital goods impute value topresent raw materials and labor. They enter the markets for rawmaterials and labor and bid against each other to buy legal controlover these scarce economic resources. That producer whose imputa-tions of the present value of these resources are the highest, and whothen bids up the price until no bidders remain to bid against him, winslegal control of specific resources. Producers give up the ownershipof present goods (money) in order to buy future goods – the outputof whatever resources they have bought – that can later be sold for

Page 110: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

29. An example of a piece of land that is worth less than zero would be a toxic waste sitewhose present owner is told by the government to clean it up at his expense.

30. Knight, “Preface to the Re-issue,” Risk, Uncertainty and Profit, p. xxvi. Misesrejected the whole concept of a stream of income: “There is in nature no such thing as astream of income. Income is a category of action; it is the outcome of careful economizingof scarce factors.” Mises, Human Action, p. 390. The stream of income concept hasnevertheless proven useful in discussing the discounting process of time-preference orinterest: a discount applied to expected income over time. We speak of time as flowing; thesame language of continuity applies equally well to the arrival of income over time.

1049

more money than they paid for them, they hope. A present purchaseof original factors of production costs a producer the ownership ofpresently owned consumer goods (i.e., money that could buy consum-er goods) over time. What it costs him, in other words, is interest.

What about owners of land? The same process of imputation takesplace. Land contains raw materials. Coupled with labor, these rawmaterials can be fashioned to produce goods. The present value ofland is therefore imputed to it by men who are acting as economicagents for future consumers. If the net value of a piece of land’s out-put is zero or less, and is expected to remain zero or less, then thevalue of the land is zero or less.29 It can rise above zero only when theexpectations of imputing agents change.

An Expected Stream of Net Income

When a person purchases a piece of property, he is buying legalownership over what the text in Leviticus calls the years of itsfruitfulness. The buyer is buying an expected stream of productionwhen he buys a piece of land, but he cannot know for sure that thisstream of income will persist in the future. As Knight wrote in 1933,“The basic economic magnitude (value or utility) is service, not good.It is inherently a stream or flow in time. . . .”30 To put it bluntly,

Page 111: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

31. On the interest rate (time-preference), see Rothbard, Man, Economy, and State, pp.319–23.

32. On the discounting process, see ibid., ch. 7: “Production: General Pricing of theFactors.”

1050

streams can dry up. This is what happened to Israel in the three yearsof drought when Elijah fled the nation (I Ki. 17).

The jubilee law limited its discussion of fruits to agricultural landlocated in Israel, but the same principle of ownership always governsthe purchase of any scarce economic resource: the owner has pur-chased legal control over an expected stream of net productivity (acapital good) or over an expected stream of passive income (a bond).

If a person buys a capital good for a cash payment, he becomes itspermanent owner. If he rents it for a specified period of time, hebecomes a lessee. Because the capital good is physical, people withouttraining in economics tend to think of it differently from the way theythink of a promissory note. But the present value of the note is notderived from the physical piece of paper or a blip in a computermemory device; rather, it is derived from the estimated value of themoney it promises to repay in the future, discounted by the prevailingrate of interest.31 Similarly, the present value of a capital good is notderived from its physical make-up; rather, its present value is theestimated value of what it is expected to produce, discounted by theprevailing rate of interest. The economic issue is value, not physicalmake-up. The economic issue is the market’s present imputation offuture value, discounted by the prevailing rate of interest. Thus, thesame process of imputation (valuation) applies equally to promissorynotes, land, and capital equipment.32 Prior to the abolition of slaveryin the nineteenth century, it also applied to human labor. We call thisimputation process capitalization.

Consider the case of a person who leases a piece of equipment. His

Page 112: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

1051

lease contract permits him to sublease it to someone else. A secondperson agrees to make a cash payment or else a periodic payment tothe person who leased the equipment first. The person who leased theasset first has now become a recipient of money income. It is now thesame as if he had purchased a bond in the first place instead of leasinga piece of equipment from someone else. He now owns a piece ofpaper issued by a third party who promises to pay him in the future.So, there is no economic difference between buying a stream of netfuture income in the form of a piece of capital equipment or a writtenpromise to pay (IOU).

Economic Oppression

The text warns against becoming an economic oppressor. Whatmust be recognized from the beginning is that in the case of buyingand selling rural land in Israel, economic oppression was a two-waystreet. Whether a person was a seller of land (buyer of money) or abuyer of land (seller of money) – i.e., whether a lessor or lessee – hecould become an oppressor, according to this passage. “And if thousell ought unto thy neighbour, or buyest ought of thy neighbour’shand, ye shall not oppress one another” (Lev. 25:14). This shouldwarn us against any thought that the potential oppressor is always abuyer of some asset, or that a seller is always the potential oppressor.

This is especially relevant with respect to buyers of labor services(sellers of money) and sellers of labor services (buyers of money). Ithas been assumed by those who favor civil legislation that “protectslabor” that employers are almost always the oppressors. Similarly, ithas been assumed by those who oppose trade unions that the unionsare normally the oppressors. Neither assumption is valid. What is validis the conclusion that when the civil government interferes in the

Page 113: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

33. Trade unions gain their economic ability to extract above-market wages from employ-ers by their legal authorization from the State to exclude non-union members from theauction for labor services. If all trade unions opened their membership to all applicants, theunions could no longer exclude competing laborers, and the unions’ ability to extractabove-market returns would then disappear. Unions adopt non-price means of excludingmembers: race, nationality, and especially the absence of family connections. See Gary S.Becker, “Union Restrictions on Entry,” in Philip D. Bradley (ed.), The Public Stake inUnion Power (Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press, 1959), ch. 10. Becker won theNobel Prize in economics in 1992.

1052

competitive market process of making voluntary contracts, the groupfavored by the legislation becomes the economic oppressor. Thisoppression is established by positive sanctions (subsidies) and negativesanctions (restraints against trade). The element of civil compulsionis the most important aspect in identifying the Bible’s concept ofeconomic oppression.

Things Seen and Unseen

Let me explain my reasoning by a discussion of the economics oflabor unions. If the State threatens violence against an employer whorefuses to hire trade union members, or refuses to pay the wagesdemanded by trade union members, the employer is being oppressedeconomically. But it is not just the employer who is victimized. If hecapitulates to the State, then he must fire (or refuse to hire) thoseworkers who are not union members. They are no longer legally em-ployable by him. They are now forced by law either to look elsewherefor employment or join the local trade union, which may not bepossible because of unofficial restrictions against entry.33 What thevoters and the politicians had regarded as economic oppression – anemployer’s refusal to hire one group of workers – was in fact adecision by the employer to hire a different group of workers: those

Page 114: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

34. Frédéric Bastiat, “What Is Seen and What Is Not Seen” (1850), in Selected Essayson Political Economy (Irvington, New York: Foundation for Economic Education, [1964]1968), ch. 1.

1053

who did not belong to a trade union. But very few legislators everconsider the effects of their law on those excluded. The legislation iscalled “pro-labor,” but it is in fact discriminatory against specificlaborers. Such legislation oppresses non-union members.

The challenge for the economist is to use economic reasoning toexplain what cannot be seen. The public can literally see specificpeople working for higher wages than they were offered before, andso the public concludes that the legislation has “helped labor.” Thepublic cannot literally see those workers who have been forced by lawto seek employment elsewhere. The voters do not readily consider thesecondary effects of this “pro-labor” legislation, for these secondaryeffects are not visible. These effects are only perceived througheconomic reasoning – a skill that must be developed. The belief that“labor” in general has been helped by legislation making trade unionscompulsory in certain industries and in certain regions is an exampleof what the mid-nineteenth-century French essayist Frédéric Bastiatcalled the fallacy of the effects not seen.34

Furthermore, it is not just the employed labor union member whobenefits. Those employers who can now afford to hire the excludedlaborers, but who could not have afforded to do so at the wagespreviously offered to these laborers, before the law was passed,receive a subsidy: lower-priced labor services. So, civil legislation to“help labor” and to “stop exploitation by employers” by making tradeunionism compulsory necessarily winds up helping some laborers atthe expense of others, and also helping some employers at the expenseof others.

It takes only the simplest level of economic analysis to understandthe economic effects of such legislation, but virtually no college-level

Page 115: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

35. James B. Jordan, The Sociology of the Church (Tyler, Texas: Geneva Ministries,1986), Appendix A: “Biblical Terminology for the Church.”

1054

economics textbook discusses the legislation in this forthright manner,and no high school textbook does. Neither do the history textbooks.There is a good economic reason for this omission. The vast majorityof textbooks are sold to tax-funded schools, and these schools aresubject to political pressure from well-organized trade unions, mostnotably the high school teacher unions. It is not in the unions’ interestto have students exposed to the idea that their teachers’ income isbased in part on the political exploitation of other potential teacherswho are willing to work for less but who are excluded through athreat of government violence against the school system’s Board ofTrustees. After several generations of such textbooks, even thetrustees fail to understand the economics of legislated violence.

The State and Economic Oppression

The text in Leviticus warns against exploiting others economically.The person who leases a piece of land from an owner can become anoppressor, but so can the owner who leases it. The ethical and judicialquestion is this: What is economic oppression? This is not so easy toanswer as Christian social commentators and humanistic legislatorshave sometimes imagined.

In Tools of Dominion, I argued that neither the Bible nor economictheory provides a legally enforceable definition of economic oppres-sion that is based on price. I argued that the State creates the condi-tions for economic oppression: injustice. This is affirmed by Psalm 82,which refers to rulers of the congregation, which was the nation as awhole.35 “God standeth in the congregation of the mighty; he judgeth

Page 116: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

36. North, Dominion Covenant, ch. 18.

37. Gary North, Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus (Tyler, Texas: Institutefor Christian Economics, 1990), pp. 679–80.

1055

among the gods. How long will ye judge unjustly, and accept thepersons of the wicked? Selah. Defend the poor and fatherless: dojustice to the afflicted and needy. Deliver the poor and needy: rid themout of the hand of the wicked” (Ps. 82:1–4). For the benefit of readerswho do not have access to Tools of Dominion, I reprint my argumentshere.

* * * * * * * * * * * * * *

Economic theory provides no definition of the concept of “econo-mic oppression” in the case of voluntary transactions. Only wherecoercion is involved – the threat of physical violence – can theeconomist be confident that oppression is involved. This does notmean that a definition of oppression is impossible, but it does meanthat no appeal to modern humanistic economic theory can provide aclear-cut definition. The use of the coercive power of the civil govern-ment to extract resources from other people can be regarded asoppression in most instances, but there are no clearly defined criteriaof oppressive voluntary transactions made in a free market. The merepresence of competitive bargaining between unequally rich or unequal-ly skillful bargainers does not constitute economic oppression, as thebargain between Jacob and Esau indicates (Gen. 25:29–34).36 Nev-ertheless, there are acts of economic oppression, even if conventionaleconomic theory cannot state the criteria scientifically (neutrally).37 .. .

In the case of voluntary economic transactions, the Bible gives nospecific guidelines as to what constitutes economic oppression, apart

Page 117: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

38. The laws requiring gleaning and prohibiting interest-bearing charitable loans tofellow Israelites had no civil penalty attached to them.

1056

from oppression in the form of commands to perform a civil crime(e.g., adultery, prostitution). There are laws that prohibit false weightsand measures or other crimes involving fraud, but these are generalrules for the whole population. They are not laws designed specificallyto protect widows, the fatherless, and strangers. Apart from the lawregarding weights and measures, the Bible does not authorize legis-lation or court decisions against perceived cases of economicoppression.38 There are no biblical (or economic) guidelines thatdefine “price gouging” or “rent-racking,” or similar unpopular prac-tices. The attempt of governors and judges, whether civil or ecclesias-tical, to go beyond the enforcement of specific laws against fraud isnecessarily an expansion of arbitrary rule. Legal predictability suffers,and therefore human freedom also suffers. The power-seeking Stateexpands at the expense of individual freedom.

This is not to argue that such evil economic practices do not exist.No doubt they do exist. The question is: What, if anything, is the civilgovernment or a church court supposed to do in any formal case ofalleged oppression? The problem that freedom-seeking Christiansocieties must deal with is the preservation of the judicial conditionsnecessary for maintaining personal liberty. How can a society avoidoppression by unjust civil magistrates if the legal system offers greatlatitude for civil judges to define arbitrarily and retroactively whatconstitutes an economic crime? Civil government is a God-ordainedmonopoly of violence. Allow arbitrary and unpredictable power here,and the entire society can be placed under the bondage of oppressors– oppressors who legally wield instruments of physical punishment. Incontrast, economic oppression is an individual act by a specific personagainst a handful of people locally. It is a temporary phenomenon,limited at the very least by the continuing wealth of the oppressor, the

Page 118: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

39. Ibid., pp. 683–84.

1057

continuing poverty of the victims, and the lifespans of both theoppressor and the oppressed. There are no comparably effectiverestraints on oppression by those who control the administration ofcivil justice. Society-wide, monopolistic, State-enforced sin is gener-ally a far greater threat to potential victims of oppression than local-ized, privately financed sin.39

* * * * * * * * * * * * * *

Oppression and the Jubilee Land Law

We now return to the text of the jubilee land law. Who is likely tobecome the victim of oppression? Answer: the person with less reli-able information about alternative offers and future economic andlegal conditions. This can be either party. In an overwhelmingly agri-cultural community, both parties probably have equally good informa-tion about the value of the fruits of production. The person who wantsto lease the land probably has somewhat poorer information about thephysical details of the property. On the other hand, the land ownermay have fallen into debt. Perhaps he is not a good manager of hismoney. He may be a poor farmer. He may have poor informationabout the value of the stream of net income from the land. So, the textdoes not specify one of the two parties as the more likely oppressor.

To identify the oppressor here, we need to identify the person whouses the State, or his knowledge about the most likely future actionsof the State, in order to gain a competitive advantage over the otherperson in a voluntary transaction. It is rare for biblical law to specifypricing as judicable economic oppression except in life-and-deathsituations – what I call “priestly pricing.” Biblically defined economic

Page 119: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

1058

oppression through price-setting is usually based on a person’s effic-ient use of illegitimate power by the State. The oppressor and the civilmagistrates act in collusion to oppress someone or some group.

A Question of Knowledge

The law of the jubilee was clear: in year 50, Israel’s agriculturalland was to revert to the original owners or their heirs. This leads meto ask: On what basis could anyone not have known what to pay foror charge for leasing the land? All land was not equally valuable. Tothe extent that one piece of land was more productive, net, thananother, to that extent the lease price would have been higher thanless productive land. For example, a farm with a well-developedorchard would have brought a higher price than a farm whose incomewas dependent on farming that required higher inputs of labor andcapital. The net income from the fruit of the orchard probably wouldhave exceeded the net income from grain farming. So, the existenceof variously priced annual leasehold rents was not necessarily evidenceof economic oppression by anyone.

Then what was? A cash payment or long-term annual rent agree-ment that was either too high (an exploiting lessor) or too low (anexploiting lessee) for the number of years remaining before the jubilee.But since everyone knew the number of years remaining, how couldthere be any doubt about this? The answer should be clear to anyonewho has followed my logic so far: one of the parties knew that thisstatute would probably not be honored by the civil magistrates whenthe year of jubilee arrived.

Which of the two would become the beneficiary if only one of themknew the truth? In the case of an advance cash payment for the fullterm of the lease, the party making the payment would have benefited.The person giving up control over the property would have asked a

Page 120: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

1059

price on the assumption that the property would return to him or hisheirs in the jubilee year. But this price was too low if the persongaining control would not in fact be required to relinquish control atthe jubilee.

In the case of a long-term lease arrangement, however, the personagreeing to pay the existing owner an annual payment until the nextjubilee year would have taken on an obligation longer than he hadsuspected. If the civil courts enforced the payment of the terms of thelease, but refused to enforce the jubilee, the person obligated to paycould become the oppressed party. If the land became less productiveor its fruits less valuable in the market, the person who leased the landwas stuck. The owner would collect his rental payment indefinitely.

The Civil Magistrates as Enforcers

The decisive factor, then, was the covenantal faithfulness of thecivil rulers. Their decision to neglect the enforcement of the jubileeyear would create conditions for economic oppression by one of thetwo contracting parties. Each party in the transaction was thereforewarned in advance by God: do not become an oppressor, even if cor-rupt civil magistrates make such oppression possible by refusing toenforce the terms of the jubilee land law. God warned everyone toabide by the jubilee law even if the civil rulers did not enforce it.

If I am correct in my analysis of this passage, then we haveadditional evidence that economic oppression in a free market is usu-ally the result of civil magistrates who refuse to enforce God’s Bible-revealed law. It is rarely the process of voluntary pricing in a freemarket that constitutes economic oppression; it is rather pricing in asociety in which civil magistrates favor a particular individual or classby means of economically discriminatory legislation or economically

Page 121: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

1060

discriminatory court decisions. State subsidies of all kinds enablepeople to oppress each other economically. The incentive to oppressothers in this way is universal. The ability to do so is very limitedwhen the civil magistrates restrict their actions to enforcing the lawsof God by imposing the sanctions specified by His law. The Stateinitiates economic oppression by creating the legal conditions in whichsuch oppression is profitable. In short, the State subsidizes economicoppression. As in the case of any State subsidy, this increases the sup-ply of the item being subsidized: economic oppression.

The Legitimacy of Both Rent and Interest

This law provides evidence of the existence of rental agreements inancient Israel. A lease is a rental agreement. A potential lesseeapproaches the land owner and makes an offer to take control of theland, meaning the fruits produced by the land over time. “Land” hereis defined as everything on the land or under the land, includinghouses, streams, ponds, fish, metals, and anything else specified byeither the lease or local custom. The lessee can pay this rent inadvance, or annually, or by a combination of the two. The terms of thelease are negotiable. What was not negotiable in ancient Israel was anextension of this lease beyond the beginning of the next jubilee year.The sound of the ram’s horn in year 50 would end all agriculturalleases.

Let us assume that the ram’s horn has sounded. How wouldIsraelites have estimated the value of a new lease? Let us begin witha hypothetical situation in which an heir has just inherited his land. Heis an international trader by profession. He has no interest in farming.Neither do his sons. What he wants is cash, so that he can makepurchases for the next voyage. He advertises that he is willing to lease

Page 122: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

1061

the property to anyone who wants it: high bid wins. Let us assume that those who might be interested in leasing the land

are all of equal forecasting ability and equal ability as farmers. They allhave cash, and they all want to farm. How will they calculate the valueof the lease?

Capitalizing Future Income

First, they will make forecasts regarding the average net incomethat can be derived from the fruit of the land over the next 49 years,including those initial six sabbatical years in which there is neitherincome nor a miraculous triple crop.

Second, they will seek information on what the correct rate ofinterest is for long-term loans. (Let us assume that a developed marketfor commercial loans did exist in Israel.) The person with money toinvest can invest in a farm for a period of time or lend the money intothe loan market. The lender makes adjustments for comparative ratesof risk, and then he decides where to invest in terms of the highestavailable rate of return. Will he invest in the land’s lease or a bond? Ifhis goal is money income, it will make no difference to him where themoney will come from. He seeks the highest rate of return. He caresnothing about getting his hands into “the good earth,” nor does hebecome ecstatic when clipping coupons. He simply wants the highestrate of return on his invested money. He can pay the land owner cashand receive lawful access to a stream of future agricultural income, orhe can pay a borrower cash and receive a stream of future moneyincome.

Let us consider a specific example. If the lessor’s land is expectedto produce an ounce of gold per year, net of all expenses, and thebond-issuer promises to repay the creditor an ounce of gold per year,

Page 123: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

40. This sounds about right for an 11-acre farm in the United States today; in ancientIsrael, it would have been too much, except possibly in the inflationary era of Solomon’sreign, when gold poured into his personal treasury (I Ki. 9:14, 28; 10:10, 14).

41. Especially if you are 49 years old.

1062

the present price of the lease will equal the present price of the bond.Why? Because the rate of interest – the discount applied to the priceof future goods in relation to the price of present goods – is appliedequally to both streams of income. Once he has adjusted for compara-tive rates of risk regarding repayment, the man with gold to invest isnot comparing a piece of paper (an IOU) with acres of dirt; he iscomparing gold held in the present vs. gold received in the future.

If there was no organized market for such loans in ancient Israel,then each of the prospective lessees would have had to estimate whathis own rate of discount was. This discount is not on money as such;it is on time itself. (I shift to the present tense.) Each potential lesseeasks himself: “How high do I discount the value to me of futureincome in relation to cash held today?” If he expects to gain from thefarm a net income of one ounce of gold per year,40 including forfeitedincome during six sabbatical years, he will not offer the farm’s owner49 ounces of gold, cash, even if he has that much available to invest.Why not? Because he already has 49 ounces of gold. Why should hegive up 49 ounces today in order to get back one ounce per year overa 49-year period? A bird in hand today is worth more than a bird inhand 49 years from now.41 The 49th ounce of gold that he owns todayis worth a great deal more to him than the 49th ounce of gold heexpects to receive 49 years in the future. The discount that he appliesto the value of each year’s ounce of gold is his rate of interest.

Interest and Rent

Page 124: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

1063

There are some contemporary commentators who claim that theOld Testament’s prohibition against interest from charitable loans tothe poor – “thy poor brother” (Deut. 15:9) – also applied to commer-cial transactions. Rarely or never are these critics professional theol-ogians, let alone economists. This interpretation of “usury” is incor-rect. The two types of loans were (and are) morally and legally differ-ent.

The Hebrew word translated as usury in the King James Versionmeans interest. Interest was prohibited when it was derived from amorally obligatory charitable loan to a poor person, either brother inthe faith or a righteous resident alien. It was not prohibited when itwas from a business loan, which was not morally obligatory. Thecharitable loan was morally compulsory (Deut. 15:9–10); the commer-cial loan was not. The charitable loan was cancelled in the seventhyear (Deut. 15:1–7); the commercial loan was not. The borrower whodid not repay a charitable loan on time could be sold into indenturedservitude; this servitude lasted until the debt was repaid or until theyear of national debt relief (Deut. 15:12–13). In contrast, theborrower who failed to repay a commercial loan suffered whateverpenalties the contract specified. This collateral could legally involveindentured servitude beyond the seventh year, but not beyond thebeginning of the year of jubilee, when every person had the right toreturn to his own land. The jubilee year was to break the bonds ofevery citizen in Israel, meaning every person who had an inheritancebased on the conquest of Canaan.

Interest is familiar to most people: a payment made to a creditor bya debtor for the use of money over time. The money is then spent bythe borrower in order to buy a factor of production or on con-sumption. But why should this definition of interest be limited tomoney? The addition of money to the transaction does not alter theeconomic nature of the transaction: payments made over time for the

Page 125: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

42. This assumes that he is not a sharecropper.

43. Rothbard, Man, Economy, and State, pp. 313–15.

1064

use of a scarce resource over time. It results from a discountingprocess: services today are worth more than the same services tomor-row. Today’s value of a bird in hand is greater than today’s value ofa guaranteed bird in hand in the future. (I am not speaking here ofcomparative risk.)

Why is a resource valuable? Because it generates rent: a stream ofincome over time. To gain legal access to this stream of income, therenter must pay rent to the owner.42 As people’s knowledge of econo-mic alternatives improves, rental payments made to the owner of aproduction factor will more closely approximate the market value ofthat factor’s output. Because the term rent has for so long beenapplied to land, people think of it exclusively as a factor payment toland. This limited definition is valid only in the case of a narrowtheoretical discussion of the original factors of production: land (rent)and labor (wage).43 But a wage is a rental payment for human labor.The analytic concept of rent – a stream of income – applies to everyfactor of production.

In terms of economic theory, the payment of rent is made to main-tain legal control over any factor of production. A consumer todaycan rent a car or a tool or almost anything else that can be purchased.What if I want to buy a stream of income for a period of time? I cango into the market and offer a cash payment. How much will I offer?If I am well informed, I will offer no more than the expected streamof income discounted by the rate of interest. I can buy land this way.I can buy tools. I can buy a contractual stream of money: a bond.Because of market competition, the cash price I must pay to buy therent (passive income stream) from land will equal the cash price I mustpay to buy the rent (passive income stream) from a bond (money

Page 126: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

44. One critic who has understood this is S. C. Mooney. He writes: “The economic simi-larity between usury and the rent of property readily is admitted. However, this closeconnection does not serve to legitimize usury, as Locke et all suppose; but to condemnrents.” Mooney, Usury: Destroyer of Nations (Warsaw, Ohio: Theopolis, 1988), p. 172. For

1065

contract), assuming everyone expects them to produce equal streamsof passive income. Unless I am misinformed (or remarkably charit-able), I will not pay more to buy the same passive income stream fromdifferent sources of equal risk. Stated differently, the interest rate(discount for time) applies equally to rental income from all sources.

If I want to gain legal control a piece of land that will provide mea passive income stream over a period of time, I can do it in either oftwo ways: (1) borrow the money and pay cash in advance for the useof the land, paying interest to the creditor; (2) lease the land weeklyor monthly, paying rent to the owner. Legally, the terms of the twocontracts are different. Economically, they are the same.

This leads us to an important conclusion: if paying interest for theuse of money over time is illegal biblically, then paying money for theuse of land over time is also illegal biblically. We call such paymentsfor land rent. I will put it another way. If I were to borrow money ata rate of interest and then go out and use this money to pay cash forthe use of a piece of property over the same period as the loan period,it is no different economically from going to the owner of the propertyand guaranteeing him monthly rent for that period. I can eitherguarantee to pay the creditor who loaned me cash a monthly rate ofinterest until I repay the principal or guarantee to pay the propertyowner a monthly rental payment until the lease expires. Legally, I amequally obligated to pay. Economically, it will cost me the sameamount of money in a competitive market.

Very few of those people – never are they trained economists –who claim that all interest payments are immoral understand that theirnegative judgment against interest must apply equally to rent.44 A

Page 127: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

my detailed critique of Mr. Mooney’s utterly bizarre theory of interest and his equallybizarre applications, see Tools of Dominion, Appendix G: “Lots of Free Time: The Existen-tialist Utopia of S. C. Mooney.”

1066

denial of the legitimacy or legality of interest payments over time isalso a denial of the legitimacy or legality of rental payments over time,i.e., a lease.

The critic of all interest payments who says that he opposes interestpayments “because the Old Testament does” has a major problem withLeviticus 25:14–17, i.e., the law governing long-term land leases. Ifa lease is legitimate, then rent is also legitimate, for a lease is a long-term rental contract. If rent is legitimate, then interest is alsolegitimate, for interest in a modern capitalist market is a rental con-tract for the use of money – an agreement entered into only becauseborrowers have uses for things money can buy. There is a lender anda borrower in each case. There is an agreement to pay money ininstallments over time for the use of goods over the same period oftime. The lender (a person who gives up money or goods for a periodof time) forfeits the use of the things that the cash would buy. Theborrower (a person who gains control over money or goods for aperiod of time) gains access to the things money can buy by means ofhis promise to repay money or goods in the future. In each case, thelender will not lend unless he receives more money or more goods inthe future than he gives up today; otherwise, it would be irrational togive them up, except as an act of charity.

Conclusion

The jubilee land law prohibited oppression in the writing of landlease contracts. Oppression resulted when one of the two parties tothe transaction used specialized knowledge to take advantage of the

Page 128: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

1067

other. The kind of knowledge was quite specific: knowledge of futuredecisions by the civil magistrates not to enforce the terms of the jubi-lee land law.

Either party to the transaction could become an oppressor underthis definition. The land owner might persuade the lessee to agree toa contract in which the lessee promised to make regular paymentsuntil the jubilee year was declared. If it was not declared, and the mag-istrates refused to allow him to escape from the terms of the contract,the lessee would find himself locked into the contract. Under someeconomic conditions (e.g., a long-term fall in the money price foragricultural products), this would defraud the lessee. On the otherhand, the lessee might be able to get the land owner to accept a cashpayment in advance for legal control over the land’s production. If thejubilee land law was not enforced, the lessee would be able to extendhis control over the land indefinitely. This would defraud the landowner. Conclusion: the State was the source of the opportunity foroppression.

Both parties were warned to honor the terms of the jubilee land lawwhether the civil magistrates did or not. God placed the primary res-ponsibility for law enforcement on the contracting parties. He warnedthem both: “Honor the terms of the leasehold that I have made withIsrael for control over My land.”

The issue of economic oppression in this law was not the actualpricing of the factor of production: land. This decision was left to thecontracting parties. Each looked at the expected future stream ofincome from the land. Each would apply the prevailing market dis-count of the price of future goods in relation to present goods to thisstream of income: interest. Then they would decide what to offer eachother. The agreed-upon price, however, had to take into considerationthe irrevocable date for the termination of the contract: the jubileeyear.

Page 129: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

45. The aforementioned Mr. Mooney has yet to reply to this argument, which I alsooffered in Tools of Dominion in 1990.

1068

The existence of a law governing land leases in Israel testifies to theerror of interpreting the Bible’s prohibition against usury in charitableloans as a prohibition against all forms of interest. The decision tomake a cash payment in order to acquire legal ownership of a streamof resource-generated income over a fixed period of time is identicaleconomically to making a cash payment to buy an interest-payingbond with the same expiration date as the lease. This means that aprohibition against all interest payments must also be a prohibitionagainst all rent payments. Yet this law establishes the legality of rent.I therefore conclude that the Bible does not prohibit interest in non-charity loans.45

There is no evidence that the jubilee laws were ever enforced inIsrael. This may indicate that the jubilee laws sometimes were notenforced. Probably they were not enforced prior to the exile, for theseventh year of release was not honored, which is why God sent Israelinto exile (II Chron. 36:21). Thus, every Israelite could safely assumethat other laws beside the jubilee land law would govern leaseholdcontracts. Other civil laws would provide differing authority tomagistrates to decide which leases would be honored and whichwould not. The magistrates of Israel arrogated authority to themselvesto disobey God regarding the sabbatical year. How far could theysafely be trusted to honor the terms of other laws? The opportunitiesfor economic oppression must have increased, compared to rule by thesabbatical law and the jubilee land law, for there would have been lesscertainty about the enforcement of the civil law. The greater thedegree of judicial uncertainty, the greater the amount of resourcesnecessary to protect oneself: better lawyers, larger bribes, and higherexpenditures on searching out information regarding the integrity of

Page 130: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Economic Oppression by Means of the State

1069

one’s trading partners and also the moral integrity of their legal heirs.These were long-term lease contracts.

Summary

Oppression in this passage applies to a contractual period of time:the years remaining until the jubilee.

It refers to a price ceiling and floor for the price of land and labor. The price must reflect the number of years remaining and the

“fruits.”The fruits have economic value.Modern economic theory teaches that value is imputed subjectively

to scarce resources by consumers and their economic agents(middlemen-entrepreneurs).

Consumers (sellers of money) are economically sovereign overproducers because they own money: the most marketable good.

Consumers also possess the right not to buy.The seller of goods and services must meet consumer demand or

else forfeit ownership of whatever the highest-bidding consumerwould have paid.

Producers act today as economic agents of consumers in the future.They impute value to producer goods.They establish prices through mutual competition.“Years of fruit” means a expected stream of income.Economic oppression is a two-way street: buyer or seller.The oppressor’s interests are favored by the State, which imposes

sanctions: positive or negative.The Bible offers no legal definition of economic exploitation in the

cases of strictly voluntary exchange.The Bible does not authorize civil legislation against perceived

Page 131: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 26 . . . Leviticus 25:14–17

1070

cases of economic exploitation.The State easily becomes arbitrary.The most likely person to be the victim of exploitation in land sales

was the least informed regarding civil government.One of the parties in an oppressive lease contract knew that the

jubilee law would probably not be enforced.This could be either the land’s owner or its renter.The failure of the civil magistrates to enforce the jubilee land laws

was the basis of the oppression.This law validated both rents and interest.The bargainers made their estimations of value based on the expec-

ted value of future output – rate of return – discounted by an expectedrate of interest.

A bird in hand today is worth more than a bird in hand tomorrow(or 49 years).

Interest is a discount applied to future goods in relation to the samegoods in the present. It is a payment for the present use of scarceresources.

The Bible does not prohibit interest.A rental payment for land or equipment is not analytically different

from an interest payment for money: both are payments made for thepresent use of scarce resources.

If interest is illegal biblically, so is rent.Leviticus 25:14–17 established rules governing land leases, i.e.,

long-term rental agreements.Leviticus 25:14–17 legitimized both rent and interest payments.

Page 132: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1071

27

FOOD MIRACLES AND

COVENANTAL PREDICTABILITY

Wherefore ye shall do my statutes, and keep my judgments, and dothem; and ye shall dwell in the land in safety. And the land shall yieldher fruit, and ye shall eat your fill, and dwell therein in safety. Andif ye shall say, What shall we eat the seventh year? behold, we shallnot sow, nor gather in our increase: Then I will command myblessing upon you in the sixth year, and it shall bring forth fruit forthree years. And ye shall sow the eighth year, and eat yet of old fruituntil the ninth year; until her fruits come in ye shall eat of the oldstore (Lev. 25:18–22).

The theocentric meaning of this passage is that God sustains Hispeople, and more than sustains them. He offers them plenty. They arerequired to acknowledge this fact by trusting His promises. Theydisplay this trust through their obedience to His law.

Universal Benefits: Peace and Food

This passage begins with a re-statement of the familiar cause-and-effect relationship between corporate external obedience to God’scovenant law and corporate external blessings. We know that theframe of reference is corporate blessings because of the use of the firstperson plural: “What shall we eat the seventh year? behold, we shallnot sow, nor gather in our increase.” In this case, the text focuses ontwo blessings: peace and food. “Wherefore ye shall do my statutes,and keep my judgments, and do them; and ye shall dwell in the land insafety. And the land shall yield her fruit, and ye shall eat your fill, and

Page 133: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 27 . . . Leviticus 25:18–22

1. The law applied to all Israelites. Aliens could become heirs of this promise throughadoption, either into a family (rural) or tribe (walled city). Excommunication removed anheir from his landed inheritance. Excommunication also removed him from citizenship.This is why a excommunicant’s adult sons had to break publicly with him and his rebellionin order to preserve their own inheritance. Although there is no law governing this, Ipresume that minor sons of an excommunicated father could inherit upon their majority at

1072

dwell therein in safety (vv. 18–19).” This is a repeated theme in theBible. “But they shall sit every man under his vine and under his figtree; and none shall make them afraid: for the mouth of the LORD ofhosts hath spoken it” (Micah 4:4).

If this dual promise of peace and food were found only in Leviticus25, it could be discussed as an aspect of the jubilee laws and thereforeno longer in force. But the list of God’s positive sanctions in Leviticus26:3–15 indicates that this pair of positive sanctions was not uniquelytied to the jubilee. The promise of peace and food is more general thanthe jubilee law, since it refers to “my statutes” and “my judgments.”God refers Israel back to His revealed law-order. It is their covenantalfaithfulness to the stipulations of this law-order which alone serves thebasis of their external prosperity. Without obedience, they can have nolegitimate confidence in their earthly future in the land. This law hasa broad application. It undergirds the observation by David: “I havebeen young, and now am old; yet have I not seen the righteousforsaken, nor his seed begging bread” (Ps. 37:25). The link betweenobedience to God’s statutes and eating is reflected in David’sobservation: righteousness and the absence of begging.

Why is this passage found in the jubilee statutes? Because of theunique place of both the land and the harvest in the jubilee laws.Preceding this section are laws that deal with the transfer of a family’sland to the heirs: the return – legally, though not necessarily physically– of each man to his father’s land (v. 13). This was a testament ofliberation. Because of this law, there could be no permanent legalenslavement of Israelites inside the land.1 The jubilee law also

Page 134: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Food Miracles and Covenantal Predictability

age 20 if they broke with their father publicly when they turned 20. The goal of biblical lawis restoration.

1073

established an obligation for all leasehold contracts to be based on thejubilee year’s requirement of rural land’s reversion to the originalfamily (vv. 14–17). Following the announcement of the dual blessingof peace and food is another promise: a triple crop in the sixth year ofthe seventh cycle of sabbatical weeks of years (vv. 20– 22).

The promise of peace and food points the reader’s attention to theauthor of the law. God is sovereign. He promises to bring themnational prosperity in response to their adherence to His laws. Thispromise is conditional: no obedience, no prosperity. This fact ofcovenantal life becomes clear in the next chapter of Leviticus. In orderto demonstrate the reliability of His promises on a year-to-year basis,He promised a manifestation of His supernatural sovereignty: amiracle year.

The Miracle Year

To the jubilee year was attached a miracle. God promised to delivera triple crop in the sixth year of the seventh sabbatical cycle of years.“And if ye shall say, What shall we eat the seventh year? behold, weshall not sow, nor gather in our increase: Then I will command myblessing upon you in the sixth year, and it shall bring forth fruit forthree years. And ye shall sow the eighth year, and eat yet of old fruituntil the ninth year; until her fruits come in ye shall eat of the oldstore” (vv. 20–22). This triple portion was God’s way of announcingHis presence with His people. They would be given sufficient crops tosustain them through the sabbath year and the jubilee year. Then, atthe end of the jubilee (eighth) year, they were to plant for the next

Page 135: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 27 . . . Leviticus 25:18–22

2. Gary North, Moses and Pharaoh: Dominion Religion vs. Power Religion (Tyler, Texas:Institute for Christian Economics, 1985), ch. 18: “Manna, Predictability, and Dominion.”

1074

year.

The Miraculous Manna

In the wilderness period, they had been given the almost dailymiracle of the manna. The exception to this miracle was itself an evengreater miracle. On the day before the sabbath, they could gather adouble portion. The manna in jars would not rot on the sabbath (Ex.16:22). On every other day of the week, any manna that was left in ajar overnight would rot (Ex. 16:20).

As I have written in my commentary on Exodus, the manna had afunction beyond the mere provisioning of the people with their dailybread. It was given to them in order that they might develop confi-dence in God as a sovereign provider. His provision of manna wasmiraculous. It was also regular. They had to trust God to bring themanna the next day, for it could not be stored overnight. Then, oncea week, the regularity of the miracle was manifested in a differentway: the miraculous rotting of the manna miraculously ceased. Theycould store it overnight, so that they would not have to labor toharvest it on the sabbath. So, the miracle was to teach them about theregularity of God’s provisioning, as well as their total dependence onHis grace.2

When they came into the land, the manna ceased forever: “And themanna ceased on the morrow after they had eaten of the old corn ofthe land; neither had the children of Israel manna any more; but theydid eat of the fruit of the land of Canaan that year” (Josh. 5:12). Thefruit of the land would henceforth sustain them. But this did not mean

Page 136: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Food Miracles and Covenantal Predictability

3. Gary North, Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1990), pp. 816–17.

1075

that they were any less dependent on God for their food. Now, how-ever, their food would come predictably in terms of their corporatecovenantal conformity to His law: the greater their obedience, themore predictable their food.

In order to remind them of their continuing need to obey Him, asthe sovereign provider of food, God did not totally remove His mira-cles from the land. Twice per century, God promised to provide themwith bread in a miraculous way: the triple crop of the sixth year in theseventh cycle of the sabbatical week of years. This would be theequivalent of manna.

The Self-Discipline of Thrift

In a normal cycle of seven years, the Israelites had to save enoughgrain over six years to get through the seventh (sabbatical) year andhalf way through the eighth year, until the eighth-year crop could beharvested.3 But this was not the case in jubilee year periods. In thesixth year would come a triple crop. That crop would feed them in thesecond half of year six, all of year seven (sabbatical), all of year eight(jubilee), and half way through year nine.

This means that in the six years prior to a jubilee year, farmers didnot have to store up crops in order to carry themselves through thesabbatical year, the jubilee year, and half way through the ninth yearuntil the crop came in. This triple crop was Old Covenant Israel’sequivalent of the manna of the wilderness: a miraculous gift from God.It was the bread of life.

In escaping the production restraints of a normal sabbatical cycle,

Page 137: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 27 . . . Leviticus 25:18–22

4. Because of the high cost of ground transportation, these exported crops would normallyhave gone by boat.

1076

they acknowledged their dependence on the grace of God. The thriftthat was agriculturally necessary during normal sabbatical periods wasnot required during the jubilee’s week of years. Each farm could safelyconsume or sell one-sixth of each year’s crop during the finalsabbatical cycle. This income would otherwise have had to be storedor sold for cash and retained in that form in preparation for thesabbatical year. This pre-jubilee miracle would have made it possiblefor thrifty farmers to increase their purchase of farming tools, or makeinvestments in urban industries, or make foreign investments. Thisextra marketable output of food would have tended to lower the priceof food in Israel during jubilee periods, thereby stimulating the exportof food to nations where food prices were higher.4 Meanwhile, not-so-thrifty Israelites could have enjoyed more food, or else they couldhave sold the agricultural surplus in order to buy urban-producedconsumer goods or imported consumer goods. To both the thrifty andthe less thrifty, God promised six consecutive years of relief from thepressure to save for the normal sabbatical year.

To take advantage of this miraculous gift from God, the Israeliteshad to trust God to deliver on His promise to the nation. If theyrefused to save for six years in preparation for the arrival of a sabbathyear of rest and the jubilee year, back to back, a refusal of God todeliver the triple crop would have created near-famine conditions bythe ninth year. Many people would have been forced to sell theirfamily lands or even sell themselves into slavery – in the very periodthat God set aside for the recovery of family lands and the release ofbondservants. Thus, they had to exercise faith that the triple cropwould arrive on schedule.

On the other hand, if God delivered on His promise, but the peoplethen refused to honor the sabbatical year and/or the jubilee year,

Page 138: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Food Miracles and Covenantal Predictability

5. Gary North, Treasure and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Luke, 2nd elec-tronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc., [2000]2003), ch. 6.

1077

planting and harvesting instead, this would have constituted a misuseof the jubilee miracle. It would have constituted theft from Godthrough the economic oppression of hired harvesters, strangers, andgleaners. It is clear from the message of Jeremiah that the nation didnot honor the sabbatical years for 70 sabbatical cycles, or 490 years.This is why they were sent into captivity. “To fulfil the word of theLORD by the mouth of Jeremiah, until the land had enjoyed hersabbaths: for as long as she lay desolate she kept sabbath, to fulfilthreescore and ten years” (II Chron. 36:21).

There is no unambiguous biblical record that the jubilee law wasever honored in Israel. We know that the sabbath year of release wasnot honored for 490 years prior to the exile. Since they did not honorthe sabbath year of release, it is highly doubtful that God ever gavethem the promised triple crop in the seventh sabbatical cycle. Withoutthe triple crop, perhaps they chose to ignore the jubilee law. The Bibledoes not say.

Miracles, Sanctions, and Mysticism

When Jesus announced His fulfillment of the jubilee year (Luke4:18–21), He was announcing the end of the miraculous jubilee year.5

Under the New Covenant, there is no triple crop in the sixth year ofthe seventh “week of years.” The faith of New Covenant-keepers hasbeen stripped of a national miracle that demonstrated the reliability ofGod’s providential and law-bounded covenantal order, just as asimilar faith during the wilderness era was stripped of a daily miraclewhen the manna ceased upon the nation’s entry into Canaan. As the

Page 139: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 27 . . . Leviticus 25:18–22

6. This has been the case in the history of Christianity. In the early church, the miraclesof healing and exorcism were important in evangelism. Today, both of these gifts are farless evident in advanced industrial nations, although both still are used by somefundamentalist missionaries working in primitive societies or in societies deeply inbondage to a rival supernatural religion.

1078

spiritual maturity of covenant-keepers advances, miracles steadilycease.6

The question arises: What about the covenantal cause-and-effectconnection between corporate external obedience and corporateblessings? Are covenant-bound societies still promised peace andagricultural prosperity if they adhere to the external requirementsGod’s revealed law? Was this annulled by Jesus in His fulfillment ofthe jubilee year? No. In Leviticus 26, which appears after the close ofthe jubilee laws, we read: “And I will give peace in the land, and yeshall lie down, and none shall make you afraid: and I will rid evilbeasts out of the land, neither shall the sword go through your land”(Lev. 26:6). This recapitulation of the promise of Leviticus 25:18–19indicates that this aspect of the jubilee law was broader than an aspectof the jubilee law. But was it a cross-boundary law? Did it applyoutside the Promised Land? The recapitulation in Leviticus 26 isparalleled in Deuteronomy 28, and is mentioned as a testimony to thenations:

The LORD shall cause thine enemies that rise up against thee to besmitten before thy face: they shall come out against thee one way, andflee before thee seven ways. The LORD shall command the blessingupon thee in thy storehouses, and in all that thou settest thine handunto; and he shall bless thee in the land which the LORD thy Godgiveth thee. The LORD shall shalt keep establish thee an holy peopleunto himself, as he hath sworn unto thee, if thou the commandmentsof the LORD thy God, and walk in his ways. And all people of theearth shall see that thou art called by the name of the LORD; and they

Page 140: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Food Miracles and Covenantal Predictability

7. Israel was not to initiate foreign wars. The Mosaic festival laws made empireimpossible. There was no permanent payoff in launching foreign wars because of thedistance of foreign nations from the central city where sacrifices were offered.

8. Gary North, Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Deuteronomy,2nd electronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc.,[1999] 2003), ch. 8.

1079

shall be afraid of thee (Deut. 28:7–10).

Why should they be afraid of Israel if they did not interpret thevisible predictable sanctions in Israel as proof of God’s uniquepresence with Israel? Did this fear apply only to the risks of invadingIsrael? Were the nations not also to fear a counter-invasion by Israel?7

Deuteronomy 20:10–20 lists the laws of siege. These laws did notapply to Israel’s invasion of Canaan, for they established legitimateterms of surrender, which were not options during the conquest.Therefore, these military laws had to apply to warfare outside theland. They were cross-boundary laws. Since Israel was to be feared byforeign nations, the corporate covenantal sanctions visible toforeigners inside the land had to be presumed by them to apply outsidethe land, too (Deut. 4:4–8).8

Without the miracle of manna or the miracle of the triple crop, NewCovenant Christians are thrown back on their faith in God’s revealedword. The compelling evidence of God is supposed to be God’s word.This always was the case, but the miracles were added to overcomethe Israelites’ weakness of faith. Old Covenant believers in thewilderness had daily edible reminders of God’s presence. In thePromised Land, these reminders were reduced numerically to twiceper century. In the New Covenant, the miracle of food is restricted tothe Lord’s Supper. This miracle – co-participation in heavenly wor-ship by the earthly church and the heavenly church – must be accepted

Page 141: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 27 . . . Leviticus 25:18–22

9. New Covenant Christians have gone in three directions to explain this miracle. RomanCatholics have turned to philosophical realism: the literal, bodily presence of Christ in thesacrament. The Lutherans also are realists, defending the body and blood of Christ as beingsubstantially present: Formula of Concord (1576), Art. VII, Sections 1, 2. Anabaptists haveadopted nominalism: the Lord’s Supper as a mere memorial. The biblical view is neitherrealism nor nominalism but covenantalism: God’s special judicial presence in the eatingof the meal. It is a meal eaten on the Lord’s Day, or Day of the Lord, or judgment day.

10. The census was to be taken prior to holy war (Deut. 20).

1080

on faith.9

Covenantal Predictability

Has God reduced His covenantal predictability in history along withHis reduction of miracles? For instance, does it take longer today thanit did in Mosaic Israel for God to bring his negative sanctions inhistory? No evidence that I am aware of suggests this. Sometimes, thenegative sanctions came soon. God was angry with Israel, so Hemoved David to take an illegal holy census (I Sam. 24:1).10 David’ssin in numbering the nation brought an immediate plague on 70,000people (II Sam. 24:15). Rapid judgment was the threat that Ninevehfaced; the nation therefore repented. Covenant-breakers outside theland understood the cause-and-effect connection between corporatesin and God’s wrath in history. In other cases, judgment was delayedfor centuries. In Mosaic Israel, the nation violated the sabbatical yearlaws for centuries. Not until Jeremiah’s day were they told that Godwould soon bring His corporate wrath against the nation for this long-term act of rebellion by sending them into captivity (I Chron. 36:21).

While miracles steadily disappear, the covenantal promise of God’spredictable corporate sanctions remain in place. If this were not thecase, the sanctions aspect of the Lord’s Supper (I Cor. 11:30) wouldbe transferred completely out of history. While a man’s verbal oath

Page 142: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Food Miracles and Covenantal Predictability

1081

and the physical sacraments are part of history, the oath is taken underGod, who is in eternity. Some of the personal sanctions are bothpredictable and eternal, but corporate negative sanctions are exclu-sively historical (no sin beyond the resurrection). On what exegeticalbasis can the sacrament’s sanctions be said to be predictable onlyoutside of history and apply only to individuals?

This raises the question of civil oaths. Nations take oaths (Ex. 19).Are these oaths enforced exclusively by men rather than God? Politi-cal pluralists are logically compelled to answer yes: no God enforcescorporate civil oaths with covenantally predictable historical sanctionsinvoked by the oaths. If pluralists were to answer no, therebyaffirming God’s predictable, corporate, covenantal, historical sanc-tions, they would have to abandon their pluralism. Their religion for-bids them to answer otherwise: no supernatural frame of reference forcivil oaths.

If God’s predictable, corporate, covenantal sanctions in historywere to disappear, just as predictable corporate miracles such as man-na and the triple crop have disappeared, Christianity would necessarilybe progressively absorbed into the larger covenant-breaking culture.Whatever regularity in corporate sanctions that might be said to existin history would be based on shared, universal categories of social andpolitical ethics, e.g., natural law theory. There would be no way forthe kingdom of God to manifest its presence among men exceptthrough the verbal testimony of individuals regarding totally invisible,subjectively discerned patterns of predictability, e.g., “I feel all tinglywhen I pray.” For those people who have no desire to feel tingly, orwho are content to take niacinamide whenever they want to feeltingly, such verbal testimony carries no weight. Christian culture couldbe differentiated from pagan culture only through the personalmysticism of its members. But mysticism is inherently without theo-logical and judicial content – beyond the realm of creeds and intel-

Page 143: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 27 . . . Leviticus 25:18–22

11. Katherine Kulhman, I Believe in Miracles (New York: Pyramid Books, [1962] 1964).

1082

lectual categories. So-called Christian mysticism cannot be disting-uished judicially from pagan mysticism. In short, if neither revelationalethics and its attached sanctions nor miracles identify the historicalpresence of the kingdom of God, the institutional church ceases tohave a role to play in history that is visibly different from any othercharitable or salvationist organization. This lack of distinctionovertook most evangelical churches in the twentieth century.Christianity is regarded by covenant-breakers as just one more amel-iorative-mystical tradition among thousands.

The way to restore the church to its position as society’s centralinstitution is to preach a separate biblical worldview based on biblicallaw and biblical sanctions. The other avenue for distinguishing thechurch from the world – the quest for miracles or continuing revela-tion – in the twentieth century became the differentiating mark ofpentecostals and charismatics.11 The third path is mysticism.

Covenantal corporate predictability in history is mandatory ifChristians are to reconstruct social theory. If such regularity did notexist in New Covenant history, then society could not be reformed ona uniquely Christian basis. The church would then seek to avoid socialtransformation. It would retreat from the world (discontinuity) orconform itself to the world (continuity). It would become eitherfundamentalist-mystical or liberal. This is generally what happened inthe United States, 1900–1975. As Rushdoony says, the fundamental-ists believe in God but not in history, while the liberals believe inhistory but not in God. In either case, the world is abandoned to thecovenantal representatives of Satan. There is no neutrality.

Miracles of Feeding

Page 144: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Food Miracles and Covenantal Predictability

12. The prophets used the miracle of feeding on numerous occasions. The pagan widowof Zerephath had two containers that filled daily, one with oil and the other with meal,when Elijah lived in her home (I Ki. 17:14–15). In the New Testament, Jesus used themiracle of feeding on two occasions.

13. North, Inheritance and Dominion, ch. 21.

1083

The law of God is given to all men so that they will learn to obeythe God of the Bible. If they live in societies that are marked bywidespread obedience to the external laws of God, they will exper-ience widespread external blessings, among which are peace and food.

To prove that this promise can be trusted, God on occasion hasestablished miracles of feeding. The first time was in the wildernessperiod: the manna. When they entered the Promised Land, theyinitially lived off the crops of their defeated enemies. Then, as theybegan to plant and reap, they were to become thrifty: saving, not fora rainy day, but for the sabbatical year. But in the seventh cycle ofsabbatical years, God promised to give them a miracle: the triple cropof the sixth year. This was to allow them to save for six years and notbe forced to consume their savings in the seventh and eighth, orconsume what would normally have been saved for six years and notbe penalized for their consumption.12

The triple crop was also to remind them that God’s blessings arepredictable in history. It would remind them that the source of theirprosperity was not thrift as such, but thrift within the framework ofGod’s covenant. They were warned not to draw a false conclusion,one based on the humanist presupposition of the autonomy of man:“And thou say in thine heart, My power and the might of mine handhath gotten me this wealth. But thou shalt remember the LORD thyGod: for it is he that giveth thee power to get wealth, that he mayestablish his covenant which he sware unto thy fathers, as it is thisday” (Deut. 8:17–18).13 Covenantal blessings are given to confirm thecovenant.

Page 145: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 27 . . . Leviticus 25:18–22

14. Herbert Schlossberg, Idols for Destruction: Christian Faith and Its Confrontationwith American Society (Westchester, Illinois: Crossway, [1983] 1993), p. 11.

15. Gary North, The Dominion Covenant: Genesis, 2nd ed. (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, [1982] 1987), Appendix A: “From Cosmic Purposelessness toHumanistic Sovereignty.”

1084

Conclusion

The miracle of the triple crop was promised to Israel in order toconfirm visibly: (1) the sovereignty of God over nature; (2) the predic-tability of God’s covenant-based blessings in history. The Israeliteswere not to capitulate to the temptation of worshipping another god,either a god of nature or a god of history – the only two kinds of idolsavailable to covenant-breaking man.14

Modern covenant-breaking man denies the miracles. He wishes todivinize either nature or history or both (Darwinism). To do this, hemust deny all traces of God’s authority over nature and history.Modern man has chosen evolution as his god, meaning his source oflaw. Evolution is said to govern both nature and historical process.Evolution is regarded as impersonal except when man, meaning elitemen, learns the secrets of evolution and then directs both nature andhistory.15 A major appeal of evolution is power.

Modern Christians reject evolution in its humanist form. They insistthat God is still sovereign over history, although Augustinians andCalvinists alone insist that God predestines everything that comes topass in history. There are virtually no visible traces of CatholicAugustinianism and very few traces of Calvinism. Furthermore, mostmodern Calvinists have explicitly or implicitly denied the existence ofcovenantal predictability in New Covenant times. They openly rejectthe idea of a national civil covenant under God. They are political

Page 146: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Food Miracles and Covenantal Predictability

16. Gary North, Political Polytheism: The Myth of Pluralism (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1989), chaps. 3–5.

17. Gary North, Millennialism and Social Theory (Tyler, Texas: Institute for ChristianEconomics, 1990), ch. 7.

18. Gary North, “Ghetto Eschatologies,” Biblical Economics Today, XIV (April/May1992).

1085

pluralists.16 They do not believe that God brings predictable corporatesanctions, positive or negative, in terms of a nation’s obedience toGod’s Bible-revealed law.17

This belief leaves them without any miracles with which to chal-lenge humanists and other covenant-breakers. This belief also providesthem with a theological explanation for the seeming helplessness ofChristianity to transform culture by establishing the civilization of Godin history: God’s kingdom. This in turn creates a deep psychologicalneed to find personal solace in the midst of inevitable cultural defeat:pietistic ecclesiastical ghettos. Finally, their widespread acceptance oflife in these ghettos has led to the development of ghettoeschatologies.18

Without a concept of God’s covenant in history, Christians havenot been able to develop an explicitly Christian social theory. Theyhave relied on imported pagan natural law concepts to develop whatfew social ideas they possess. All of this has been the product of thewidespread acceptance of the original theological assumption, namely,that God in the New Covenant era has annulled the covenantalpredictability of Leviticus 26 and Deuteronomy 28. With neitherwidespread faith in the miracle of covenantal predictability nor thepresence of earlier covenantal miracles of food and healing, modernChristians have become almost totally defensive in their thinking.Ideas have consequences.

Page 147: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 27 . . . Leviticus 25:18–22

1086

Summary

The promises of peace and food were corporate.The promises of peace and food were covenantal, not jubilee-

related.These promises appear in the jubilee passage because of the unique

place of both land and harvest in the jubilee.God promised a miraculous triple crop in the year before the sab-

batical year prior to the jubilee.This was analogous to the manna of the wilderness.In normal sabbatical cycles, they had to save for six years to pre-

pare for the seventh.The triple crop allowed them to escape the normal burden of

scarcity in the sabbatical year.They had to rely on a miracle to take advantage of it during years

one through six.They announced their dependence on God and their faith in God by

not laying up food for six years.But to fail to honor the sabbath year and the jubilee by planting and

harvesting would have constituted rebellion.Jesus fulfilled the jubilee year.This marked the end of the triple crop, as surely as crossing into

Canaan marked the end of the manna.Over time, God’s miracles steadily are removed.Christians are to rest their faith in the Bible, not miracles.The miracle of the Lord’s Supper must be taken on faith: not

transubstantiation or consubstantiation but rather co-participation inheavenly worship.

Miracles of feeding were to persuade Israel of God’s sovereigntyover nature.

Page 148: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Food Miracles and Covenantal Predictability

1087

They were given to remind Israel of God’s predictability in history.This was to keep Israel from both kinds of idols: idols of nature and

idols of history.Modern man denies the miracle of covenantal predictability.Modern man chooses to believe in the twin idol of nature and his-

tory: evolution.Modern Christians deny God’s sovereignty (predestination) and His

covenantal predictability (historical sanctions).They deny covenant theology.The church is no longer able to be distinguished from any other

charitable organization. This keeps them from developing a uniquely Christian social theory.

Page 149: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1. Had the first three or four people who looked inside the Ark immediately been strickenwith leprosy, as Miriam was stricken in the wilderness (Num. 12:10), the infraction wouldhave ceased.

1088

28

THE RIGHT OF REDEMPTION

The land shall not be sold for ever: for the land is mine; for ye arestrangers and sojourners with me. And in all the land of your pos-session ye shall grant a redemption for the land (Lev. 25:23–24).

We begin with a theocentric analysis of this passage. The prohibi-tion against the permanent sale of rural land was connected to thenation’s judicial status as strangers and sojourners with God. What didthis mean? God began to dwell in the land of Israel when the conquestbegan, i.e., after the nation had crossed Canaan’s border. This meansthat He lived among them judicially. He did not take up residencewith them physically. His unique judicial presence in the land wasmarked physically by the presence of the two tablets of the law insidethe Ark of the Covenant. Even this testimony had to be taken on faith;no one was allowed to look inside the Ark. When this law wasviolated by the men of Bethshemesh, God killed 50,070 of them (ISam. 6:19). Negative corporate sanctions came immediately after Godallowed the corporate infraction to take place.1

Covenantal Inheritance

This law identified the Israelites as strangers and sojourners withGod. The meaning here is “strangers from the world in the land.” Thiswas in contrast to strangers and sojourners who might come into theland. These would become strangers and sojourners in the land, but

Page 150: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

2. None of this is visible in W. Brueggemann’s book, The Land (London: SPCK, 1978).He writes the following: “But Israel’s Torah is markedly uninterested in a religion ofobedience as such. It is rather interested in care for land. . .” (p. 60). Thus, he interpretsthe Mosaic law’s universally acknowledged concern for ethics as a concern for ecology.You would be hard-pressed to find any interpretation of the Pentateuch more bizarre andmisleading than this one. Then he quotes Joshua 1:7–8, God’s command to be strong andcourageous in the conquest of the land. Concludes Brueggemann: “The rhetoric is peculiarbecause it is an imperative to martial bravery and courage. But what is asked is not courageto destroy enemies, but courage to keep Torah” (p. 60). It is not the Bible’s rhetoric thatis peculiar. What is peculiar is Prof. Brueggemann’s hermeneutic.

1089

without God, i.e., not members of an Israelite family. To be a stranger and sojourner with God under the Mosaic Coven-

ant had a specific judicial meaning: one’s heirs would inherit a portionof a particular plot of land in Israel. To inherit, a person had to be amember of an Israelite family that had participated in the conquest.The Israelites’ righteous shedding of the blood of that generation ofCanaanites had been a covenant sign for Israel. No one who was notbiologically or judicially (through adoption) an heir to one of thosefamilies that had participated in that original ritual sacrifice could ownrural land on a permanent basis in Israel until the law was changed byGod after the exile (Ezek. 47:21–23).

The special judicial presence of God among them had beenmanifested historically to Israel by the genocide of the Canaanites.God had used His people – a royal priesthood (Ex. 19:6) – to bringnegative historical sanctions against His enemies. They had served ina holy army. They had inherited the land of God’s enemies. This wasinheritance through corporate execution. Their landed inheritancebegan with their obedience in committing genocide.2 It ended withtheir national disinheritance at the fall of Jerusalem in A.D. 70.

To be a covenantal stranger with God meant that you possessedpermanent legal title to a plot of land. This land could not be perm-anently alienated. Title could not be legally transferred to anotherfamily by a leaseholder in any generation. God held original title;

Page 151: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

3. Gary North, Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Deuteronomy,electronic edition (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1999), ch. 22.

4. David Chilton, The Days of Vengeance: An Exposition of the Book of Revelation (Ft.Worth, Texas: Dominion Press, 1987).

1090

families held secondary title. This was a guarantee to Israel: for aslong as the nation remained obedient to God, its original familieswould not be disinherited. There was only one way for corporatedisinheritance to take place: God’s public execution of the nation ofIsrael. “And it shall be, if thou do at all forget the LORD thy God,and walk after other gods, and serve them, and worship them, I testifyagainst you this day that ye shall surely perish. As the nations whichthe LORD destroyeth before your face, so shall ye perish; because yewould not be obedient unto the voice of the LORD your God” (Deut.8:19–20).3 This took place at the fall of Jerusalem in A.D. 70.4 Theinheritance was transferred to another corporate people, just as Jesushad promised: “Therefore say I unto you, The kingdom of God shallbe taken from you, and given to a nation bringing forth the fruitsthereof” (Matt. 21:43). This was God’s act of covenantal execution,not literal execution.

Redemption on Demand

Why would an Israelite have voluntarily leased out his land? Theobvious reason was that the owner believed that he had better uses forthe money than for the land. Perhaps he preferred to live in a city.Perhaps he was involved in commerce and wanted capital. Perhaps hewas involved in some infraction that required an immediate paymentto a victim.

An involuntary lease was used to raise money to pay off debts:

Page 152: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

1091

victims of crimes or lenders in some business transaction in which theland had been used as collateral. The repayment of interest-freecharitable loans was not governed by the jubilee law but by the morefrequent sabbatical year law (Deut. 15:1–10). Charitable debts werecancelled every seventh year. But charitable loans were not collater-alized by land; they were collateralized by the debtor’s willingness togo into bondage for up to six years, should he default.

The existence of an interest payment in a loan agreement identifiedthe loan as non-charitable, non-compulsory, and therefore more riskyfor the debtor, for the sabbatical year of release (Deut. 15:7–10) didnot apply to business loans. The man who began as a poor man whenhe borrowed money in an emergency did not put his land on the line,assuming that he still owned any land. In contrast, the man whobecame a poor man after going into debt in order to finance a businessventure or a consumer purchase did have to forfeit his land if his landwas the collateral he had agreed to provide the lender.

The jubilee law specified that in such instances, the collateral couldbe redeemed at any time. The lender who had repossessed thecollateral of the family’s inheritance was permitted to use it as aproductive asset until one of two things took place: (1) the jubileeyear began; (2) the poor man or his kinsman-redeemer paid back theprincipal.

If thy brother be waxen poor, and hath sold away some of hispossession, and if any of his kin come to redeem it, then shall heredeem that which his brother sold. And if the man have none toredeem it, and himself be able to redeem it; Then let him count theyears of the sale thereof, and restore the overplus unto the man towhom he sold it; that he may return unto his possession. But if he benot able to restore it to him, then that which is sold shall remain in thehand of him that hath bought it until the year of jubile: and in the jubileit shall go out, and he shall return unto his possession (Lev. 25:25–28).

Page 153: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

1092

The Kinsman-Redeemer

The person who is identified in Leviticus 25 as the person with theauthority to buy back a poor man’s land is the kinsman (Lev. 25:25–26). The same root word in Hebrew is used for the verb for purchas-ing: “And if it be not redeemed within the space of a full year, thenthe house that is in the walled city shall be established for ever to himthat bought it throughout his generations: it shall not go out in thejubile” (Lev. 25:30). “And if a man purchase of the Levites, then thehouse that was sold, and the city of his possession, shall go out in theyear of jubile: for the houses of the cities of the Levites are theirpossession among the children of Israel” (Lev. 25:33).

The office of kinsman-redeemer was based on a messianic model:“Yea, all kings shall fall down before him: all nations shall serve him.For he shall deliver the needy when he crieth; the poor also, and himthat hath no helper. He shall spare the poor and needy, and shall savethe souls of the needy. He shall redeem their soul from deceit andviolence: and precious shall their blood be in his sight” (Ps. 72:11–14). The kinsman-redeemer was the same office as the blood-avenger,the go’el (sometimes transliterated as ga’awl). “But if the man haveno kinsman [go’el] to recompense the trespass unto, let the trespassbe recompensed unto the LORD, even to the priest; beside the ram ofthe atonement, whereby an atonement shall be made for him” (Num.5:8). “The revenger of blood [go’el] himself shall slay the murderer:when he meeteth him, he shall slay him” (Num. 35:19). God identifiedHimself as Israel’s kinsman-redeemer: “Wherefore say unto thechildren of Israel, I am the LORD, and I will bring you out from underthe burdens of the Egyptians, and I will rid you out of their bondage,

Page 154: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

1093

and I will redeem [go’el] you with a stretched out arm, and with greatjudgments” (Ex. 6:6).

The blood avenger was the nearest of kin. It was he who had theresponsibility of pursuing and then slaying anyone suspected of havingmurdered his kinsman. The cities of refuge were built in order toprovide a place for suspected murderers to flee. The city of refugewas a legal boundary into which the authority of a blood avenger fromoutside the city did not extend. “And they shall be unto you cities forrefuge from the avenger; that the manslayer die not, until he standbefore the congregation in judgment” (Num. 35:12). Outside theboundaries of a city of refuge, “The revenger of blood himself shallslay the murderer: when he meeteth him, he shall slay him” (Num.35:19). After a trial in the city, a man convicted of murder (asdistinguished from accidental manslaughter) was placed outside thecity, to be executed by the blood avenger (Num. 35:25). A manconvicted of accidental manslaughter could lawfully be killed by theblood-avenger at any time outside the city of refuge, until the highpriest died. Here the language of release is the same as the languageof the jubilee year: returning to the family’s land: “Because he shouldhave remained in the city of his refuge until the death of the highpriest: but after the death of the high priest the slayer shall return intothe land of his possession” (Num. 35:28).

In the captivity of Israel, God acted as their kinsman: “Go ye forthof Babylon, flee ye from the Chaldeans, with a voice of singing declareye, tell this, utter it even to the end of the earth; say ye, The LORDhath redeemed his servant Jacob” (Isa. 48:20). In doing so, God actedas blood-avenger: “And I will feed them that oppress thee with theirown flesh; and they shall be drunken with their own blood, as withsweet wine: and all flesh shall know that I the LORD am thy Saviourand thy Redeemer, the mighty One of Jacob” (Isa. 49:26).

Page 155: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

5. David Daube, The New Testament and Rabbinic Judaism (1956), p. 272, cited inDonald A. Leggett, The Levirate and Goel Institutions in the Old Testament: With SpecialAttention to Ruth (Cherry Hill, New Jersey: Mack, 1974), p. 93.

1094

Why Redeem Another Man’s Land or Person?

The kinsman-redeemer was the agent authorized by God to buyback the property of a close relative. The question is: What was thebenefit for him? Why would any relative do this? It would have beena major capital outlay unless the jubilee was near. David Daube hasoffered a plausible explanation: the kinsman-redeemer bought the useof the land for himself until the jubilee year or until his relative couldpurchase the land from him, whichever came first. In other words, thekinsman-redeemer became the new master of the property.5

It was also a benefit to the original owner when his kinsman-redeemer leased back the property. First, the land would probably betaken care of more carefully by a relative, i.e., there would be less“strip mining” of its productivity. Second, the kinsman-redeemermight be willing to allow him to work the land as a sharecropper. Theoriginal owner would come under the authority of a relative ratherthan a stranger. The relative might treat him better; he, in turn, wouldhave family pressures on him to perform more efficiently as a care-taker. These are economic arguments. Third, the land would remainin the family – an important aspect of family authority in Israel. Thisis a social factor rather than economic: a matter of status. It was anembarrassment for a family to have an insolvent member in its midst.This was a way for the family to demonstrate its willingness to “carefor its own.”

The text does not indicate that the land had to be returned immed-iately to the original owner. The economics of the case does indicatethat without the kinsman-redeemer’s right to use the land for his ownbenefit until either the jubilee or the land’s redemption by the relative,

Page 156: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

6. Gary North, Dominion and Common Grace: The Biblical Basis of Progress (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1987), ch. 5.

1095

there would have been little likelihood that this law would have beenhonored in practice.

The same principle of transferred authority applied also to theredemption of an Israelite brother from servitude in the household ofa resident alien. “And if a sojourner or stranger wax rich by thee, andthy brother that dwelleth by him wax poor, and sell himself unto thestranger or sojourner by thee, or to the stock of the stranger’s family:After that he is sold he may be redeemed again; one of his brethrenmay redeem him” (Lev. 25:47–48). Better to be a servant in thehousehold of a relative than in the household of a foreigner. Better tobe under the temporary authority of a covenant-keeper with sufficientmoney to redeem you than under the authority of a covenant-breaker.But the poverty-stricken man had still fallen into poverty. He was stillstricken. The best way to return him to full productivity was to trainhim in the ways of productivity. The necessary hierarchy of master andservant was not broken by this form of redemption. The poor man stillhad to learn the techniques of serving the consumer. He needed anintermediary to teach him these techniques: his more prosperouskinsman-redeemer.

When God redeems us, He does not turn us loose to do whateverwe want; He becomes our new master. The standard antinomianrefrain – “We’re under grace, not law” – is incorrect. Men in historyare always under both grace and law. The question is: Which kind ofgrace and which kind of law? Every society has laws and sanctions.Non-biblical laws and sanctions are an aspect of common grace; bibli-cal laws and sanctions are an aspect of special grace.6 Without grace,there would be social chaos: hell’s down payment (“earnest”) inhistory. If there were no predictable covenantal sanctions in history for

Page 157: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

7. Remove God from theology, and death points to another principle of ownership: theland owns man. The land stays; men depart. Man becomes a steward for the land, not ofthe land. This is the view of the radical ecological activist groups.

1096

obedience and disobedience, there could be no social predictability.We would then live in moral and social chaos. The greater the chaos,the less social order.

Man’s autonomy is never a valid theoretical option. God remainsthe original owner of us and our property. This fact receives confirma-tion every time someone dies. The old question – “How much did heleave behind?” – is always answered: “All of it.” Men are inescapablystewards of God’s property.7 The question is: Who should teach usthe principles and practices of responsible stewardship? The jubileelaw made this plain: the kinsman-redeemer, the Israelite family’s agentof redemption and judgment. Only when the jubilee land laws endedwith the establishment of a New Covenant did this system of familyredemption and training end.

Walled Cities

The law of redemption applied inside the walled cities of Israel ina different way: the seller or his kinsman had only one year to redeema home (dwelling place). Once this year had passed, the buyer becamea permanent owner. “And if a man sell a dwelling house in a walledcity, then he may redeem it within a whole year after it is sold; withina full year may he redeem it. And if it be not redeemed within thespace of a full year, then the house that is in the walled city shall beestablished for ever to him that bought it throughout his generations:it shall not go out in the jubile” (Lev. 25:29–30). Notice: this lawapplied only to homes. It did not apply to other kinds of urban realestate. Only a residence was protected by the year of grace. Title to

Page 158: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

8. Rabbinical opinion was that only the walled cities in the era of Joshua’s conquest wereexempted from the jubilee rural land law. Arakhin 9:6; The Mishnah, trans., Herbert Danby(New York: Oxford University Press, [1933] 1987), p. 553.

1097

other real estate passed at the time of sale. Title to urban real estatewas alienable: for sale to aliens.

Outside the boundary of the wall, the Israelite’s right of redemptionwas universal, bounded by a 50-year limit. “But the houses of thevillages which have no wall round about them shall be counted as thefields of the country: they may be redeemed, and they shall go out inthe jubile” (v. 31).

Was it legal for subsequent generations to build walls aroundunwalled cities? Yes. Would this new wall have changed the legalstatus of the heirs of the original families? No. An unwalled city ofJoshua’s day, with the exception of the cities of the Levites, cameunder the jubilee’s rural land law. The inheritance left by the originalgeneration could never be alienated by contract.8 The inheritancecould only be alienated by God, through corporate covenantal exe-cution. So, a wall could be built for the sake of military defense, butthis would not have changed the legal status of the heirs of the originalfamilies. No alteration of the inheritance of the original families wasallowed; the defensive wall was not a judicial wall.

Citizenship could not be revoked for any reason other than excom-munication. This means that the priests, through their delegatedauthority to the Levites, could alone revoke citizenship. This is themark of a biblical civil order. The civil order does not autonomouslyestablish or enforce the criteria of citizenship. Citizenship is creedal,and the church enforces the content of the creed. A biblical civil ordercannot become autonomous; biblical political theory reflects this fact.

Any Israelite family would have had the right to participate in thedistribution of rural land. This would have been that family’s perm-anent inheritance. Who would have chosen to live in a walled city in

Page 159: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

9. The Bible does not say whether convicted criminals were part of the jubilee land law’sprimary benefit: a judicial return to the family’s land, i.e., liberation from bondage. Thiswould have meant freedom for all criminals in the jubilee year. This, in turn, would havecreated a subsidy to crime as the jubilee year approached: a conviction would not have ledto a high price for his sale into bondage, since the time of potential servitude was steadilyshrinking. The victims would have been short-changed. Because God defends the victim,it seems safe to conclude that there were two exceptions to the jubilee law of liberation: theapostate who had forfeited his inheritance and the criminal who was still under therequirement to pay off his victims or the person who bought him, with the purchase pricegoing to the victims. This conclusion follows from two general principles of biblical law:(1) God does not subsidize evil; (2) victim’s rights. If this is correct, then the criminal whowas released from bondage would have had to wait until the next jubilee year to reclaimhis land.

1098

the era of the conquest? Urban residents would then have been madeup of the following: (1) land-owning Israelites who became absenteelandlords; (2) permanent resident aliens who had been adopted intothe tribe of a city; (3) permanent resident aliens who had not beenadopted by an Israelite family or tribe; (4) traders who would residethere relatively briefly; (5) Levites who were not residents of aLevitical city; (6) soldiers or other officials from the central gov-ernment; (7) Israelites who had been excommunicated (i.e., circum-cised strangers: nok-ree); 8) convicted Israelite criminals who hadbeen sold into servitude to someone in a walled city.9

One Year’s Grace

The period of redemption was limited to one year. Why? Again,nothing explicit is said about this. We have to deduce reasons fromour knowledge of the Bible and our knowledge of men’s motivations.

The idea of a period of grace applied only to the seller of the house.The seller’s interests were defended by this law. The buyer remaineduncertain for a year. He did not know if he could remain in his newhouse; it could be redeemed at any time. Perhaps he left his previous

Page 160: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

10. The concept of need, beyond mere physical survival, should never be discussed apartfrom the question of price.

1099

house empty, forfeiting rental income. Perhaps he subleased it tosomeone for a year. If the buyer of the new house was evicted beforethe sublease on his original residence had expired, he had to findtemporary living quarters under difficult circumstances: rapid eviction.Such a threat of eviction would have raised the price of a move in pre-exilic Mosaic Israel. The more numerous the buyer’s possessions, themore expensive the move. In the words of a modern proverb: “Twomoves equal one fire.” Each transfer of ownership of a house in awalled city would have tended to go to a richer person than the onewho was selling it. Why? Because wealthy people could more easilyhave borne the risks of eviction. The existing owner probably had agreater “need to sell” than the buyer had a “need to buy.”10

Why would anyone have sold? A business setback is one obviousreason, especially if the business involved debt. The Bible teaches thatthe debtor is servant to the lender: “The rich ruleth over the poor, andthe borrower is servant to the lender” (Prov. 22:7). The Biblediscourages servitude, which is why the jubilee law existed: God’sredemption of His servants as their kinsman-redeemer – the owner ofall the land – by mandating their right to return to their ancestral plots.

In walled cities, however, this redemption process did not exist,except for the one-year grace period. In the case of loans collateral-ized by homes, there were greater incentives to lend in walled citiesthan in rural areas, and greater risks for borrowing. A person whotook a loan secured by the collateral of his rural inheritance knew thatthe closer the year of jubilee came, the less money he could expect toborrow against his collateral. The lender would lose whatever netincome the land might produce in the year beyond the jubilee. Hewould be allowed to keep all of the triple crop in the sixth year, but in

Page 161: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

11. The rate of interest in walled cities would have tended to be lower than elsewhere inIsrael: better collateral, with more rich people seeking to lend money.

1100

the seventh he could not farm it. In the eighth year, he lost it. Incontrast, an urban dweller knew that if he went bankrupt, he wouldhave only one year to raise enough cash to redeem his house. Afterthat, it was lost forever unless he could persuade the buyer to sell itback – unlikely at the price he had been paid: the value of the loan.Thus, his risk was comparatively much greater that he would lose hisurban inheritance than his rural.

In walled cities, the Israelites would experience the continualtemptations of debt: rich resident aliens enthusiastic to lend money,hoping that the debtor would default. This would be a comparativelyeasy way to buy up property in urban Israel. If the loan was repaid,the lender received his normal urban rate of return.11 If the loan wasnot repaid, he received a revocable lease on the house plus thepossibility of permanent possession one year after the original ownertransferred title. This would have been the preferred way for wealthyaliens to give their heirs a permanent stake in Israelite society.

Any Israelite who borrowed significant sums on these terms wouldhave been either a “high roller” – a person willing to bear a lot of risk– or a very present-oriented consumer, like the prodigal son in Jesus’parable. A very confident entrepreneur might think he had a uniqueopportunity, probably connected to an invention or trade. He might bewilling to risk his inheritance for the capital to develop it. But a lessrisk-oriented person would have preferred invested capital – selling ashare of ownership – to debt financing.

This limit of one year on the right to redeem an urban house wouldhave channeled urban investment into higher-risk debt ventures ormoderate-risk joint ventures. A resident alien (or anyone else) whowas looking for a permanent home to buy in Israel would have soughtout (advertised for) Israelites who were willing to accept debt finan-

Page 162: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

12. Though not interest-free: see above. There is no escape from the phenomenon ofinterest: a discount of future goods as against those same goods in the present.

1101

cing for high-risk projects that other investors had already shunned.The lender’s offer would have amounted to this: “Win, and I win withyou; lose, and you’re out in the cold. I won’t be.”

The text does not speak of a deferred payment, i.e., a mortgagebeyond one year. The right of redemption was one year. There is noindication that this meant anything except one year from the time thatthe transfer of ownership took place. Ownership is a judicial concept:the identification of the legally responsible agent. The owner has theright to disown the property.

Could there have been home mortgages under such a legal system?Yes, but the original owner had only one year to reclaim his propertyunless the buyer subsequently defaulted on his payments. He wouldhave had to repay to the new buyer whatever the new buyer had paidhim during the interim. The purchaser had to forfeit the use of the itemor money that he used to buy the house. This is what the seller owedhim if the former wanted to reclaim the house.

A Stake in Society

No explicit reason is provided in the Bible to explain this judicialdifference: wall vs. no wall. The judicial boundary established by thecity’s wall provided an exemption from the jubilee land law after 12months.12 Inheritance there was based on secondary purchase ratherthan original conquest. It was based on economics rather thanecclesiastical confession. This made possible a place for resident aliensor post-conquest converts to the faith to gain what is sometimes calleda stake in society. A stake is a marker that establishes the edge of a

Page 163: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

13. Chapter 30, under the heading, “Holy War, Citizenship, and Liberty.”

14. Deborah, a prophetess, also served as a judge (Jud. 4:4). She served functionally asa holy warrior: senior in command (Jud. 4:8). As the sanctions-bringer against Sisera, Jaelalso served as a holy warrior (v. 22). Neither was circumcised, but both were under legalauthority of circumcised males: husbands.

1102

boundary in land, but it is used here more broadly: a permanentresidence or a permanent possession of value that is tied to a specificplace. A stake in society is therefore a legal claim, something that atsome price is worth defending, either in a court or on a battlefield.

Would resident aliens have been required to fight to defend thecity? Not unless they were citizens. They did not possess membershipin an Israelite family. The military numbering process would not havetouched them (Ex. 30). Presumably they could volunteer, but only ifthey professed the required national confession of faith, the shamawIsrael: “Hear, O Israel: The LORD our God is one LORD” (Deut. 6:4). There were many instances of foreign soldiers in Israel’s holyarmy, Uriah the Hittite being the most famous. Citizenship was prob-ably a reward granted to circumcised resident aliens who volunteeredfor military service. If you could be legally numbered, you were acitizen; conversely, if you could not legally be numbered, you werenot a citizen.13

Was confession, circumcision, and eligibility for service in theLord’s army sufficient to establish an inheritable claim of citizenship?Yes. Was this citizenship inalienable? Yes. Citizenship was covenantal.Covenantal inheritance was by confession, circumcision, and eligibilityto bring sanctions: as a holy warrior and therefore as a judge.14 Oncea citizen of Israel, a person could not become a permanentbondservant under Mosaic law.

Page 164: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

15. Gary North, Treasure and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Luke, 2ndelectronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc., [2000]2003), ch. 6.

1103

Post-Exilic Israel

This raises an extremely important point: the alteration of landownership after the exile. Ezekiel prophesied that after Israel’s returnfrom exile, strangers in the land would participate in a second divisionof the land by lot. These strangers would gain permanent possessionin the land. Strangers who resided within the jurisdiction of aparticular tribe at the time of the reclaiming of the land by that tribewould become part of a new land allocation (Ezek. 47:21–23). Theycould not be disinherited. But if that was true, then they could not beenslaved.

There is no indication that the jubilee’s heathen-slave law wasannulled after the exile. Jesus announced His ministry in terms ofjubilee liberation (Luke 4:18–21).15 This assertion rested on the con-tinuing authority of the jubilee slave law. That aspect of the jubileewas related to family inheritance, not the original distribution of landunder Joshua. But a new land allocation would free participatingheathen families from any threat of inter-generational bondage. Thosewho resided in the land at the time of the return could not lawfully beenslaved.

This was the source of the lawful continuing presence of Samar-itans in the land. These foreigners had been brought into the NorthernKingdom by the Assyrians to replace the captive Israelites. Thereturning Israelites were not authorized to kill or exile these people.There would never again be a lawful program of genocide to establishoriginal title in Israel. Rather, the resident alien at the return would re-ceive an inheritable grant of rural land. The worship of Canaanite godsand religion never reappeared. The gods of Canaan had been gods of

Page 165: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

16. The one city that refused to submit to the Jews was Pella. W. H. C. Frend, The Riseof Christianity (Philadelphia: Fortress, 1984), p. 19. It was to Pella, located beyond theJordan, that the Jerusalem church supposedly fled just before the siege of the city by Romein A.D. 69. Eusebius, Ecclesiastical History, III:V.

1104

the land, meaning gods of the city-state. Those gods were no longerrelevant in a nation under the authority of Medo-Persia, then Hellen-ism, and finally Rome. In contrast, Persian dualism, Hellenism, andTalmudism were not bound by geography. These became the mainthreats to biblical orthodoxy.

The returning Israelites took centuries to reconquer the land. Thereconquest was never completed, nor was Mosaic civil authority everre-established. The tribes did not re-establish their original borders,nor were they ever again free from foreign civil rule. But the Jews didcome close to re-establishing their pre-exilic political power andnational boundaries in the decades prior to Rome’s invasion, which lednon-Jewish inhabitants of Palestine to welcome the Romans.16

Because the physical boundaries of the Promised Land had beenbreached during the exile, never to be healed, and because the pre-exilic judicial boundaries were never again established, the originalland distribution of the era of the conquest lost its judicial relevance.Israelite citizenship therefore lost most of its judicial relevance exceptduring periods of civil revolt. Confession, circumcision, and adoptionremained the basis of this much-reduced citizenship. God’s holy armyhad ceased to exist.

Urban Citizenship

Ammonites and Moabites could become members of the congre-gation after 10 generations (Deut. 23:3). This was citizenship, for thesame 10-generation limit applied also to Israelite bastards (Deut. 23:

Page 166: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

17. Rushdoony argues that it was an Israelite who became a eunuch. R. J. Rushdoony,The Institutes of Biblical Law (Nutley, New Jersey: Craig Press, 1973), p. 84.

1105

2). The question is: Where would these new citizens have exercisedtheir judicial powers? I think it must have been inside walled cities.The cities were tribal affairs. They had been parcelled out to the tribesunder Joshua (Josh. 13:23–32; 15). Citizenship in a city must havebeen tribal. But judges in cities probably resided in those cities. Localurban residents possessed knowledge of local affairs.

The question is: Was real estate ownership required to be an urbancitizen? Did an urban resident lose his citizenship if he lost ownershipof his home? That could happen in one year. Was the threat of disen-franchisement hanging over the head of every urban real estate ownerwho did not have an inheritance in rural Israel? The Bible does notsay. Any answer is speculative. But since lawful participation in holywarfare seems to be the best way to define the mark of citizenship, myconclusion is that aliens could become eligible for citizenship asadopted members of the tribes governing walled cities. Citizenship didnot require the ownership of a home in a walled city. Urban citi-zenship was by confession, circumcision, and eligibility for holy war.It was not based on landed inheritance.

For an alien to become a citizen in Israel meant that he became afree man. Israelites were not allowed to own Israelite slaves asinheritable property (Lev. 25:46b). By becoming a citizen, the alienpermanently established his legal claim as an Israelite.

This raises the question of access to citizenship. Deuteronomy 23is the main section dealing with this. The context is that of an outsiderwanting in. Deuteronomy 23:1 lists the eunuch. I think this refers toa foreign eunuch, not an Israelite.17 If an Israelite warrior, for exam-ple, received such an injury, was he expelled from the congregation?Did he cease to be an Israelite? Did he become a heathen subject to

Page 167: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

18. The adoption of the Ethiopian eunuch – a foreigner – into the New Covenant church(Acts 8:26–40) is indicative of the law of adoption.

19. He may not have been adopted into a family. This took place prior to the conquest ofCanaan, so the issue of family adoption and landed inheritance was not yet relevant.

1106

permanent bondage? This does not seem reasonable. The passagerefers to outsiders wanting in, including bastards, i.e., outsiders to thecovenantal family. The context is not of an insider who is being forcedout. In any case, adoption into an Israelite family could alwaysovercome this restriction.18 Caleb, the son of a Kenizite (Num. 32:12), was surely a citizen. He must have been adopted into the tribe ofJudah (Num. 13:6), the tribe of Jacob’s messianic promise (Gen. 49:10).19

Circumcised resident aliens were not citizens unless they wereeligible to serve in God’s holy army: adoption into the tribe underwhose authority they fought. They did not otherwise possess the legalright to impose judicial sanctions as judges in Israel. Only citizenspossessed this right. In other words, resident aliens could neverbecome citizens except by adoption: the implicit or explicit acceptanceof military service. Urban adoption was tribal, not familistic.

Uriah was called a Hittite. This may have meant that he was not athird-generation circumcised resident, and therefore not normallyeligible for citizenship. But he was a warrior in God’s holy army. Thisindicates that the resident alien could become a citizen through mili-tary service in the defense of Israel during wartime, even if he was nota third or tenth generation circumcised resident. If a circumcised alienwas willing to risk dying for God in defense of Israel’s boundaries,and if his offer to serve was accepted by the military, this made him acitizen: a man with the right to the office of judge – a sanctions-bringer.

Page 168: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

1107

The Sociology of Home Ownership

Poor people rent; rich people own; middle-class people pay offmortgages. Economic freedom produces incentives for owners tobuild housing for poorer people to rent. Poor people rent new quarterswhen they grow richer. People move to better quarters when theygrow richer. Only the richest sons of the richest families stay put,decade after decade. They move from their palatial summer homes totheir palatial winter homes. They are mobile; ownership is not. Perm-anent landed estates are an important mark of “old money.” Thedispersal of landed estates in Europe in the twentieth century throughthe drastic taxation of large inheritances was an aspect of classwarfare: the middle classes, in the name of the poorer classes, votedaway the wealth of the landed classes, whose heirs could no longerafford to inherit.

In walled cities, the kinds of people who would have wound up asowners of urban housing would have been the same kinds of peoplewho own urban property today. Richer people would have beendominant home owners. That is, those who were the most productivepeople in the economy would have been most likely to buy a homeand retain a stake in society. This property right, irrespective of afamily’s creed or ritual, to buy and inherit housing in Mosaic Israel’swalled cities was an important way for Israel to attract and keep veryproductive people from abroad. It would have made Israel’s walledcities centers of entrepreneurship and trade. Innovative, creative bus-inessmen from the Mediterranian region would have immigrated.

Turnover of ownership would initially have been much more rapidin walled cities than in rural settings or in unwalled cities. Nineteenth-century American capitalism’s story of “poor man to rich man to poorman” in three generations would have been much more common inIsrael’s walled cities than outside them, at least until population

Page 169: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

20. Tocqueville commented on the United States in the 1830's: “But wealth circulatesthere with incredible rapidity, and experience shows that two successive generationsseldom enjoy its favors.” Alexis de Tocqueville, Democracy in America, edited by J. P.Mayer (Garden City, New York: Doubleday, [1835] 1966), I:3, p. 54.

1108

growth shrank the size of the average farm.20

The walled cities of the Canaanite era became the walled cities ofIsrael. Which cities would have been the walled cities of Canaan?First, cities that housed cultures with military aspirations: city-stateempires. Second, cities with wealth to protect from invasion: tradecenters. Third, cities with unique religious icons or practices thatserved the needs of a particular region: religious centers. Walled citieswould have tended to be cities on the crossroads of trade. Theirarchitecture, water systems, and similar “infrastructure” would havebeen suited to trading centers. Thus, their character as crossroad citieswould not have been radically altered by Israelite civilization. Thismeans that walled cities would have become cosmopolitan: world(cosmos) cities (polis = city). This raises the question of citizenship.It also raises the question of pluralism.

Pluralism: Cultural, Not Judicial

The walled city would have been the preferred place of residencefor wealthy aliens and wealthy covenant converts who were not heirsof the generation of the conquest. These cities would have been thecenters of cosmopolitan life, where ideas and customs from outsidethe land would have intermingled. This means that the ideas andcustoms of a particular foreign god would always have had compe-tition from people who had faith in other gods. This would havecreated a true cultural pluralism within the legal framework of abiblically covenanted community. The walled cities would have been

Page 170: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

21. Gary North, Political Polytheism: The Myth of Pluralism (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1989), Part 3.

1109

testing areas – social laboratories – for many ideas and practices, butalways within the judicial boundary of God’s law.

These testing areas were sealed off judicially from the land outsidetheir walls. This seal was not absolute. Resident aliens could leaseagricultural property outside the walls, but they had no assurance ofbeing able to renew these leases, nor could they pass on legal accessto rural land to heirs. The jubilee was designed to cut short anyattempt by foreigners to colonize the land of Israel. Even urbancolonization would have been restricted to ideas and customs thatwere not in violation of the laws of God. Urban aliens were not citi-zens. They could not serve as judges.

Not being citizens, resident aliens could not impose judicialsanctions in Mosaic Israel. They could not lawfully seek converts totheir imported religions. Only the non-confessional expressions ofthese imported religious worldviews were legal in the public square.This is why cultural pluralism is not the same as judicial pluralism.Cultural pluralism within a holy commonwealth is stripped of theolo-gical confession and judicial sanctions.

The modern humanist world has made politics formally aspluralistic as culture is. This has created a situation in which politicshas become polytheistic.21 Beginning at the outbreak of World War Iin 1914, Western nations have imposed immigration barriers in orderto keep out foreigners, for fear of losing both culture and politics tohordes of aliens. The expansion of the welfare State has made suchrestrictions even more important: keeping aliens away from the publictreasuries. But “alien” is not defined covenantally; it is definedculturally. National boundaries become walls barring too great adisruption of the established culture, however pluralistic it may already

Page 171: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

22. Priests occasionally could. See chapter 37.

1110

be. Barbed wire has replaced theological confession as the preferredmeans of discouraging immigrants.

In Mosaic Israel, foreign culture was bounded by urban walls,physiological walls (circumcision), and confessional walls. When theMosaic law was enforced, immigrants from foreign cultures (plural)could not become threats to Israel. God’s word alone had judicialauthority, so imported cultures had to conform to the covenant. Theethical and judicial terms of the covenant became filtering devices forsifting through the wheat and the chaff in every cultural import. Therewas no need for immigration barriers. There is no evidence that suchbarriers ever existed. Mosaic law does not authorize them, preciselybecause it does not authorize political pluralism.

Lest we forget: the ultimate immigration barrier is abortion.

The Levites’ Cities

There was one additional aspect of the jubilee land law: Leviticalcities. There were 48 of these cities, six of which were cities of refuge(Num. 35:6–7). “Notwithstanding the cities of the Levites, and thehouses of the cities of their possession, may the Levites redeem at anytime. And if a man purchase of the Levites, then the house that wassold, and the city of his possession, shall go out in the year of jubile:for the houses of the cities of the Levites are their possession amongthe children of Israel. But the field of the suburbs of their cities maynot be sold; for it is their perpetual possession” (Lev. 25:32–34).

The Levites were therefore likely to be urban dwellers at any pointin Israel’s history. They could not become owners of rural land, whichwas the inheritance of other tribes.22 Their presence in a region would

Page 172: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

23. Julian Simon, The Ultimate Resource (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton UniversityPress, 1981); Warren T. Brookes, The Economy in Mind (New York: Universe, 1982); E.Calvin Beisner, Prospects for Growth: A Biblical View of Population, Resources, and theFuture (Westchester, Illinois: Crossway, 1990).

1111

have been concentrated in a local tribal city. At the same time, theywere dispersed as a tribe throughout the land, just as their cities were.This kept all of the tribes in close proximity to specialists incovenantal law and ritual. This also kept the nation free from priestlyattempts to centralize rural land ownership, except in periods in whichthe jubilee inheritance laws were not enforced. Even in such rebelliousperiods, there was always the possibility that some subsequentgeneration would enforce the law. Anti-jubilee legal title was alwaysat risk.

A Nation of City Dwellers

The Levites would have been urban residents. They advised ruralpeople, but they lived primarily in cities. Their “home base” wasurban. This fact should tell the commentators something, but none ofthem ever mentions it. Israel’s legal structure was designed to prod-uce an urban society. Covenant-keeping would bring rapid populationgrowth. In a growing economy, wealth is increasingly based on intel-lectual labor and creativity, not on raw materials.23 As agriculturebecomes more efficient, fewer people need to work the land, or canafford to. Thus, the structure of jubilee ownership led the Levites tolive in cities, which is where a growing percentage of the populationof covenant-keeping Israel was expected by God to dwell as timewent on – and outside the Promised Land, also in cities. The Leviteswould become the major urban real estate owners except in non-Levite walled cities. Most people would have to rent or lease housing

Page 173: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

1112

from them.Let us not mistake what this would have meant: the accumulation

of urban wealth by one tribe. Urban wealth would increasingly havebecome the dominant form of wealth in a growing economy, as it istoday. Unless Israel conquered new lands, Israelites had only fourplaces to go if they wanted to escape rural life: the original walledcities, unwalled cities, Levitical cities, and other nations. They couldnot permanently own homes in unwalled cities: a disadvantage. In theoriginal walled cities, the influence of the Levites as advisors wouldhave been strong. In Levitical cities, they would have been the pre-dominant home owners, renting space to poorer residents. Thus, thestructure of land ownership favored the Levites above all other tribesin times of righteousness. They were the most mobile tribe, the mosturban tribe, and the most educated tribe. They had the greatestnumber of personal contacts across the nation. They would steadilyhave become the dominant tribe and the wealthiest tribe in a covenan-tally faithful society.

Why did God subsidize the Levites in this way? One economicreason was the fact that the Levites had an incentive to make sure thatthe jubilee laws were enforced. They had the authority to excommuni-cate civil rulers who refused to enforce God’s civil law. Leviticalfamilies would receive back their homes in the same year that theother tribes’ families received back their lands. But did they do this?It seems more likely that they refused to pressure civil magistrates toenforce the jubilee. If they did refuse, there would have been a classof homeless Levites who had to rent housing in their own cities. Thiswould have led to class division within the priestly tribe. If the civilauthorities enforced the jubilee only in Levitical cities, there wouldhave been widespread resentment among the other tribes.

Page 174: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

1113

Conclusion

This law had to be temporary. The tribal structure was not designedto be permanent; its purpose would end after Shiloh (the Messiah) hadcome: a member of the tribe of Judah (Gen. 49:10). When theredeemer came, the right of redemption would end. The ideal of thecity of God would then replace the ideal of the land of God.

The structure of land ownership under the jubilee system wasclearly a wineskin destined to be broken, either through God’s bless-ing – urbanization and/or the conquest of new lands – or God’s curs-ing: conquest by other lands and dispersion. The inheritance of Josh-ua’s day would fade into insignificance: (1) through urbanization; (2)through the extension of the boundaries of Israel outward, beyond theoriginal land grant and the jubilee law; or (3) through emigration,either voluntary or forced. In any case, the importance of the right ofredemption would fade.

The right of redemption meant different things to different peoplein ancient Israel. For the rural land owner, it meant that he couldcollateralize a business loan or lease his property without the risk ofdisinheriting his children. An urban home could become the propertyof the lender if the borrower defaulted. It could become part of thelender’s permanent legacy to his children. Also, an urban house waslocated in a commercial center. The benefits of lending to the urbanreal estate owner were greater than lending to a rural family with theland as collateral. This meant that a rent-seeking lender might not lendhim so much, or at so low an interest rate, as he would lend the home-owning resident of a walled city.

The resident of a walled city lived in an economically active tradingcenter that was cosmopolitan. Resident aliens could buy permanentownership of homes in such cities. They could even become citizens.The influence of resident aliens in Israel was concentrated here, for

Page 175: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

1114

only here could they buy homes and pass them to their children. Thebuying and selling of homes would have concentrated home ownershipinto the hands of rich families irrespective of their religion. Therewould have been considerable turnover in ownership, with successfulmerchants buying or foreclosing on the homes of the less successful.It would have been difficult for any family residing in a walled city toretain ownership of a home through several generations. In otherwords, home ownership in a walled city in Israel was far more like themodern world than home ownership was elsewhere in Israel. As wehave seen, a growing Israelite population would have pushed thepopulation out of rural Israel and into walled cities or outside thenation.

For the Levite, the jubilee redemption law was limited to Leviticalcities. This would have tended to tie Levitical families to certain cities.A Levite could also buy a permanent home in a walled city, althoughhe had no competitive advantage over any other buyer. He had noinheritance in the land outside the cities. This structure of inheritancewould have made the Levite primarily an urban figure. If the economyand the population grew, the Levites would become the principalJewish home owners in Israel. But since God’s law is not designed tofavor one family over another, long-term, we can safely conclude thatthe jubilee inheritance laws were not designed to be permanent. Theywould end when the Kinsman-Redeemer finished His work. As itturned out, it was in His office of Blood-Avenger that He ended thejubilee laws: in A.D. 70.

Summary

God dwelt in Israel judicially.The Israelites dwelt with Him as strangers because they had partici-

Page 176: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

1115

pated in genocide: the shedding of Canaanite blood.Landed inheritance was based on the original corporate execution.Title to rural land could rarely be permanently transferred out of a

specific family, and then only to a priest.Disinheritance was by covenantal excommunication: either per-

sonally (by the priests) or corporately (by God).This corporate excommunication – covenantal execution – took

place in Israel in A.D. 70.A man would lease out his land because he (or his victim in a

crime) valued the cash more than the expected physical output of theland until the jubilee year.

Charitable loans were governed by the sabbatical year of release.A man could redeem his collateral at any time.The kinsman-redeemer (go’el) could redeem property for his rela-

tive.This was the same office as the blood-avenger.God acted as Israel’s go’el.It was a model of the messianic office.The go’el probably had a financial interest in buying back the land

of his relative: to gain control over the property.This was beneficial for the original owner: greater care of his land,

plus (possibly) a job as a sharecropper.The land would remain inside the family.The poor man, becoming a servant on his own land, would get

training to become more successful: hierarchy.Inside walled cities, the redemption law worked differently: one

year to redeem a home (residence).Urban dwellers were Israelite families, resident aliens, traders,

Levites, soldiers or central government officers, excommunicatedIsraelites, and convicted criminals who had temporarily lost their land.

No reason is offered for the one-year period of grace.

Page 177: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 28 . . . Leviticus 25:23–24

1116

The urban home buyer remained uncertain for a year.A wealthy buyer could more easily have borne the risk of being

evicted within the year.A business setback would have been one reason for selling.Mortgage loans could have been collateralized by a home in walled

cities.Such loans were high-risk loans for borrowers: no jubilee-year

redemption.Rich resident aliens were probably active lenders: hoping the

owners would default.This would have tended to keep interest rates lower in walled cities:

more lenders, greater security of collateral.Turnover of ownership would have been more rapid than in rural

areas or in unwalled cities.Canaan’s walled cities would have become Israel’s walled cities.These would have been cities located on trade routes.Homes could have been bought for cash or leased with an option

to buy.Redemption would normally have been in cash: whatever the buyer

had paid during the year.The resident alien could attain a stake in society: a home.Resident aliens could not be compelled to defend the city militarily:

no civil oath, i.e., no participation in the numbering of God’s holyarmy.

They could volunteer.Citizenship was based on being eligible for military numbering:

adoption into an Israelite tribe.The threat of excommunication was this: you could be sold into

permanent slavery if you got into financial trouble.Cities were cosmopolitan centers: cultural pluralism.The cities were cultural testing laboratories.

Page 178: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Right of Redemption

1117

These laboratories were sealed off judicially from the land outsidethe walls.

Foreign nations therefore could not hope to colonize Israel exceptby force.

Urban home owners would have been the most productive peoplein walled cities.

This was one of Israel’s lures to successful foreigners involved intrade: the possibility of becoming home owners.

The 48 cities of the Levites were governed by a different rule fromother cities: Levites could redeem their homes at any time.

Their homes were returned to them automatically in the jubileeyear.

This enabled them to be dispersed throughout the nation.All the tribes were to have access to legal specialists: the Levites.The cities were to become population centers.The structure of jubilee ownership favored the accumulation of

wealth by the Levites in times of covenantal obedience.The economics of home ownership favored the Levites’ enforce-

ment of the jubilee year.Their failure to enforce it must have led to two classes of Levites:

home owners and renters.The jubilee law was not intended to be permanent: only until Shiloh

(messiah) came (Judah’s tribe).

Page 179: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1. Gary North, Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1990), ch. 23.

1118

29

POVERTY AND USURY

And if thy brother be waxen poor, and fallen in decay with thee; thenthou shalt relieve him: yea, though he be a stranger, or a sojourner;that he may live with thee. Take thou no usury of him, or increase:but fear thy God; that thy brother may live with thee. Thou shalt notgive him thy money upon usury, nor lend him thy victuals forincrease. I am the LORD your God, which brought you forth out ofthe land of Egypt, to give you the land of Canaan, and to be yourGod (Lev. 25:35–38).

The theocentric basis of this law was God’s role as the liberator.Men are to fear God. This fear of God should overcome men’s fear ofnature and history. Fear of God is liberating; fear of the creation isparalyzing.

Usury Defined

This law is an extension of Exodus 22:25: “If thou lend money toany of my people that is poor by thee, thou shalt not be to him as anusurer, neither shalt thou lay upon him usury.”1 The Hebrew wordtranslated here as usury means bite. “And the LORD sent fieryserpents among the people, and they bit the people; and much peopleof Israel died” (Num. 21:6). In both Exodus and Leviticus, theborrower is described as being a poor brother in the faith, i.e., underGod’s covenant. The heart of the matter in Leviticus 25:35–38 andExodus 22:25 is the establishment of judicial conditions for charitable,

Page 180: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

2. The non-theologians have been even more muddled. See, for example, S. C. Mooney,Usury: Destroyer of Nations (Warsaw, Ohio: Theopolis, 1988). For my response, see GaryNorth, Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus (Tyler, Texas: Institute for ChristianEconomics, 1990), Appendix G: “Lots of Free Time: The Existentialist Utopia of S. C.Mooney.”

3. Gary North, Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Deuteronomy,2nd electronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc.,[1999] 2003), ch. 69.

1119

interest-free loans: poverty, covenantal brotherhood, and geographicalproximity. As we shall see, these conditions had to be legallyidentifiable in order for the prohibition against usury to be enforced bya civil court. It was this aspect of conditionality that medievaltheologians failed to recognize when they issued prohibitions againsttaking interest in all loans. The biblical texts are clear; it is thetheologians who have been muddled.2

What is usury? Both texts are quite clear about the definition: usuryis any positive rate of return taken from a loan. There is no universalprohibition in the Bible against interest. This is clear from the text inDeuteronomy that authorizes covenant-keepers to make interest-bearing charitable loans to covenantal strangers. “Thou shalt not lendupon usury to thy brother; usury of money, usury of victuals, usury ofany thing that is lent upon usury: Unto a stranger thou mayest lendupon usury; but unto thy brother thou shalt not lend upon usury: thatthe LORD thy God may bless thee in all that thou settest thine handto in the land whither thou goest to possess it” (Deut. 23: 19–20). Infact, God encourages His people to lend to those outside the faith; itis a means of subduing them. “For the LORD thy God blesseth thee,as he promised thee: and thou shalt lend unto many nations, but thoushalt not borrow; and thou shalt reign over many nations, but theyshall not reign over thee” (Deut. 15:6).3 Lending at interest is anaspect of the dominion covenant. Biblically, there is no universalprohibition against this.

Page 181: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

4. The prohibition against interest (usury) began with the Council of Nicea (325): clericswere prohibited from making interest-bearing loans. J. Gilchrist, The Church andEconomic Activity in the Middle Ages (New York: St. Martin’s, 1969), p. 155. Thisprohibition was gradually extended by the theologians after 800. Ibid., p. 63. The SecondLateran Council (1139) was especially hostile, going so far as to prohibit usurers frombeing granted Christian burial. Ibid., p. 165. The Council at Vienna (1311–12) mandatedthe excommunication of civil rulers who permitted usury within their jurisdictions. Ibid.,p. 206. Gilchrist’s excellent book did not receive the audience that it should have. Itincludes translations of the texts of the general councils. This makes it invaluable.

1120

Medieval Christian expositors concluded, following Aristotle ratherthan Moses, that interest is always prohibited.4 It is not. What wasprohibited under Mosaic law was interest taken from a poor brotherin the faith or a poor resident alien who had subordinated himself tothe civil covenant, presumably by submitting to circumcision. Thelender, then as now, was not to take advantage of certain poor people:those who had submitted themselves to the terms of the covenant. Hewas required by God to make a charitable loan. He would therebyforfeit the interest he might have earned from a business loan.Forfeited interest was the charitable component of his act. If interestwere universally prohibited, then all legal loans would be charitable.There would then be no economic distinction between charity loansand business loans, or between dominion by restoring the covenant-keeping poor and dominion by subordinating the covenant-breakingpoor. The Bible teaches otherwise.

Charity: Conditional vs. Unconditional

Charitable loans are part of God’s program to provide help tohonest, covenant-keeping people who have fallen on hard times. Theseloans are not supposed to subsidize sloth or evil. God does not wantus to subsidize evil with the money or assets that He has provided for

Page 182: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

5. R. J. Rushdoony, “Subsidizing Evil,” in Rushdoony, Bread Upon the Waters (Nutley,New Jersey: Craig Press, 1969), ch. 3.

6. Ray R. Sutton, “Whose Conditions for Charity?” in Theonomy: An Informed Response,edited by Gary North (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1991), ch. 9. Suttonis responding to Timothy J. Keller, “Theonomy and the Poor: Some Reflections,” inTheonomy: A Reformed Critique, edited by William S. Barker and W. Robert Godfrey(Grand Rapids, Michigan: Zondervan Academie, 1990), ch. 12.

7. James L. Payne, The Culture of Spending: Why Congress Lives Beyond Our Means(San Francisco: ICS Press, 1991), p. 51.

8. Marvin Olasky, The Tragedy of American Compassion (Westchester, Illinois:Crossway, 1992).

1121

us.5 In this sense, biblical charity is necessarily morally conditional.6

Biblical charity is never a judicially automatic “entitlement,” to use theterminology of the modern welfare State: a compulsory redistributionof wealth from the successful to the unsuccessful (minusapproximately 50% for “handling” by government bureaucrats7). It isthis element of covenantal conditionality which distinguishes biblicalcharity from humanist compulsion.8

The modern welfare State does not distinguish judicially betweenfaith and unbelief, or between righteousness and moral rebellion, asprimary factors underlying both wealth and poverty. The Bible’sethics-based correlation is an implicit denial of the very foundation ofhumanism’s welfare State. The welfare State rests on two rivaltheories of the origin of wealth and poverty, held together dialecticallyin most humanist explanations of economic inequality: (1) the chancedistribution of economic assets and personal skills; (2) the exploitationof the poor by the economically and politically successful. The Stateis seen as the most powerful agency that possesses a moral and legalobligation to offset the effects of either chance or exploitation. Thewelfare State therefore in theory looks only at the numbers, not at themoral condition of the recipients of State money: their reported

Page 183: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

9. Charles Murray, “The Coming White Underclass,” Wall Street Journal (Oct. 29,1993), editorial page.

10. Ronald J. Sider, Rich Christians in an Age of Hunger: A Biblical View (DownersGrove, Illinois: Inter-Varsity Press, 1977). For a line-by-line refutation of Sider, includinghis revised second edition (1984), see David Chilton, Productive Christians in an Age ofGuilt-Manipulators, 3rd ed. (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, [1985] 1990).Sider did not reply to Chilton in either his second or third edition (Waco, Texas: Word,1990). The fourth edition (1997) recanted much of what the first three editions hadproclaimed in the name of biblical ethics. North, Inheritance and Dominion, Appendix F.

1122

income in relation to statute law. Being bureaucratic, the West’swelfare State must by law ignore moral criteria and respond strictly interms of formal criteria: so much income; so many children in thehousehold under age 18, irrespective of the mother’s marital status;and so forth. The welfare State is to biblical charity what fornicationis to biblical marriage. It literally subsidizes fornication by subsidizingthe bastards who are produced by fornication, thereby swelling theranks of the government-dependent children of the morally corrupt.9

This creates lifetime employment for the next generation of welfareState bureaucrats – the unstated but inevitable goal of the welfareState. Yet so powerful is humanism today in the thinking ofacademically trained Christians that they have become open defendersof the legitimacy of the modern welfare State’s system of compulsorywealth redistribution, despite the fact that it rests on a theory ofunconditional legal entitlement.10

Reducing Our Fear of the Unknown

Biblical charity is essential for building God’s kingdom on earth, forit reduces our fear of the unknown. We are not to live in fear of theunknown. We are to live in the fear of God, which is the beginning ofwisdom (Prov. 1:7; 9:10). Intense fear of any aspect of the creation

Page 184: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

11. Herbert Schlossberg, Idols for Destruction: Christian Faith and Its Confrontationwith American Society (Westchester, Illinois: Crossway, [1983] 1993), p. 304.

1123

tends to paralyze men, to keep them in bondage to the creation. Fearand paralysis are what the biblical covenant was designed toovercome. Perfect love casts out fear (I John 4:18).

Bad things can and do happen to good people from time to time,while good things happen to the unrighteous (Ps. 73). The worldsometimes appears to be governed by a system of perverse historicalsanctions. Schlossberg is correct: “The Bible can be interpreted as astring of God’s triumphs disguised as disasters.”11 Covenant-keepersare not immune from the corporate curse that God has placed on thecreation. We are also not immune to the corporate curses He placeson the covenant-breaking society in which we live. So, as a way toreduce our fear of the unknown, God commands us to be generous toothers in the faith during their time of need.

Biblical charity is a form of social insurance – not State insurance,but social insurance: provided through voluntarism without any threatof civil sanctions. Biblical charity begins with those who labor in thework of building God’s kingdom on earth, who in turn voluntarilysupport other covenantally faithful people who share in this work.Biblical charity is therefore part of God’s system of corporate coven-ant sanctions – in this case, positive sanctions, beginning with coven-ant-keepers and extending to covenant-breakers only after those insidethe household of faith have been assisted.

The State as Insurer

Charity creates dependence. This dependence is to be temporaryexcept in cases of permanent physical or mental helplessness. The bib-

Page 185: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

12. Shirley Scheibla, Poverty Is Where the Money Is (New Rochelle, New York:Arlington House, 1968).

1124

lical goal is dominion by covenant, not by permanent dependence.This is why State charity is so dangerous to biblical dominion andtherefore to liberty. It creates a permanent political base of dependentsand also a permanent corps of State-funded welfare agents whoseincome depends on the maintenance of poverty to relieve. For thiscorps of welfare agents, poverty is where the money is.12 The positivesanction of charity is not to be provided by the State, which mustimpose compulsory negative sanctions (taxes) on some people inorder to extend positive sanctions (welfare) to others. The State is topromote the general welfare only by punishing criminals and defendingthe nation from invasion. A biblical positive sanction – the generalwelfare – is the social result of the State’s exclusively negativesanctions.

The State is required by God to defend the legal boundaries thatestablish private property, not invade these boundaries in an illegiti-mate messianic quest to bring positive sanctions to the poor. The civilmagistrate is figuratively to stand inside the boundaries beside of theproperty owner to defend him against any threat of invasion by a non-owner. He is not to stand outside the boundaries by the side of thenon-owner, threatening to invade. Defenders of the welfare Statereject this view of the civil magistrate. Because so many of thesedefenders are orthodox theologians and church leaders, Christiansocial theory today is either non-existent (baptized humanism) orundermined by humanism.

The Stranger and the Sojourner

Page 186: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

1125

This text says that we are to relieve the stranger and the sojourner.The text in Deuteronomy 23:20 says that we may lawfully chargestrangers interest. How can this apparent contradiction be resolved?Answer: by going to the Hebrew text. At this point, I reprint a portionof a chapter, “The Prohibition Against Usury,” which appears in mycommentary on the case laws of Exodus, Tools of Dominion (pp.709–16). I have made a few additions and corrections.

* * * * * * * * * * * * * *

The text in Leviticus 25, the chapter on the jubilee year, is clear:“And if thy brother be waxen poor, and fallen in decay with thee; thenthou shalt relieve him: yea, though he be a stranger [geyr], or a so-journer [to-shawb]; that he may live with thee. Take thou no usury ofhim, or increase: but fear thy God; that thy brother may live with thee.Thou shalt not give him thy money upon usury, nor lend him thyvictuals for increase” (Lev. 25:35–37). It begins with the determiningclause: “If thy brother be waxen poor.”

The interpretation of the Leviticus 25 passage initially seems diffi-cult because of the King James translation of Deuteronomy 23:20:“Unto a stranger [nok-ree] thou mayest lend upon usury; but unto thybrother thou shalt not lend upon usury: that the LORD thy God maybless thee in all that thou settest thine hand to in the land whither thougoest to possess it.” We must begin with the presupposition thatGod’s revealed law is not inconsistent. But here we have what appearto be two rules regarding the stranger: you may not lawfully chargethe stranger interest, yet you may lawfully charge him interest. Howcan we reconcile these two statements?

The answer is that the Hebrew word used in Leviticus 25:35,transliterated geyr [gare], is not the same as the Hebrew word inDeuteronomy 23:20. Similarly, “sojourner” [to-shawb] is related to

Page 187: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

13. Strong’s Concordance, Hebrew and Chaldee Dictionary, p. 123.

14. Ibid., p. 52.

15. This is the translation given in the Revised Standard Version, the New AmericanStandard Bible, and the New International Version. The alien and the sojourner wereequivalents judicially in the Mosaic law. The NIV translates Leviticus 25:35 as “an alienor a temporary resident.”

1126

yaw-shab,13 meaning “sit,” and implying “remain,” “settle,” “dwell,”or even “marry.”14 To-shawb therefore means resident alien. Thestranger [nok-ree] referred to in Deuteronomy 23:20 was simply aforeigner.15 Two different kinds of “stranger” are referred to in thetwo verses. Thus, if the resident alien was poor, and if he was willingto live in Israel under the terms of the civil covenant, then he wasentitled to a special degree of civil legal protection. What was thislegal protection? If he fell into poverty, he was not to be asked to payinterest on any loan that a richer man extended to him. With respectto usury, he was to be treated as a poverty-stricken Hebrew. Not sothe foreigner.

What must be understood is that the economic setting is clearly therelief of the righteous poor. The recipient was any poor person whohad fallen into poverty through no ethical fault of his own, and whowas willing to remain under God’s civil hierarchy.

There is a parallel passage in Deuteronomy 15. Deuteronomy 15lists the economic laws governing Israel’s national sabbatical year. Inthis national year of release, the text literally says, all debts to neigh-bors are to be forgiven: “At the end of every seven years thou shaltmake a release. And this is the manner of the release: Every creditorthat lendeth ought unto his neighbour shall release it; he shall notexact it of his neighbour, or of his brother; because it is called theLORD’S release” (Deut. 15:1–2). The text is clear: the neighborlyloan is the focus of the law.

Page 188: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

1127

At least one kind of loan was explicitly exempted by the text: loansto non-resident foreigners. “Of a foreigner [nok-ree] thou mayestexact it again: but that which is thine with thy brother thine hand shallrelease” (Deut. 15:3). This could have been a traveller or foreignerwho owned a business locally. It could have been a business contactin another country. It was not a poverty-stricken resident alien, whowas treated by biblical civil law as a neighbor.

Who Is My Neighbor?

Because all debts to a neighbor are to be forgiven, the legal ques-tion legitimately arises: “Who is my neighbor?” This was the questionthat the lawyer asked Jesus (Luke 10:29). Jesus answered this ques-tion with His parable of the good Samaritan. The Samaritan finds abeaten man on the highway. The man had been robbed. He looked asthough he was dead. He was in deep trouble through no fault of hisown. He was on the same road that the Samaritan was traveling. TheSamaritan takes him to an inn, pays to have him helped, and goes onhis journey. He agrees to cover expenses. He shows mercy to theinjured man who was incapable of helping himself. He is the thereforetrue neighbor of the person on the road. The lawyer admitted this(Luke 10:37).

So, the context of the parable is not simply geographical proximityin a neighborhood. It is proximity of life. Samaritans did not normallylive in Israel. They had very little contact with the Israelites. But thisSamaritan was walking along the same road as the beaten man, and hewas in a position to help. He saw that the man was a true victim. Thelatter was in trouble through no visible fault of his own. He thereforedeserved help – morally, though not by statute law – but the priest andthe Levite had refused to offer him any help. The Samaritan was being

Page 189: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

1128

faithful to the law.This parable was a reproach to the Jews. They knew what Jesus

was saying: they were too concerned with the details of the ceremon-ial law to honor the most important law of all, which the lawyer hadcited. “Thou shalt love the Lord thy God with all thy heart, and withall thy soul, and with all thy strength, and with all thy mind; and thyneighbour as thyself” (Luke 10:27). What they also fully understoodwas that Jesus was predicting that the gentiles (Samaritans) who didobey this law of the neighbor would eventually rule over the Jews, forthis is what Deuteronomy 15 explicitly says. He who shows mercy tohis neighbor will participate in his nation’s rule over other nations.“Only if thou carefully hearken unto the voice of the LORD thy God,to observe to do all these commandments which I command thee thisday. For the LORD thy God blesseth thee, as he promised thee: andthou shalt lend unto many nations, but thou shalt not borrow; andthou shalt reign over many nations, but they shall not reign over thee”(Deut. 15:5–6). Notice also that the means of exercising this rule isthrough extending them credit.

This is a very significant covenantal cause-and-effect relationship.If a nation is characterized by the willingness of its citizens to loanmoney, interest-free, to their poverty-stricken neighbors, includingresident aliens, who are stricken by poverty, not immoral pursuers ofpoverty by their lifestyles, the nation will eventually extend its controlover others by placing them under the obligation of debt. “The richruleth over the poor, and the borrower is servant to the lender” (Prov.22:7). This is why it was legal to take interest from the foreigner whowas living outside the land. It was a means of subduing him, hisfamily, and his God-defying civilization. It was (and is) a means ofdominion.

[Added in 1994:] This does not mean, as Timothy Keller insists thatit means, that my neighbor is anyone in need anywhere on earth. He

Page 190: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

16. Keller, “Theonomy and the Poor,” p. 275. For my critique of this position, see GaryNorth, Westminster’s Confession: The Abandonment of Van Til’s Legacy (Tyler, Texas:Institute for Christian Economics, 1991), pp. 271–80.

17. R. J. Rushdoony, “The United Nations,” in Rushdoony, The Nature of the AmericanSystem (Fairfax, Virginia: Thoburn Press, [1965] 1978); Rushdoony, “Has the U.N.Replaced Christ as a World Religion?” in Your Church – Their Target, compiled byKenneth W. Ingwaldson (Arlington, Virginia: Better Books, 1966), ch. 10; Rushdoony,“The United Nations: A Religious Dream,” in Rushdoony, Politics of Guilty and Pity(Fairfax, Virginia: Thoburn Press, [1970] 1978), pp. 184–199. See also Chesley Manly, TheUN Record: The Fateful Years for America (Chicago: Regnery, 1955); V. Orval Watts, TheUnited Nations: Planned Tyranny (New York: Devin-Adair, 1955); G. Edward Griffin, TheFearful Master: A Second Look at the United Nations (Boston: Western Islands, 1964);Robert W. Lee, The United Nations Conspiracy (Boston: Western Islands, 1981).

1129

writes: “Anyone in need is my neighbor – that is the teaching of theGood Samaritan parable.”16 No, that is the teaching of the modernwelfare State and its international embodiment, the United NationsOrganization, a would-be reincarnation of the Roman Empire, but ona much wider scale: the incarnation of humanism’s New WorldOrder.17

Moral Obligation

Because these charitable loans were supposed to be cancelled in theseventh year, the national sabbatical year, there was an obvioustemptation to refuse to make such loans as the sabbatical year ofrelease approached. God recognized this temptation, and He warnedagainst it.

If there be among you a poor man of one of thy brethren within any ofthy gates in thy land which the LORD thy God giveth thee, thou shaltnot harden thine heart, nor shut thine hand from thy poor brother: Butthou shalt open thine hand d shalt surely lend him sufficient for his

Page 191: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

1130

need, in that which he wanteth. Beware that there be not a thought inthy wicked heart, saying, The seventh year, the year of release, is athand; and thine eye be evil against thy poor brother, and thou givesthim nought; and he cry unto the LORD against thee, and it be sin untothee. Thou shalt surely give him, and thine heart shall not be grievedwhen thou givest unto him: because that for this thing the LORD thyGod shall bless thee in all thy works, and in all that thou puttest thinehand unto (Deut. 15:7–10).

This indicates that God placed a moral obligation on the heart ofthe more successful man, who was supposed to lend to his neighbor.But this was not statute law enforceable in a civil court. God wouldbe the avenger, not the State.

The context of the obligatory loan of Deuteronomy 15, like thezero-interest loan of Exodus 22:25–27, is poverty. There will be poorpeople in the promised land, Moses warned. Because of this, thesespecial loans are morally mandatory. There must be a year of release,“Save when there shall be no poor among you; for the LORD shallgreatly bless thee in the land which the LORD thy God giveth thee foran inheritance to possess it” (Deut. 15:4). Does this mean that theseloan provisions would eventually be annulled? No. “For the poor shallnever cease out of the land: therefore I command thee, saying, Thoushalt open thine hand wide unto thy brother, to thy poor, and to thyneedy, in thy land” (Deut. 15:11). Everything in Deuteronomy 15speaks of poverty and biblical law’s means of overcoming it. Deuter-onomy 15 is not dealing with business loans; it is dealing with charityloans. There was no statute law that imposed sanctions on anyonewho refused to make an interest-free loan.

Defining Poverty by Statute

Page 192: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

1131

Why was this not a statute law? Because biblical civil law imposesonly negative injunctions. It prohibits publicly evil acts. Biblical civillaw does not authorize the State to make men good. It does notauthorize the State to force men to do good things. It does notauthorize the creation of a messianic, salvationist State. The Statecannot search the hearts of men. God does this, as the Creator andJudge, so the State must not claim such an ability. The State is onlyauthorized by God to impose negative sanctions against publicly evilacts. It is not authorized to seek to force men to do good acts. Inshort, the Bible is opposed to the modern welfare State.

There is no way for biblical statute law to define what poverty isapart from the opinions of those affected by the law, either as taxpay-ers, charitable lenders, or recipients of public welfare or privatecharity. “Poverty” is too subjective a category to be defined by statutelaw. The State needs to be able to assign legal definitions to crimes,in order that its arbitrary power not be expanded. Economic defini-tions of wealth and poverty that are not arbitrary are not available tothe civil magistrates for the creation of positive legal injunctions.Thus, God’s civil law does not compel a man to make a loan to a poorperson.

Nevertheless, the civil law does prohibit taking interest from certaincategories of poor people. How can the law do this without creatingthe conditions of judicial tyranny through arbitrariness? If themagistrates cannot define exactly what poverty is for the purpose ofwriting positive civil injunctions, how can they define what a charit-able loan is? How can the State legitimately prohibit interest from acharity loan if the legislators and judges cannot define poverty with asufficient degree of accuracy to identify cases where a charity loan is

Page 193: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

18. This is the question that S. C. Mooney raises in his attempt to remove any distinctionbetween charity loans and business loans. Mooney, Usury, pp. 123–27.

19. A debt slave was a person who had asked his neighbor for a morally mandatory, zero-interest charity loan, and who had then defaulted. He was then placed in bondage until thesabbatical year, or until his debt was paid.

1132

legally obligatory for the potential lender?18

The lender decides who is deserving of his loan and who is not.This is his moral choice. God will judge him, pro or con, not the State.However, once the lender grants this unique, morally enjoined charityloan, he may not extract an interest payment. This is a negativeinjunction – not doing something which is forbidden by law – andtherefore it is legitimately enforceable by civil law, as surely as thecivil magistrates in ancient Israel were supposed to enforce the releaseof debt slaves19 in the seventh (sabbatical) year (Deut. 15:12– 15). Therequirement to lend to a needy brother under the terms specified inbiblical law is a positive injunction. It therefore comes under the self-government provisions of the conscience and the negative sanctionsof God. This positive injunction is not under the jurisdiction of thecivil courts. On the other hand, the prohibition against charginginterest on these unique loans, being a negative injunction, does comeunder the enforcement of both civil courts and church courts.

Bondservice

The key to understanding the Bible’s civil definition of poverty isthe loan’s contract. There must be a mutually agreed-upon contract,explicit or implicit, in order to establish a legally enforceable loan. Ifthe borrower came to the lender and called upon him to honor Deut-eronomy 15:7–8, then the borrower admitted that his was a specialcase, a charity loan, and it was governed by the civil law’s terms of the

Page 194: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

20. North, Tools of Dominion, pp. 738–40.

1133

sabbatical year and the prohibition against interest. The borrowermade his request a matter of conscience.

In so doing, he necessarily and inescapably placed himself under theterms of biblical civil law. If he could not repay his debt on time, hecould legally be sold into bondservice. This was not a collateralizedcommercial loan. The borrower was so poor that he had almost nocollateral except his land. He chose not to use his land as collateral –or was forced to because he had already leased his land. Yet he wasstill in dire need. All he could offer as collateral was his promise, hiscloak, and his bodily service until the next sabbatical year, should hedefault. Thus, the borrower admitted that he in principle had alreadybecome a bondservant. He admitted through the loan’s contractualarrangement that the borrower is servant to the lender. If he could notrepay, he would go into bondservice until the next sabbatical year, oruntil his debt was repaid, whichever came first.

How would the civil magistrate in Israel know which kind of loanwas in force, commercial or charitable, and therefore whether interestwas valid or illegal? By examining the nature of the loan’s collateral.If a loan went to an individual who, if he should default on the loan,would be placed in debt slavery, then this was a charitable loangoverned by the provisions of Deuteronomy 15. This is why the yearof release applied to both kinds of servitude: debt servitude and bodilyservitude that arose because of a man’s default on a charity loan.

Furthermore, if it was a loan with the individual’s cloak as security,then it was also a zero-interest loan. The collateral described inExodus 22:25–27 insured little more than that the individual was alocal resident – he had to come to the lender to get it back eachevening – and that the loan was temporary. (It also made multipleindebtedness more difficult.)20 It would have been a very small loan.

Page 195: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

1134

This was clearly not a business loan. A business loan would have adifferent kind of collateral: property that was not crucial to personalsurvival on a cold night. If the borrower defaulted on a commercialloan, he would forfeit the property specified in the loan contract. Hewould not forfeit his freedom or his children’s freedom. In short, theOld Testament’s texts governing lending specify that certain kinds ofloans would have certain kinds of collateral, and wherever theseunique forms of collateral appeared, the lender could not legallydemand an interest payment.

Biblical civil law is exclusively negative law – prohibiting evil publicdeeds – not positive law, which enjoins the performance of righteouspublic deeds. An example of this distinction is the enforcement of thetithe: church courts can legitimately require voting members to titheas a condition of maintaining their voting church membership; theState cannot legitimately require residents to tithe to a church or otherorganization on threat of civil punishment.

Once the contract was made, the lender was placed under the limitsof the civil law. He could not extract interest from the borrower, evena resident alien. But the borrower also was placed under limits: if hedefaulted, he could be sold into bondservice. Each party was underlimits. Each had decided that this was a true poor loan situation. Eachagreed to a unique set of contractual obligations by entering into thisarrangement.

Thus, once the contract was made, either implicitly or explicitly, theState had a legal definition of poverty. If the borrower was legallysubject to the possibility of being sold into bondservice for defaultingon the loan, then the lender could not lawfully extract interest fromhim. On the other hand, if the borrower was unwilling to place hisown freedom in jeopardy, then he was unwilling to define himself asa poor man for the sake of the civil law’s definition. Thus, he had topay interest on the loan, and his obligation to repay the loan extended

Page 196: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

21. Gary North, Treasure and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Luke, 2nd elec-tronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc., [2000]2003), ch. 10.

22. Gary North, Coorperation and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Romans,2nd electronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc.,[2000] 2003), ch. 10.

1135

beyond the sabbatical year. If he was not under the threat ofbondservice, he was not under the protection of the sabbatical year orthe zero-interest provisions against usury.

* * * * * * * * * * * * * *

Today, the State does not recognize the legitimacy of temporaryservitude in order to repay loans. The modern State has annulled thedefining legal condition under which God established the Mosaic law’smorally compulsory charitable loans.

What about the New Covenant? Jesus set forth this rule: “And if yelend to them of whom ye hope to receive, what thank have ye? forsinners also lend to sinners, to receive as much again. But love ye yourenemies, and do good, and lend, hoping for nothing again; and yourreward shall be great, and ye shall be the children of the Highest: forhe is kind unto the unthankful and to the evil” (Luke 6:34–35).21 Thelaw has been extended to God’s covenantal enemies even when thethreat of servitude for default has been eliminated. The law is broaderand more rigorous in the New Covenant. But it is still conditional: nosubsidy of evil. It is part of God’s judgment: “Therefore if thine enemyhunger, feed him; if he thirst, give him drink: for in so doing thou shaltheap coals of fire on his head” (Rom. 12:20).22

Interest and Inflation

Page 197: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

23. North, Tools of Dominion, ch. 23.

24. I use the Rolls-Royce example because its style does not change very often, and oldermodels retain their market value.

25. This assumes that the bird’s species is not known to be facing extinction or sometremendous fall in numbers next year.

26. Ludwig von Mises, Human Action: A Treatise on Economics (New Haven, Connec-ticut: Yale University Press, 1949), ch. 19.

1136

In Tools of Dominion, I went into considerable detail about theeconomics of time-preference: the originary interest rate. I also discus-sed the thousand-year history of the church’s false interpretations ofthe usury prohibition as a universal prohibition against all forms ofinterest. I do not need to reprint the entire chapter here. Those readerswho want a detailed treatment may consult that chapter. Warning: itis a long chapter.23

The interest rate is a universal category of human action. It is nota purely monetary phenomenon. It results from the inescapable dis-count that acting men place on the future. For example, a brand newRolls-Royce automobile is worth more to me today than the sameRolls-Royce delivered a year from now is worth to me today.24 A birdin hand today is worth more than the same bird in hand in a year.25

This rate of discount of future goods vs. physically identical goodsthat are in our possession today is the rate of interest.26 It does notapply to money alone, just as the text in Leviticus indicates; it appliesto food and, by extension, all goods and services. Interest on charit-able loans is prohibited in the case of money, services, or goods – arecognition in God’s law of the universality of the interest rate. Therate of interest is a discount for time across the entire economy.

Monetary Policy

Page 198: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

27. The word is seldom used outside of backward rural areas.

1137

In a period of rising prices (i.e., falling value of money), an astutecharitable lender prefers to lend food (“victuals,” or “vittles,” as theword is pronounced)27 rather than money. He cannot lawfully chargeinterest on such loans. A loan “in kind” – a consumer good rather thanmoney – means that the lender will receive back the physicalequivalent of whatever he gave up temporarily to the borrower. Hewill not suffer an additional loss from the debtor’s repayment of theloan in money of reduced purchasing power. Since he cannot lawfullycharge interest, he does not tack on what is called an inflation prem-ium to the loan: an extra payment to compensate him for the fall in thevalue of money. There is little doubt that price inflation in Israel wouldhave increased the number of loans in kind compared to money loans.A charitable loan made in money would have produced a loss of morethan the forfeited interest; it would have meant the loss of capital.

On the other hand, in a time of falling prices (rising money value),either as a result of an economic depression or because of addedeconomic output, an astute lender would prefer to lend money ratherthan goods. He would then receive an implicit interest return on theloan: added capital (purchasing power) despite the numerical equalityof the monetary units repaid. The Bible allows this. In times of fallingprices, an astute borrower will prefer a loan in goods rather thanmoney, but he is not in a position to demand such a loan. “Beggarscan’t be choosers,” as the saying goes. However, in most periods inhistory, this added return on money loans is very low, since pricesrarely fall rapidly except following a period of high monetary inflation.Economic output grows slowly most of the time; prices therefore fallslowly.

There is no question that the lender’s decision to loan in money orin goods is heavily dependent on the civil government’s monetary

Page 199: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

28. Murray N. Rothbard, Man, Economy, and State: A Treatise on Economic Principles(Auburn, Alabama: Mises Institute, [1962] 1993), p. 715.

1138

policies. Because monetary policy cannot achieve economic neutral-ity,28 to some extent there will always be profits and losses in debtarrangements. Either the lender loses or the debtor loses, dependingon the terms of the contract and monetary policy. The key judicialissue, however, is that in a covenanted Trinitarian nation, the contractfor a charitable loan must not impose an explicit interest payment.

Conclusion

Usury from the poor brother is prohibited by the Bible. In theMosaic Covenant, this poor person had to be willing to risk going intobondservice for up to six years if he defaulted on such a zero-interestloan. The civil courts were required to enforce this provision of acharitable loan. This bondservice provision was assumed in everyzero-interest loan, which the court could safely assume was a charityloan. It was this willingness on the poor person’s part to risk bond-service that identified him as a needy person. Accepting such a loanwas a last resort. It was this degree of poverty, and only this degreeof poverty, that created a moral obligation on the lender to lend to adeserving poor person.

This usury prohibition has nothing to do with interest on businessloans or consumer loans, whether or not they are collateralized,although large loans normally will be. Commercial loans possess noelement of moral obligation. Such interest-bearing loans in MosaicIsrael were not under the cancellation provisions of the sabbaticalyear, but the collateral for the loan could not be perpetual bond-service, for only heathens could be enslaved permanently in Israel. The

Page 200: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

29. Chapter 30.

30. Martin E. Marty, Pilgrims in Their Own Land: 500 Years of Religion in America(Boston: Little, Brown, 1984).

31. Gary North, Political Polytheism: The Myth of Pluralism (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1989).

32. An example is Gary Scott Smith, The Seeds of Secularization: Calvinism, Culture,and Pluralism in America, 1870–1915 (Grand Rapids, Michigan: Christian UniversityPress, 1985).

1139

Israelite bondservant had to be paid a wage, enabling him to buy hisway out.29

The Pentateuchal texts are clear: covenant-keepers do not oweinterest-free charitable loans to those who are not under the jurisdic-tion of either God’s ecclesiastical covenant or God’s civil covenant.This means that Christians who live under a civil government in whichcitizenship is not based on taking or implicitly accepting a formalTrinitarian oath owe no loans to resident aliens, i.e., non-believers.Why not? Because, covenantally speaking, Christians have becomethe resident aliens. We are the strangers in a strange land. We live asAbraham lived in Canaan, not as Joshua’s heirs lived in Israel.30 Thedifference is, Abraham looked forward to deliverance and victoryduring Joshua’s generation (Gen. 15:16). Today, the vast majority ofChristians praise their permanent resident-alien status as God’s planfor the New Covenant era: political pluralism.31 What Jews in Jesus’day correctly regarded as civil tyranny – subservience to Rome’spantheon of gods, incarnated in the State – today’s Christians regardas political freedom. Even Calvinists, Protestantism’s historicdefenders of theocracy, from Calvin’s Geneva through Cromwell’sEngland to Puritan New England, have fallen into this humanist mind-set.32 The Greek rationalism of the medieval university’s curriculumhas triumphed over whatever biblical elements had been sporadically

Page 201: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 29 . . . Leviticus 25:35–38

1140

tacked on by wishful Scholastic thinkers.The New Testament has broadened the net of those who have a

legitimate moral claim on our charitable loans: from poor brothers topoor covenant-breakers. But the law is still conditional. We are not tosubsidize evil. We lend to very poor people who are not poor becauseof their own moral flaws. We are not even to lend in the hope ofregaining our principal, let alone interest (Luke 6:34–35). Thecharitable loan law is more rigorous in the New Covenant, but it is notunconditional.

Summary

Usury (interest) is prohibited in charity loans to poor brothers in thecovenant and to faithful resident aliens.

Biblical charity is morally conditional: no subsidy of evil.The modern welfare State does not distinguish between faith and

unbelief, righteousness and rebellion, in its identification of povertyand the State’s proposed solutions.

Welfare State theorists blame poverty on chance (birth) and ex-ploitation (by the rich).

Biblical charity reduces our fear of the unknown.It is a form of social insurance, but not State insurance.The text requires that covenant-keepers relieve impoverished

strangers and sojourners through interest-free loans.Resident aliens were not to be charged interest in charitable loans.Foreigners were not so protected.The determining legal status was “neighbor.”The determining issue was proximity: geographically and ethically

(righteousness).Showing mercy was an aspect of Israel’s national dominion.

Page 202: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Poverty and Usury

1141

So was making interest-bearing loans to foreigners.This does not mean that every poor person was the neighbor of

every Israelite, and therefore deserving of charity, contrary to whatwelfare State advocates assume.

There was a moral obligation on Israelites to make charitable loans.There was no enforceable legal obligation to do so.This was not civil statute law, for biblical civil law does not enjoin

positive sanctions, i.e., wealth-distribution.Also, poverty is too subjective a category to be defined by biblical

civil law.Arbitrariness by civil rulers is a threat to freedom.Civil statutes must reduce arbitrariness.The prohibition on taking interest from charity loans is a civil

statute: negative in scope.The mark of a charity loan contract is the debtor’s consent to be

placed in bondservice to repay the loan if he defaults.The modern State does not allow bondservice as a means of paying

off defaulted charitable loans.Interest is a phenomenon of human action, not a strictly monetary

phenomenon.In times of price inflation, lenders of zero-interest charity loans will

tend to make loans of goods, not money.In times of price deflation, lenders of zero-interest charity loans will

tend to make money loans.Christians do not owe charitable loans to “resident aliens” in a State

that is not under a formal Trinitarian covenant.Christians have become strangers in the land.

Page 203: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1142

30

PROMISE, ADOPTION, AND LIBERTY

And if thy brother that dwelleth by thee be waxen poor, and be soldunto thee; thou shalt not compel him to serve as a bondservant: Butas an hired servant, and as a sojourner, he shall be with thee, andshall serve thee unto the year of jubile: And then shall he depart fromthee, both he and his children with him, and shall return unto his ownfamily, and unto the possession of his fathers shall he return. Forthey are my servants, which I brought forth out of the land of Egypt:they shall not be sold as bondmen. Thou shalt not rule over him withrigour; but shalt fear thy God (Lev. 25:39–43).

The theocentric principle is clear: God is the master. He sets theterms for bondservice.

Bondservants

What was a bondservant in Mosaic Israel? The Hebrew words usedin this passage cannot be distinguished by grammar. In verse 39, theHebrew translated as bondservant is ‘abodah. It is used in many waysin the Old Testament, sometimes referring to honorable labor, some-times not. The word is found in the description of Israel’s bondage inEgypt: “And they made their lives bitter with hard bondage, in morter,and in brick, and in all manner of service in the field: all their service,wherein they made them serve, was with rigour” (Ex. 1:14). It is alsoused with respect to priestly service: “This is the service of thefamilies of the sons of Merari, according to all their service, in thetabernacle of the congregation, under the hand of Ithamar the son of

Page 204: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1143

Aaron the priest” (Num. 4:33). It is used to describe work prohibitedon the sabbath or other festival days: “And on the seventh day ye shallhave an holy convocation; ye shall do no servile work” (Num. 28:25).There is no ethical pattern here. The word simply means service.

In Leviticus 25:42–43, another Hebrew word is used, ‘ebed. Thisword is used twice: “For they are my servants, which I brought forthout of the land of Egypt: they shall not be sold as bondmen. Thoushalt not rule over him with rigour; but shalt fear thy God.” The firstsense is honorable; the second is dishonorable. Grammar does not tellus anything that would enable us to distinguish the two legal condi-tions: servants to God vs. slaves to men. Context must determine itsinterpretation. In this respect, both of these Hebrew words – ‘abodahand ‘ebed – are analogous to the Greek word doulos, which is some-times translated slave and other times as servant.

We must therefore turn from grammar to context in our search formeaning. The context of this passage is twofold: poverty and perman-ent slavery. The preceding section in Leviticus 25 deals with zero-interest charitable loans to poor people, either Israelites or residentaliens (vv. 35–38). The succeeding section deals with inter-gener-ational slavery: a legal condition exclusively of non-Israelites (vv.44–46). In between is this section: how to treat a poor Israelite.

Two Forms of Bondservice

In the previous chapter, I argued that the identifying mark of aperson who was morally entitled to consideration for a zero-interestcharitable loan was his willingness to become a bondservant if he didnot repay the debt on schedule. In the sabbatical year, charitable debtsas well as bondservice that resulted from a debtor’s inability to repaya charitable loan (Deut. 15:12) were to be cancelled nationally (Deut.

Page 205: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

33. Gary North, Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Deuteronomy,2nd electronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc.,[1999] 2003), ch. 35.

1144

15:1–7).33 The reason for this was that the two obligations were linkedjudicially. When the legal obligation to repay a charitable loan ceased,so did the obligation to serve as a bondservant for having defaulted ona charitable loan.

Leviticus 25:39 states that an Israelite could be sold into bond-service. He would not automatically go free until the jubilee year. Thesabbath-year release did not apply to him. I call this jubilee bond-service, in contrast to sabbatical bondservice. I argue in this chapterthat both forms of bondservice were likely to have been legal penaltiesfor personal bankruptcy. There was always the threat of debt bondagein Mosaic Israel. The differences between the two forms ofbondservice were the results of two different types of loans: charitablevs. non-charitable. There was a much greater threat of long-termbondage for having defaulted on a non-charitable loan than a chari-table loan. A person entered a business debt contract with open eyes.A poor man who sought a charitable loan was under greater externalconstraints. God imposed reduced risks of servitude on him.

Bondservice as Collateral

A man’s unwillingness to bear the risk of up to six years of bond-service for his failure to repay a loan established the loan as a morallycompulsory, zero-interest, charitable loan. Unless the poor borrowerwas willing to take this risk, he had no moral claim on the lender. Yetit is clear from the text that Israelites could lawfully be sold intoservitude until the next jubilee year. This bondage was a means of debtrepayment. So, if servitude of up to 49 years was possible, why did

Page 206: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1145

the threat of no more than six years of bondservice judicially identifya morally compulsory charitable loan?

The answer is found in the issue of legal access to the inheritance.A man who was so poor that he was willing to risk bondservice untilthe next sabbatical year, but who was unwilling to put up his land ascollateral, had a moral claim on a zero-interest charitable loan. He hada property to return to. He was poor, but he was obviously not sopresent-oriented or risk-oriented that he would use his inheritance ascollateral. His poverty was temporary. He had an inheritance to returnto in the sabbatical year after a period of bondservice. His post-crisisgoal was liberty and dominion: self-government. So, he used his ownpotential servitude as collateral to secure the charitable loan.

The borrower who was willing to use his inheritance as collateralin a business loan, or one who had already leased out his land until thenext jubilee year, was not equally protected by the Mosaic law. Hehad no moral claim on a zero-interest charitable loan. Either this wasa business loan, in which the element of moral obligation was notinvolved, or else the person was economically incompetent: he hadalready leased his inheritance, yet he still wanted a loan. For thisperson, the time limits on bondservice that were offered by the sab-batical year of release were inoperative. He could be placed into bond-service until the next jubilee year.

Access to the inheritance served as the debtor’s sanctuary. If he hadnot leased out his land, or if he had not lost it because he had used itas collateral to secure a non-charity loan that later went bad, he couldnot be placed in bondservice for longer than six years. God remindedthe debtor that retaining possession of his inheritance was veryimportant in God’s eyes. Debtors who were willing to place theirinheritance at risk to secure a business loan, or who had already leasedout their land, were regarded by the Mosaic law as second-classdebtors. They had no moral claim on a zero-interest loan. They also

Page 207: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

1146

did not possess a sanctuary from bondage: they could serve beyondsix years, i.e., until the next jubilee trumpet sounded.

Bondservice and Boundaries

An impoverished Israelite who had been sold into jubilee bond-service was not to be treated as a bondservant by a fellow Israelite;instead, he was to be treated as a hired servant. This passage indicatesthat being a hired servant was preferable to being a bondservant. AnIsraelite was not to compel a fellow Israelite to serve as a bondserv-ant. We need to ask: What was the difference between a bondservantand a hired servant?

There were exclusionary boundaries on hired servants and sojourn-ers that did not apply to bondservants: “There shall no stranger eat ofthe holy thing: a sojourner of the priest, or an hired servant, shall noteat of the holy thing. But if the priest buy any soul with his money, heshall eat of it, and he that is born in his house: they shall eat of hismeat” (Lev. 22:10–11). A sojourner and a hired servant could not eata holy meal with a priest; the priest’s household bondservant could.What was different between the two? The sojourner and hired servantwere not owned, and therefore they could leave the household; thehousehold’s boundary did not restrict them. The slave could not leave;the boundary did restrict him. He therefore had legal access to theritual meal of the priest’s household. He was judicially inside thehousehold’s boundary.

The shared judicial status of sojourners and hired servants inMosaic Israel seems to have been two-fold: first, they could leave thehousehold of the employer; second, in some instances they were uncir-cumcised. We see this in the law of the Passover: it prohibitedstrangers and hired servants from eating, yet it allowed circumcised

Page 208: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1147

strangers to eat.

And the LORD said unto Moses and Aaron, This is the ordinance ofthe passover: There shall no stranger eat thereof: But every man’sservant that is bought for money, when thou hast circumcised him,then shall he eat thereof. A foreigner and an hired servant shall noteat thereof. In one house shall it be eaten; thou shalt not carry forthought of the flesh abroad out of the house; neither shall ye break abone thereof. All the congregation of Israel shall keep it. And when astranger shall sojourn with thee, and will keep the passover to theLORD, let all his males be circumcised, and then let him come nearand keep it; and he shall be as one that is born in the land: for nouncircumcised person shall eat thereof (Ex. 12:43–48).

The defining judicial issue in the Passover law was an individual’scircumcision, not his right of mobility. In contrast, the definition of“sojourner” and “hired servant” applicable to Leviticus 25:40 is basedon the existence of a household boundary. The sojourner and the hiredservant could legally leave the jurisdiction of the household at the endof their voluntary, contractual service. The bondservant could not.The jubilee law did not require the Israelite to treat his impoverishedbrother as an uncircumcised person. It therefore must have requiredthe owner to treat his fellow Israelite as well as he would treat ageographically mobile person. The poor Israelite was to be protected.

Who Were the Poor in Israel?

The poor man had no money or marketable assets except his labor.This is an economic definition. There is no biblical text that revealssuch a definition. It is not suitable as a legal definition. The Mosaiclaw applied to legally identifiable classes of individuals. It prohibited

Page 209: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

1148

certain forms of behavior regarding the treatment of the poor: “thoushalt not.” But there is no economic definition of poverty offered bythe Bible. This case law had a judicial definition rather than aneconomic definition.

A man was defined as legally poor in terms of his willingness to riskbondservice if he defaulted on a charitable loan. Access to one’s in-heritance assured liberation from debt servitude, either in thesabbatical year (where the land was not pledged) or the jubilee year(where the land might be pledged). The jubilee law did not makeeconomic poverty illegal. It did not equalize wealth. It did not equalizeopportunity. What it did was place maximum limits on debt servitude,and therefore maximum limits on debt: six years (zero-interestcharitable loans) and 49 years (interest-bearing business loans). Thejubilee law restricted the discounted market value of a loan collater-alized by a man’s inheritance. In year 50, the land would return tohim. Lenders beware!

There was no guarantee that a plot of ground would be econo-mically valuable through the centuries. The jubilee law made no legalguarantee of anyone’s economic condition. The Bible is not a hand-book of statist wealth redistribution. It is a handbook of covenantalliberty: God’s handbook for man’s redemption, i.e., a transformationof his judicial status in God’s court: from guilty to innocent.

If my explanation of the Mosaic law’s judicial definition of povertyin this case law is correct, then this case law no longer applies underthe New Covenant. The definition was tied to inheritance within thePromised Land. With the annulment of the Promised Land’s specialcovenantal status, this case law’s definition of poverty ceased to bejudicially relevant.

To Buy a Brother

Page 210: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1149

This passage governs the treatment of an Israelite who has beensold to another Israelite. He had to serve the purchaser until the jubi-lee unless his kinsman-redeemer bought him out of bondage. Thismeans that he was not under the protection of the sabbatical year ofrelease (Deut. 15). Why not? Because he was not in his predicamentas a result of his inability to repay a zero-interest charitable loan. Suchloans were cancelled in the sabbatical year. Also, the person who wassold into bondage because of his failure to repay a charitable loan hadto be provided with capital when he departed during the sabbaticalyear: “And when thou sendest him out free from thee, thou shalt notlet him go away empty: Thou shalt furnish him liberally out of thyflock, and out of thy floor, and out of thy winepress: of thatwherewith the LORD thy God hath blessed thee thou shalt give untohim” (Deut. 15:13–14). This is not specified as a requirement here:“And then shall he depart from thee, both he and his children withhim, and shall return unto his own family, and unto the possession ofhis fathers shall he return” (Lev. 25:41). Yet in both cases, the justifi-cation for the law was the former condition of the Israelites in Egypt:“And thou shalt remember that thou wast a bondman in the land ofEgypt, and the LORD thy God redeemed thee: therefore I commandthee this thing to day” (Deut. 15:15). “For they are my servants,which I brought forth out of the land of Egypt: they shall not be soldas bondmen” (Lev. 25:42).

What is the judicial distinction between the two conditions ofhousehold servitude? The Bible is not explicit, but the differenceappears to relate to lawful immediate access to rural land. The poorman in Deuteronomy 15 was to be sent away with sheep, grain, andwine. This indicates that he had a home to return to. The poor man inLeviticus 25 was to be sent back to his land only with his family.Nothing is said of his buyer’s responsibility to provide him with anyeconomic resources. His judicial status as a free man was his primary

Page 211: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

34. Chapter 31.

35. The resident alien did not have to pay him a wage. This law did not apply to the res-ident alien, who was no brother. This gave the resident alien a competitive position in themarket for Israelite servants. He could pay a higher price for the net value of expectedstream of income, since the net was higher: no wage expense. This was not a civil law.Civil laws had to apply equally to all residents (Ex. 12:49). Gary North, Moses andPharaoh: Dominion Religion vs. Power Religion (Tyler, Texas: Institute for ChristianEconomics, 1985), ch. 14.

1150

resource; his landed inheritance was his economic resource; and hisfamily went free with him. This distinguished him from both the poorman who had defaulted on a zero-interest, morally mandatory chari-table loan (Deut. 15:12) and the pagan slave who never departed, andwhose children became the property of the Israelite who had boughthim (Lev. 25:45–46).34

The poor man in Leviticus 25 had already been legally stripped ofimmediate access to his land. Until the jubilee, he became as a poorresident alien in the land. He did not own a home in a walled city. Hewas landless. But this landless condition was economic, not judicial.His judicial status as a free man was guaranteed by his legal claimto his landed inheritance. The jubilee year would reinstate him asowner and legal occupier of his family plot. He had no claim to hisfamily’s land in the present, but he had permanent title. The year ofjubilee guaranteed this. But if he became a bondservant, he forfeitedhis judicial status as a freeman until he was released. He could nolonger respond to a call to be numbered without his master’s permis-sion.

Unlike the foreign slave, who was the property of the family thatbought him or inherited him, the temporarily landless Israelite inbondage had to be paid a wage by his Israelite master.35 At the veryleast, he had to be treated as well as a hired man was treated. Thehired man could walk away from a tyrant. The permanent slave couldnot. So, the master was not allowed to treat his Israelite servant in the

Page 212: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1151

way that he was allowed to treat his permanent heathen slaves. But this distinction between freeman and slave does not explain

why this case law required the owner to treat him as a hired servant.What was the distinguishing mark of the hired servant? Answer: hecould walk away from the household of the man who hired him. Toretain his services, the renter of his labor services had to pay him awage.

Wages

This means that in order to obey this law, an Israelite master musthave had to pay a wage to an Israelite bondservant. The master wasto this extent not an owner but a renter of services. Yet the servanthad been sold into servitude. We must examine the apparent discrep-ancy between these judicial conditions: owner vs. renter; bondservantvs. hired servant.

The wage was crucial to the servant. If saved, it was this money orgoods that would serve as his source of re-capitalization in the year ofjubilee. He did not have to be given anything at the time of hisdeparture in the jubilee year, unlike the land-owning poor Israelitewho had defaulted on a charitable loan (Deut. 15:14–15). He had tobe paid a wage, also unlike the Deuteronomic (sabbatical) bondserv-ant. The jubilee bondservant was under bondage for a much longerperiod than the Deuteronomic bondservant, except in the seventhcycle of sabbatical years that preceded the jubilee. He could amassmore wealth through thrift because he had more years of bondservicein which to save.

This arrangement raises a significant question. If the buyer could gointo the open market and hire an Israelite for a day, or a month, or ayear, why would he buy a full-time hired servant? The latter had to be

Page 213: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

1152

cared for in bad times, whereas a hired servant could be dismissed.The buyer’s expected stream of net income had to reflect the costs offeeding, clothing, and housing the servant, in good times and bad, andalso paying him a wage. Why would anyone bother to buy such aservant? Answer: the buyer was securing a permanent hired workerwho could not legally depart in search of higher wages elsewhere orbetter working conditions elsewhere. What the buyer was securingwas a hired servant who could not be bid away from the buyer’shousehold. The servant could not leave at will. He was placed withina legal boundary: the household of the family that had purchased him.The buyer was buying a stream of labor services until the jubilee. Theservant could not lawfully cut off this stream of service by walkingaway.

Did the owner-renter have to pay the bondservant a wage equal tothat paid to a hired servant? The text is not explicit on this point. Itsays only that the Israelite must be treated as a hired servant. If a hiredservant could leave at any time in response to a better offer, did theowner-renter have to match every offer? This seems unlikely, giventhe status of the bondservant as a member of the household untilredemption. The bondservant gained security; this always comes at aprice. The price of security is the loss of entrepreneurial opportunities– in this case, the future prospects of renting one’s services to anotheremployer. So, the wages paid would have been discounted to compen-sate the owner-renter for the “lifetime (jubilee) employment contract”costs of employing the servant.

The legal option of liberty was always open: buying one’s way outof bondage. But would he do this? This decision depended heavily onthe owner’s treatment. If his wages were high enough, he might dothis. I conclude that wages that would not have enabled a man to buyhis way out of servitude before the jubilee would have been judged astoo low by a church court. But there was another factor that limited

Page 214: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1153

his personal exodus. The jubilee Israelite bondservant had no land toreturn to. He probably would have preferred the security of servitude,given the fact that his wages could accumulate to serve as his capitali-zation in the year of jubilee.

He was protected by law from exploitation. It is not clear whetherthe court with jurisdiction was civil or ecclesiastical. With respect tothe requirement that he pay the servant a wage, it was ecclesiastical.The Bible does not designate the State as an agency that lawfullyimposes positive sanctions. The State protects people from force andfraud by others.

“If He Be Sold Unto Thee”

The passive language indicates that the individual did not sellhimself; he was sold to the buyer. Who would do this? A previousowner? No; the law stipulates that “he shall be with thee, and shallserve thee unto the year of jubile.” He had to be taken care of. He wasnot a commodity to be bought and sold at will. He had been a localresident: “thy brother that dwelleth by thee.” He did not expect to besent away from the neighborhood.

The likelihood is that the man had been sold in order to pay a debt,but not a charitable debt, which would have been governed byDeuteronomy 15. Perhaps he had moved into a walled city to live.Perhaps he got involved in a business transaction that involved debt.The venture failed, and he was sold to pay off the debt. He wouldhave been sold to the highest bidder, but the bidders would have beenrestricted by the market to residents of the walled city or the immed-iate surrounding area, or to someone living in the neighborhood closeto the man’s family plot. These were the people who knew him and hiscapacities. There was not to be a large-scale market for Israelite

Page 215: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

36. Gordon J. Wenham, The Book of Leviticus (Grand Rapids, Michigan: Eerdmans,1979), p. 322.

1154

servants in Israel. Servitude was personal, just as God’s system ofservitude is. Owners were supposed to know something about thosewhom they purchased.

It is possible that the man sold himself to the buyer in order to putaside money for his return to his land. This form of voluntary servi-tude was something like that of the voluntary servant of Deuteronomy15: “And it shall be, if he say unto thee, I will not go away from thee;because he loveth thee and thine house, because he is well with thee;Then thou shalt take an aul, and thrust it through his ear unto thedoor, and he shall be thy servant for ever. And also unto thy maidserv-ant thou shalt do likewise” (Deut. 15:16–17). The difference is thatthe jubilee form of bondservice allowed the servant to return to hisland at the jubilee.

An Exception to the Law: Criminal Trespass

Wenham says that the reason why a man was sold to another wasto pay off a debt.36 I agree. He cites as proof Exodus 22:3, a case lawgoverning a criminal trespass: “The sun be risen upon him, there shallbe blood shed for him; for he should make full restitution; if he havenothing, then he shall be sold for his theft.” I disagree with this prooftext for Leviticus 25:39–43. The reason why I disagree is this: Goddoes not subsidize evil.

A criminal, seeing the approach of the jubilee year, might think tohimself: “If I get away with this crime, I will benefit. If I do not getaway with it, I will not have to remain in another man’s service forvery long. The larger the value of what I steal, the better the risk-

Page 216: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

37. Gary North, Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus (Tyler, Texas: Institutefor Christian Economics, 1990), chaps. 7, 8, 11–14. See also Gary North, Victim’s Rights:The Biblical View of Civil Justice (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1990).

1155

reward ratio is.” The closer to the jubilee year, the better the risk-reward ratio for crimes against property, if Wenham’s interpretationis correct. The criminal’s victim could not expect anything like doublerestitution from the sale of a criminal if the jubilee year was near. Thestream of expected labor services would be cut off by the jubilee.Thus, the sale price of the criminal would be low. If the criminal wasto be liberated at the jubilee, this legal arrangement would not onlysubsidize theft, it would subsidize high-value thefts. The victimswould be penalized because of the liberation aspect of the jubilee year.

My conclusion is that the year of jubilee did not apply to convictedcriminals. Neither did the law mandating owners to treat Israelitebondservants as hired workers. Criminals were sold into slavery inorder to repay their victims and meet God’s judicial requirements. Themost important issue was not the liberation of the criminal; rather, itwas the maximization of the criminal’s selling price, so that the victimwould receive double restitution. The law of God does notdiscriminate against victims of crime in the name of liberation. Theprinciple of victim’s rights lies at the heart of the Bible’s criminaljustice system.37 The criminal must have remained outside the protec-tion of the jubilee, and therefore outside the judicial status of citizen,until he repaid his debt to his victim. He could regain his citizenshiponly when his debt was paid. His adult sons, however, could return tothe family’s land at the time of the jubilee. Their inheritance was notforfeited by their father’s crime, for the sins of the father do nottransfer to his children (Deut. 24:16). As redeemers, they might evenhave paid off his debt.

The biblical warrant for this interpretation is Israel’s experience inthe Babylonian captivity. God removed most of them from the land for

Page 217: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

1156

70 years. They had violated His sabbath year of release and the land’srest for 490 years (II Chron. 36:17, 21). God did not allow them toreturn to their individual patrimonies in the normal jubilee year. Theywere under criminal sanctions, repaying their victim: the land itself.They could not return to their patrimonies until the debt was repaid.They temporarily lost their judicial status as judges in the land.

The Price of Redemption

If my view is correct, then the closer the jubilee year, the larger themarket for buying convicted criminals. As the legal term of serviceshortened for Israelite bondservants, and their market prices droppedaccordingly, those in the market for long-term bondservants wouldhave been forced increasingly to enter the market for heathen slavesand Israelite criminals.

Second, if I am correct about the unique inapplicability of the lawgoverning the treatment of Israelite bondservants, the net return on anIsraelite’s investment in buying a convicted criminal would haveequalled the return available to resident alien purchasers, who werenot under the terms of this law. The price for criminals would havetended to be higher than the price of other Israelite bondservants,assuming that the criminal was not violent. The price-depressingaspects of buying a criminal would have been offset in whole or in partby the higher rate of return: no requirement to pay him a wage. This,too, was a benefit to the criminal’s victim: a higher sale price wasmore likely to assure him of his double restitution payment.

The questions arise: What was the proper redemption price? Howlong would he have to serve? Did he become a lifetime slave? If hiskinsman-redeemer wanted to buy him out of bondage, how much didhe owe the buyer? The prorated price of the jubilee year did not apply

Page 218: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1157

if he was not entitled to go out in the jubilee. Let us consider modern business practice. If a man buys an interest-

paying instrument at face value in order to receive a guaranteedincome, and if the company issuing the bond possesses the right ofredemption, the company must repay the face value of the bond inorder to cancel the debt. The buyer has received guaranteed incomefrom the asset in the meantime.

The economic difference between a bond and a bondservant is thatthe buyer is not sure how much net income the bondservant willproduce. The bond pays a guaranteed rate of return. It is purchasedat a discount from its face value. The discount is based on theprevailing rate of interest. The face value – redemption price – of thebond and today’s rate of interest are known in advance. The price andthe rate of return can be calculated.

There is no guaranteed rate of return for a bondservant. The buyermust estimate the future net income from a bondservant. Then he mustdiscount this by the prevailing rate of interest. The higher theestimated net income, the higher the market price. But how long willhe retain control over the bondservant? Unlike a bond, there is nofixed time period. Unlike a bondservant under the protection of thejubilee, there is no fixed time period. There must be a way to reducethe number of variables, so that the victim gets paid. But how?

The higher the estimated value of the criminal’s productivity as aservant, the higher the price he will bring. This means that a criminalwith a good work ethic is less likely to be able to escape servitude; hisredemption price will be too high. This is contrary to biblical law: asubsidy for evil. There must be a way around this anomaly. But what?

The solution solves both problems: (1) too many variables and (2)the subsidy for evil. His legal redemption price must be limited by thepayment to the victim. The kinsman-redeemer must be allowed to buyhim out of servitude for this payment. If a bidding war pushes the

Page 219: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

1158

criminal’s market price above this maximum restitution payment, whoreceives the extra money? Not the victim; he is not entitled to it. Notthe State; it is not entitled to it. It must go to the criminal’s account– money for his redemption. This puts a ceiling on the market price ofcriminals. A buyer is less likely to continue to bid if he knows that thecriminal can use the money above the restitution payment to shortenhis time of service. The extra money will make it less expensive for theman’s kinsman-redeemer to put up the difference and buy him out ofservitude. Conclusion: the purchase price of a convicted criminal onthe competitive market for bondservants will not be significantlyhigher than the money owed to his victims. When this limit is reached,bidding will tend to cease as bidders drop out. This is as it should be:the punishment (servitude) should be proportional to the crime(damages produced).

But if he has no kinsman-redeemer who is willing to pay off hisdebt, he will remain in bondage forever. He cannot buy his way out.He has no assets and no way to earn any. The message is clear: anenslaved criminal needs a kinsman-redeemer who has both the assetsand the willingness to sacrifice his own interests on behalf of hisrelative.

Holy War, Citizenship, and Liberty

A citizen is a person who has the authority to serve as a civil judge,declaring innocence or guilt. The Israelite bondservant’s judicial statusas a temporary slave removed his judicial status as a citizen. He couldnot serve as a civil judge during his period as a man bound to anotherman’s household. He did remain an Israelite. He did possess post-jubilee title to his land. No text says the following, but my biblical law-immersed intuition tells me that for a man to become a bondservant

Page 220: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

38. North, Tools of Dominion, ch. 32: “Blood Money, Not Head Tax.”

39. My presumption is that David was under age 20 at the time of his confrontation withGoliath. This would explain why his brother regarded him as an observer rather than as awarrior at risk (I Sam. 17:28). David had not paid his redemption blood money. He wasthen authorized by Saul to serve as the army’s representative in battle, but there is nomention of the required payment. This may have been an oversight on Saul’s part, orperhaps Saul paid it for him. We are not told.

1159

was judicially the equivalent of having become a minor. An Israelitehad become a slave in another man’s house, under another’stemporary authority. Judicially, he had become a child.

Citizenship in a holy commonwealth is the legal authority to declareor bring negative civil sanctions in God’s name. The pre-eminentmanifestation of this authority in pre-exilic Israel was service in themilitary: God’s holy army. The army had the task of defending theboundaries of the land, i.e., keeping it holy, secure from foreign invad-ers. The army had to keep the land from being profaned by invaders:boundary violators. To be a member of the army required the paymentof redemption blood money at the time of the numbering of the nationimmediately prior to a holy war (Ex. 30:12–13).38 Circumcised Israel-ite males became eligible to serve at age 20 (Ex. 30: 14).39

The Israelite slave had to treated as “as an hired servant,” the textsays. He had to be paid a wage by his Israelite master. He thereforehad money to pay the redemption blood money to the priests. Did thisgive him the right to serve in the army? No; he was judicially a childeven though he was over age 20. Only with his owner’s permissioncould he serve in the army. He was not a free man; he was not acitizen.

Gentile Slaves

Page 221: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

40. It is one of the most interesting facts about the American Civil War (1861–65) thatin its final months, Southern leaders and generals began to discuss the possibility ofgranting freedom to any Negro slave who was willing to enlist in the Confederate army. Butthe South had gone to war to defend the region’s right to slavery. With this publicdiscussion, the war effort began to collapse. If the slaves could be trusted to defend theConfederacy, then the old myth of their innate status as children in need of supervision hadbeen ludicrous. This called into question the legitimacy of the “peculiar institution” and thewar to defend it. See Richard E. Berringer, et al., Why the South Lost the Civil War(Athens: University of Georgia Press, 1986), ch. 15.

1160

Was a gentile slave who paid his redemption blood money and alsofought for Israel in a holy battle subsequently released from bondage?Abram had fighting men (Gen. 14:14), but they did not receiveautomatic freedom. However, this was before the Abrahamic covenantwas established (Gen. 15). It may be that in pre-exilic Israel, thewillingness of a slave to risk his life in holy battle gained him hisfreedom, though not landed inheritance.40 He became a citizen in awalled city. If nothing else, manumission might have been a bonusoffered to him by his master. This view helps explain the considerablenumber of foreigners listed among David’s 30 mighty men (I Chron.12:3–6). It may also explain the presence in David’s army of the mostfamous foreign officer of all, Uriah the Hittite.

What we do not know is whether these gentile slaves would havebeen required by law to wait until the jubilee year in order to receivetheir freedom. They surely could not have become citizens unless theycontinued to attend Passover, even though, as household slaves, theywould automatically have been circumcised (Gen. 17:11–13).Circumcision was necessary but not sufficient to make an adult malea citizen. Attendance at Passover was mandatory. My view is that theyand their families would have been released immediately after thecessation of military hostilities. This release had nothing to do with thejubilee. The release provisions of the jubilee year were uniquelyassociated with inheritance in the land, and the released gentilebondservant had no inheritance in the land. In any case, his owner

Page 222: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1161

would have had to consent in the first place to his enrollment in God’sholy army.

The same rule governed the Israelite bondservant, whether a bank-rupt or a convicted criminal. His owner had to consent to his militaryservice. The owner may have had to pay his blood money fee for him– certainly this was the case with a criminal. I do not think anybondservant could be called into service by the State unless his ownerconsented. He was not his own man. He was the lawful property ofanother man until his debt was paid.

The Basis of Liberty

As New Covenant people, we have difficulty understanding thedegree of importance associated with landed inheritance under theMosaic economy. The connection between land and inheritance wasextremely close. The question is: Was it unbreakable?

The section on the jubilee ends with these words: “For unto me thechildren of Israel are servants; they are my servants whom I broughtforth out of the land of Egypt: I am the LORD your God” (Lev. 25:55). The legal status of later generations as God’s covenantal bond-servants rested on their ancestors’ historical experience in the days ofMoses: deliverance from bondage in Egypt. It also rested on the nextgeneration’s participation in the conquest of Canaan under Joshua.This participation was the legal foundation of landed inheritance inMosaic Israel. From everything we find in this section of Leviticus,inheritance was the legal foundation of every aspect of the jubilee law.I see no exceptions. Even in the case of the enslavement of heathens(vv. 44–46), the judicial issue was perpetual inheritance, though notlanded inheritance.

This raises a whole series of questions. Commentators rarely ask

Page 223: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

1162

them, let alone answer them. This is why there has been so muchconfusion regarding the jubilee year among conservative evangelicals,and why liberation theologians have gotten away with exegetical mur-der.

Freemanship

First, who was a free man under the Mosaic law? There weredegrees of freedom. Every resident of Israel was free from arbitrarylaw. The same civil law code applied to all men: “One law shall be tohim that is homeborn, and unto the stranger that sojourneth amongyou” (Ex. 12:49). But it is obvious that this principle of equalitybefore the civil law did not apply to the jubilee law. The jubilee madea fundamental distinction between the resident who did not have aninalienable legal claim to landed inheritance and the resident who did.The resident who did have such a claim was identified by God as Hisservant.

There was only one way that someone who had not participated ineither the exodus or the conquest could become God’s servant, sodefined: by adoption. God adopted Abram and his covenantal heirs,but the promised inheritance was not secured until Joshua’s day. Thatis, God’s promise to Abraham was not fulfilled until Joshua’s day.The fulfillment of this promise (Gen. 15:16) was God’s proof inhistory of the reliability of His covenant and its promises. Adoption,promise, and inheritance were linked judicially in the Abrahamiccovenant and the Mosaic Covenant.

Naturalization

Page 224: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

41. On gaps in this genealogy, see North, Tools of Dominion, pp. 149–51.

1163

Second, there were two forms of adoption: into a tribe (walled city)or into a family (rural land). The circumcised resident alien wasoffered the promise of citizenship for his heirs (Deut. 23:3–8): tribaladoption. The tenth-generation heir of a bastard Israelite was offeredcitizenship (Deut. 23:2): access into God’s holy army. The supremeexample was David, the ultimate holy warrior, the tenth-generationheir of Judah and Tamar (Ruth 4:18–22).41

Adoption for males was not automatic, except (probably) for thosewho volunteered for military service during a war. Presumably, threegenerations constituted the standard period of testing for most resi-dent aliens (Deut. 23:8). This adoption must have been made in thename of the congregation, presumably by the local tribal congregationinside a walled city, but not by a specific family. Had citizenship beenavailable only through adoption by a family, the naturalization lawswould have forced a dilution of the landed inheritance of specificfamilies. This would have been a mandatory program of economicdisinheritance. No such program was mandated by the Mosaic law.

Criminals

Third, what about the criminal? The criminal lost his citizenshipuntil the debt was repaid. He could not be numbered to fight in God’sholy army until his debt was repaid; hence, he was not a citizen duringthis period. He was not a free man; hence, he was not a citizen.Having had civil judicial sanctions brought against him, he did notpossess the right to participate as a civil judge, bringing the State’sjudicial sanctions on others. This restriction is not found any text, but

Page 225: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

42. This is the judicial basis of the re-established inheritance of a portion of the sons ofAdam. A son of Adam who was not under the negative sanction of forfeited citizenship hadto break publicly with the crime of His earthly father, thereby reclaiming the inheritanceon behalf of those whom He has chosen to redeem. This was the act of the supremeKinsman-Redeemer, Jesus Christ, the last (second) Adam (I Cor. 15:45).

43. The New Covenant warns us: “The wages of sin is death” (Rom. 3:23). We are inneed of grace from a kinsman-redeemer.

1164

it is inferred by the nature of citizenship: the lawful authority to bringGod’s civil sanctions against lawbreakers. Until the victim was repaid,or the buyer whose purchase had provided the funds was repaid, thejudicial status of the criminal was that of non-citizen.

I argue that he also lost his claim to his family’s land, and thereforelost his right to participate in the jubilee. That is, he did notautomatically return to his land at the jubilee. This legal status did notapply to his adult male children. They could go back to the land at thejubilee if they broke with him publicly regarding his crime. They couldthen become his kinsman redeemers, which is another reason why theywere allowed to return to the family plot. In this sense, he could beadopted by his son or sons. That is, he regained access to his forfeitedinheritance through an act of redemption in his behalf.42 Otherwise,the judicial status of the criminal as an heir in the jubilee was forfeiteduntil his debt was repaid. Because he received no wage, his kinsman-redeemer had buy him out of servitude.43

Possession or Confession?

Another problem case is the adopted immigrant. When an Israeliteadopted an immigrant, he was conveying a kind of manumission tohim: manumission prior to enslavement. The covenantally faithfuladopted person and his heirs could not be lawfully enslaved perm-

Page 226: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

44. Chapter 31.

1165

anently after the adoption except on the same basis that an Israelitecould lose his citizenship and his inheritance, i.e., excommunication.This act of grace cost the adopting family something: the dilution ofthe sons’ economic inheritance. It was a major step for a father withsons to adopt another son, at least in the period in which a few acresmeant something economically to the heirs. This means that if God’scovenantal blessings continued, and families grew large, the economiccost of adoption would decrease, since the economic value of thedilution of acreage would have been minimal.

The circumcised immigrant could become a citizen, or his heirseventually could, through adoption by a tribe, probably in a walledcity, but he had no claim to land distributed at the conquest. Onlyadoption into an Israelite family could provide land. The jubilee yeartherefore offered no unique economic benefit for him. Did it conferany judicial benefit? Yes. The heathen slave law was part of the jubileelaw. The heathen slave law expressly stated that all inheritable slaveshad to be purchased from heathens (Lev. 25:44–45).44 This was themagna carta for the naturalized citizen. By breaking covenantally withheathendom, and by becoming a full citizen ready to serve as a holywarrior, the immigrant received a perpetual grant of manumissionfrom inter-generational servitude. He could not be permanentlyenslaved inside Israel. The jubilee year therefore functioned as a yearof release for every citizen, even those with no inheritable property.

The naturalized citizen could not hope to indebt himself by meansof the collateral of an inheritable plot of land unless an Israelite familyhad adopted him. To this extent, he was less able to gain access to themarket for loans. But with respect to his liberty, he could not lawfullybe enslaved. Leviticus 25 does not say that the landless immigrantcitizen would be released from debt bondage. The language is that of

Page 227: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

45. North, Tools of Dominion, ch. 5.

1166

a return to the family’s land. But because the slave law made it illegalto enslave an Israelite on an inter-generational basis, the jubilee yearof release must have applied to the non-inheriting naturalized citizen.The trumpet announced release from bondage for every Israeliteexcept the criminal.

Cross-Family Adoption

There were three ways out of slavery for gentiles. First, there wasmanumission, either as payment for physical brutality by his owner orthrough voluntary manumission by his owner, but this would notautomatically have freed his family (Ex. 21:2–4).45 Second, there waslegal adoption by his owner. This would have freed his family from thethreat of bondage forever. There was a third way out: adoption byanother Israelite family. This act of grace would have transferred theright of inheritance to him. He and his family would then go out in thejubilee.

This aspect of the Mosaic law is never discussed by the commen-tators, yet it was fundamental to the redeeming work of Jesus Christ.Adoption by one household head could liberate other men’s slaves.In fact, if one man had been willing to divide his sons’ landed inherit-ance to the point of no economic return, he could have freed everyslave in Israel. He would not even have been required to purchase theliberated slaves in order for them to receive their freedom at thejubilee. The moment he adopted them, they would have become heirsof his estate, meaning heirs of his judicial status. They would havebecome citizens of Israel at the next jubilee. No heir of the conquestcould be legally kept in slavery beyond the jubilee year. This act of

Page 228: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1167

universal adoption would have made the liberator very unpopular, aswe can easily imagine, but it was always a legal option under theMosaic covenant. The most likely candidate to do this was a man withabolitionist sentiments and without biological heirs.

Would he have owed the slave owners anything? Only for the timeremaining until the jubilee. This prorated payment would have becomeprogressively smaller as the jubilee year approached. In the year ofjubilee, he would have owed them nothing. There was only oneexception to this rule: the criminal who had been sold into slavery topay his victim. In this case, his owner had to be repaid fully before theslave could be released. The buyer had paid a price based on theamount of restitution the criminal owed to the victim, not the proratedvalue of his services until the jubilee. The criminal was not protectedby the jubilee. God’s law does not subsidize crime. So, in order for theredemption to be secured through adoption, the adopting redeemerwould have had to pay to the owner whatever the owner had paid tothe criminal’s victim.

It is understandable why Israel may never have invoked the jubilee.Had it been honored, almost every slave owner’s investment wouldhave been at risk. All it would have taken to free all the gentile slavesin Israel was for one lawful heir to decide that the per capita economicvalue of his children’s landed inheritance was worth forfeiting for thesake of a single mass adoption.

The Ultimate Adoption

There was such a man. His name was Jesus. He publicly declaredthe judicial intent of His ministry by announcing the availability ofliberation through adoption into His family (Luke 4:18–21). The resultwas predictable: the slave-owners and their accomplices killed Him.

Page 229: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

46. “For where a testament is, there must also of necessity be the death of the testator.For a testament is of force after men are dead: otherwise it is of no strength at all while thetestator liveth” (Heb. 9:16–17).

47. James B. Jordan, “Jubilee, Part 3,” Biblical Chronology, V (April 1993), p. 2.

48. It would not surprise me in heaven to learn that Stephen’s stoning took place on theday of atonement. Christ, the slain Passover lamb, asked God to forgive His executioners(Luke 23:34). Similarly, Stephen’s last words were: “Lord, lay not this sin to their charge”(Acts 7:60). If he was in fact the symbolic purification offering for the day of atonement(Lev. 16), Stephen’s words would have been appropriate, paralleling the words of thesymbolic Passover lamb. As required by the laws of sacrifice governing the day of atone-ment, the Jews killed one goat, Stephen, but the scapegoat, present at the execution, wassoon to wander into the wilderness, bringing the message of liberation to the gentiles: Paul. Lest it be thought that no execution could lawfully take place on the day of atonement,consider Joseph ibn Migash, a Jewish judge who had an informer executed on a day ofatonement that fell on a sabbath. A modern Jewish legal scholar remarks that this action“shows how sacred a duty the elimination of informers was conceived by great judges.”Haim H. Cohn, “Informer,” The Principles of Jewish Law, edited by Menachem Elon(Jerusalem: Keter, [1975?]), col. 508. An informer is defined as “a Jew who denounces afellow-Jew to a non-Jew, and more particularly to non-Jewish authorities, thereby causingactual or potential damage. . . . It is no defense to a charge of informing that the persondenounced is a sinner and wicked, or has caused the informer grief or harm – no informerwill ever have a share in the world to come.” Ibid., col. 507. Immediately preceding his execution, Stephen had publicly charged the Jews withmurder because of their betrayal of Jesus to the Romans. “Which of the prophets have notyour fathers persecuted? and they have slain them which shewed before of the coming ofthe Just One; of whom ye have been now the betrayers and murderers” (Acts 7:52). In otherwords, Stephen charged them with having been informers to the Romans, betraying a fellow

1168

With the death of the Testator came the inheritance: judicialliberation.46 But because of the jubilee law, this deliverance had toawait the blowing of the trumpet at the next jubilee year: on the tenthday of the seventh month, the day of atonement (Lev. 25:9), yomkippur. I agree with James Jordan that this final jubilee year camethree years after the crucifixion, in the same year as the inaugurationof Paul’s ministry to the gentiles.47 On that historic yom kippur, Godreleased from judicial bondage every gentile slave in Israel who hadpublicly professed faith in, and subordination to, the New Covenant’shead of household.48 Because Old Covenant Israel refused to honor

Page 230: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

Jew to the gentiles. This is one reason – I believe the main one – why they took the risk ofbreaking Roman law by executing him themselves without a Roman trial. To have takenhim to the Roman authorities would have constituted an act of informing, therebyconfirming his accusation against them. As historian Michael Grant has written, theyparticipated either in the equivalent of an unauthorized lynching or a deliberately illegalexecution by the Council of Jerusalem. Michael Grant, The Jews in the Roman World (NewYork: Dorset, 1973), p. 116.

49. David Chilton, The Great Tribulation (Ft. Worth, Texas: Dominion Press, 1987).

1169

this adoption, having killed the adopter instead, God destroyed OldCovenant Israel.49

As I said, there was one exception to manumission through outsideadoption: the criminal who had been sold into slavery to repay hisvictim. The adopter would have had to pay the owner’s purchase priceplus anything still owed to the victim. In the case of Jesus Christ, Hemade this supreme payment to the victim, God the Father, who hadplaced all of mankind into servitude because of man’s rebellion in thegarden.

This should end the debate over whether a man needs to profess theLordship of Christ in order to be saved. A regenerate person has nochoice but to profess Christ’s comprehensive lordship. He cannotlawfully partake in the jubilee inheritance without this profession. Butbecause of God’s mercy, this oath can be taken for him representa-tively, either by his parents when they offer him for baptism as aninfant or when he voluntarily consents to baptism after infancy.Whether the oath is verbally professed or not, it is an inescapableaspect of God’s covenant. There is no lawful inheritance apart fromthis subordination to the head of the church. There is therefore noliberation apart from such a confession.

To keep Christian slaves in bondage beyond that final jubilee yearwas a crime. Furthermore, all slaves who claimed Jesus’ universaloffer of adoption into His family after this jubilee year would have tobe released at the next jubilee. But the fall of Jerusalem 37 years after

Page 231: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

50. Chapter 31.

1170

this final jubilee year ended the temple’s Passover system and the landinheritance system established by the Mosaic covenant. There wouldnever again be a God-authorized jubilee. There could be no authorizedblowing of the ram’s horn. Thus, the fall of Jerusalem ended thelegality of Mosaic slavery forever.

Conclusion

The jubilee law established protection for poor Israelites who weresold into servitude. This servitude was mild, requiring the masters topay wages to their Israelite servants. It required them to treat thesepeople as they would treat a hired servant who could leave anemployer who was abusive.

The jubilee law established a legal distinction between a free manand a heathen slave. The pre-exilic heathen slave had no right tojubilee freedom, for he was not eligible for military service. He wasoutside the civil covenant. The legal basis of citizenship was adoption,either by a tribe or a family. A woman was adopted by marriage to anIsraelite, e.g., Rahab and Ruth. This was adoption into a family.Citizenship was automatic with adoption.

Citizenship was possible for male gentile converts to the covenant.This judicial promise was carried out by tribes. This might take as longas 10 generations (Deut. 23:2); it might take as few as three (Deut.23:7–8). Once they became citizens, they could not be permanentlyenslaved (Lev. 25:44–45).50 The heathen slave law served as a magnacarta of liberty for the naturalized immigrant. He could achieve fulllegal status as a citizen despite the fact that he had no inheritance inthe land. Citizenship was by confession, circumcision, and numbering

Page 232: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1171

in the holy army. But it was not granted overnight by a tribe.Jesus Christ was the ultimate Heir, the promised Seed (Gal. 3:16),

the One for whom the Mosaic system of tribal inheritance had beencreated. It was He who announced the jubilee year (Luke 4:18–21).It was He who offered men adoption into His family (John 1:12). Itwas He who paid the debts of the criminals He adopts into His family.Instead of a hole in the ear drilled by an awl at the doorway of anIsraelite’s household (Ex. 21:6), baptism is the new mark of adoption.The New Covenant’s jubilee year of release was the final jubilee forOld Covenant Israel.

Summary

The Hebrew words for “servant” do not reveal a consistent defini-tion; their context determines their meaning.

There were two forms of Israelite bondservice: sabbatical and jubi-lee.

The inheritance served as a sanctuary from bondservice: sabbaticalrelease and jubilee release.

A poor man who offered himself as collateral, but who did notplace his inheritance at risk, had a moral claim on a charitable loan.

A man who placed his inheritance at risk, or who had already leasedit, could wind up as a bondservant until the next jubilee if he defaultedon a business loan.

An impoverished Israelite sold into jubilee bondage was to betreated as a hired servant: paid a wage rather than given capital at theend of the period of service.

The hired servant could leave; the bondservant could not.There is no Mosaic definition of economic poverty.Leviticus 25 identifies poverty for an Israelite as judicial: a

Page 233: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

1172

willingness to be enslaved for default on a charitable, zero-interestloan.

The jubilee constituted restoration of landed inheritance.This inheritance was more judicial than economic: the restoration

of freemanship.Such a definition of poverty no longer applies in the New Coven-

ant.The bondservant of Deuteronomy 15 returned to his land at the

sabbatical year.The bondservant of Leviticus 25 returned to his land only at the

jubilee, unless his kinsman-redeemer bought him out of bondage, orhe bought himself out.

The jubilee bondservant had to be paid a wage.The buyer was securing the services of a servant who could not

legally walk away, but at the wages of a hired servant who could.These wages had to be high enough to enable a man to buy his

freedom before the jubilee.Israelite servants were not to be bought and sold by Israelites as

commodities.The sale into bondage would have been a one-time affair.God does not subsidize evil; hence, a criminal would not have been

released in a jubilee year.The law did not subsidize crime in the years closer to the jubilee.The criminal was outside the protection of the jubilee until he or his

kinsman-redeemer repaid his buyer for his sale, which had paid hisvictim.

When Israel went into captivity, God did not allow them to returnto their land in the next jubilee year: restitution to the land hadprecedence.

The Israelite bondservant lost his citizenship, i.e., his judgeship,until his release.

Page 234: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Promise, Adoption, and Liberty

1173

Citizenship was based on eligibility to serve in God’s holy army.The bondservant was judicially a child: ineligible for military

service.Gentile slaves were probably granted citizenship upon serving in the

army.Their owners had to authorize such service-manumission.A free man in Mosaic Israel was called God’s servant.God’s promise to Abraham regarding the inheritance of Canaan

was fulfilled in Joshua’s day.Citizenship was available to resident aliens.A criminal lost his citizenship until the debt was paid.His citizenship could be restored by payment of his debt by his

adult son: a form of adoption by his son (e.g., Adam and Christ).An inalienable long-term inheritance was a mark of inalienable long-

term freemanship.A heathen slave remained a slave despite being circumcised unless

manumitted by his owners or adopted by an Israelite family.Any Israelite family could liberate anyone else’s heathen slave by

adopting him.He then went free at the jubilee, despite protests from his former

owner.Citizenship legally accompanied this adoption.This adoption would have diluted the economic inheritance of the

other heirs.Every slave owner’s investment was at risk at all times if the jubilee

was honored and if another Israelite was willing to adopt his slave(s).Jesus Christ served as the liberator, for He announced His adoption

of the gentiles, making them citizens of God’s holy commonwealth.This ended the legitimacy of Mosaic slavery forever at the final

Mosaic jubilee.Because Old Covenant Israel rejected this adoption, God disinher-

Page 235: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 30 . . . Leviticus 25:39–43

1174

ited Old Covenant Israel.

Page 236: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1175

31

SLAVES AND FREEMEN

Both thy bondmen, and thy bondmaids, which thou shalt have, shallbe of the heathen that are round about you; of them shall ye buybondmen and bondmaids. Moreover of the children of the strangersthat do sojourn among you, of them shall ye buy, and of their familiesthat are with you, which they begat in your land: and they shall beyour possession. And ye shall take them as an inheritance for yourchildren after you, to inherit them for a possession; they shall beyour bondmen for ever: but over your brethren the children of Israel,ye shall not rule one over another with rigour (Lev. 25:44–46).

The theocentric principle undergirding this law is simple to state,but difficult for modern man to accept: God is the cosmic slavemaster,the holy one who employs the cosmic whip.

Permanent Slaves

The text must be taken literally. First, Israelites could buy slavesfrom other nations. These people were already slaves according to thelaws of their own nations. The Israelites did not make them slaves;they merely changed the slaves’ residence: new boundaries. Second,the Israelites could buy slaves from among strangers residing in theland. But there was no authorization to buy slaves from other Israel-ites. This means that slaves in one Israelite family could not be sold toanother family. They became part of a family’s permanent inheritance.

There is no question about it: Mosaic law legalized inter-genera-tional slavery. If Leviticus 25:44–46 is still binding, then the enslave-ment of those who not part of the covenant by those who are is legalin God’s eyes. Enslaved converts who make a profession of faith after

Page 237: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

1. In some cultures, most notably Islamic, the idea has yet to take deep root.

1176

their enslavement, or the descendants of slaves, would still remainpermanently bound. But no Bible commentator today wants to con-clude such things, unlike almost all commentators, Jews and Chris-tians, up to the 1750’s. The exegetical question facing every Biblecommentator is this: Has this law been explicitly annulled by the NewCovenant? If not, then on what explicitly biblical ethical basis is it nolonger binding?

Modern man rebels against this thought, just as he rebels againstthe thought of an eternal lake of fire: no exit from God’s cosmic tor-ture chamber. Even Christians are squeamish about this. They prefernot to think about its implications. They also do not like to thinkabout the fact that God’s Mosaic law authorized slavery, but it did. Infact, the decline of Western man’s faith in the reality of eternal dam-nation loosely paralleled the decline of his faith in the moral legitimacyof slavery.

Prior to the 1750’s, virtually the whole world believed in the morallegitimacy of slavery. The ideal of abolition came quite late to WesternCivilization, in the era of the Enlightenment.1 Yet it was notEnlightenment rationalists who proposed the idea. It was only with thedecision of a handful of members of the Society of Friends (Quakers)that the ideal of abolition as morally obligatory began to be spread byan identifiable organized group. This began at the Philadelphia YearlyMeeting in 1758. The group agreed to cease doing business withmembers who bought or sold black slaves. In 1761, the LondonYearly Meeting ruled that Quaker slave dealers should be disowned.Professor Davis comments on the remarkable speed with whichslavery fell out of favor after millennia of acceptance:

As late as the 1770s, when the Quaker initiative finally led to a rash of

Page 238: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

2. Ibid., p. 108.

3. Gary North, Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1990), ch. 4.

1177

militant antislavery publications on both sides of the Atlantic, norealistic leader could seriously contemplate the abolition of New Worldslavery – except, on the analogy with European slavery and serfdom,over a span of centuries. Yet in 1807, only thirty-four years after adelegation of British Quakers had failed to persuade the Lord of Tradeto allow Virginia to levy a prohibitive tax on further slave imports,Britain outlawed the African slave trade. Twenty-six years later,Britain emancipated some 780,000 colonial slaves, paying 20 millionpounds compensation to their supposed owners. Only ninety yearsseparated the first, cautious moves of the Philadelphia Quakers fromthe emancipation edicts of France and Denmark (1848), which leftBrazil, Cuba, Surinam, and the southern United States as the onlyimportant slaveholding societies in the New World. It was barely acentury after the founding of the London Society for Effecting theAbolition of the Slave Trade (1787), sixty-one years after the finalabolition of slavery in New York State (1827), that Brazil freed thelast black slaves in the New World. . . . From any historical perspec-tive, this was a stupendous transformation. . . . From the distance ofthe late twentieth century, however, the progress of emancipation fromthe 1780s to the 1880s is one of the most extraordinary events inhistory.2

In Tools of Dominion, I devoted over one hundred pages to adiscussion of the biblical theology of slavery.3 It would be unwise forme to reproduce that chapter here. It was appropriate to include sucha discussion in a book dealing with the case laws of Exodus, becausethe case laws begin with a consideration of the purchase of a slave(Ex. 21:2–6). Slaves on their way out of a generation of servitude andinto freedom would have been interested in a law governing slavery.

Page 239: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

4. Ibid., pp. 140–44.

5. The sabbatical year was honored in the inter-testamental era. In 162 B.C., during hisbrief one-year reign, King Antiochus V (Eupator) “made peace with the people of Bethsura,who abandoned the town, having no more food there to withstand a siege, as it was a sab-batical year when the land was left fallow” (I Macc. 6:49, NEB).

1178

I here reprint part of that chapter, but with modifications noted by thebrackets.

* * * * * * * * * * * * * *

The Economics of Israelite Slavery4

The jubilee land tenure law, when enforced, made it impossible forany family to amass permanently large land holdings. It is usuallyassumed by commentators that the jubilee land law was neverenforced, but this is debatable. The sabbatical year of rest for the landwas clearly not enforced, which was the reason God gave for sendingIsrael into captivity (Jer. 50:34; I Chron. 36:21).5 The jubilee land lawwas tied to the sabbatical year: it was to follow the seventh sabbaticalyear (Lev. 25:8–9). Nevertheless, the repeated unwillingness ofIsraelites to sell their land to those outside the family, most notablyNaboth’s refusal to sell his land to King Ahab (I Ki. 21), indicates thatthe State must have enforced some sort of prohibition against thepermanent sale of a family’s land. Ahab stole Naboth’s inheritance.Jezebel had him accused of blaspheming God and the king (I Ki. 21:13), but this would not have been sufficient to disinherit Naboth’schildren or at least his nearest kinsman. The king had to steal the land(vv. 15–16). What may have taken place was the continuing refusal ofgreedy owners to rest their land one year in seven, but also the insis-tence of heirs that the jubilee year be honored, at least with respect to

Page 240: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

6. Patrick Fairbairn, The Revelation of Law in Scripture (Grand Rapids, Michigan:Zondervan, [1868] 1957), p. 118.

7. The law of diminishing returns applied to labor: too much labor in relation to land.

1179

the redistribution of family land. Both decisions are consistent with theassumption of land hunger in a predominantly agricultural economy.

A family could lease a neighboring piece of property for up to halfa century, but then it reverted to the original family. We know thatlarge families are a sign of God’s covenantal blessing (Ps. 127:3–5).The larger that Israel’s families grew in response to the nation’s cov-enantal faithfulness to God, the smaller each family’s inherited landholding would become. This made it economically impossible for anybranch of a family to amass a large number of heathen slaves duringperiods of God’s covenantal blessings, for it was illegal to amasspermanently the large tracts of land that were necessary for the sup-port of slaves.6

Thus, at the beginning of each jubilee year, when all land holdingsreverted to the heirs of the original land-owners, most [rural] heathenslaves would have been released [or sold] by their owners, whether ornot the law allowed them to retain ownership of them indefinitely.Heathens were allowed to buy homes in walled cities, where thejubilee land laws did not apply (Lev. 25:29–33). Those heathens whoremained in slavery would have been parceled out among inheritingIsraelite children when the heirs returned to their share of the family’straditional lands, thereby reducing the possibility of large-scale slavegang labor. It would also have increased the likelihood of manumis-sion: freedom for slaves whose economic productivity, without largeland holdings, would have dropped sharply. In other words, byreducing Israel’s per capita capital (land), the jubilee land tenure lawwas designed to reduce agricultural labor productivity in Israel.7 Thiswas the whole idea: to encourage covenantal dominion outside the

Page 241: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

1180

land by encouraging Israelite emigration.This economic link between the size of land holdings and the econ-

omic feasibility of large-scale gang slavery is the simplest explanationfor God’s inclusion of the heathen slave laws within the section ofLeviticus that presents the jubilee land tenure laws. One possiblereason why the Bible offers no example of the nation’s honoring of thejubilee land distribution laws is that politically influential owners oflarge slave gangs recognized that the economic value of their slaveholdings would be reduced drastically if they had to return their landto the original families. Thus, any significant increase in the inter-generational slavery of heathens would have testified to a refusal bythe judges to enforce the original jubilee land distribution agreementthat had been agreed to by all the tribes prior to the conquest. Agrowing population of permanent foreign slaves would therefore havebeen a visible warning to Israel that they were disobeying God’s law.This was the same visible warning that God had given to Egypt (Ex.1:12, 20).

Slavery very clearly was not supposed to become a major insti-tution in Israel. The larger the population grew – a promised blessingof God – the more valuable the land would become: increaseddemand. The more expensive the land became, the less would be thereturn from economic rents produced by an investment in slaves. Freelaborers and tenant farmers would compete to work at low wages andlow returns. By lowering the economic return from slaves, this lawwas designed to reduce the demand for slaves.

[There was a way around this limitation: some form of cooperativeagriculture. If family members pooled their rural inheritancesoperationally, allowing a common administrator to employ slaves,larger plots could have been maintained. But the gangs of slaves thatwere common to the American South prior to 1865 were employedonly on large plantations, which could not exist in Israel when the

Page 242: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

8. Evsey D. Domar, “The Causes of Slavery or Serfdom: A Hypothesis,” Journal ofEconomic History, XXX (1970), pp. 18–32.

9. This was an important aspect of the argument by Alfred H. Conrad and John R. Meyerin their classic 1958 article, “The Economics of Slavery in the Antebellum South,” Part III,ibid., reprinted many times. There is not much debate about this: Stanley L. Engerman,“The Effects of Slavery upon the Southern Economy: A Review of the Recent Debate,” inHugh G. J. Aitkin (ed.), Did Slavery Pay? (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1971), pp. 318–20.Both essays are reprinted here, as they are in Robert W. Fogel and Stanley L. Engerman(eds.), The Reinterpretation of American Economic History (New York: Harper & Row,1971).

1181

jubilee was enforced.] Without cheap land, or increasingly productive land, permanentagricultural slavery is unlikely to be maintained long term.8 Undercircumstances of increasing land scarcity, the reasons for holdingslaves would then be more consumption-oriented than production-oriented: slaves as status symbols, i.e., consumer goods rather thanproducer goods.

Because chattel slavery remained profitable in the American Southprior to 1860, there is no need to resort to the thesis of slaves asmerely status symbols. They were status symbols, surely, but theywere also profitable. Where, then, was the South’s cheap land, if thiseconomic thesis is correct? There is evidence that it was the continu-ing development of the fertile lands in the West South Central regionof the South – Alabama to east Texas – that kept slave prices highthroughout the South, since slave owners who owned less fertile landscould profitably export slaves to the region with more fertile lands.9

But if cheap land is basic to profitable slavery, did the slave owners inthe British West Indies suffer losses when land became scarce? Thetentative answer is yes, since it was only when new land could bebrought under cultivation that the Caribbean economies grew. TheGenoveses write: “Thus, as early as the period 1670–90, overproduc-tion plunged the sugar economies of Brazil and the Caribbean into

Page 243: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

10. Elizabeth Fox-Genovese and Eugene D. Genovese, Fruits of Merchant Capital: Slav-ery and Bourgeois Property in the Rise and Expansion of Capitalism (New York: OxfordUniversity Press, 1983), pp. 45–46.

11. Ibid., p. 44.

12. Gary North, Moses and Pharaoh: Dominion Religion vs. Power Religion (Tyler, Tex-as: Institute for Christian Economics, 1985), ch. 1.

1182

crises that ruined both planters and their creditors. The patternrecurred many times. . . . When Caribbean sugar production ran afoulof market gluts, the ensuing crises led to a shift of resources to fresherland in newly developed colonies. Thus, one factor, ‘land,’ aloneaccounted for the regional economy’s ability to survive the periodicpurges of the market generated by the tendency toward overproduc-tion.”10 They conclude: “So long as land remained available at pricesunthinkably low by European standards – so long as colonial settlersfaced empty spaces or spaces that could be emptied by a controlleddose of genocide – resources would be shifted, and the grim waste-fulness of the system as a whole would remain disguised.”11

What we must recognize is that the whole economic thrust of thejubilee land tenure laws, when coupled with God’s promise of popula-tion growth for national obedience, was to push the Israelites out ofthe Promised Land, and therefore outside the geographical boundarieswhere the jubilee land law, including its slave laws, operated. Thejubilee law’s goal was world missions and covenantal dominion, notthe permanent enslavement of heathens inside tiny Israel.12

Neither the Roman Republic nor the Roman Empire, as a pagansociety already in spiritual bondage, came under the terms of thejubilee land tenure law. That law applied to Israel because of thespecific terms of the military spoils system of land distribution thatfamilies had agreed to prior to Israel’s invasion of Canaan (Num. 36).Rome developed the latifundia, the huge family land holdings that

Page 244: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

13. So, for that matter, does corporate ownership of land, either by ecclesiastical or Stateagencies, or by a corporate distribution of share ownership.

14. North, Tools of Dominion, pp. 166–68.

1183

apparently supported the slave gang system. The Roman land tenuresystem may not actually have produced slave gangs, if land holdingswere divided into smaller units within the latifundia. Scholars stilldebate the issue. In any case, a legal order that permits the long-termamassing of inheritable land, and does so through such restrictions oninheritance as primogeniture (eldest son inherits) and entail (theprohibition against the permanent sale of a family’s land), makes econ-omically possible the creation of huge plantations.13 Such permanent,inheritable land holdings, if accompanied by a legal order that permitslifetime slavery, can lead to the creation of slave gangs whenevermarket conditions make gang labor profitable. On the other hand,whenever the legal principle of “all sons inherit” or “all childreninherit” is enforced, it becomes nearly impossible to create anagricultural economy that is based on the widespread family owner-ship of large gangs of slaves. Such was to have been the case inancient Israel, for the eldest son was limited to an inheritance of onlya double portion of his father’s assets (Deut. 21:17). . . .

Slavery and Hell14

The doctrine of perpetual slavery is nothing special when comparedto the doctrine of eternal damnation. In fact, perpetual slavery is aninstitutional testimony to the reality of eternal damnation. It shoulddirect the slave’s attention to the fate of his eternal soul. (It shouldalso direct the master’s attention to the same issue.) Slavery wasdesigned by God to be a means of evangelism in the Old Testament.

Page 245: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

15. Cited by Stanley N. Gundry, Love Them In: The Proclamation Theology of DwightL. Moody (Chicago, 1976), p. 99.

1184

The question can therefore legitimately be raised: Is it a means ofevangelism in New Testament times? For instance, why did Paul sendthe runaway slave Onesimus back to his master Philemon (the Epistleto Philemon)? But anyone who dares raise this obvious question todayfaces the verbal wrath of Christian pietists and antinomianseverywhere, not to mention secular humanists.

Slavery embarrasses Christians, yet earthly slavery can sometimesoffer hope. Eternal slavery is hopelessness incarnate. Eternal slavery– without productivity, without hope of escape, and with perpetualpain – is a good description of hell. Is it any wonder that the doctrineof eternal damnation is de-emphasized in preaching today? Is it anywonder that God is spoken of mostly as a God of love, and seldom asthe God of indescribable eternal wrath? D. L. Moody, the turn-of-the-century American evangelist, set the pattern by generally refusing topreach about hell. He made the preposterous statement that “Terrornever brought a man in yet.”15 That a major evangelist could makesuch a theologically unsupported statement and expect anyone to takehim seriously testifies to the theologically debased state of modernevangelicalism. It has gotten no better since he said it.

Consider the theological implications of Moody’s statement. Godcreated the place of eternal terror. He revealed His plans concerningfinal judgment in the New Testament, unlike the Old, which is verynearly silent concerning the details of the afterlife. If God does notintend that the terror of final judgment bring people to repentance,then hell is exclusively a means of God’s vengeance, for supposedlyit in no way brings anyone to repentance this side of death. Moodywas implicitly arguing that there is no grace attached in history to thedoctrine of hell; therefore, hell must be exclusively a means of

Page 246: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

16. Ray R. Sutton, That You May Prosper: Dominion By Covenant, 2nd ed. (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, [1987] 1992), ch. 4.

17. I have written in greater detail regarding the biblical doctrine of hell in myPublisher’s Epilogue to David Chilton’s book, The Great Tribulation (Ft. Worth:Dominion, 1987).

1185

punishment. But nothing in the creation is exclusively a means ofpunishment for those still living. There is grace to living men in everyact of God and in every biblical doctrine. There is grace attached tothe doctrine of hell; people sometimes do get scared into repentance.Any warning of imminent judgment before God’s final judgment canserve as a means of personal or institutional restoration. All judgmentsin history are simply testimonies to the coming final judgment, andtherefore all of God’s temporal judgments offer both cursing andblessing.16

God punishes deceased covenant-breakers forever, not in order toreform them, but because they refused to be reformed by God’s savinggrace in history. Hell is not a reform school; it is a place of eternalretribution.17 God therefore holds ethical rebels in perpetual slavery.God is in this sense the Cosmic Slaveholder. Rebels beyond the gravedo not work in order to please this Cosmic Slaveholder; they arestripped of the power to work, for labor is an aspect of dominion.They serve Him exclusively as recipients of His incomparable wrath.We may not like the idea, but this is what He says He has done andwill do. No one ever escapes God’s eternal slave system if he departsfrom this life as a moral slave to Satan rather than a moralbondservant to God. There is no “underground railroad” out ofslavery in hell. This is why Christians offer the gospel of salvation torebels against God: to enable them to escape eternal punishment andeternal slavery to the Sovereign Master of the eternal fiery whip.

In history, we are either involuntary slaves to God or voluntarybondservants to God. Both conditions are permanent beyond the

Page 247: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

18. “So likewise ye, when ye shall have done all those things which are commanded you,say, We are unprofitable servants: we have done that which was our duty to do” (Luke 17:10). See Gary North, Treasure and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Luke, 3rdelectronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc., [2000]2005), ch. 41: “Unprofitable Servants.”

19. North, Tools of Dominion, pp. 144–47.

20. Gary North, Liberating Planet Earth: An Introduction to Biblical Blueprints (Ft.Worth, Texas: Dominion Press, 1987).

1186

grave. We either serve Him willingly in history, openly acknowledgingour status as unprofitable servants in His covenantal household,18 orelse beyond this life we will experience perpetual lashes from Hisjudgmental whip as eternal slaves without hope. There is no middleground. There is no alternative scenario. Being a bondservant to Godis the essence of freedom. Being a slave to God is the essence of hell.Choose this day which condition of servitude you prefer. . . .

Jesus’ Annulment of the Jubilee Land Laws19

The fulfillment of the jubilee year by Jesus at the outset of Hisministry (Luke 4:17–21) made plain the liberating aspects of the ruleof Christ in history.20 He announced His ministry with the reading ofIsaiah 61, “to preach delivery of the captives” (Luke 4:18). His inten-tion was clearly the spiritual liberation of His people, and this leads toprogressive maturity in the faith, which in turn is supposed to lead toliberation out of chattel slavery, if offered by the owner (I Cor. 7:21b). We have our “ears pierced” (Deut. 15:17) spiritually by Christ;we become permanent adopted sons of His household. Yet even in thecase of Leviticus 25, God’s goal was always liberation. These paganswere being purchased out of their covenantal slavery to demonicreligion. They were being redeemed (bought back). They were being

Page 248: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

21. David Chilton, The Days of Vengeance: An Exposition of the Book of Revelation (Ft.Worth, Texas: Dominion Press, 1987), and The Great Tribulation.

22. Theodosian Code 9:40:2; cited in Finley, Ancient Slavery and Modern Ideology (NewYork: Viking, 1980), p. 127.

1187

given an opportunity to hear the gospel and see it in operation inhouseholds covenanted to God. They were being given an opportunityto renounce paganism and thereby escape eternal slavery in the lakeof fire.

Obviously, if the legal provision that allowed Israelite families toretain the lifetime services of heathen slaves, as well as to transferownership of the heathens’ children to the Israelites’ children, is sever-ed from the jubilee land tenure law, then the economic possibility ofestablishing slave gangs becomes a reality. The legal restriction againstthe permanent amassing of land disappears. Thus, to argue that thelifetime slave-holding provisions of Leviticus 25 were not an integralpart of the jubilee land tenure system is to argue that the history ofchattel slavery in the West was in principle sanctioned by the Bible. Iam arguing the opposite: the lifetime slave-holding provisions ofLeviticus 25 were an integral aspect of Israel’s jubilee land tenurelaws, and therefore when God annulled the latter, He also annulledthe former. By transferring legal title to His kingdom to the gentileworld (Matt. 21:43), and by visibly annulling Israel’s legal title to theland of Palestine at the time of the fall of Jerusalem in A.D. 70,21 Godthereby also annulled the Israelite land tenure laws. What had been aGod-approved spoils system for a unique historical situation – themilitary conquest of Canaan by Israel – became a dead letter of biblicallaw after the fall of Jerusalem.

Constantine announced in 315 that slaves who had been condemnedto work in the mines or as gladiators were to be branded on the handsor legs, not on the face.22 This act of comparative charity led the

Page 249: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

23. Davis, Slavery and Human Progress, pp. 59–66.

24. Leonard Woods Larabee, Conservatism in Early American History (Ithaca, NewYork: Cornell University Press Great Seal Books, [1948] 1962), pp. 32–36.

25. John W. Reps, Town Planning in Frontier America (Princeton, New Jersey: PrincetonUniversity Press, [1965] 1969), ch. 5; Sumner Chilton Powell, Puritan Village: TheFormation of a New England Town (Garden City, New York: Doubleday Anchor, [1963]1965), chaps. 2, 8, 9; Kenneth A. Lockridge, A New England Town: The First HundredYears (New York: Norton, 1970), pp. 10–13, 70–72.

1188

owners, who had formerly branded their slaves, to have metal collarsput around their slaves’ necks. Clearly, Constantine was noabolitionist. Later legislation under Christian rulers in Rome andByzantium was not noted for any tendency toward abolitionism.

The Christian West did not honor God’s abolition of permanentslavery through Christ’s fulfillment of the jubilee year. The Renais-sance revived the example of the Roman Empire: reinstituting slaveryto farm sugar plantations – a new agricultural development – in thesecond half of the fourteenth century.23 The Western hemisphere’splantations from the fifteenth century onward, and especially theAmerican South in the nineteenth century, made slave gang agricul-ture profitable again. The church did not recognize that God no longerallows His people and those under His civil covenant the legal right toamass slaves and deed them to the next generation.

It was the creation of huge land grants in Virginia especially, butalso in other southern colonies in the United States, from the late sev-enteenth century through the eighteenth, that initially made econom-ically possible North American Negro slavery, with its extensive useof gang labor. The Virginia legislature repeatedly made land grants topolitically favored families of many thousands of acres per family.24 InNew England, the towns did not make such huge land grants. Theymultiplied towns rather than allowing individual families to amasshuge tracts of land.25 Without large plantations, slave gang labor was

Page 250: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

26. Winthrop D. Jordan, White Over Black: American Attitudes Toward the Negro, 1550–1812 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1968), pp. 66–71.

27. Charles M. Andrews, The Colonial Period of American History, 4 vols. (New Haven,Connecticut: Yale University Press, [1936] 1964), II, p. 30.

28. Seymour Drescher, Capitalism and Antislavery: British Mobilization in ComparativePerspective (New York: Oxford University Press, 1987); Christine Bolt and SeymourDrescher (eds.), Anti-Slavery, Religion, and Reform (Hamden, Connecticut: Archon, 1980);David Eltis, Economic Growth and the Ending of the Transatlantic Slave Trade (NewYork: Oxford University Press, 1987); Roger L. Ransom, Conflict and Compromise: ThePolitical Economy of Slavery, Emancipation, and the American Civil War (New York:Cambridge University Press, 1989); Barbara L. Solow (ed.), Slavery and the Rise of theAtlantic System (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1991); Robert William Fogel,Without Consent or Contract: The Rise and Fall of American Slavery (New York: Norton,1989). A week before I completed this chapter, Fogel was awarded half of the one milliondollar 1993 Nobel Prize in economics, which he shared with economic historian DouglasNorth (no relation).

1189

not economically feasible in the New England area. While NewEnglanders were heavily involved in the slave trade as owners of ship-ping facilities and as investors in the sea trade, they were seldomowners of slaves.26 In 1652, Rhode Island actually passed a lawagainst Negro slavery, but there is no evidence that the law was everenforced. Newport, Rhode Island, became the center of the slave tradein the next century.27

* * * * * * * * * * * * * *

The Ethics of Slavery

An Anglo-American economic historian is tempted to dwell on theeconomics of Anglo-American slavery and Anglo-American abolition-ism in relation to Anglo-American capitalism, topics whose scholarlyliterature seems to grow exponentially year by year.28 But the far moreimportant and more lasting question is the relationship between

Page 251: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

29. Forrest G. Wood, The Arrogance of Faith: Christianity and Race in America fromthe Colonial Era to the Twentieth Century (New York: Knopf, 1990). On his self-conscioussecularism, see page xx.

1190

Christianity and slavery, which in the context of the post-medievalWest, is related to the question of Christianity and racism. Here is ablot on the church of Jesus Christ that appears, in retrospect, to be theproduct of an incomparable moral blindness, yet for many centuries itwas not recognized as such by Christianity. Of course, it was also notrecognized to be a blot on Judaism, Islam, or any other major religion.Slavery throughout man’s history was universal until the nineteenthcentury. But because the United States fought a civil war over thequestion of the constitutional legality of abolitionism (1861–65), andalso because the United States was (and remains) the nation in whichProtestant fundamentalism has had the largest representation, the issueof the close connection between Bible-affirming Protestantism andNegro slavery refuses to go away. Forrest G. Wood, a dedicated andself-conscious secular historian and the son of a conservativeProtestant family, has described this Christian racist mentality well: thearrogance of faith.29 What went wrong?

What went wrong, as I argued in Tools of Dominion and also arguehere, was the refusal of Christians to take seriously the full implica-tions of Jesus Christ’s annulment of the jubilee laws (Luke 4). Whenthe jubilee ceased, the only legitimate biblical justification for perm-anent servitude also ceased. But Christians have not taken seriouslyeither the jubilee year or its New Covenant annulment. Those few whodo take it seriously, if only as an ethical model, generally deny that ithas been completely annulled forever. This blindness toward theMosaic law, its context, and its functions led to the near-universalacceptance by the church of the moral legitimacy of slavery.

In 1856, less than a century after the decision of the PhiladelphiaQuakers to place negative economic sanctions on those members of

Page 252: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

30. Thornton Stringfellow, “A Scriptural View of Slavery” (1856), in Slavery Defended:The Views of the Old South, edited by Eric L. McKitrick (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey:Prentice-Hall, 1963), p. 92.

31. Ibid., pp. 92–93.

1191

their fellowship who owned slaves or trafficked in them, Rev. Thorn-ton Stringfellow, a Baptist from Virginia, wrote a widely distributedessay, “A Scriptural View,” in which he appealed to the Bible indefense of slavery. Rev. Stringfellow appealed to Abraham’s owner-ship of servants, Joseph’s enslavement of the Egyptians during thefamine, and Job’s ownership of servants. He also appealed to Levi-ticus 25:45–46. He noted that not one prophet arose in Israel to chal-lenge the legitimacy of involuntary heathen slavery.30 He went on toargue: “It is from God himself; it authorizes that people, to whom hehad become king and law-giver, to purchase men and women as prop-erty; to hold them and their posterity in bondage; and to will them totheir children as a possession forever; and more, it allows foreignslaveholders to settle and live among them; to breed slaves and sellthem.”31

This is correct but misleading. What Leviticus 25 did not authorizewas the breeding of slaves for sale by citizens of the holy common-wealth. When an Israelite household bought a slave, that slave had toremain in the household of that family until he died, or was releasedvoluntarily, or was disfigured through battery by the owner, or wasadopted by another Israelite household. The same was true of theslave’s children. Leviticus 25:44–45 is clear: Israelites could buyslaves only from foreigners, either outside the nation or resident aliensdwelling inside the nation’s borders. Thus, even on the assumptionthat this law was still in force, no one in the American South whoclaimed to be a United States citizen could lawfully appeal to this textto justify breeding slaves for sale.

Page 253: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

32. Ibid., p. 93.

33. Ibid., p. 94.

34. Ibid., pp. 95–97.

35. John Murray, Principles of Conduct: Aspects of Biblical Ethics (Grand Rapids,Michigan: Eerdmans, [1957] 1964), p. 100.

1192

Stringfellow saw that the previous Levitical law, which prohibitedthe Israelites from compelling their fellow Israelites from serving aspermanent bondservants, is proof that the heathen slave could betreated differently under the Mosaic law’s provisions. The Israeliteservant went out in the jubilee.32 Having said this, Strinfellow thenwent to the New Testament: “I affirm then, first, (and no man denies,)that Jesus Christ has not abolished slavery by a prohibitory command:and second, I affirm, he has introduced no new moral principle whichcan work its destruction, under the gospel dispensation; . . .”33 Hereferred to several passages in Peter’s and Paul’s epistles that giverules to servants.34 He ignored Luke 4:18–23.

A hundred and one years later, Professor John Murray of West-minster Theological Seminary wrote this Politically Incorrect state-ment: “But though slavery as the property of one man in the labour ofanother is not intrinsically wrong, it does not follow that we ought toseek to perpetuate slavery. Though the Scripture exercises an elo-quent reserve in refraining from the proscription of the institution, andthough it does not lay down principles which evince its intrinsicwrong, nevertheless the Scripture does encourage and require thepromotion of those conditions which make slavery unnecessary.”35

Lest he be mistaken for a would-be confessor to Simon Legree, hewrote in a footnote: “The thesis that slavery is not intrinsically wrongdoes not in the least justify the ‘gigantic evils’ frequently accompany-ing the institution.” He praised William Wilberforce and his evangeli-

Page 254: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

36. Ibid., p. 101n.

1193

cal Clapham Sect of the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centur-ies.36 But Murray’s exposition is, theologically speaking, a mild-mannered, guarded, but nonetheless unmistakable condemnation ofnineteenth-century abolitionism: the only abolitionism that any Ameri-can remembers. On the question of slavery, Wilberforce was anabsolutist; it was his moral absolutism that attracted his followers andsteeled their will to do political battle in England for over four dec-ades, despite seemingly impervious political resistance. The ClaphamSect would have rejected Murray’s exposition as in principle on theside of the slave holders. Abolitionism’s goal, after all, was abolition.It was not the reform of slavery that Wilberforce called for, but itspermanent, universal abolition by civil law.

Murray did not refer to Leviticus 25. Had he done so, he wouldhave raised a whole series of issues that he was not prepared to dis-cuss in a short chapter on labor. The main issue that he did not chooseto raise was the question of judicial continuity. If slavery has not beenjudicially annulled by the New Testament, then by what judicialstandard should civil judges evaluate the legitimacy or illegitimacy ofany particular instance of permanent slavery? He stated plainly that theabolitionist impulse is not biblical. This question then becomestheologically inescapable: By what standard? By what standard arespecific cases of slavery to be judged?

Murray was skirting the issue, just as several generations of Chris-tian ethicists have skirted it. Prior to the American Civil War, the Cal-vinist scholar Moses Stuart of Andover Seminary in 1835 appealed toLeviticus 25:44–46 as the proof text that refuted the Christian

Page 255: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

37. Robert Bruce Mullin, “Biblical Critics and the Battle Over Slavery,” Journal ofPresbyterian History, LXI (Summer 1983), p. 215. Cf. J. H. Giltner, “Moses Stuart and theSlavery Controversy: A Study in the Failure of Moderation,” Journal of Religious Thought,XVIII (1961), p. 31.

38. Ibid., pp. 216–17.

39. Ibid., p. 220.

40. Ibid., pp. 218–19.

41. Ibid., pp. 221–22.

1194

abolitionists’ claim that slavery is sinful in itself.37 Yet Stuart per-sonally regarded slavery as an institution that should and wouldgradually fade away without legislative pressure. His position wasmorally ambiguous.38 He was not alone in his ambiguity.

During the Civil War, Bibliotheca Sacra, the Andover journal,published three essays by Elijah P. Barrows, whose exegetical strategywas to ignore the Old Testament texts on slavery and then claim thatthe New Testament’s ethic was against it. He moved from the text toan alleged Gospel spirit.39 This was close to the Christian abolitionists’pre-War view. Charles Hodge, the leading conservative Presbyteriantheologian in America, 1825–1877, author of Systematic Theology(1871–72), took an even more neutral position than Stuart’s prior tothe War: slavery as not sinful in itself, but subject to legislativereforms to do away with certain evil aspects of slavery as thenpracticed.40 When the Southern congregations in 1861 seceded fromthe Northern Presbyterian Church, both the Old School and the NewSchool denominations, thereby matching the secession of the Southernstates from the United States, Hodge wrote five Princeton Reviewessays critical of Southern slavery, calling for its abolition, but still herefused to say that the Bible condemns slavery. He appealed to nation-alism instead.41 This theological compromise led to the destruction ofOld School Presbyterianism after its reunion of the pro-abolition New

Page 256: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

42. Gary North, Crossed Fingers: How the Liberals Captured the Presbyterian Church(Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1996), ch. 1.

43. Mullin, p. 222.

1195

School wing in 1869.42 In 1875, biblical higher criticism began toinvade the United States and its theological seminaries. Mullin writesof the Unitarians’ response to the Calvinists’ exegetical ambivalenceon slavery: “Bound by their dogmatic presuppositions and their beliefthat the Bible contained a perfect moral law, they were unable to dealwith the biblical ambivalence towards slavery. The obvious solution. . . was to abandon the belief in the infallibility of Scripture, andinstead to acknowledge the historical relativity of the biblicalrecord.”43

Here is the exegetical problem: if there is unmodified judicialcontinuity between the Mosaic law and today, then there is no bib-lically legitimate justification for the compulsory abolition of chattelslavery. This conclusion would also involve pulling into the NewCovenant era all the other laws governing slavery. The ethicistsshudder at this prospect. Most of them remain prudently silent. Otherssearch for a principle of judicial discontinuity, but they never find it.Why not? Because they do not analyze contextually the only law in theBible that authorizes inter-generational chattel slavery. What is itscontext? The jubilee laws.

The Jubilee Context

It is my contention that the laws governing permanent heathenslaves were an unbreakable part of the jubilee laws. If I am correct,this means that the exegetical case in favor of the annulment of theheathen slave laws rests on the New Testament’s annulment of all of

Page 257: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

1196

the jubilee laws. It is also my contention that if the heathen slave lawsare not subsumed under the jubilee laws, then there is no NewTestament case for the abolition of chattel slavery. On the contrary,abolitionism itself would be anti-biblical, since the Mosaic law clearlyauthorized slavery. Abolitionism’s universal condemnation of slaverywould then go against the Bible’s authorization of a certain type ofinter-generational chattel slavery. Abolitionism would then be sinful,which John Murray refused to write but obviously believed.

There are Christian social analysts today, on the right and the left,who call for the reintroduction of the jubilee laws. The conservativeswant the jubilee’s law regarding debt repudiation, while the liberation-ists want its laws of land redistribution, which they think should beapplied to all forms of privately owned (but never State-owned)property. No one, however, is publicly calling for the restoration ofinter-generational chattel slavery. This is a typical example of smor-gasbord Christianity: “A little of this, a little of that, but not that overthere, certainly; I never touch the stuff.”

The Purpose of the Law

To understand the law of inter-generational heathen slavery, wefirst must understand the purposes of the jubilee law. Its overridingpurpose was judicial: to create an inter-generational link between thefamilies and tribes of the conquest with their heirs, culminating in theadvent of the promised Seed.

Citizenship was by covenant: by circumcision and by participationin the national feasts, especially Passover. But this was not sufficient;household slaves also were circumcised (Gen. 17:12–13) and partici-pated in the Passover (Ex. 12:44). What identified a citizen in Israelwas his eligibility for numbering in the army of Israel. This made him

Page 258: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

1197

a free man, or as citizens are often called, a freeman. Who was elig-ible? Adult circumcised men who were: (1) members in good standingin the church, and (2) not under bondage. This would have includedcircumcised men who lived in walled cities, whether or not theyowned real estate, and heirs of the original families that conqueredCanaan. An inheritance in rural land was a covenant-keeper’sguaranteed legal status as a freeman. He could permanently lose thiscivil status only through ecclesiastical excommunication, i.e., coven-ant-breaking.

The naturalized citizen was no less a citizen. He could not beenslaved even though he had no inheritance in the land. The inheri-tance proved that a man was a citizen, but it was not necessary thatevery citizen have an inheritance. The inheritance was proof of citi-zenship; it was not the only proof. Proof of adoption was equallyvalid.

What this points to is the centrality of the doctrine of adoption inIsrael’s civil order. The doctrine of adoption was placed by Ezekiel’srevelation at the center of Israel’s history. Israel had been adopted byGod as His wife.

Now when I passed by thee, and looked upon thee, behold, thy timewas the time of love; and I spread my skirt over thee, and covered thynakedness: yea, I sware unto thee, and entered into a covenant withthee, saith the Lord GOD, and thou becamest mine. Then washed Ithee with water; yea, I throughly washed away thy blood from thee,and I anointed thee with oil. I clothed thee also with broidered work,and shod thee with badgers’ skin, and I girded thee about with finelinen, and I covered thee with silk. I decked thee also with ornaments,and I put bracelets upon thy hands, and a chain on thy neck. And I puta jewel on thy forehead, and earrings in thine ears, and a beautifulcrown upon thine head. Thus wast thou decked with gold and silver;and thy raiment was of fine linen, and silk, and broidered work; thou

Page 259: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

1198

didst eat fine flour, and honey, and oil: and thou wast exceedingbeautiful, and thou didst prosper into a kingdom. And thy renown wentforth among the heathen for thy beauty: for it was perfect through mycomeliness, which I had put upon thee, saith the Lord GOD (Ezek.16:8–14).

For the convert to Judaism, adoption was the only way into guar-anteed legal status as a free man. This could be family adoption. AnIsraelite family could adopt him and give him a portion of the family’sinheritance. This is why the Jews were furious with Jesus’ gospel ofredemption: it offered full legal status as free men to any personthrough adoption. They understood exactly what He was doinglegally. Paul wrote of his brethren in the flesh: “For I could wish thatmyself were accursed from Christ for my brethren, my kinsmenaccording to the flesh: Who are Israelites; to whom pertaineth theadoption, and the glory, and the covenants, and the giving of the law,and the service of God, and the promises; Whose are the fathers, andof whom as concerning the flesh Christ came, who is over all, Godblessed for ever. Amen” (Rom. 9:3–5). The Jews had been theadopted ones, and now the gentiles would be, too. All of this liber-ating judicial inheritance would come to the gentiles through adoptionby Christ. He was offering them liberation through His redemption.He was buying them out of slavery – slavery to sin above all, but alsoslavery in the broadest sense.

Christians should acknowledge that Jesus Christ was the ultimateabolitionist. He paid the slaves’ ultimate Owner the price required: thesacrifice even to death of a perfectly righteous man. But because thoseredeemed by Christ have been legally adopted, they can never againfall into the ultimate judicial status of servitude: sin and eternaldeath. “And we know that all things work together for good to themthat love God, to them who are the called according to his purpose.For whom he did foreknow, he also did predestinate to be conformed

Page 260: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

1199

to the image of his Son, that he might be the firstborn among manybrethren” (Rom. 8:28–29). The issue is judicial immunity: “Who shalllay any thing to the charge of God’s elect? It is God that justifieth.Who is he that condemneth? It is Christ that died, yea rather, that isrisen again, who is even at the right hand of God, who also makethintercession for us” (Rom. 8:33– 34).

Slavery as a Model of Sin

Heathen residents of Israel could be permanently enslaved to repaytheir debts. The presence of permanent slaves in Israelite householdswas a visible testimony of what it means to be outside the inheritanceof God. Slave status was like a permanent sign in front of a person’seyes: “No Exit.” This was the representative mark of eternal punish-ment. There is no exit for Adam’s heirs apart from adoption into thefamily of God through Jesus Christ, the firstborn Son. The Seed – theculmination of the Abrahamic promise – lawfully inherited the land.Elect gentiles are heirs of this promise. But the focus of this promiseis liberation from sin. Those who trust in the law for their inheritanceare disinherited, replaced by those adopted by grace. This is whyJesus’ message outraged the Jews. Paul spelled out the message in itsjudicial context: promise, inheritance, and seed. He began his discus-sion with the redeemed person’s escape from the imputation ofAdam’s sin.

Blessed is the man to whom the Lord will not impute sin. Cometh thisblessedness then upon the circumcision only, or upon the uncir-cumcision also? for we say that faith was reckoned to Abraham forrighteousness. How was it then reckoned? when he was in circum-cision, or in uncircumcision? Not in circumcision, but in uncir-cumcision. And he received the sign of circumcision, a seal of therighteousness of the faith which he had yet being uncircumcised:

Page 261: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

1200

that he might be the father of all them that believe, though they be notcircumcised; that righteousness might be imputed unto them also: Andthe father of circumcision to them who are not of the circumcisiononly, but who also walk in the steps of that faith of our father law, butAbraham, which he had being yet uncircumcised. For the promise, thathe should be the heir of the world, was not to Abraham, or to his seed,through the righteousness of faith. For if they which are of the lawbe heirs, faith is made void, and the promise made of none effect:Because the law worketh wrath: for where no law is, there is notransgression. Therefore it is of faith, that it might be by grace; to theend the promise might be sure to all the seed; not to that only whichis of the law, but to that also which is of the faith of Abraham; who isthe father of us all, (As it is written, I have made thee a father of manynations,) before him whom he believed, even God, who quickeneth thedead, and calleth those things which be not as though they were. Whoagainst hope believed in hope, that he might become the father of manynations; according to that which was spoken, So shall thy seed be(Rom. 4:8–18).

It was Jesus Christ who sacrificed His lawful inheritance in thePromised Land in order to bring His brethren through adoption intothe family of God. The son of David abandoned His lawful inheritancefor the sake of His elect. In doing this – delivering to them thepromised inheritance – He gave them their irrevocable judicial statusas freemen.

It is worth noting that the judicial precedent for this act wasJoseph’s decision to forfeit his status as the namesake of a tribe ofIsrael for the sake of his Egyptian sons, Ephraim and Manasseh (Gen.48). His father Jacob acquiesced to this transfer of inheritance: thename. Jacob thereby adopted into his household the foreign-born sonsof an Egyptian mother: gentiles. Thus, even prior to the announce-ment regarding the promised Seed, Shiloh (Gen. 49:10), there had

Page 262: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

44. To inherit, the sons of an excommunicated man would have had to renounce theirfather’s act of rebellion. In the case of a man who became a eunuch while in slavery, thelaw is silent regarding his sons. It seems to me that their father’s legal status at the timeof their conception would have been legally determinative. They would have inherited atthe jubilee.

1201

been an adoption by the patriarch which disinherited his son for thesake of this beloved son’s gentile sons. Joseph, the kinsman-redeemerof Israel/Jacob, was the primary redemptive model in the Old Cov-enant for Jesus, the Kinsman-Redeemer of the New Israel in the NewCovenant.

Outraged Slave Owners

This had always been the threat to slave owners in Israel: a manmight adopt another man’s slave as his own son, thereby providinghim with a lawful inheritance. This legal status as an adopted soncould not be taken away except through ecclesiastical excommuni-cation, and even then, his sons would inherit.44 At the sound of thetrumpet in the jubilee year, the adopted slave would go free. It was thesound of the trumpet in the jubilee year that invoked every heir’s legalstatus as a free man.

There was nothing that a slave owner could do to prevent this. Ifa lawful heir to the original conquest was willing to dilute his descend-ants’ economic inheritance, he could share with anyone an undilutedlegal inheritance. The point of the jubilee land law was not that itpromised the heir a guarantee of some sort of economic future.Rather, it identified him and his descendants as free men. This was theultimate form of civil liberation that any foreigner could hope for: tobe an adopted son of a citizen of Israel. This grant of liberation couldbe offered to any slave. But there was no way that the slave could

Page 263: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

1202

purchase this judicial grant of liberty. He had nothing of his own togive in exchange. His liberation was the result of an act of grace onthe part of a head of an Israelite household.

The possibility of “formerly heathen” slave liberation alwaysexisted, but we have no record of any non-Levite who reduced hissons’ economic inheritance for the sake of liberating his own slaves orother men’s slaves through adoption. This indicates that God’scovenant blessing of population growth was not granted for very long,and men clung to their few acres of land in the expectation that it wasreally worth more than the liberation of other men’s slaves.

The slave, of course, could refuse this offer of liberation. He mightprefer bondage to liberation, servitude to inheritance. If you regardthis possibility of refusal as being so unlikely that it must be the spec-ulation of a madman, consider the response of millions of sin-cursedslaves to the message of the gospel. They will not accept Christ’s offerof liberation. They know that there are three conditions attached tothis offer of freeman’s status: acceptance of the adopting man’s name;lifetime subordination to a priesthood; taking personal responsibilityfor one’s actions. So it would have been in Mosaic Israel. First, theadopter would have a bad reputation among slave owners: thedestroyer of the value of the lawful inheritance of slave-owningfamilies. Second, the legal status of a freeman in Israel could be lostthrough excommunication. Third, his economic condition could sinkquite low if he was incompetent.

But wouldn’t a gentile slave have regarded these conditions as mildcompared to lifetime servitude for himself and his heirs? Probably.Then what about an Israelite slave? But how could there have beenany Israelite slaves? Didn’t the jubilee law protect them from slavery?Not if they suffered excommunication and then fell into servitudethrough an economic crisis or some other negative sanction. Thisscenario is exactly what Jesus was threatening the Jews with if they

Page 264: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

45. If there have been others, their observations have not been picked up by the majorcommentators.

1203

rejected His offer of adoption: excommunication, negative sanctions,and slavery. He was the true High Priest who could lawfullyexcommunicate God’s enemies, an authority that He demonstratedwhen He used whips against the money changers in the temple. Didthe Jews heed His warning? Not many did. Did they assent to beingadopted by Him? Not many did. But gentiles did.

Biblical Law: Death and Resurrection

At this point, I ask myself: Could there be any Christian who hasread this far and still not understand what the jubilee law was allabout? Then I ask myself: Why do the commentators emphasize thejubilee law’s economic inheritance and its supposed ramifications,applications, and implications? Why have expositors who are mastersof Hebrew, with years of experience, failed to recognize what is soincredibly obvious that it screams at the reader? The moment anyoneputs three obvious pieces together, he concludes that any predomin-antly economic interpretation of the jubilee is ridiculous. The threepieces are: (1) God’s covenantal blessing of population growth; (2) afixed supply of rural real estate; (3) an ever-shrinking economicinheritance in rural land under the conditions of covenantal blessing.I ask myself: Why has this not been obvious? Why (as far as I know)am I the first expositor who has seen all this?45

The most important factor in exegeting specific Old Testament lawsis a presupposition: the Mosaic law is a coherent system thatculminates in the work of Jesus Christ. Some Mosaic laws wereburied with Him; others were resurrected with Him. Seed laws, food

Page 265: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

46. This is why God required that the Mosaic law be read to the assembled nation oneyear in seven (Deut. 31:10–13).

1204

laws (priestly), and land laws stay buried. They are replaced, respec-tively, by the law of spiritual adoption, the Lord’s Supper, and theworldwide kingdom of God. Once a person understands this simplepreliminary set of hermeneutical rules, it takes only a little imaginationand some attentive Bible reading to make sense of God’s law.

This is not to say that making the real-world applications is easy.This may take a lifetime of study in just one field. But the judicialprinciples are easy to understand, and not very difficult to becomefamiliar with.46

Conclusion

My conclusion in Chapter 4 of Tools of Dominion is my conclusionhere, which I reprint below. I must add here an observation regardingfreemanship. A freeman was eligible to serve in God’s holy army. Aslave was not a freeman. The jubilee law identified freemen: heirs ofthe original conquest. But they were not the only freemen in Israel.Circumcised resident aliens could be adopted by the tribes governingwalled cities and by rural families.

Economically, the jubilee inheritance law, if enforced, would havetended toward the manumission of heathen slaves. The net cost ofowning slaves would have grown high as the size of inherited agri-cultural parcels shrank in response to a growing population. The samewould also have been true in walled cities. Thus, we must regard thejudicial aspect of the heathen slave law as more important than theeconomic: the Mosaic law’s identification of freeman status for land-owning heirs of the conquest, so long as they remained members ofthe ecclesiastical covenant.

Page 266: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

47. North, Tools of Dominion, pp. 203–6.

48. Augustine, City of God, Book 19, Chap. 15. Cf. R. W. Carlyle and A. J. Carlyle, AHistory of Mediaeval Political Theory in the West, 6 vols., 2nd ed. (London: Blackwood,[1927] 1962), I, p. 113.

49. Richard Baxter, A Christian Directory (London: Robert White for Nevil Simmons,1678), Part II, Christian Oeconomicks, p. 71. The first edition appeared in 1673.

1205

When Jesus annulled the jubilee laws, He annulled the heathen slavelaw. He removed the judicial basis for inter-generational slavery. Inthis sense, Jesus was an abolitionist. While it took the church over 17centuries to begin to preach abolition, this legal and moral positionwas nevertheless implied by the abolition of the jubilee law. Whencovenantal freemanship no longer tied in any way to landedinheritance within the boundaries of Israel, but came exclusivelythrough spiritual adoption into God’s family, there was no longer anycovenantal purpose for inter-generational heathen slavery. There wasalso no longer any covenantal purpose for geographical Israel.

As for the economics of the heathen slave law, the Conclusion inTools of Dominion suffices.47

* * * * * * * * * * * * * *

Servitude exists because sin exists and because God’s judgments inhistory and eternity also exist. This was Augustine’s argument amillennium and a half ago, an argument that was old when he offeredit: slavery is one of God’s penal sanctions against sin.48 RichardBaxter warned slave owners in 1673: “If their sin have enslaved themto you, yet Nature made them your equals.”49

Covenant theology teaches that slavery is an inescapable concept.Slavery’s positive model is the indentured servant who buys his wayout of poverty, or who is released in the sabbatical year or jubilee

Page 267: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

1206

year. He learns the skills and worldview of dominion. He becomesself-governed under God, a free man. Slavery becomes a means ofliberation when coupled with biblical ethics. The fundamental issue, asalways, is ethical rather than economic. His ability to buy his way outis indicative of a change in his ethical behavior.

Slavery’s negative model is God’s judgment of covenant-breakersthroughout eternity. He consigns them first to hell and then, at theresurrection, to the lake of fire (Rev. 20:14–15). God places peopleon the whipping block, and then He flogs them forever. Of course,what they actually experience for eternity is far more horrifying thanthe comparatively minor inconvenience of an eternal whip. I am onlyspeaking figuratively of whips; the reality of eternal torment is far, farworse than mere lashes. Thus, the legal right of some people toenslave others under the limits imposed by God’s revealed law isbased on the ultimate legal right of God to impose eternal torment oncovenant-breakers. Biblical servitude is a warning to sinners as wellas a means of liberation.

What I am arguing is simple: it is not chattel slavery as such thatappalls most covenant-breakers and their Christian ideologicalaccomplices; rather, it is the doctrine of eternal punishment. Thedenial of the New Testament doctrine of eternal punishment, above allother denials, is the touchstone of modern humanism. It is thisdoctrine, above all others, that humanists reject. They stand, clenchedfists waving in the air, and shout their defiance to God, “You have noauthority over us!” But He does. They proclaim, “There is no hell!”But there is. And the lake of fire will be even worse.

For all his protests, modern man nevertheless still accepts thelegitimacy of slavery. Humanists understand implicitly that the rightto enslave others is an attribute of God’s sovereignty. They declarethe State as the true God of humanity, and then they proclaim the

Page 268: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

50. Libertarian anarchists are exceptions to this rule, since they do not acknowledge thelegitimacy of the State.

1207

right of the State to enslave men.50 They have created the modernpenal system, with its heavy reliance on imprisonment, yet haverejected the criminal’s obligation to make restitution to the victim.They allow murderers to go free after a few years of imprisonment orincarceration in a mental institution, to murder again, for humanistsare unwilling to allow the State to turn the murderer’s soul over toGod as rapidly as possible, so that God may deal with him eternally.They regard man as the sovereign judge, not God. They have inventedthe slave-master institution of the modern prison, while they havesteadily rejected the legitimacy of capital punishment. Better to letmurderers go free, humanists assert, than to acknowledge covenan-tally and symbolically that the State has a heavenly judge above it, andthat God requires human judges to turn murderers over to Him for Hisimmediate judgment, once the earthly courts have declared them guiltyas charged.

The humanist abolitionist tries to put God in the dock. He tries toput the State on the judgment throne of God. What he hates is theBible, not slavery as such. The question is never slavery vs. no slavery.The question is: Who will be the slave-master, and who will be theslave? Autonomous man wants to put God and His law in bondage.On judgment day, this strategy will be exposed for the covenant-breaking revolution that it has always been. The abolitionists will thenlearn what full-time slavery is all about. It is a lesson that will betaught to them for eternity.

The spiritual heirs of Pharaoh’s Hebrew agents (Ex. 5:20–21) arewith us still. Christians are in spiritual and cultural bondage to thetheology of the power religion, and therefore to the State. They mustprepare for another exodus, meaning they should be prepared toexperience at least a share of the preliminary plagues, just as the

Page 269: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

1208

Israelites of Moses’ day went through the first three out of 10. It isnevertheless time to leave Egypt, leeks and onions notwithstanding.

We must be prepared for numerous objections from Pharaoh’sauthorized and subsidized representatives inside the camp of thefaithful. They owe their positions of influence to Pharaoh and histaskmasters, and they will not give up their authority without aconfrontation. They will complain that their potential liberators are atfault for the increased burdens that Christians suffer (Ex. 5:20–21).They will continue to sing the praises of the welfare State. They willcontinue to sing the praises of tax-supported “neutral” education.They will tell the faithful that humanist slavery is freedom, and biblicalfreedom is barbaric. They will attract many followers within the camp,for there will always be camp followers close by any army. Choosethis day whom you will serve.

Summary

Mosaic law authorized inter-generational slavery.This case law has been annulled by the New Covenant.The Society of Friends (Quakers) were the first to condemn

slavery: the late eighteenth century.The jubilee land law was designed to keep any family from perm-

anently amassing large land holdings.Very large-scale slave holdings were therefore economically

impossible when this law was enforced, even with corporate manage-ment of family farms.

Most heathen slaves would have been released in the jubilee year.The jubilee land law was designed to reduce per capita agricultural

labor productivity in relation to the value of rural land.This encouraged dominion outside the land: emigration.

Page 270: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

1209

The larger the population grew, the more valuable agricultural landin general would have become (though not necessarily tiny parcels).

This would have lowered the return on investments in slaves com-pared to investment capital to increase the output of land.

To maintain agricultural slavery, owners must have access to inex-pensive, productive land.

This was true in the American South and the British West Indies.One goal of the jubilee laws was to push Israelites off the land: into

cities and abroad.This heathen slave law was unique to Israel: part of spoils of the

conquest.Primogeniture (eldest son inherits) and entail (no sale of land)

creates conditions favorable to agricultural slavery.Slavery testified to the reality of eternal slavery.Yet slavery also served as a means of evangelism to the heathen

world.God holds deceased covenant-breakers in eternal slavery.God holds an eternal whip.Jesus annulled the jubilee laws with His ministry of liberation.Christians are adopted sons in God’s household.The inter-generational slave-holding provisions of Leviticus 25

were an aspect of the jubilee land laws.When the land laws ceased to be covenantally mandatory, so did

inter-generational slavery.The transfer of God’s kingdom out of Israel and into the whole

world ended Mosaic Israel’s unique covenantal status.The church did not acknowledge that slavery is illegitimate until the

nineteenth century. Neither did Judaism.Christians in the American South still appealed to the Bible in

defense of slavery in the 1850’s.Without the New Testament annulment of the jubilee laws, slavery

Page 271: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 31 . . . Leviticus 25:44–46

1210

is still authorized by the Bible.Yet there are Christians today who still appeal to the jubilee laws

as models for economic reform.The eschatological purpose of the jubilee law was the creation of

inter-generational family and tribal links from the conquest to thepromised messiah: the Seed.

Citizenship was by military numbering.Those with jubilee ownership in the land were irrevocably citizens

unless subsequently excommunicated.Slaves were never eligible for numbering without permission from

their owners.If a man had an inheritance in the conquest, only excommunication

could threaten his citizenship.Adoption could extend freemanship to all men.Jesus offered gentiles liberation out of slavery through adoption.Jesus Christ was the ultimate abolitionist.Heathen slave status in Israel was analogous to condemnation in

hell: no exit.This is the curse of being outside God’s inheritance.Jesus sacrificed His earthly inheritance for the sake of the inheri-

tance of those whom He would adopt.Christians are judicial freemen: no more slavery to sin.At any time in Mosaic Israel, a man could adopt the slaves belong-

ing to others.The economic burden was a dilution of the economic inheritance of

his sons.The heirs’ judicial inheritance could not be diluted.The slave could legally refuse this offer of adoption.So can slaves of sin today.Excommunication could result in slave status.The Jews were excommunicated by Jesus, the true high priest.

Page 272: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Slaves and Freemen

1211

The Mosaic law is a coherent system that culminates in the ministryof Jesus Christ.

Seed laws, food laws, and land laws were buried with Him in Hiscrucifixion and were not resurrected.

They were replaced by spiritual adoption, the Lord’s Supper, andthe worldwide kingdom of God.

Modern man denies the reality of eternal punishment.He still adopts the theology of slavery.The State is seen as possessing the right to enslave others: to

extract their wealth without their consent or God’s authorization.The prison system is another example: slavery to the State rather

than restitution to victims.Autonomous man wants to put God and His law in bondage.We are seeing a replay of Pharaoh and the Israelites.The welfare State is the new bondage of Egypt.

Page 273: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1212

32

MANDATORY REDEMPTION

UPON PAYMENT

And if a sojourner or stranger wax rich by thee, and thy brother thatdwelleth by him wax poor, and sell himself unto the stranger orsojourner by thee, or to the stock of the stranger’s family: After thathe is sold he may be redeemed again; one of his brethren may redeemhim: Either his uncle, or his uncle’s son, may redeem him, or anythat is nigh of kin unto him of his family may redeem him; or if he beable, he may redeem himself. And he shall reckon with him thatbought him from the year that he was sold to him unto the year ofjubile: and the price of his sale shall be according unto the numberof years, according to the time of an hired servant shall it be withhim. If there be yet many years behind, according unto them he shallgive again the price of his redemption out of the money that he wasbought for. And if there remain but few years unto the year of jubile,then he shall count with him, and according unto his years shall hegive him again the price of his redemption. And as a yearly hiredservant shall he be with him: and the other shall not rule with rigourover him in thy sight. And if he be not redeemed in these years, thenhe shall go out in the year of jubile, both he, and his children withhim. For unto me the children of Israel are servants; they are myservants whom I brought forth out of the land of Egypt: I am theLORD your God (Lev. 25:47–55).

The theocentric meaning of this passage is that deliverance out ofbondage is an act of God’s grace. The central figure in biblicalredemption is the kinsman-redeemer, who in the Mosaic Covenantwas the closest relative to the person who has been sold into bondage.The kinsman-redeemer was also the blood avenger (Num. 35:12).

Page 274: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Mandatory Redemption Upon Payment

1213

Payment and Liberation

The universal redemption of Israelite freemen out of bondage wasto be automatic in the fiftieth year, the jubilee year. On the day ofatonement in the jubilee year, the day on which the ram’s horn sound-ed, no Israelite heir of the original conquest could lawfully be kept inbondage except for criminals and those who, through renunciation ofthe covenant or by excommunication, had lost their judicial status asfreemen.

This law added another way of escape for the Israelite bondservant:redemption by his kinsman-redeemer. The first form of redemption –the jubilee – required no payment to the slave owner; the second did.The first was based on judicial inheritance; the second was based onpersonal grace by the nearest of kin.

Why would anyone have sold himself to a resident alien? Becausehe had finally run out of income. This raises another question: Had healready leased his land to another? I think he had. The sabbatical yearsystem of morally mandatory interest-free charitable loans would haveprotected a person with a farm to return to. Defaulting on this kind ofloan, he would have sold himself to another Israelite to repay it. Histemporary owner then had to care for him and his family, althoughwithout paying him wages, and then was required to give him foodand animals in the sabbatical year (Deut. 15:14–15). This implies thatthe man in year seven owned his own land to return to with his newflock. But the man in Leviticus 25 was in such desperate straits thathe had to sell himself and his family into bondage until the next jubileeyear. He would not be entitled to assets out of his master’s capital atthe end of his term of service. He had become a stranger in the land.This was only permitted by God until a kinsman-redeemer bought himback, or until he could buy his way out of bondage, or until the

Page 275: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 32 . . . Leviticus 25:47–55

1. I use the word slavery to refer to the permanent enslavement of heathens.

1214

jubilee’s trumpet sounded. But the foreigner was under no obligationto pay him a wage. The made the Israelite slave especially helpless.

God’s Designated Agents

The kinsman-redeemer was God’s designated agent of familyredemption. He was the one who had the primary authority to buyback a close relative who had been forced to sell himself intobondservice.1 That someone in his family had been reduced to such adesperate, humiliating act was a mark of family shame. It was such ashameful thing that a kinsman-redeemer would have felt some degreeof moral obligation to make the purchase. But, as we shall see, therewere also economic incentives involved.

An Israelite was supposed to serve God as God’s designated agentin Old Covenant history. If an Israelite fell under the family authorityof a resident alien, this would interfere with his service to God. Acovenant-breaker would become an economic intermediary standingbetween God and the Israelite.

Then why was the resident alien allowed to buy an Israelite?Because he had been economically successful. Verse 47 identifies thenature of his success: “And if a sojourner or stranger wax rich by thee.. . .” His wealth not only enabled him to buy an Israelite; it authorizedhim to do so. The Mosaic law recognized that covenant-breakerssometimes possess skills that are more effective in meeting thedemands of consumers than those possessed by covenant-keepers.These skills may be able to be imitated. By subordinating themselvesto the authority of a rich resident alien, the poor Israelite and membersof his family were placed in an educational relationship under an

Page 276: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Mandatory Redemption Upon Payment

1215

economically productive family. The Mosaic law acknowledged thatit was better to be under the authority of an economically successfulcovenant-breaker than to live a life of economic failure, i.e.,bankruptcy.

This indicates that God wants His people to be economicallyproductive. He was willing to have covenant-keepers subordinatethemselves to covenant-breakers as a means of educating covenant-keepers in the techniques of wealth accumulation. This education wasa positive sanction of bondage.

Consumer Sovereignty

Nothing is said in this passage that would have prohibited anotherIsraelite from buying the poor man. What is affirmed is that the resi-dent alien could also enter the market. He was authorized by God’slaw to become a competitive bidder in the market’s auction for thepoor Israelite’s labor services. This raised the market price of theseservices. Why did God allow this? First, in order to allocate scarcelabor services according to the demand of consumers. Second, inorder to enable the poor Israelite to become a more efficient economicagent of consumers. He had to become the subordinate agent of acovenant-keeper – a rich one. He would have to hew wood and drawwater in a covenant-breaker’s household until the day of his redemp-tion. He would learn from the most aggressive bidder in the localmarket.

The covenant-breaker, acting as the economic agent of consumers,was allowed to purchase the capitalized labor services of covenant-keepers in order to meet the demands of consumers. The scarceeconomic resource of labor would then be channeled into goods andservices that were demanded by consumers. What this means is that

Page 277: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 32 . . . Leviticus 25:47–55

2. Chapter 30.

1216

preserving consumer sovereignty (authority) in Israel was morefundamental in God’s law than preserving freeman legal status ofbankrupt Israelites, at least until redemption took place or the jubilee’strumpet sounded. In this case, that which served consumers mostefficiently was authorized by God’s law. A bankrupt Israelite’s legalstatus as a freeman was not to defended, free of charge, at the expenseof the consumer.

The kinsman-redeemer could lawfully buy back the servant’s legalstatus as a freeman, but this involved a risk on his part. He wouldprobably have had to take over the care of the man and his family, forthey had no land to return to. Freemanship was not a free gift to alandless Israelite until the day of jubilee. Someone had to pay: thekinsman-redeemer.

A man in bondage retained the right to buy his freedom: “. . . or ifhe be able, he may redeem himself.” Where would he get the moneyto redeem himself? Probably from an inheritance. A relative died andleft him the purchase price of his redemption.

A Stronger Competitor

The resident alien had no obligation to pay a wage to an Israelitewho had been sold into bondage. In contrast, the Israelite who pur-chased another Israelite had to pay a wage (Lev. 25:39–40).2 In bothcases, the bondservant would go free in the jubilee year. Since thebuyer was buying an expected stream of net income until the jubilee,which buyer could expect a larger stream of net income? Presumably,the resident alien. He did not have to pay a wage; the Israelite buyerdid.

Page 278: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Mandatory Redemption Upon Payment

3. Once the auction price of the bondservant matched the debt he owed, any additionalmoney raised by the bidding process went to the bondservant. This would have placed aloose cap on the bidding, since the additional money could be used by the bondservant tobuy his way to freedom. The buyer was then subsidizing a reduced return on hisinvestment: a shorter term of service.

1217

The resident alien was in a stronger bidding position than an Israel-ite buyer, but the Israelite might decide to outbid the alien in order toavoid the shame in Israel of the sale of an Israelite to a resident alien.Altruism and religious pride have limits, however; at some price, theIsraelite bidders would have dropped out of the auction. This meansthat those Israelites who defaulted on the largest sums would havebeen most likely to serve in the households of resident aliens. Theresident alien could better afford to bid a higher price for purchasinga debtor.3 Also, in the jubilee year, the Israelite departed withoutcapital from the household of a resident alien. Had he been under theauthority of an Israelite, he could have saved his wages. Conclusion:the more money a man owed, the more likely that only a resident aliencould afford to buy him to discharge the man’s debt. It was thereforebetter to owe less money than more money, in the hope that anIsraelite would buy you in a crisis, out of charity. Charity has limits.

The greater the man’s debt had been, the longer his years of servi-tude. This system of bondage was therefore a model of hell. Greaterdebts resulted in more burdensome servitude. “And that servant,which knew his lord’s will, and prepared not himself, neither didaccording to his will, shall be beaten with many stripes. But he thatknew not, and did commit things worthy of stripes, shall be beatenwith few stripes. For unto whomsoever much is given, of him shall bemuch required: and to whom men have committed much, of him theywill ask the more” (Luke 12:47–48). The difference was this: Israelhad the jubilee year for those Israelites who were heirs of the conquestand who were still members of the ecclesiastical covenant. Hell has no

Page 279: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 32 . . . Leviticus 25:47–55

1218

jubilee year of release. There is no longer a jubilee year. Jesus Christ,the cosmic Kinsman-Redeemer, abolished it: definitively (Luke4:18–21), progressively (through the adoption of gentiles: Paul’sministry), and finally (A.D. 70). Apart from His redemption, there isno escape from eternal servitude.

This means that the greater the debt, the more money the kinsman-redeemer would be required to pay to redeem his relative, or else thelonger the man would have remained in bondage. The greater thedebt, the greater the price of redemption; the greater the debt, thegreater the grace of redemption.

A New Master

The Israelite who had been purchased from a resident alien wassubsequently to be treated by his relative as a hired servant. He wasto be paid a wage: “And as a yearly hired servant shall he be with him:and the other shall not rule with rigour over him in thy sight” (v. 53).This means that the kinsman-redeemer was leasing his relative’s laborservices, not simply liberating him. The poor man had no land toreturn to. Until the jubilee year came, he was tied to the kinsman-redeemer unless the latter voluntarily released him.

Then why buy him at all? First, to overcome the shame of thefamily: to liberate a brother from bondage in the household of aforeigner. Second, to keep the resident alien from profiting at theexpense of an unpaid Israelite servant. If the price of labor had risensince the day that the stranger bought the man, the resident alien wasreaping an entrepreneurial profit. The unexpected rise in the value oflabor services was being pocketed by the foreigner. The jubilee lawauthorized the kinsman-redeemer to buy the future labor services ofhis relative, which would run out at the next jubilee. He paid the

Page 280: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Mandatory Redemption Upon Payment

4. Prior to widespread computerization of inventories in the 1980’s, and prior to FederalExpress and other overnight delivery private mail firms, inventories in American businesswere larger. The “just in time” techniques of computerized production did not exist, orexisted only in a few firms.

5. If no one needed cash in reserve, there would be no cash; its value would fall to zero.Transactions would be by barter only. We cannot really imagine such a money-less world,for it is a world of man’s omniscience, which is neither possible nor conceivable (Deut.29:29). This is a major problem for economic theory, which assumes omniscience in thecreation of such theoretical constructs as equilibrium.

1219

original purchase price minus the years already served. The value ofthese labor services was higher than when the alien purchased theIsraelite, but the purchase price per year of servitude remaining wasfixed by the jubilee law. The kinsman-redeemer was in a position tore-claim from the alien all remaining entrepreneurial profits in anagricultural venture, should they continue. The tithe on these profitswould then revert to the Levites.

The kinsman-redeemer would have had to pay his kinsman a wage.This leads us to the third point: the presence of an economic return.What was the nature of this return? The kinsman-redeemer couldalways hire labor services on a piece-rate basis. Why, economicallyspeaking, would he commit himself to buying an Israelite, who wouldbe owed a wage? Answer: to reduce his risk. The kinsman-redeemermight buy his relative for the same reason that producers buy goodsto put into an inventory. If a producer has very little time to getdelivery of the particular resource input, he has to pay a higher priceto buy it “off the shelf” – some seller’s shelf. Instead, he puts it on hisown shelf.4 Keeping an inventory is a substitute for knowing the futureperfectly, just as holding cash is. If we knew the future perfectly, wecould time production and sales so well that we would need neitherinventories nor cash in reserve.5

By purchasing his kinsman out of bondage, the kinsman-redeemerwould have secured a permanent employee for himself until the jubilee

Page 281: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 32 . . . Leviticus 25:47–55

1220

year. The relative was still a bondservant who was not allowed towalk away. He was legally tied to the household of his redeemer untilhe could afford to redeem himself or the jubilee came. But he was atleast out from under the authority of a resident alien. He wouldhenceforth receive a wage. He was better off.

The kinsman-redeemer could buy his relative out of bondage at aprice commensurate with the years remaining until the jubilee: a pro-rated price that dropped as the jubilee approached (v. 50). When thealien paid for the Israelite, the redemption price was locked in by civillaw. The alien could not readily sell the capitalized services of theIsraelite to the highest bidder, who probably would have been anotherresident alien. The price paid by the original purchaser established themaximum price that a kinsman had to pay to redeem his relative, andthis price steadily dropped as the jubilee year approached. It is unlikelythat any subsequent buyer would pay the original purchaser more thanthe redeemer’s price, for he would have risked seeing the kinsman-redeemer buy the man out of bondage at a price based on the originalowner’s purchase price. It was legal for a resident alien to buy anIsraelite servant, but the jubilee law placed limits on this market.

Capitalized Value

The terms of redemption were the same for Israelite bondservantsas for rural land (Lev. 25:14–16). It was a prorated redemption: theredeemer had to pay only for the time remaining before the jubilee.This means that the purchase price would be averaged on an annual-ized basis: from the time of purchase to the jubilee.

This means that the original buyer took a risk. If he “bought low,”when the expected value of the land’s output or the servant’s outputwas low, on the assumption that prices for these services would rise,

Page 282: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Mandatory Redemption Upon Payment

1221

he could lose his entrepreneurial profit if a redeemer came to claim hisright of purchase. The original buyer would be repaid whatever wasowed to him based on the original purchase price, not on the new,higher value of the expected stream of services. On the other hand, ifhe “bought high,” when the expected returns were high, and then thevalue of the services fell, the land or bondservant would be less likelyto be redeemed, since the redeemer would have to pay a proratedprice based on the original purchase price, which was high. Thismeans that the original buyer was more likely to suffer losses thanenjoy profits if the market value of the expected stream of serviceschanged.

This was even more true of land redemptions. The kinsman-redeemer could re-purchase his kinsman’s land from a buyer at a fixedprice: whatever the buyer had paid prorated according to the yearsremaining till the jubilee. He had no wages to pay. When he bought arelative out of bondage, he had to pay him a wage. Not so with land.

What is clear is that the purchase of either rural land in Israel or anIsraelite bondservant was a lease agreement. Because of the jubileeyear’s limits on both rural land transfers and Israelite servitude, thiswas not a purchase; it was a lease. It was a not a lease with an optionto buy; it was a lease in which an outsider – the kinsman-redeemer –had the option to redeem the lease. The lease was a rental arrange-ment in which the redeemer could interrupt the long-term rental agree-ment by making a prorated payment to the lessor. God was the ownerof the land and the Israelites; He set the terms of trade. This pricesystem would have restricted the market for Israelite bondservants andrural land.

Utopian Populists

Page 283: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 32 . . . Leviticus 25:47–55

6. Keynes wrote that “a properly run community . . . ought to be able to bring down themarginal efficiency of capital in equilibrium approximately to zero within a singlegeneration; . . .” Keynes, The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money (NewYork: Macmillan, 1936), p. 220. If the marginal efficiency of capital is zero, then the priceof capital has to be zero, since the value of any asset’s output under equilibrium conditionsis equal to the value of the final (marginal) unit produced, which in his example is zero.Zero multiplied by anything is zero.

7. Calvin Elliott, Usury: A Scriptural, Ethical and Economic View (Middlesburg, Ohio:Anti-Usury League, 1902); C. F. Parker, Moses the Economist (London: Covenant, 1947),pp. 55–60. For “usury” defined as “interest which is higher than is requisite,” see J. TaylorPeddie, The Economic Mechanism of Scripture: The Cure for the World Crises (London:Williams & Norgate, 1934), p. 156. For a critique of the Social Credit movement’ssuggested reform, the abolition of private banking and interest-bearing loans, see GaryNorth, Salvation Through Inflation: The Economics of Social Credit (Tyler, Texas:Institute for Christian Economics, 1993).

1222

On the fringe of many political movements, both right wing and leftwing, are populist utopians who claim that a world without interest onbusiness loans is both morally obligatory and economically possible.This is the economic equivalent of claiming that perpetual motion ispossible in this world. It is rarely pointed out that this was the positionpromoted by John Maynard Keynes, the most influential economist inthe world in the second half of the twentieth century.6 Because of themedieval commentators’ confusion over interest from business loans(biblically valid) and interest from charity loans to fellow believers(biblically prohibited), they prohibited all interest, which they regardedas a single phenomenon. This religious tradition has led manysubsequent monetary cranks – Protestants, Catholics, and cultists – toclaim that their position is biblical.7 Let me point out one more timethat those people who preach the ideal of a world of zero interestrates cannot defend their system biblically.

Rent is the economic return produced by some scarce resource overa specified time period. The resource may be land, but it could also belabor. What is the present value of this stream of income? We cannotknow until we know the rate of interest: the time discount applied by

Page 284: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Mandatory Redemption Upon Payment

8. Chapter 26, subsection on “Interest and Rent.”

9. S. C. Mooney, a defender of interest-free business loans, is one of the few populistswho have understood this. He insists that “it is not lawful for one to sell the use of hisproperty (rent).” S. C. Mooney, Usury: Destroyer of Nations (Warsaw, Ohio: Theopolis,1988), p. 173.

10. Mooney refused to comment in his book on Leviticus 25:25–28 and 25:47–51. For acritique of Mr. Mooney, see Gary North, Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus(Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1990), Appendix G: “Lots of Free Time:The Existentialist Utopia of S. C. Mooney.”

1223

economic actors to all streams of income. The origin of interest ishuman action: time preference. Rents will, through competition, tendto equal the rate of interest.8 Thus, the defender of a zero-interesteconomic system must, if he follows the logic of his system, deny themoral legitimacy of all rental contracts. (There are very few populistanalysts who have understood this implication of their system.)9 Butthis section of Leviticus clearly affirms the legitimacy of such rentalcontracts. This poses an insolvable theoretical problem for thosepeople who argue that, biblically speaking, rental contracts areillegitimate. They deal with this problem by ignoring it.10

On the Fringe of a Movement

The populist, being a fringe figure, appeals to people on the fringeof a movement who are ideologically committed but untrained in eco-nomic reasoning. They have a taste for ideas that are outrageous andeven bizarre. They are tempted to push beyond the ideological limitsof the movement to which they are loosely attached. If somethingsounds new, unique, or controversial, they have a tendency to believeit. There are many such ideas in life that deserve a hearing, despite theopposition of establishments. There are establishments in life; indeed,

Page 285: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 32 . . . Leviticus 25:47–55

11. Thomas Kuhn, The Structure of Scientific Revolutions (University of Chicago Press,1962).

12. Henry Hazlitt, Economics in One Lesson (Norwalk, Connecticut: Arlington House,[1946] 1979), p. 15.

13. Ibid., p. 17.

1224

scholarship and science are impossible without establishments. Theseestablishments do suppress the public discussion of certain ideas.11 Butevery anti-establishment hypothesis must be examined very carefullyin order to determine whether it makes sense logically and alsocorresponds to the data it seeks to explain. Fringe ideas must betested. Those who gravitate toward them are rarely able to do the nec-essary testing. They are true believers, not careful scholars.

Economic analysis involves long chains of reasoning. A recom-mended policy must be analyzed in terms of its effects, as they spreadthrough the economy. Few people are equipped intellectually or bytraining to examine long chains of reasoning. Therefore, as Hazlittsays in the opening sentence of Chapter 1 of Economics in OneLesson, “Economics is haunted by more fallacies than any other studyknown to man.”12 He then explains why this is the case: “The art ofeconomics consists in looking not merely at the immediate but at thelonger effects of any act or policy; it consists in tracing the conse-quences of that policy not merely for one group but for all groups.Nine-tenths of the economic fallacies that are working such dreadfulharm in the world today are the result of ignoring this lesson.”13

Crackpot economics always breaks this chain of reasoning.People who are attracted to populism do not understand that when

some writer denies the legitimacy of interest from business loans, heis also denying the legitimacy of the economic category known asrent. They do not understand that anyone who denies the legitimacyof interest and rent then must explain how a world without interest

Page 286: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Mandatory Redemption Upon Payment

14. North, Salvation Through Inflation.

1225

would operate. They take the populist’s word on faith. Commitmentto crackpot economics can easily become a substitute for orthodoxreligion,14 or at least a false corollary to orthodox religion.

I will say it one more time: economics becomes crackpot when itclaims that the economic world can operate apart from a rate ofinterest. It is crackpot to the same degree that physics becomes crack-pot when it affirms the possibility of perpetual motion.

The Unity of Economics

The phenomenon of interest affects every aspect of economictheory and practice. It is the discount that every rational person placeson future goods as against present goods: the free gift of a Rolls-Royce automobile delivered next year vs. the Rolls Royce deliveredthis afternoon. Better sooner than later, other things being equal. Theanti-interest utopian therefore has an intellectual and moral obligationto reconstruct all of economic theory in terms of his radical hypothe-sis. No one has ever done this, in the millennia in which anti-interesthypotheses have been offered, from Aristotle to the present.

When Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk’s monumental History and Cri-tique of Interest Theories was published in 1884, he understood thatall of capital theory had to be reconstructed in terms of his theory ofinterest as a discount of future goods as against present goods. Hethen wrote The Positive Theory of Capital, equally monumental,which appeared in 1889. Then he spent years writing Further Essayson Capital and Interest, a book defending the first two volumes.Certain problems in Böhm-Bawerk’s theory led his student Ludwigvon Mises to write Theory of Money and Credit, published in 1912.

Page 287: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 32 . . . Leviticus 25:47–55

1226

From there, Mises went on to write Socialism (1922) and HumanAction (1949), each book extending his theory of capital, interest, andmoney. The point is, you cannot legitimately announce that an econ-omy can and should operate without interest payments on businessloans and leave it at that. Yet this is what the populist utopians do.

Conclusion

The jubilee was the year of redemption in Israel. It reunited judi-cially the dispossessed Israelite and his landed inheritance. Themaximum time limit placed by God’s law on Israelite bondservice wastherefore the same as the limit on the leasing of rural property: thenext jubilee year.

The possibility of immediate redemption was available in bothcases: land and labor. The kinsman-redeemer could buy his relativeout of bondage by making a prorated payment to the buyer based onthe original purchase price. This payment was based on the yearsremaining until the jubilee: the original purchase price divided by thenumber of years until the jubilee multiplied by the number of yearsremaining.

The presence of this law in the Mosaic law indicates how importantthe ideal of consumer sovereignty (authority) is in God’s eyes. AnIsraelite who found himself in dire straits economically could lawfullysell himself to a resident alien. The economic success of the residentalien was legitimate. He had met the demands of consumers. TheIsraelite had failed to meet the demands of consumers. The residentalien was authorized to buy the Israelite until the next jubilee year. Soimportant were the twin ideals of efficiency and profit that God waswilling to see some of His people in temporary bondage to covenant-breakers within the boundaries of the Promised Land. Perhaps these

Page 288: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Mandatory Redemption Upon Payment

15. Gary North, Treasure and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Luke, 2nd elec-tronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, [2000] 2003), ch.6.

1227

less efficient Israelites would learn to become more efficientproducers, thereby improving the options available to consumers.

Because the resident alien did not have to pay a wage to an Israelitebondservant, while Israelites were required to pay him a wage, thislaw gave a competitive advantage to the resident alien in the marketfor Israelite bondservants. It made it clear what the consequence ofbankruptcy was likely to be: long-term bondage to covenant-breakers.

What was illegal for an Israelite – the refusal to pay a wage to hisIsraelite bondservant – was not illegal for resident aliens. Why not?Because bondage to resident aliens was a model of hell: the wrath ofGod. It served as a reminder to the Israelites of their need for a kins-man-redeemer. They were all in debt to God. They could not affordto buy their way out of Adam’s bondage. Only God’s grace of the ful-filled jubilee offered the nation long-term hope, and only God’s gracein the interim as their kinsman-redeemer offered short-term hope.God’s designated Kinsman-Redeemer is Jesus Christ, who announcedthe fulfillment of the jubilee principle when He began his publicprophetic ministry (Luke 4:18–21).15

This law rested on a required wage payment, but there were nospecifics regarding the amount of the wage. This made law enforce-ment difficult for the magistrates, and therefore also made legalpredictability difficult for Israelite masters. I conclude that this lawwas enforced by the Levites, not the civil magistrate. They would havehad more leeway in working out equitable arrangements with themasters. This law did not prohibit an evil act, i.e., the legitimate func-tion of civil government. It mandated positive sanctions, and only forIsraelite masters. It therefore discriminated economically againstIsraelite masters. But Mosaic civil law was to be equal for all (Ex. 12:

Page 289: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 32 . . . Leviticus 25:47–55

16. Gary North, Moses and Pharaoh: Dominion Religion vs. Power Religion (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1985), ch. 14.

1228

49).16 So, this must have been an ecclesiastical law.

Summary

The jubilee year was the year of universal redemption for freemen.This law authorized the kinsman-redeemer to redeem his kin out of

bondage before the jubilee year.Anyone who sold himself to a resident alien, or who was sold to

one, probably had no immediate access to his family’s landed inheri-tance.

This forced sale was shameful for his family and near kinsmen.Being under the lawful jurisdiction of a resident alien interfered

with covenantal dominion.A covenant-breaker thereby became a lawful intermediary standing

between God and an Israelite family.This situation was permitted by God in order to reward economic-

ally productive people – the rich – and penalize the unproductive: thepoor.

The poor Israelite was expected to learn from the rich alien: betterthis than continued low productivity.

Economic education was a positive sanction of bondservice.The alien’s presence in the market for bondservants allocated labor

services according to market demand.The alien represented the consumers economically.This preserved consumer sovereignty in Mosaic Israel.This was more important than preserving the legal status of bank-

rupt Israelites.

Page 290: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Mandatory Redemption Upon Payment

1229

The resident alien did not have a legal obligation to pay wages toIsraelite bondservants; an Israelite owner did (Lev. 25:39–40).

The resident alien therefore had a competitive market advantage inthe market for bondservants.

The larger a man’s defaulted debt, the longer the term of bondserv-ice.

Bondservice was a model of hell.The greater the debt, the greater the redemption price.The kinsman-redeemer had to pay his redeemed relative a wage (v.

53).He was leasing his relative’s labor services, not merely liberating

him.The redeemer had incentives to redeem the man: removing family

shame and keeping profits away from a resident alien.The kinsman-redeemer was also buying labor inventory.The original buyer would therefore not gain maximum profits if

labor costs went higher.The kinsman-redeemer had an advantage in redeeming his kinsman

in times of rising labor prices, though offset in part by having to paywages.

He had an even greater advantage in redeeming his kinsman’s landin times of rising land prices: no wages to pay to a relative.

It was legal because God owned both the land and the Israelites; Heset the terms of trade.

Populist utopians claim that all interest payments are immoral andeconomically unnecessary.

A rent payment is the same as an interest payment: the payment forthe use of a scarce resource over time.

If interest payments are illegitimate, so are rent payments.A fringe movement is susceptible to crackpot ideas.Fringe ideas must be examined carefully: tested rigorously.

Page 291: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 32 . . . Leviticus 25:47–55

1230

Economic analysis is complex: long chains of reasoning.Crackpot economic analysis always breaks the chain.Economic analysis is crackpot whenever it denies the inescapable

category of interest.Economics is a unified system.To assert that economics can do without the category of interest is

to make mandatory the complete reconstruction of all economics.The utopians refuse to begin this task.

Page 292: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1231

33

NATURE AS A SANCTIONING AGENT

If ye walk in my statutes, and keep my commandments, and do them;Then I will give you rain in due season, and the land shall yield herincrease, and the trees of the field shall yield their fruit. And yourthreshing shall reach unto the vintage, and the vintage shall reachunto the sowing time: and ye shall eat your bread to the full, anddwell in your land safely. And I will give peace in the land, and yeshall lie down, and none shall make you afraid: and I will rid evilbeasts out of the land, neither shall the sword go through your land(Lev. 26:3–6).

The theocentric message here is that God is the sovereign sustainerof the creation, who personally intervenes into the realm of nature interms of His covenant. Because His covenant with Israel was judicial,the land was uniquely under His law’s sanctions. This law was notpurely impersonal-mathematical; it was ethical.

Covenantal Blessings

The covenantal blessings of Leviticus 26:3–6 were corporate. Rainin due season was promised by God for all the land within theboundaries of national Israel, not just for the land belonging to cov-enant-keeping individuals. The individual Israelite would receive theseblessings only as a resident of a covenanted nation: inside the nationalcovenant’s geographical boundaries. These boundaries were primarilyjudicial and secondarily geographical. Only within these covenantalboundaries could the promised blessings be successfully invoked in

Page 293: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

1. It is a theologically and psychologically disastrous misinterpretation of God’s promisesof wealth to place them within an exclusively personal or individual framework. Theindividualism of the “positive confession” charismatic movement is an example of just sucha false interpretation of covenantal, corporate promises. God’s blessings are notsuccessfully invoked verbally; they are invoked corporately and ethically. IndividualChristians are not supposed to “name it and claim it.” Instead, we are to do the following:obey God personally by following His law; pray for the widespread movement of the HolySpirit in what is called revival; work toward a corporate, constitutional, and civilaffirmation of the absolute authority of the God of the Bible; and hope for the best untilthese covenantal requirements are met. Only after this can we be confident aboutpredictable, sustainable corporate blessings.

1232

God’s name, generation after generation, and only if those livingwithin these boundaries were actively conforming themselves to theethical boundaries of God’s revealed law. Only inside the land ofpromise – a covenanted nation – were there sufficient numbers ofcovenant-keepers and also publicly law-abiding covenant-breakers tocall forth these promised blessings through the generations.1 Thesewere not cross-boundary laws.

As I shall argue later in this chapter, the covenantally predictablesanctions of rain and sunshine were exclusive to Mosaic Israel’seconomy. They were land sanctions, which are no longer God’smeans of imparting predictable blessings and curses. The New Cov-enant has transferred God’s predictable sanctions from climate tosociety. What a society does in response to the terms of God’s Bible-revealed law determines God’s predictable blessings and cursings.Nature’s climatic processes are no longer covenantally predictable,and hence are no longer covenantal sanctions. It is what society doesin response to God’s revealed law that will determine whethernature’s covenantally unpredictable climatic processes become bless-ings or curses.

Does this mean that none of the Mosaic covenant’s system ofcorporate sanctions applied outside of the boundaries? No, but it doesmean that only inside Israel’s boundaries was there any legitimate

Page 294: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

2. Gary North, Dominion and Common Grace: The Biblical Basis of Progress (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1987), ch. 6.

1233

hope that positive blessings could be sustained long term. The basisof God’s blessings is always judicial: God’s grace. The nationsoutside the land could become the recipients of God’s common grace,but only if they outwardly obeyed the terms of God’s revealed law.But apart from special grace, common grace cannot be maintainedlong term. The covenant-breaking recipients of common grace willeventually revolt against God and His law. The blessings are notsufficient rewards to persuade them to remain outwardly faithfulindefinitely. Large numbers of covenant-breakers must be convertedto saving faith if they are not to rebel.2

The best example of this process of moral backsliding under theMosaic Covenant economy is Nineveh, capital city of Assyria. Thefact that God threatened Nineveh with destruction in 40 days indicatesthat the Levitical system of negative corporate sanctions was inoperation outside the land of Israel. These were not Mosaic seed andland sanctions. These were cross-boundary sanctions. Nineveh repent-ed on a corporate but external basis in the face of Jonah’s preachingof imminent negative sanctions. Why do I say external sanctions?Because no one was required to become circumcised in order forGod’s wrath to be withdrawn. This was common grace, not special(soul-saving) grace. The nation escaped external destruction becausetheir flagrant sinning ended. Eventually Assyria revolted against God,invaded Israel, and carried off the residents of the Northern Kingdom.Then Babylon destroyed Assyria.

Common grace cannot be sustained apart from special grace.Covenant-breakers eventually return to their outward rebellion. God

Page 295: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

3. Gary North, Cooperation and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Romans, 2ndelectronic edition (West Fork, Arkansas: Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 2002),ch. 3.

4. This is why Egypt was not brought to saving faith under Joseph. We know this becausethere was no covenantal succession; every Egyptian family suffered the death of thefirstborn at the exodus. Egypt’s faith was a common grace faith.

5. Gary North, The Sinai Strategy: Economics and the Ten Commandments (Tyler, Texas:Institute for Christian Economics, 1986), pp. 40–43.

6. Peace might be considered the absence of war, but given the condition of mankindafter Adam’s rebellion, it takes God’s active grace to bring peace to man. Peace is notnormal even though it is normative. Peace is not passive. War and sin are the passivecondition of covenant-breaking man (James 4:1).

1234

then gives them up to their lusts (Rom. 1:18–22).3 Apart from circum-cision, there was no possibility of special grace under the Old Coven-ant after Abraham.4 There could be no inheritance of covenantal bless-ings beyond the third and fourth generation of those who hated God(Ex. 20:5).5

Sanctions and Representation

The blessings listed here are agricultural and social: bread, wine,and peace. These are positive sanctions.6 Ten righteous representa-tives of Sodom would have kept God from bringing total negativesanctions against that city, but only because of Abraham’s negotiationwith God (Gen. 18:24–32). But what about positive sanctions inIsrael? What had to be done in Israel in order to gain bread, wine, andpeace? The people as a covenantal unit were told to obey God. TheBible never mentions a specific percentage of the population that mustobey God in order for God’s positive, visible sanctions to becomepredictable in history. This is why the absolute predictability of God’s

Page 296: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

7. The law’s visible sanctions are more predictable at the final judgment.

1235

sanctions in history is an unobtainable ideal. But absolute anything inhistory is unobtainable by men, so this should not deter us in our questto gain His positive sanctions. What the Bible teaches is that thenumber of active covenant-keepers must be large enough to representthe nation judicially. The society must be marked by widespreadobedience to the civil laws set forth by God. Blessings apart fromfaithfulness are a prelude to negative sanctions on a comparable scale.

Covenantal Representation

God promised covenantal blessings to the residents of the nation ofIsrael in response to individuals’ covenantal obedience. Obedience isalways in part individual, for individuals are always held responsibleby God for their actions. This responsibility is inescapable in historyand at the day of final judgment.7 Nevertheless, there is no doubt thatGod’s promised historical responses to individual obedience werecorporate sanctions. The question is: How many people in Israel hadto obey God’s law in order for the nation to receive these promisedvisible blessings? This is the question of covenantal representation.

In the bargaining process between Abraham and God over the fateof Sodom, Abraham persuaded God to drop the minimum-requirednumber of righteous men to only 10 as the condition of avoiding totalnegative sanctions against the city (Gen. 18:24–32). These threatenedcorporate sanctions were both negative and total. There is nothing inthe Mosaic law to indicate that a remnant of only 10 men would havepreserved the nation of Israel from lesser negative sanctions, such asinvasion or captivity. God told Elijah that He had kept 7,000 menfrom bowing the knee to Baal, but God did not on their account

Page 297: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

1236

promise to spare Israel. On the contrary, He used Elijah as His agentto anoint Hazael the Syrian, who would then bring negative sanctionsagainst Israel. This revelation from God came as a unit:

And the LORD said unto him, Go, return on thy way to the wildernessof Damascus: and when thou comest, anoint Hazael to be king overSyria: And Jehu the son of Nimshi shalt thou anoint to be king overIsrael: and Elisha the son of Shaphat of Abel-meholah shalt thouanoint to be prophet in thy room. And it shall come to pass, that himthat escapeth the sword of Hazael shall Jehu slay: and him thatescapeth from the sword of Jehu shall Elisha slay. Yet I have left meseven thousand in Israel, all the knees which have not bowed untoBaal, and every mouth which hath not kissed him (I Ki. 19:15–18).

Abraham’s bargaining was based on a theory of covenantal repre-sentation. Ten righteous men in Sodom could have served as repre-sentatives for the entire city, even though the city’s population wasperverse. This is an indication of the magnitude of God’s grace. ButHis grace is not without ethical conditions. There did have to be 10righteous men in Sodom in order for God to display His grace to allthe other inhabitants. The 7,000 covenant-keepers of Elijah’s dayserved as covenantal representatives who kept Israel from beingtotally destroyed, Sodom-like, but their presence in the land did notprotect the nation from lesser negative sanctions. God’s grace some-times temporarily offsets a widespread decline of faith, as it did in thedays of Hezekiah (II Ki. 20:1–6), but if there is no widespread repent-ance during this period of grace, God’s specially imposed negativecorporate sanctions will inevitably come on a rebellious society. Theseare predictable in history. The New Covenant has not altered thiscause-and-effect relationship.

Who was responsible for gaining these blessings? The text does notidentify any single representative. Could a single agent represent the

Page 298: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

8. “And one of them, named Caiaphas, being the high priest that same year, said untothem, Ye know nothing at all, Nor consider that it is expedient for us, that one man shoulddie for the people, and that the whole nation perish not. And this spake he not of himself:but being high priest that year, he prophesied that Jesus should die for that nation; And notfor that nation only, but that also he should gather together in one the children of God thatwere scattered abroad” (John 11:49–52).

9. David Chilton, The Days of Vengeance: An Exposition of the Book of Revelation (Ft.Worth, Texas: Dominion Press, 1987).

10. In most cases, this would have been a circumcised male. In the case of widows anddivorced women, they became the heads of their households, for they were required tofulfill their vows without initial approval by a male (Num. 30:9).

11. During the feast of tabernacles, Israel sacrificed a total of 70 bulls for the 70 nations(Jud. 1:7), plus one for Israel (Num. 29:13–36).

12. A representative discussion is Bertrand de Jouvenal, Sovereignty: An Inquiry into thePolitical Good (University of Chicago Press, 1957). The author was a conservative. Thisbook was a companion volume to his equally political study, Power: The Natural Historyof Its Growth, rev. ed. (London: Batchworth, 1952).

1237

nation as a whole? In some cases, yes. God spared Judah for the sakeof Hezekiah’s repentance. The crucifixion of Jesus definitively provesthe point.8 By bringing Him under the negative sanction of publicexecution, Israel’s representatives brought the whole nation underGod’s negative sanction of public execution in A.D. 70.9 In Israel,covenantal representatives included the high priest, priests in general,Levites, civil rulers, prophets, and heads of households.10 The peopleof Israel were to serve the world as a royal priesthood (Ex. 19:6).They represented other nations.11 The Mosaic law did not single outcivil officers as the nation’s primary legal representatives. The officeof high priest was far more important than the office of king. NationalIsrael could and did exist without a king; it could not exist without ahigh priest. It is a sign of the modern world’s perversity that the civilruler is regarded as possessing the crucial form of sovereignty.12 This

Page 299: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

13. R. J. Rushdoony, The One and the Many: Studies in the Philosophy of Order andUltimacy (Fairfax, Virginia: Thoburn Press, [1971] 1978), chaps. 3–5.

14. Even during wartime, politicians should strive to let the market allocate resources inmost instances. Fiscal policy – taxing and spending – not monetary inflation coupled witha system of compulsory rationing, should be the primary control device. This enablesproducers to make rational decisions about what to produce. The profit system motivatesproducers to create the most efficient weapons. Ludwig von Mises, Human Action: ATreatise on Economics (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1949), ch. 34,sect. 2.

1238

same error governed pagan men’s thinking in the ancient world.13

God’s promises to a corporate entity do not mandate that there bea representative political agency to serve as His primary economicagent. This means that a central agricultural planning bureau shouldnot be created by the State, nor should such an agency make thedecisions about what to plant, where, and when. There must be nocivil “Department of Bread and Wine.” Neither it nor any anotherpolitical agency should decide which crops to sell, at what price, andto whom, except during wartime, and then only because the Statetakes on a priestly function, when its corporate decisions are literallylife-and-death representative decisions.14 Nevertheless, the questionremains: If God makes men responsible collectively, as His covenantalpromises indicate that He does, then what kind of representativehuman authority should be established in order to monitor the arena– the boundaries – in which the sanctions are applied, both positiveand negative?

Stipulations and Representation

God’s covenantal promises in the Mosaic law were ethical, notmagical or technical. They were governed by God’s stipulations: theboundaries of legitimate behavior. Were these stipulations exclusively

Page 300: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

15. “In the beginning was the Word, and the Word was with God, and the Word was God.The same was in the beginning with God. All things were made by him; and without himwas not any thing made that was made” (John 1:1–3).

16. Jesus said: “But when the Comforter is come, whom I will send unto you from theFather, even the Spirit of truth, which proceedeth from the Father, he shall testify of me”(John 15:26). “Howbeit when he, the Spirit of truth, is come, he will guide you into alltruth: for he shall not speak of himself; but whatsoever he shall hear, that shall he speak:and he will shew you things to come” (John 16:13).

17. Jesus said: “I have given them thy word; and the world hath hated them, because theyare not of the world, even as I am not of the world” (John 17:14). “Sanctify them throughthy truth: thy word is truth” (John 17:17). Paul wrote: “All scripture is given by inspirationof God, and is profitable for doctrine, for reproof, for correction, for instruction in right-eousness” (II Tim. 3:16).

1239

civil? No. Were they predominantly civil? No. The Mosaic lawsmatched the four covenants, i.e., the four biblically legitimate self-maledictory oaths: individual, familial, ecclesiastical, and civil. Theproblem in any covenanted society is to discover which agency hasprimary jurisdiction in any specific instance. No human agency hasfinal, total authority. Only God possesses absolute authority, anauthority that He transfers in history only to His incarnate livingWord, Jesus Christ,15 to the Holy Spirit,16 and to His incarnate writtenword, the Bible.17

The primary form of biblical government is always self-government.The primary agency of jurisdiction is the individual conscience. It hasto be: only at this level does the individual law-enforcer havesufficiently accurate and detailed information regarding both hismotivation and the results of his actions. Furthermore, only theindividual can search his own heart, and even then, such knowledgeis flawed. “The heart is deceitful above all things, and desperatelywicked: who can know it? I the LORD search the heart, I try thereins, even to give every man according to his ways, and according tothe fruit of his doings” (Jer. 17:9–10). This is why God threatenseternal sanctions, positive and negative, on individuals: to persuade

Page 301: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

18. In the New Covenant, the one feast is the Lord’s Supper, which is the heir of thePassover and the other Mosaic Covenant feasts.

1240

them to focus their attention in history on the requirement ofobedience.

Adam was given a positive injunction: to dress and guard thegarden (Gen. 2:15). He was also given a negative injunction: to avoideating the fruit of a specific tree (Gen. 2:17). The first was a task ofpersonal dominion. The second was a warning against false worship:eating a forbidden meal. Both stipulations necessarily involved corp-orate responsibility: familial (dominion) and ecclesiastical (commun-ion). Corporate responsibility flows from individual responsibility.The point is, responsibility does flow outward from the individual.There is more to biblical responsibility than personal responsibilitybecause personal responsibility in a covenantal order is necessarilyrepresentative. The representative models of the principle of represen-tation are Adam and Christ.

The Mosaic law reflects this judicial fact of life, especially inLeviticus, the premier book of stipulations. Leviticus begins withecclesiastical stipulations: priestly laws governing the representativesacrifices and laws governing the enforcement of covenantal boun-daries, i.e., excommunication from the assembly. The feasts and ritualsacrifices of the Mosaic Covenant are obvious examples of priestlylaws.18 Next in number and importance are the family-related statutes,mainly laws controlling sexual deviation (Lev. 18; 20), personal ethicsand land management (Lev. 19), and inheritance (Lev. 25). Civilstatutes and civil sanctions are a distant fourth in both number andimportance.

Body and Head

Page 302: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

19. “For the husband is the head of the wife, even as Christ is the head of the church: andhe is the saviour of the body” (Eph. 5:23). “And he is the head of the body, the church: whois the beginning, the firstborn from the dead; that in all things he might have the pre-eminence” (Col. 1:18).

1241

Obedience must be representative when God’s sanctions are corp-orate. Certain individuals represent a larger body of individuals. Theword body is covenantally appropriate: a head represents the othermembers.19 This judicial principle provides us with no specific infor-mation regarding corporate ownership. The Mosaic law does, how-ever. Leviticus 25 says a great deal about Old Covenant corporateownership: it was familial. The jubilee law centered around a man’sfamily inheritance, which was based in turn on God’s original distri-bution of the land of Canaan to the Israelite conquerors. The crucialinheritance was judicial: the legal status of freeman. The far lessimportant inheritance was geographical: a specific plot of ground. Theprimary role of civil government in Israel with respect to landedinheritance was to enforce the terms of the jubilee law.

The jubilee law was the most important corporate civil law inMosaic Israel, for it established freemanship. This is what identified afree man, a man who could not be sold into permanent servitude withhis family. There were other civil laws, but this was the archetype. Thejubilee was not a law guaranteeing a specific economic income. It wasinstead a law establishing a legal right: an enforceable boundaryaround his legal status as a freeman.

The jubilee law served Mosaic Israel as a model for all civillegislation. It was primarily a defense of legal rights, not a promise ofpositive economic sanctions. It was God alone who promised positiveeconomic sanctions, not the State. These positive sanctions came toindividuals primarily through their families. The economic success ofindividuals and families determined the size of the tithe: positivesanctions to the church and State. Families also provided charity to

Page 303: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

20. The limit is 40 lashes (Deut. 25:3). It is worth noting that Noah’s flood came from40 days of rain, and Christ’s encounter with Satan came after 40 days of temptation in thewilderness (Luke 4:2).

1242

the poor, under threat of church sanctions. The gleaning law servedas the model of this form of charity: if a man did not work, neither didhe eat. Men also received positive sanctions from the church throughthe Levites. Presumably, people received positive sanctions fromvoluntary, non-ecclesiastical organizations that served the poor, butthere are no biblical injunctions in this regard.

Finally, there were civil sanctions, which were exclusively negative:to protect the nation from God’s corporate negative sanctions inhistory. Faithfulness by the civil government in executing these neg-ative sanctions would bring God’s positive sanctions, most notablypeace. It is the civil government’s task to insure peace: defensiveboundaries placed around violent people within the nation – economicrestitution, public flogging,20 and public execution – and a geo-graphical defensive boundary placed around violent people outside thenation. Peace is God’s national blessing: a successful quarantineagainst violence. This quarantine begins with the work of the cons-cience: “From whence come wars and fightings among you? comethey not hence, even of your lusts that war in your members?” (James4:1). It moves outward from the individual to the other covenantalinstitutions, and from there to all of society. It is the responsibility ofcivil magistrates to suppress external violence. This results in externalpeace. But without the grace of God in regenerating the souls of men,the civil suppression of violence cannot be maintained indefinitely. Thefundamental form of government is self-government, not civilgovernment.

Common Grace

Page 304: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

21. Gary North, Priorities and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Matthew, 2ndelectronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc., [2000]2003), ch. 10.

22. North, Cooperation and Dominion, ch. 12.

1243

The question arises: Did the covenantal promises of Leviticus 26perish with the other land laws of Israel? The law promised predic-table blessings: “If ye walk in my statutes, and keep my command-ments, and do them; Then I will give you rain in due season, and theland shall yield her increase, and the trees of the field shall yield theirfruit” (vv. 3–4). The New Testament seems to establish another prin-ciple, that of common grace: the rain falls on everyone indiscrimin-ately, irrespective of covenantal status. The context of the New Testa-ment teaching is individual behavior, but the sanctions are corporate:

Ye have heard that it hath been said, Thou shalt love thy neighbor, andhate thine enemy. But I say unto you, Love your enemies, bless themthat curse you, do good to them that hate you, and pray for them whichdespitefully use you, and persecute you; That ye may be the childrenof your Father which is in heaven: for he maketh his sun to rise onthe evil and on the good, and sendeth rain on the just and on theunjust. For if ye love them which love you, what reward have ye? donot even the publicans the same? And if ye salute your brethren only,what do ye more than others? do not even the publicans so? Be yetherefore perfect, even as your Father which is in heaven is perfect(Matt. 5:43–48).21

The context of this passage is the rule of law: love thy neighbor.Here is the biblical principle of love: “Love worketh no ill to hisneighbor: therefore love is the fulfilling of the law” (Rom. 13:10).22

We are to treat friends and enemies lawfully. This is the personalapplication of the Mosaic law’s principle of equality before the law:

Page 305: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

23. Gary North, Moses and Pharaoh: Dominion Religion vs. Power Religion (Tyler, Tex-as: Institute for Christian Economics, 1985), ch. 14.

24. Ray R. Sutton, “Whose Conditions for Charity?” in Gary North (ed.), Theonomy: AnInformed Response (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1991), ch. 9.

25. “And meanwhile it [the common grace order] must run its course within the uncer-tainties of the mutually conditioning principles of common grace and common curse,prosperity and adversity being experienced in a manner largely unpredictable because ofthe inscrutable sovereignty of the divine will that dispenses them in mysterious ways.”Meredith G. Kline, “Comments on an Old-New Error,” Westminster Theological Journal,XLI (Fall 1978), p. 184.

1244

“One law shall be to him that is homeborn, and unto the stranger thatsojourneth among you” (Ex. 12:49).23 Nature’s patterns affect all menthe same in New Covenant history, sending rain and sun on good menand evil men. We are therefore to treat all men justly. In this passage,our righteous judgment is the equivalent of God’s gift of rain andsun.

The focus of Jesus’ discussion of the rain and sun in the Sermon onthe Mount is God’s unmerited gift of justice: every man is to be therecipient of justice. Antinomian commentators shift the focus of thispassage from our righteous treatment of other men to another topic:God’s universal distribution of blessings in history. These blessings areindeed universal, but they are also conditional. They are asconditional as the positive sanctions of God’s law. The impartiality ofGod’s justice mandates the conditionality of the blessings of justice.Every decision on our part must be ethically conditional, even thepositive sanction of charity.24 The context of the passage is themandatory distribution of our justice. It is not, as Meredith G. Klinewould have it, the general unpredictability of God’s corporate sanc-tions in New Covenant history.25 Rather, the point that Jesus wasmaking is that men must be utterly predictable in administering civiljustice. All negative sanctions must match those mandated by God.They are ideally to be as predictable as the universality of both rain

Page 306: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

26. Gary North, Millennialism and Social Theory (Tyler, Texas: Institute for ChristianEconomics, 1990), chaps. 7, 8.

1245

and sunshine. These sanctions must be predictable because they areconditional. Where does God prescribe these civil sanctions? Whereelse but in His revealed law? Hope for a peaceful and prosperous landhas been universal in man’s history.

But there is a problem: the question of the rain. There is no explicitindication that the Levitical promise of rain in due season – a uniquepositive sanction in the Mosaic law – continues into the New Cov-enant era. Kline has correctly recognized that this indicates a shiftfrom the Old Covenant to the New Covenant. Kline then extrapolatesfrom Jesus’ announcement of the visible randomness (i.e., covenantalunpredictability) of the rain in the New Covenant to the visiblerandomness of all the promised sanctions in the Mosaic law. WhatKline does is to assume that the rain, which was an aspect of the landlaws, represents all the corporate sanctions in the New Testament.This assumption is incorrect. If it were correct, there could be nouniquely biblical system of social theory.26 This is why we must payconsiderable attention to the positive covenantal sanction of rain indue season.

Rain in Due Season

The Levitical positive sanctions listed in the text are peace, wine,and bread. Rain in due season is a means of producing grain andgrapes, meaning bread and wine. The rain is a blessing only insofar asit produces crops. Obviously, rain was no blessing in Noah’s day. Toomuch rain ruins crops. So, the promise was for rain in due season. Itwould be just the right quantity of rain to produce the positive

Page 307: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

27. Chapter 10.

28. Jesus warned the Pharisees: “Therefore say I unto you, The kingdom of God shall betaken from you, and given to a nation bringing forth the fruits thereof” (Matt. 21:43).

1246

economic sanction of agricultural productivity.The New Testament’s teaching is that rain and sunshine fall on all

men. This is God’s common grace. The New Testament’s emphasishere is on a common blessing. As I have already argued, the twinblessings of sunshine and rain are representative of God’s blessing ofrighteous judgment, which His covenant people are to emulate. Butboth rain and sunshine can become common curses: rain becomesflooding; sunshine becomes drought. The question we must getanswered is this: Is nature under the New Covenant a means of God’spredictable covenantal sanctions in history? It was in Moses’ day, atleast inside the boundaries of the Promised Land. The land had vom-ited out the Canaanites:

Defile not ye yourselves in any of these things: for in all these thenations are defiled which I cast out before you: And the land is defiled:therefore I do visit the iniquity thereof upon it, and the land itselfvomiteth out her inhabitants. Ye shall therefore keep my statutes andmy judgments, and shall not commit any of these abominations; neitherany of your own nation, nor any stranger that sojourneth among you:(For all these abominations have the men of the land done, which werebefore you, and the land is defiled;) That the land spue not you outalso, when ye defile it, as it spued out the nations that were before you(Lev. 18:24–28).27

But after the Promised Land ceased to be a kingdom boundary,28

did climate still play this judgmental role? No. Jesus today spews outHis enemies, not the land. “So then because thou art lukewarm, andneither cold nor hot, I will spue thee out of my mouth” (Rev. 3:16).

Page 308: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

1247

Climate in the New Covenant has ceased to be a means of predictablecovenantal judgment. What determines the fruitfulness of the fieldtoday is adherence to God’s laws, including his laws of ownership. Putanother way, a Christian nation whose civil government imposessocialist ownership will not enjoy the large number of external bless-ings experienced by a pagan nation whose civil government defendsfree market ownership. Also, if the two nations were to reverse theirsystems of ownership, there would be no predictable long-termreversal of rainfall and sunshine patterns within their respective geo-graphical boundaries. The New Covenant moved from climate tosociety with respect to the locus of predictable sanctions. More to thepoint, this shift culminated a shift that had begun at the time of theconquest of the land. The earlier shift in the locus of sanctions hadbeen a far more radical shift: from predictable manna outside thePromised Land to predictable inheritance without manna inside thePromised Land. When the Israelites crossed the boundary from thewilderness into Canaan, the source of their bread ceased to be manna.“And the manna ceased on the morrow after they had eaten of the oldcorn of the land; neither had the children of Israel manna any more;but they did eat of the fruit of the land of Canaan that year” (Josh. 5:12).

The Plow and the Plains

During the great westward expansion into the Great Plains of theUnited States, 1840–90, two myths competed for men’s allegiance:the myth of the uncivilized wilderness vs. the myth of the garden. Bothmyths were based on environmental determinism. Beginning in the1840’s, some observers argued that the arid plains would makesavages of civilized men. But as the American population moved

Page 309: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

29. Charles Dana Wilber, The Great Valleys and Prairies of Nebraska and the Northwest(1881), p. 69; cited by Henry Nash Smith, Virgin Land: The American West as Symbol andMyth (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, [1950] 1978), p. 182.

30. Wilber, ibid., p. 70; in idem.

1248

westward, another myth slowly took shape, or more to the point, wasshifted from the East to the Midwest: the myth of the garden. Thecoming of civilization would somehow increase the rainfall of the aridregion.

Initially, the second myth was the product of unscientific dreams,but in the late 1870’s, it began to gain scientific support, most notablyfrom University of Nebraska scientist Samuel Aughey. The idea wasencapsulated in 1881 by an epigram from Aughey’s disciple, amateurscientist and professional town builder Charles Dana Wilber: “RainFollows the Plough.”29 This was a secularization of the promise ofLeviticus 26:4. Wilber wrote that “in this miracle of progress, theplow was the avant courier – the unerring prophet – the procuringcause. Not by any magic or enchantment, not by incantations orofferings, but, instead, in the sweat of his face, toiling with his hands,man can persuade the heavens to yield their treasures of dew and rainupon the land he has chosen for his dwelling place. It is indeed a grandconsent, or, rather, concert of forces – the human energy or toil, thevital seed, and the polished raindrop that never fails to fall in answerto the imploring power or prayer of labor.”30 The honest labor of theplowman would bring the rain. Man’s sweat would bring nature’s rain.This was an assertion that the curse of God (sweat) would bring theblessing of God (rain). Here was “works religion” with a vengeance.

The gigantic dust storms of the 1930’s – the “dust bowl” – disa-bused those who might otherwise have been tempted to perpetuatethis myth. Year after year, these dust storms buried hundreds ofthousands of square miles of land in many feet of air-borne dirt. There

Page 310: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

31. The Department of Agriculture was headed by Henry A. Wallace, a seed companymillionaire and an occult mystic: Arthur M. Schlesinger, Jr., The Coming of the New Deal(Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1959), pp. 31–34. He persuaded the Secretary of the Treasuryto place the Masonic pyramid and all-seeing eye on the back of the one dollar bill: ibid.,p. 31. Agriculture was the first department to be heavily infiltrated by the Communists,1933– 35: the “Ware cell.” Schlesinger writes: “For the Communist party, the AAA groupwas a staging area for personnel, not a fulcrum for policy.” Ibid., p. 54.

32. Bernard Sternsher, Rexford Guy Tugwell and the New Deal (New Brunswick, NewJersey: Rutgers University Press, 1964); R. G. Tugwell, The Brains Trust (New York:Viking, 1968). Four decades later, Tugwell had published under his name a book, TheEmerging Constitution (New York: Harper & Row, 1974). This was the result of a decadeof work by a hundred people, funded by the Center for the Study of Democratic Institutions,which had published an early draft in its Center Magazine (Sept./Oct. 1970). The book wasa draft for a radically revised U.S. Constitution.

33. At $35/ounce of gold, this was about 171 ounces of gold.

1249

was literally darkness at noon. The sweat of man’s brow was caked.Then the myth of the garden shifted: from the hard-working farmer tothe scientific planner. The Agricultural Adjustment Administration(AAA) of the United States Department of Agriculture began topreach a new gospel of works: the plow was destroying the soil.31 Thenation needed government-mandated soil conservation, voters weretold.

The Resettlement Administration of the Department of Agriculturewas ordered by its director, Rexford Guy Tugwell, one of the mostnotorious statists of the Roosevelt Administration (1933– 1945),32 tocreate a propaganda film promoting this viewpoint, The Plow ThatBroke the Plains (1936). It was written and directed by Pere Lorentz,a 30-year-old former West Virginian, who had been a New Yorkmovie critic, a Washington gossip columnist, and political reporter. Hehad never before made a movie. He had written a pro-Rooseveltpicture book, The Roosevelt Year (1934). The movie cost a minuscule$6,00033 to produce, but was incredibly successful artistically. As apropaganda film of the era, it is matched only by Eisenstein’s The

Page 311: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

34. The standard account of his career is Robert L. Snyder, Pare Lorentz and the Docu-mentary Film (Norman: University of Oklahoma Press, 1968).

35. James C. Malin, The Grassland of North America (Lawrence, Kansas: By the Author,1961), pp. 134–37. Malin was a distinguished regional historian who taught at theUniversity of Kansas.

36. A full transcript of the film’s script appears in Pere Lorentz, FDR’s Moviemaker:Memoirs and Scripts (Las Vegas: University of Nevada Press, 1992), pp. 44–50.

37. Ibid., pp. 39–43. Lorentz followed this movie with The River (1938), a promotion forthe national government’s rural electrification and flood control project, the TennesseeValley Authority, but disguised as a history of the Mississippi River. President Rooseveltpersonally hired him to produce more propaganda films after seeing The River at a specialscreening at his home in Hyde Park. Ibid., pp. 55–56. Decades later, in 1981, these twofilms were given a special salute by the Academy of Motion Picture Arts and Sciences, andhe subsequently received several awards. Ibid., p. 233.

1250

Battleship Potemkin, silent movie defending the Bolshevik revolution,and by Leni Riefenstahl’s 1935 promotion of Hitler and the NaziParty, Triumph of the Will. (Riefenstahl died in 2003.) It was sosuccessful that President Roosevelt established the United States FilmService in 1938, with Lorentz in charge.34

The Plow that Broke the Plains was so blatantly misleading in itssplicing together of scenes, some of which historian James C. Malinsays were faked, that a United States Senator and other critics forcedit out of circulation in 1939.35 The narrative suggested nothing specificin the way of a restoration program for the land. It ended with thisevaluation: “The sun and winds wrote the most tragic chapter inAmerican agriculture.”36 In the script, the plow is not blamed for theerosion of the soil, but this theme is communicated visually. AsLorentz later wrote, he relied primarily on pictures and music; hewrote the narrative only after the pictures and the music were finish-ed.37 (Lorentz died just before his book appeared in early 1992.)

With respect to the Midwest of the United States, the myth of thewilderness was superseded by the myth of the garden, which had two

Page 312: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

38. Such justice ceases to be a blessing for covenant-breakers in eternity.

1251

versions: the myth of the plow and the myth of the State. In each case,these myths rested on some version of autonomous man in the midstof an autonomous environment. God and His law had no place in anyof these myths.

Coals of Fire

If rain in due season is a blessing, and if all of God’s gifts are ethic-ally conditional, then what is the nature of climate’s conditionality? Ihave argued that the blessings of climate are analogous to – represen-tational of – the blessing of God’s predictable justice in history.38 Godtells His people to give good gifts – render impartial justice – tocovenant-breakers, just as He sends rain and sunshine on sinners.There is an ulterior motive in such unmerited common grace: an escal-ation of their condemnation. In the section on justice in Romans, Paulquotes Proverbs 25:21–22. The passage in Proverbs reads: “If thineenemy be hungry, give him bread to eat; and if he be thirsty, give himwater to drink: For thou shalt heap coals of fire upon his head, and theLORD shall reward thee.” Here is how Paul applies this biblicalprinciple of condemnation through mercy: “Dearly beloved, avengenot yourselves, but rather give place unto wrath: for it is written,Vengeance is mine; I will repay, saith the Lord. Therefore if thineenemy hunger, feed him; if he thirst, give him drink: for in so doingthou shalt heap coals of fire on his head. Be not overcome of evil, butovercome evil with good” (Rom. 12:19–21).

At the very least, the common blessings of nature bring covenant-breakers under greater eternal condemnation. This is because of theprinciple that there is a link between God’s blessings and man’s res-

Page 313: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

39. Gary North, Treasure and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Luke, 2nd elec-tronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc., [2000]2003), ch. 28.

1252

ponsibilities. “But he that knew not, and did commit things worthy ofstripes, shall be beaten with few stripes. For unto whomsoever muchis given, of him shall be much required: and to whom men have com-mitted much, of him they will ask the more” (Luke 12:48).39 But whatabout in history? In what way is nature’s ethically random distributionof gifts ethically conditional in history? We can be sure that those whoreceive such undeserved gifts heap up coals of fire on theirunrepentant heads in eternity. What about in history?

Paul writes: “Be not overcome of evil, but overcome evil withgood” (v. 21). The goal here is the overcoming of Satan’s kingdom.This victory is not confined to eternity. Satan’s kingdom is obviouslygoing to be overcome in eternity, with or without mercy from Chris-tians in history. So, Paul’s frame of reference in this passage has to behistory. By showing mercy in history, Christians accomplish twothings: they weaken some covenant-breakers’ resistance to the truth,and they strengthen other covenant-breakers’ resistance to the truth.That is, covenant-breakers’ reactions to the gift of mercy vary inhistory. If their negative reactions to mercy always strengthened theirresolve to defy God and His kingdom, and also always strengthenedtheir ability to resist, or even left such strength “neutral,” then howcould showing mercy to evil men lead to the overcoming of evil withgood? Wouldn’t mercy in this case be counter-productive, strengthen-ing evil men’s will to resist and also their ability to resist God’skingdom? Wouldn’t showing mercy then subsidize evil? Yet the Bibledoes not recommend that covenant-keeper subsidize evil.

This is why Paul does not presume that mercy always strengthensevil men’s ability to resist the expansion of God’s kingdom. On thecontrary, he assumes that our showing mercy – dealing lawfully with

Page 314: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

40. North, Cooperation and Dominion, ch. 8.

1253

sinners – leads to an expansion of the kingdom of God in history. InRomans 11, Paul prophesies an era of great blessings in history.Speaking of the future conversion of the Jews, Paul writes: “Now ifthe fall of them be the riches of the world, and the diminishing of themthe riches of the Gentiles; how much more their fulness?” (Rom.11:12).40 Romans 12 continues his message of victory in history.Good will overcome evil. This means that the merciful gift of God’scivil justice in history will strengthen God’s kingdom in history.

God’s unmerited gifts in nature produce analogous effects. Theyprogressively condemn covenant-breakers and bless covenant-keepers.While the rain in due season in the New Covenant era does not fallonly on covenant-keepers or only on covenant-keeping societies, itdoes have kingdom-expanding effects in history. It brings covenant-breaking societies under God’s condemnation. Jesus Christ willimpose negative sanctions against them in history. Long-term rebel-lion increases the quantity of judgmental fire on their corporateheads. What is different in the New Covenant is that climate no longerimposes the negative sanctions. In Elijah’s day, God withheld rain inIsrael for several years in order to strengthen Elijah’s position andweaken Ahab’s resistance (I Ki. 17:1). This is no longer God’smethod of bringing negative sanctions in history. Climate is no longerGod’s covenantal agent. But, contrary to Kline in particular and amil-lennialists in general, this does not mean that God no longer bringspredictable sanctions in history. His sanctions are no less real justbecause they are no longer delivered through climate. They are deliv-ered through society.

The language of Leviticus 26:3–6 is not only covenantal, it is inpart sacramental. By identifying the vineyard and bread as the blessedproducts of the land, the Mosaic law invoked the language of Abra-

Page 315: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

41. Lenin, “All Power to the Soviets!” (July 18, 1917), in Collected Works (Moscow:Progress Publishers, 1964), vol. 25, pp. 155–56.

42. The earlier months (February, October) are based on Russia’s old style calendar.

43. Peter Gay and R. K. Webb, Modern Europe (New York: Harper & Row, 1973), p.954.

1254

hamic Holy Communion: bread and wine (Gen. 14:18). The visibleproof of God’s communion with His people – His residence insideIsrael’s boundaries – was the four-fold blessing of peace and land,bread and wine.

Peace, Land, and Bread in the Soviet Union

The power of this sacramental language has not been lost on his-torians. This is especially obvious in standard accounts of the RussianRevolution, meaning the October revolution of 1917. It is not aca-demically risky to point out that V. I. Lenin was one of the two great-est pamphleteers in history, matched only by Martin Luther. Hisslogan, “All power to the Soviets,”41 was the Bolsheviks’ most promi-nent rallying cry in the months after the first Russian Revolution ofFebruary/March, 1917,42 but before the second revolution, the Octo-ber/November revolution, in which the Bolsheviks seized power. Thetextbook account is that Lenin also employed another rhetoricallypowerful slogan: “Peace, land, and bread!”43 This is such a powerfulslogan that it is disappointing to learn that there is no first-hand evi-dence that the slogan was ever used in this form. Historians find italmost irresistible – as irresistible as it supposedly was for Russianpeasants. In several documents on the World Wide Web, the phraseis said to appear in Lenin’s “April Thesis” of 1917. Unfortunately forthe authors of textbooks and chroniclers of the Russian Revolution,

Page 316: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

44. Lenin, “The Tasks of the Proletariat in the Present Revolution” (April 7, 1917),Collected Works (Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1964), 24, pp. 21–26.

45. Lazar Volin, A Century of Russian Agriculture: From Alexander II to Khrushchev(Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1970), p. 128.

46. Warren Bartlett Walsh, Russia and the Soviet Union: A Modern History, rev. ed.(Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1968), p. 384.

47. Robert Conquest, Harvest of Sorrow: Soviet Collectivization and the Terror – Famine(New York: Oxford University Press, 1986), p. 306. A personal account is provided byMiron Dolot, Execution by Hunger: The Hidden Holocaust (New York: Norton, 1985).

48. Robert Conquest, The Great Terror: A Reassessment (New York: Oxford UniversityPress, 1990), p. 486.

1255

the phrase doesn’t exist there.44 (“History does not repeat itself, buthistorians repeat each other.”)

The fact is, the Communists did not give the peasants their land; atbest, they accelerated what had already begun when Lenin issued hisNovember 8 decree, “Concerning the Land.”45 Then the Communistsstole it back from them through collectivization. The peasants in thesummer of 1917 had confiscated land that had been owned by the pre-Revolutionary land owners, months before the October Revolution.46

Lenin had advocated this, but the peasants were way ahead of him.For this act of collective theft, the peasants subsequently paid far morethan double restitution to the Communists. As many as eleven millionpeasants paid with their lives, 1930–37, through famine and farmcollectivization, plus another 3.5 million in the camps.47 Overall,during Stalin’s entire dictatorship, the Soviet death toll was at least 20million.48 Paul wrote that he who does not work, let him not eat (IIThes. 3:10). Soviet totalitarianism reworked Paul’s injunction, at leastaccording to the most famous victim of Comrade Stalin (Djugashvili),Comrade Trotsky (Bronstein): “In a country where the sole employeris the State, opposition means death by slow starvation. The old prin-ciple: who does not work shall not eat, has been replaced by a new

Page 317: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

49. Leon Trotsky, The Revolution Betrayed, Max Eastman, trans. (Garden City, NewYork: Doubleday, 1937), p. 76.

50. Maurice Paléologue, An Ambassador’s Memoirs, 3 vols., 4th ed.( New York: Doran,1925), III, p. 325.

51. Adam B. Ulam, Russia’s Failed Revolutions: From the Decembrists to the Dissidents(London: Weidenfeld & Nicolson, 1981), pp. 105–12, 116–17, 119–21. Ulam writes that“Land and Freedom was a revolutionary party which never succeeded in fully organizingitself – a conspiracy which never carried its conspiratorial activities to the point ofplanning, let alone attempting to seize power” (p. 111).

52. Ibid., pp. 126–27; Ulam, In the Name of the People (New York: Viking, 1977), p.288.

1256

one: who does not obey shall not eat.”49

Land and Liberty

The language of millennial peace was systematically employed tofurther the secular messianism of the Russian Revolution, and not justduring its Bolshevik phase. The power of this language is universal.The French Ambassador to the Russian court reported that on May 1,1917 (Western calendar: May Day), he attended a large public meet-ing sponsored by the St. Petersburg soviet, or workers’ council. Hesaw over 30 banners, and among the slogans were these: “Down withthe War! . . . Long Live the internationalle! . . . We want Liberty,Land and Peace!”50 The Communists did not control this meeting; itwas sponsored by the city’s soviet, which represented several socialistgroups. These slogans had become common by 1917.

Land and Liberty (Zemla i Volya) had been the name of two separ-ate Russian peasant organizations: a disorganized, pamphleteering,conspiratorial organization in the early 1860’s51 and a terrorist groupin the late 1870’s.52 Alexander Kerensky, a moderate socialist and the

Page 318: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

53. Paléologue, Memoirs, III, p. 301.

54. V. I. Lenin, What Is to Be Done? (1902), in Lenin, Collected Works, 45 vols. (Mos-cow: Progress Press, 1973), V, p. 474.

55. Ulam, In the Name of the People, chaps. 12, 13.

56. Ibid., pp. 392–93; cf. Rolf H. W. Theen, Lenin: Genesis and Development of a Revo-lutionary (New York: Lippencott, 1973), pp. 40–41.

57. Robert Payne, Lenin (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1964), p. 362. It is one of themost extraordinary facts of the twentieth century that the Communists fell from power justas they had come into power: in a near-bloodless coup that lasted less than a week: August19–21, 1991. Only three people were shot during this failed coup. The military refused tosupport the Communist regime in Moscow, exactly as the military had failed to support thesocialist regime during Lenin’s coup.

1257

Prime Minister of the Russian Duma (parliament) after July 7, 1917,appealed back to the first organization’s populism.53 Lenin appealedback to the second organization’s tradition of centralized authority.54

Lenin could hardly escape this legacy. His older brother Alexanderhad been executed as a result of this legacy. A tiny splinter group ofthe second Land and Liberty, the People’s Will, successfully assas-sinated the liberal Czar Alexander II in 1881.55 His successor, Alex-ander III, imposed a repressive regime, and during his reign, Lenin’sbrother, Alexander Ulyanov, was executed for having participated ina conspiracy to assassinate Alexander III. He had been arrested onMarch 1, 1887, seven years to the day after the assassination of Alex-ander II. He was a member of a group called the Terrorist Faction ofthe People’s Will.56 It was self-consciously an imitation of the originalPeople’s Will.

Three weeks before Lenin and the Bolsheviks staged their suc-cessful, bloodless coup, Lenin was hiding in Finland. He did not returnto Russia until October 20 (Russian calendar), a week before theBolsheviks’ coup.57 From this sanctuary, Lenin wrote a letter to theCommunist Party’s city conference in St. Petersburg on October 7. He

Page 319: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

58. “Lenin to the Petrograd City Conference,” Collected Works, XXVI, p. 148.

59. The other perpetual economic failure was the shortage of housing, but the annualneed to import food from abroad could not be concealed internationally; the housingshortage was less visible to outsiders.

60. Alec Nove, “The Incomes of Soviet Peasants,” The Slavonic and East EuropeanReview, XXXVIII (1960), p. 330.

1258

recommended a three-part program as the basis of overthrowing theKerensky government: (1) the transfer of additional land to thepeasants, (2) the offer of an immediate and just peace to the Germans,and (3) anti-capitalist measures that would insure that the armyreceived bread, clothing, and footwear.58 This at least was reminiscentof the “peace, land, and bread” slogan. Liberty was missing from hislist. It would remain missing in Russia for the next seven and a halfdecades.

Land did not prove sufficient to bring the blessings of bread to theSoviet Union. Daily bread in a self-sufficient Soviet Union remaineda failed dream of Communists, who were forced from the first coupto the second in 1991 (failed) to rely on imports of food from theWest. Liberty, not land, is the key element in successful agriculture.Poor land owned by free men is more productive than good landowned by the State and worked by slaves of the State. The commissarsof Soviet agriculture could not admit this and remain alive in Stalin’sday. After his death, they could not admit this and keep their jobs,which gave them State-subsidized access to imported food.

Soviet agriculture was always the greatest visible economic failureof Communism.59 For decades, the tiny half-acre plots controlled byindividual peasant families supplied a remarkable percentage of thenation’s food. In the 1950’s, something in the range of 30 percent ofall Soviet agricultural output came from these small family plots, yetthey received no allocation of fertilizer or equipment.60 Four decades

Page 320: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

61. Volin, Russian Agriculture, p. 110.

62. Marshall I. Goldman, USSR in Crisis: The Failure of an Economic System (NewYork: Norton, 1983), p. 63.

63. Ibid., p. 64.

64. Ibid., p. 65.

65. Volin, Russian Agriculture, p. 562.

66. Ibid., p. 566.

1259

after the Revolution, three decades after Stalin collectivized agricul-ture, this private sector produced half of the nation’s meat and pota-toes and almost all of the eggs. Prior to World War I, 1909–1913,Russia exported more grain than any other nation: 30 percent of theworld’s total, 11 million metric tons per year.61 After the revolution,this figure never exceeded 7.8 million,62 achieved in 1962,63 the yearbefore the great reversal of Soviet agriculture. By 1981, the USSRwas still a net importer of grain: 40 million metric tons.64 For theentire era of the USSR, the huge collective farms and state farmsstruggled in vain to feed the Soviet population adequately. As late as1953, the number of cattle was less than in 1916 on the same terri-tory.65 Russia did export grain after World War II, but only becausethe Communist State confiscated it to use as an export to gain West-ern currency. After the reversal of agricultural production underKhrushchev in 1963, the imports from the West began in earnest.66

The Communist Party hierarchy removed Khrushchev from office in1964, but the crisis could not be solved by Communist tinkering. TheSoviets’ dependence on imported grain was permanent. The USSRremained a net importer of grain – paid for, decade after decade, byhuge subsidies from Western governments – when it collapsed politic-

Page 321: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

67. This collapse had been predicted two years before by Judy Shelton: The ComingSoviet Crash: Gorbachev’s Desperate Pursuit of Credit in Western Financial Markets(New York: Macmillan, 1989). Two years after this economic collapse and his removalfrom office, Gorbachev was in charge of the Green Cross, an international ecologicalpropaganda organization. His headquarters were in the Presidio, the recently closed U.S.Army base in San Francisco. This was the fate of the national leader who the U.S.government had spent $300 billion a year to defend against in the late 1980’s– all the whilesupporting him and his regime with U.S. taxpayer-funded food. Such is late twentieth-century politics. Who won? The huge U.S. grain conglomerates and the armamentsindustry. For the sordid story of seven decades of U.S. aid to the USSR, see Antony Sutton,The Best Enemy Money Can Buy (Billings, Montana: Liberty House, 1986). I wrote theForeword.

68. Mikhail Heller and Aleksandr Nekrich, Utopia in Power: The History of the SovietUnion from 1917 to the Present (New York: Summit, [1982] 1986), p. 633.

1260

ally in 1991 because the West refused to increase these subsidies.67 Inthe 1971–73 period, the average Soviet agricultural worker harvestedfour and a half tons of grain per year; meanwhile, the average UnitedStates agricultural worker harvested over 54 tons.68 Poor land and ashort growing season were not the main reasons for Soviet foodshortages; collectivist tyranny was.

A fence, either literal or judicial, separated the collective farm’sproperty from the peasant family’s property. On one side of this boun-dary, the land brought forth much fruit. On the other side, it broughtforth so little fruit that the Soviet Union’s leaders for seven decadesblamed the agricultural shortfall on Russia’s bad weather, usuallydrought. Here was an official implicit announcement of a stupendousand continuous national miracle: rain in Russia apparently fell on onlyone side of these fences.

Two Forms of Representation

This preliminary discussion of Communist slogans and Soviet

Page 322: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

1261

agriculture may seem far afield from the wilderness in which God’slaw was first given to Israel. The ultimate issue, however, was ascontroversial in the twentieth century as in the days of Moses. Theissue was: Who owns the land? The Bible is clear: God owns the landand everything on it. “For every beast of the forest is mine, and thecattle upon a thousand hills” (Ps. 50:10). The secondary question isthis: Who acts as God’s lawful agent in the administration of anygiven plot of land? It is this question that has divided Christians fromvery early days.

God delegates two forms of limited sovereignty to man: judicialsovereignty and market sovereignty. The first we call ownership; thesecond we call consumer sovereignty. Each has its own respectivedoctrine of representation. The jubilee land law makes it clear that theheirs of the families of the conquest possessed judicial authority overIsrael’s rural land. This does not mean that these families possessedeconomic authority over the land. Control over any economic res-ource must be defended in the market. The person who owns a scarceeconomic resource – a resource that commands a price – either servesthose consumers who offer the high bids for the asset’s fruits of prod-uction or else he must content himself with a reduced level of income.If he experiences reduced income, he thereby pays for the privilege ofserving consumers other than those who offer the high bids. There istherefore a cost of serving low-bidding consumers: forfeited income.Over time, control of scarce resources moves, through the competitivebidding process, to those economic agents who most efficiently servethe consumers who offer the high bids. The profitable producers(consumer agents) buy productive assets from those who are lessprofitable.

The jubilee land law governed the leasing of rural land, and thereis no question that resident aliens and converts to the faith could buyand sell individual plots of land for up to 49 years. Thus, economic

Page 323: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

1262

authority over the land remained in the hands of consumers. Theycould, through their decisions to buy or not buy, establish who theireconomic representatives would be. Those economic agents who weremore responsive to the demands of consumers would prosper morethan those who were less responsive. Those agents who prosperedwould be in a strong position to lease the key agricultural resource:land. The heirs of the conquest retained long-term legal sovereigntyover the land as God’s agents. The more productive farmers couldnevertheless purchase economic authority over the land as theconsumers’ agents. In 42 years out of 50, consumers were authorizedby God to exercise primary authority – economic authority – throughtheir agents: the more efficient farmers.

The primary mark of economic representation in Mosaic Israel wasthe lease. God delegated far more economic authority to the efficientproducer than to the original owner. This points to the minimaleconomic impact of the jubilee land law. This law was not primarilyeconomic; it was primarily judicial. It established freemanship, not aguaranteed income. In a free society, only consumers can establish aland owner’s income, and consumers are notoriously fickle. Theyguarantee nothing to any of their representatives. “What have youdone for me lately?” is their rallying cry. “What will you do for menow, and at what price?” is their battle cry. The authority of theconsumer rests on his right to change his mind until he signs acontract.

Conclusion

God’s covenantal sanctions in history are corporate. Positivesanctions rest on the obedience of individuals: representatives. Theboundaries of Mosaic Israel were primarily judicial and secondarily

Page 324: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

1263

geographical. Within these boundaries, climate itself was bound to thestipulations of God’s national covenant. The rain would fall in dueseason if the nation’s representatives remained faithful. Theserepresentatives included the high priest, priests in general, Levites,civil rulers, and heads of households.

The positive sanctions listed in this passage are land and peace,bread and wine. The Levitical laws governing ownership prove that itwas not the civil government which was the primary representativeagent in Mosaic Israel. It was not the State which was to createnational economic planning for agriculture. The success or failure ofIsrael’s agriculture depended on the obedience of the people, manifes-ted publicly in the behavior of their representatives, i.e., their leaders.The primary form of government is self-government, and the leadershad to begin with self-government, as did every other Israelite.Corporate responsibility flows from individual responsibility.

The promised sanction of rain in due season was unique to MosaicIsrael. It was not a cross-boundary sanction. In the New Covenant,the universality of common grace governs the climate, just as it didoutside of the place of residence of the Israelites under the OldCovenant. Rain and sunshine fall on covenant-breakers and covenant-keepers without distinction in the New Covenant. Climate is no longerGod’s agent of judicial sanctions. God’s law governs man’s legalrelationships, and obedience to His law-order is what determinespredictable corporate sanctions in New Covenant history. Societiescan overcome the restraints (boundaries) of climate through obedienceto God’s law.

The doctrine of representation is inherent in any system of biblicalauthority. The judicial representatives of the land were the heirs of theconquest. The economic representatives of the consumers were thosewho were willing to buy their continued control over the land. Controlover the land was to be maintained by those who used the land least

Page 325: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

1264

wastefully in serving those who offered the high bids for the fruits ofthe land: consumers. It was the consumers’ authority over the landthat Mosaic law defended in 49 years out of 50.

The covenantal promise of bread and wine has sacramental over-tones. It points to the communion of God and man at a meal: themarriage supper of the lamb (Rev. 19:9). Israel was also promisedland and peace. From an economic standpoint, land is not nearly socrucial as freedom in producing the largest possible quantities of breadand wine. The law of God provided freedom; the land was secondary.The law was given at Sinai before the generation of wandering. Thestipulations would remain basic to continued prosperity in the land.Obedience was the foundation of the promised positive sanctions.Corporate prosperity is therefore ethically conditional.

Summary

The covenantal blessings of Leviticus 26 are corporate.Covenantally predictable sunshine and rain were land sanctions:

unique to Mosaic Israel.Outside of Israel’s boundaries, other covenantally predictable sanc-

tions did operate: Nineveh.Without special grace, no society can maintain the covenant’s

external, common grace blessings indefinitely.Corporate responsibility is representative.Obedience is always partly individual.Ten representatives would have sufficed to save Sodom.In Elijah’s day, 7,000 did not suffice to save Israel from captivity.No percentage of citizens is mentioned in the Mosaic law as

automatically establishing national representation.In some cases, one man visibly represented Israel.The high priest was the primary representative on a continuous

Page 326: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

1265

basis, not the king.The covenant’s promises are ethical.Ethics establishes boundaries of acceptable behavior.These boundaries are not predominately civil.They are covenantal: individual, familial, ecclesiastical, and civil.No human agency has final, total authority in history.Self-government is primary.Information costs are lowest at this level of government.Corporate responsibility flows from individual responsibility,

beginning with Adam.Leviticus begins with ecclesiastical stipulations.Next were family stipulations (Lev. 18; 20).Next came personal stipulations (Lev. 19; 25).Fourth in importance came civil stipulations.Corporate sanctions invoke representative government: body and

head.Leviticus 25 indicates that Mosaic ownership was familial.The crucial inheritance was freemanship.The State was to enforce God’s lease contract in year 50.The jubilee law was the most important corporate civil law in

Mosaic Israel: the freemanship law.Freemanship was an enforceable judicial boundary.The jubilee law was primarily a defense of legal rights.God alone promised positive economic sanctions, not the State.God’s primary means of blessing is through the family.Civil sanctions are exclusively negative: to insure peace.Peace means placing a quarantine around violence and fraud.This quarantine begins with conscience.It moves to family government.Civil government can sustain peace only through God’s common

grace, and ultimately through special grace.

Page 327: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 33 . . . Leviticus 26:3–6

1266

The blessing of rain was God’s response to obedience (Lev. 26:4).The blessings of sunshine and rain are now common (Matt. 5:45).The focus of Jesus’ teaching was Christians’ righteous judgment:

showing equal justice to all, analogous to sunshine and rain.God’s justice is impartial and therefore ethically conditional.Rain in due season is not representative of all of God’s common

grace blessings in the New Covenant, contrary to Kline’s assumption.Rain is a blessing in the context of agriculture.Rain produces grain and grapes: bread and wine.Rain and sunshine can become common curses: flooding and

drought.Climate is not the means of God’s predictable covenant sanctions

in the New Testament economy.It was in Moses’ day.When the Promised Land ceased to be a kingdom boundary,

climate ceased to be the means of predictable blessing and cursing.The locus of predictable sanctions moved from climate to society.This process had begun at the conquest: from predictable manna to

predictable inheritance.The American myth of the plow and the plains was a myth of

environmental determinism: works religion.The predictability of climate’s sanctions in Mosaic Israel was

representative of God’s predictable justice in history.By showing equally impartial grace, Christians bring covenant-

breakers under God’s condemnation (Rom. 12:19–21).Our mercy overcomes Satan’s kingdom in history: a means of

Christianity’s historical dominion.Rebellion against common grace increases the wrath of God in

history against evil-doers.Peace and land were Mosaic covenantal sanctions. Bread and wine were Abrahamic sacramental sanctions (Gen. 14:

Page 328: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Nature as a Sanctioning Agent

1267

18).Lenin used such language as religious-political slogans in 1917.Liberty was missing from his slogan: the source of the other bless-

ings.Who owned the Promised Land? God.Who acted as God’s judicial agents in administering the land? Heirs

of the conquest’s families: owners.Who acted as God’s economic agents? Consumers, whose decis-

ions allocated ownership of rural land.The jubilee transferred ownership to the heirs: one year in 50.Economic representation was manifested by the lease.

Page 329: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1268

34

LIMITS TO GROWTH

For I will have respect unto you, and make you fruitful, and multiplyyou, and establish my covenant with you. And ye shall eat old store,and bring forth the old because of the new (Lev. 26:9–10).

The theocentric meaning of this passage is easy to summarize: God,who is the author of life, establishes the covenantal laws governinglife.

A Biological Promise

The biological promise in verse 9 is two-fold: the multiplication ofobedient covenant-keepers in history and the equal or greater multi-plication of their crops. This two-fold promise is covenantal. It istherefore ethically conditional.

The dual positive sanctions of a growing population and growingfood supplies are tied to the law of God. As in the case of every posi-tive covenantal sanction, there is an unstated assumption: the threatof negative sanctions. In this case, the negative sanctions match thepositive sanctions: (1) zero population growth or even populationdecline; (2) hunger. Corporate disobedience calls forth these negativesanctions.

Were these two sanctions part of what I have called seed and landlaws? No. A seed law, in the sense that I am using it in this com-mentary, was tied to the promised Seed, the Messiah, the prophesiedson of Judah. It had to do with maintaining the tribal divisions inMosaic Israel until Shiloh came (Gen. 49:10). The earlier promisegiven to Abraham regarding the multiplication of his heirs through the

Page 330: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

1. “Now to Abraham and his seed were the promises made. He saith not, And to seeds,as of many; but as of one, And to thy seed, which is Christ” (Gal. 3:16).

1269

Seed, Jesus Christ (seed, in Paul’s sense)1 was not a seed law sanctionin the sense that I am using the term, i.e., Jacob’s later prophecy.Jacob’s prophecy governed the promise up to the coming of the Seed:the end of the Old Covenant. God’s promise to Abraham regardingthe multiplication of his seed – heirs – applies to both Old and NewCovenants: a cross-boundary covenant and promise (Gen. 15:5). Itsmark in the Old Covenant was circumcision (Gen. 17:10). This was acovenantal stipulation in the sense of confession rather thangeography: a visible boundary separation from covenant-breakersrather than geographical boundary separations among biological units(tribes). Leviticus 26:9 is an application of the Abrahamic covenant,not Jacob’s tribal prophecy.

Broadly covenantal sanctions applied outside of the land of Israel.That is, these covenantal sanctions were common grace sanctions.Societies that obeyed the covenant’s external laws would prosper;those that rebelled would not. The promise of high population growthin this passage was an implicit threat of reduced population forrebellion. The archetype of this threat was Noah’s Flood: a pre-Abrahamic sanction. God will not again bring a flood to cut off allmankind, but He does reduce the populations of rebellious societies,primarily through the covenantally predictable effects of socialorganization in a particular natural environment.

The Curse of Hunger

Hunger is a major covenantal threat in God’s law. “Because thouservedst not the LORD thy God with joyfulness, and with gladness of

Page 331: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

1270

heart, for the abundance of all things; Therefore shalt thou serve thineenemies which the LORD shall send against thee, in hunger, and inthirst, and in nakedness, and in want of all things: and he shall put ayoke of iron upon thy neck, until he have destroyed thee” (Deut. 28:47–48). Again, “They that be slain with the sword are better than theythat be slain with hunger: for these pine away, stricken through forwant of the fruits of the field” (Lam. 4:9).

Food is therefore a major covenantal blessing. This blessing isstated in Leviticus 25:10 in a way that is easily recognized by anagricultural people: “And ye shall eat old store, and bring forth the oldbecause of the new.” The time of greatest potential crisis for anagricultural society is the period immediately preceding the harvest.The old store is running low; the new store has not yet arrived. Theword for “old” is used with regard to the stored produce in the yearfollowing the jubilee year. “And ye shall sow the eighth year, and eatyet of old fruit until the ninth year; until her fruits come in ye shall eatof the old store” (Lev. 25:22). God’s promise is not slack. Israel neednot fear famine; the stored crop will not be entirely consumed beforethe new crop is harvested.

This means that the covenantal blessing of “fruitfulness” wascomprehensive, applying equally to the fertility of obedient covenant-keeping families and to their crops. The rate of human populationgrowth inside the boundaries of Israel would be matched by the rateof population growth in the fields. In this way, God promised toconfirm His covenant publicly. He promised a growing population inIsrael: the application of Genesis 1:28 and Genesis 9:7 to His coven-ant people, the true heirs of the promise. This means that God’scorporate, covenantal standard for the expansion of covenant-keepingfamilies is above 2.1 children per family, which is the biological re-placement rate.

The modern world understands hunger as a threat to humanity –

Page 332: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

2. An example: the decision by Western nations in the late 1960's to dig water wells insub-Sahara Africa, which led the nomads to locate their herds close to the “free” water.This produced overgrazing and famine in the mid-1970’s. See Claire Sterling, “The Makingof the Sub-Saharan Wasteland,” Atlantic Monthly (May 1974).

3. Appendix I: “Malthusianism vs. Covenantalism.”

1271

not a curse, which is personal, but a threat. Unlike the Bible, a major-ity of modern humanist intellectuals and their accomplices withinChristianity have contrasted the blessing of food with populationgrowth. They have argued since the mid-1960’s that in order for theworld’s poorest people to attain sufficient food supplies, they must bewilling to reduce the size of their families. These intellectuals havealso frequently argued that the West, which has abundant quantitiesof food, must give away food to the world’s poor. This means havingWestern governments give food away to the governments of ThirdWorld (aid-receiving) nations. Such political food transfers have beengoing on throughout the post-World War II era.

Anti-population growth proponents refuse to admit that there is nospecter of famine haunting the vast majority of humanity, and whereit does haunt a handful of small, backward nations, all located inAfrica, this is the result of government policies, such as: (1) war,especially civil war; (2) a government monopoly on the purchase offood from farmers, with prices set far below market prices; or (3)government intervention into the local agricultural economy.2 That isto say, people face food shortages because the free market is notallowed to function.3

Physical Limits to Growth

Boundaries are limits. In a finite world, there are limits to every

Page 333: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

4. Gary North, “The Theology of the Exponential Curve,” The Freeman (May 1970);reprinted in North, An Introduction to Christian Economics (Nutley, New Jersey: CraigPress, 1973), ch. 8.

5. Lincoln H. and Alice Taylor Day, Too Many Americans (New York: Delta, [1963]1965); William and Paul Paddock, Famine – 1975! America’s Decision: Who Will Survive?(Boston: Little, Brown, 1967); Paul Ehrlich, The Population Bomb (New York: Ballantine,1968); Gordon Rattray Taylor, The Biological Time Bomb (New York: World, 1968);Population and the American Future, the Report of the Commission on Population Growthand the American Future (New York: New American Library, 1972). For an economist’scritique, see Jacqueline Kasun, The War Against Population: The Economics and Ideologyof World Population Control (San Francisco: Ignatius, 1988).

6. Ezra J. Mishan, The Costs of Economic Growth (New York: Praeger, 1967); Mishan,The Economic Growth Debate: An Assessment (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1977);Donella Meadows, et al., The Limits to Growth (New York: Universe Books, 1972); E. F.

1272

promise of growth. These limits may be geographical or they may beeconomic, but there are limits to growth. This is the inescapable real-ity of finitude. The process of compound physical growth cannot goon forever in a finite world. Growth has temporal limits.4

God calls for population growth because He calls for covenantalobedience. He wants to see positive growth in covenant-keeping soc-ieties. Long-term compound growth is a moral imperative in God’scovenantal universe. Long-term stagnation is a sign of God’s curse.Yet there are unquestionably limits to growth. This is why God’s callfor population growth points to God’s final judgment at the end ofhistory and the transformation of mankind into a host like the angels:fixed numbers, either in the lake of fire (Rev. 20:14–15) or in the res-urrected New Heaven and New Earth (Rev. 21:1–2).

Covenant-breakers who do not wish to think about the final judg-ment have become advocates of zero population growth: an exchange,either compulsory or voluntary, either natural or political, of a com-pounding human population for extra eons of time. The growingacceptance by intellectuals in the West of the zero-population growthmovement5 and the zero economic growth movement,6 which became

Page 334: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

Schumacher, Small Is Beautiful: Economics As If People Mattered (New York: Harper &Row, 1973); Mancur Olson and Hans H. Landsberg (eds.), The No-Growth Society (NewYork: Norton, 1973); Leopold Kohr, The Overdeveloped Nations: The Diseconomies ofScale (New York: Schocken, 1977). For a critique, see E. Calvin Beisner, Prospects forGrowth: A Biblical View of Population, Resources, and the Future (Westchester, Illinois:Crossway, 1990).

7. Robert L. Sasone, Handbook on Population (Author, 1972), p. 98.

1273

a unified cause and intellectual fad almost overnight in the mid-1960’s,testifies to the presence of widespread covenant-breaking andphilosophies to match. In 1970, the world’s population could havebeen housed in American middle-class comfort in a city the size ofTexas and New Mexico – 15 percent of United States land – with apopulation density no larger than what one-third of Americansexperienced. If people had been content to live in a city as crowded asNew York City, they could all have fit in the state of Montana.7 Yetintellectuals became fearful of the “population bomb.”

Living Space

At some point, even covenant-keepers will run out of living spaceif they continue to grow in number. They will reach environmentallimits: boundaries beyond which man’s dominion cannot extend. Weneed to consider three facts regarding man’s limits to growth. First,any rate of growth, if compounded, eventually becomes exponential.The population of any multiplying species approaches infinity as alimit. But environmental finitude makes its presence felt long beforepopulation infinitude is reached. The environment places limits ongrowth. No species can maintain a positive growth rate indefinitely.Second, mankind, unlike the angels, is not a numerically fixed host inhistory. Yet mankind is ultimately limited by the environment. This

Page 335: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

8. Gary North, The Dominion Covenant: Genesis, 2nd ed. (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1987), ch. 21.

1274

fact points to the ultimate limit to growth: time. At some point,mankind will reach its maximum population. Third, and by far themost significant fact, this point in time of maximum population isreached when God returns in final judgment. What must be under-stood is that this maximum population limit is covenantal more thanenvironmental. It comes because God runs out of mercy for covenant-breakers, not because mankind runs out of living space or food.

The limits of nature and the reality of compound growth indicate apoint in history when mankind reaches a maximum. We do not knowwhere this point is – it is in this sense indeterminate – but we knowthat the environment does impose limits. The economist’s evidence forthis is the rising price of some goods in relation to others. One thingcannot grow forever. It is governed by what the economist calls thelaw of diminishing returns.8 But this “Newtonian” insight is significantonly insofar as it warns rational covenant-breakers of the reality offinitude and the limits to growth. The reality of finitude is not nearlyso significant a limit as the reality of covenantal rebellion. It is notmankind’s fertility in general that presses our species toward itsbiological limits; it is rather covenant-breaking man’s rebellion thatreaches God’s judicial limits in history. While the logic of finitudedoes warn scientific man of autonomous mankind’s limits – thedestruction of all meaning in the heat death of the universe (absolutezero) – this insight can be misinterpreted by covenant-breakers. Theycan (and have) proposed technical solutions to a covenantal problem.One such proposed solution is the zero-growth ideology.

Limits: Newtonian vs. Covenantal

Page 336: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

9. There are some journalists and social thinkers who prefer to substitute quantummechanics for Newtonian mechanics as a model for social theory. They want to escape theNewtonian world’s determinate limits to growth by means of an appeal to theindeterminacy of the quantum world: physical indeterminacy, not merely conceptual. Thetwo most prominent American authors who take this approach are George Gilder andWarren Brookes. At the time of his death in December of 1991, Brookes was working ona book developing this idea. He and I had spent hours on the phone discussing this issue.He had presented an early version of his thesis in The Economy in Mind (New York:Universe Books, 1982), ch. 1. He was a Christian Scientist and leaned toward acceptingnon-physical explanations of man’s condition. Gilder outlines his thesis in Microcosm(New York: Simon & Schuster, 1989). Eloquent as Gilder is regarding the exponentialincrease in the power of computers, he cannot apply his thesis to population growth. Bodiescannot escape into the realm of the quantum in order to evade the limits to growth. Gilderinvokes Moore’s Law, which says that the number of transistors on commercial microchipsdoubles every 18 months. This law has held true since the late 1950’s. The law seems toovercome certain physical limits. But Moore’s Law does not overcome the limits onbiological growth. Moore’s Law was discovered by Gordon Moore, the co-founder of Intel,the largest American microchip producer. On Moore’s Law and its commercialimplications, see Robert X. Cringely (pseudonym), Accidental Empires (New York:Addison-Wesley, 1992), pp. 41, 144, 306–7.

1275

According to a strictly Newtonian interpretation of the environ-mental limits to growth, the faster the rate of compound growth, thesooner growth will cease or time will run out. The greater the bless-ings of growth, the shorter the time remaining before time runs out ormankind ceases to grow. Man’s limits are regarded as exclusivelyenvironmental.

The Bible speaks of other limits as more fundamental. God bringsfinal judgment in response to a final rebellion of human covenant-breakers against human covenant-keepers (Rev. 20:7–10). The discus-sion of the limits to growth needs to be framed in terms of the Bible’scovenantal limits – moral, judicial, and eschatological – rather than interms of Newtonian environmental limits: mathematical, physical, andbiological.9

The growth of population points either to the limits of growth orthe limits of time. Because the Bible affirms that the limits tocovenant-keeping man’s population growth are covenantal rather than

Page 337: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

1276

biological, the Bible affirms that there will be a final judgment. TheBible’s promise of growth in one segment of the human population –covenant-keepers – is a testimony to the end of history. Men areexpected to obey God’s law; if they do, God promises to extend tothem the positive sanction of growth. Therefore, time will run out.But, the Bible also tells us, time will run out before mankind pressesagainst unyielding environmental limits. The primary limit to growthin history is covenantal. The environmental limits to growth are merelytheoretical – not hypothetical, but determinate physical limits that areindeterminate in man’s knowledge.

Social Limits to Growth

The more fundamental limits to growth are social. This is theeconomic manifestation of the covenantal principle of hierarchy. Noteveryone can attend the best universities, drive the finest automobiles,and wear the latest fashions. These goods are limited in supply. Wecannot produce many more of them, so competition to use or ownthem is intense. Fred Hirsch uses the analogy of the person at a sport-ing event who wants to see the game more clearly. He stands up. Buteventually, others also stand up. Then one person stands on tiptoe.Others do the same. Eventually, the tallest people with the strongestlower leg muscles get the best view. So, society informally agrees tosit down at sporting events and in concert halls, since this is lesstaxing on everyone’s leg muscles, and in the long run, nobody canovercome his height limits. Hirsch’s point: in this case – seeing overeveryone’s head – what a few people can do, not everyone can do at

Page 338: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

10. Fred Hirsch, The Social Limits to Growth (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1978),p. 11.

1277

the same time. He calls such goods and services positional goods.10

As economic growth continues, more and more people can afford tobuy these goods, so more will be produced. When this happens, thesegoods lose their initial character: providing the owners with status,i.e., position. Other goods and services, more fixed in number, arethen sought by those seeking status. There will always be positionalgoods.

Legal Barriers to Entry

One of the ways that the rich defend themselves from new com-petitors is to create government barriers to entry. They get lawspassed to keep “the unwashed” middle classes and successful entre-preneurs at a safe distance. Their problem is that the free marketsystem extends wealth to many people. As economist Thomas Sowelldescribes it, the poor can outbid the rich collectively; there are somany of them. Land developers start buying of formerly unoccupiedland in order to sell condominiums and other smaller property units tothe upper middle class. Businessmen serve the needs of the less richbecause the world of the less rich is where the money is. The less richcollectively bid valuable property away from the rich. This isespecially true of scarce resources such as beachfront property andwilderness areas located within driving distance of commercialairports. In response to this competitive threat to their “free ride” –scenery they do not own or are afraid their rich neighbors’ heirs willsell to developers – the rich seal off land adjacent to their valuableproperty in the name of preserving the environment. They do this by

Page 339: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

11. Thomas Sowell, “Those Phony Environmentalists,” Los Angeles Herald Examiner(March 23, 1979); reprinted in Sowell, Pink and Brown People and Other ControversialEssays (Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press, 1981), pp. 104–5. See my summaryin North, Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1990), pp. 584–87.

12. Nelson W. Aldrich, Jr., Old Money: The Mythology of America’s Upper Class (NewYork: Knopf, 1988), pp. 158–69. Aldrich is the great-grandson of the U. S. Senator whoin 1912 introduced the original version of the legislation that created the Federal ReserveSystem (1913), the quasi-private U.S. central bank. The original Aldrich became fabulouslywealthy as a pay-off from the business and banking interests that controlled him throughouthis career, as this book chronicles without remorse.

13. Ibid., p. 160.

1278

having the State legislate limits on all new real estate development.11

Members of the wealthiest class in the United States – what someanalysts have called “Old Money” – have for over a century regardedthemselves as the trustees of the nation’s beautiful things: art andscenic land. By trustees, they have in mind those special people whocan properly maintain these assets, mainly for themselves and theirown social class. As the value of these scarce positional goods hasincreased, these self-appointed trustees have sought government inter-vention to enable them to keep the middle classes away from thesetreasures.

Nature is regarded by the Old Money as the means of an ordealprocess (i.e., initiation rite) which the young males of this class aresupposed to experience as a means of both health and maturation.12

For example, at the age of 23, future author Francis Parkman (TheOregon Trail, 1849) was sent west by his wealthy Boston family forhis health just prior to the California gold strike that launched thegreat gold rush. Over the next half century, he was followed by manyothers of his class.13 Among them was the Old Money’s most famouscareer model, Theodore Roosevelt, who spent much of his youth inthe West shooting game, and who, as President of the United States

Page 340: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

14. Ibid., p. 161.

15. Ibid., p. 158.

16. Ibid., p. 169.

17. Ibid., pp. 222–23. For a brief survey of these three groups, see Jo Kwong Echard,Protecting the Environment: Old Rhetoric, New Imperatives (Washington, D.C.: CapitalResearch Center, 1990), Appendixes 8–10.

1279

(1900–1909), became the legendary promoter of conservation andFederal land control through a system of national parks.14

A new paganism has appeared, and members of the Old Rich havebeen its dedicated promoters. As Nelson Aldrich, one of their own,wrote in 1988: “Nature worship today is laying the spiritual and insti-tutional groundwork for the closest thing to a widespread social relig-ion (as opposed to the individualistic religion of success) that Ameri-cans have ever had. Nature is sacred to millions of people in America.. . .”15

We have now entered the political battle for control over nature, hesays, a battle that is both religious and economic. “The social religionof Nature, which began with rich kids going outdoors for their health,ends in political action against the market – the condo developers, theshopping-mall impresarios, the army of entrepreneurs whom OldMoney (and not Old Money alone) imagines to be despoilingArcadia.”16 As Aldrich’s book makes clear, the Old Money deeplydistrusts and sometimes even despises the open-entry system knownas the free market, for the free market transfers economic power tothe masses. This is why Old Money supports such organizations as theNature Conservancy, the Wilderness Society, and the Sierra Club.17

These groups are using their tax-exempt foundation status to buy upand seal off millions of acres of land across the nation. They use taxmoney to do it.

The system works approximately like this. First, these organizations

Page 341: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

18. Warren Brookes, Washington Times (Jan. 29, 1991), cited by Larry Abraham andFranklin Sanders, The Greening (Atlanta, Georgia: Soundview, 1993), p. 93.

19. Abraham and Sanders, Greening, pp. 51–53, 59–61, 93.

20. Aldrich, Old Money, p. 223.

1280

target certain prime wilderness areas. Second, individuals in the knowbuy land near these targeted areas, thereby locking up property that,in Warren Brookes’ words, is ideal for “profitable upscale adjacentresidential development that is then used to finance still more acquisi-tion.”18 Third, they use tax-deductible money to buy up the prime landthat makes the nearby developed areas valuable. Fourth, they sellthese prime parcels – but not the land designated for development –to the United States government, thereby halting any further develop-ment inside the newly “socialized” boundaries. Fifth, they developtheir privately owned parcels. Presto: a marvelous legal monopoly,purchased at low prices in part with taxpayers’ money. A similarprocess works internationally. Large New York banks – protected bythe United States government’s bank deposit insurance system andalso by the policies of the quasi-private Federal Reserve System – aremaking debt-for-nature swaps, exchanging their now-depreciatedThird World debt certificates for prime land in those nations.19 Thisprocess also can be used to remove prime land from development bythose other than the favored few.

Aldrich writes: “The roots of Old Money environmentalism go backto the most fiercely protected of all the treasures of Old Money, thesummer places on the coast of Maine, their ‘camps’ in the Adir-ondacks, their ranches out West.”20 An early operational model of thisplan was designed by John D. Rockefeller, Jr. He bought a summerhome on Mt. Desert Island in Maine. This unique island became thesummer center of America’s Establishment – the place where elitesfrom different fields – finance, industry, journalism, foreign policy, and

Page 342: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

21. William R. Hutchison, “Protestantism as Establishment,” in Hutchison (ed.), Betweenthe Times: The Travail of the Protestant Establishment in America, 1900–1960 (New York:Cambridge University Press, 1989), p. 10.

22. Peter Collier and David Horowitz, The Rockefellers: An American Dynasty (NewYork: Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1976), p. 147.

23. Ibid., p. 148; John Ensor Harr and Peter J. Johnson, The Rockefeller Century (NewYork: Charles Scribner’s Sons, 1988), p. 200.

1281

religion – met and mixed with each other.21 Rockefeller and EdselFord, along with other affluent neighbors, over a period of yearsbought up 5,000 acres on the island and then turned this property overto the National Park Service in 1916. This became the first nationalpark in the eastern states.22 Two pairs of favorable biographers insistthat this was in no way a self-serving act because Rockefeller thenwent on to promote national conservation all over the country.23 Onthe contrary, this conservation impulse is enormously self-serving.Buying up geographically unique and aesthetically desirable land forpersonal use and then placing the surrounding property under govern-ment control is part of a systematic elitist strategy. The rich maintainthe “unspoiled” wilderness which lies on the fringes of their spaciousretreats – “unspoiled” in this case meaning “legally cut off from theless rich.” The less rich may be allowed to hike in, but they are notallowed to buy land, build cabins, and in other ways permanently“spoil nature.” This process of selective exclusion through govern-ment control accelerated as the twentieth century moved forward.

Angelic Hosts Are Fixed; Races Are Not

Living species multiply. Angels do not. The angels constitute afixed host. In heaven and hell, the number of angels remains constant.

Page 343: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

1282

This fact of life is rarely discussed by theologians and never by socialtheorists. It should be. It is fundamental to understanding the ultimateorigin of the zero population growth ideology.

Satan rules representatively, just as God does. He rules hierarch-ically. But, unlike God, Satan is neither omniscient nor omnipotent.His decree is that of a creature: under God’s decree. This has organi-zational consequences for the way he exercises power. He is depend-ent on the supply of information flowing to him, whether from demon-ic beings or from other sources. This flow of information is limited. Itcontains “noise,” just as it does for humans. God is omniscient; Satanis not. He gets confused. He has trouble monitoring the thoughts andactivities of those under his covenant.

This flow of information is finite. So is his power to make decisionsand enforce them. To the extent that his sources of information andpower depend on the activities of those under his command, he facesa problem. The more people he needs to monitor, the greater the flowof accurate information necessary to his empire. The greater thenumber of people, the more strain this places on the resources at hisdisposal. In short, Satan’s host is put under ever-greater pressure asthe human population under their covenantal authority grows. This iseven more true of the pressures brought by those under God’s cov-enantal authority. The more covenant-keepers on earth, the more thebreakdown of Satan’s control. Like a juggler who has to keep agrowing number of oranges in the air, so is Satan.

People are a threat to Satan. They multiply; his demonic host doesnot. Even covenant-breakers pose a problem: the coordination ofSatan’s plans becomes more difficult as mankind’s numbers increase.Then there is the eschatological threat: a major move by the HolySpirit could adopt large numbers of covenant-breakers into the familyof God. When this happens, Satan’s fixed host will have their handsfull, to use a non-angelic expression. More than full: they will find

Page 344: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

24. The numbers of the judgments on earth described in Revelation 8 also indicate a two-to-one advantage.

25. Kenneth L. Gentry, Jr., He Shall Have Dominion: A Postmillennial Eschatology, 2nd.ed. (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, [1992] 1997).

1283

control over events slipping through the equivalent of their fingers.The increase of mankind’s numbers poses no threat to the host of

heaven, for God is absolutely sovereign. God is not dependent on Hisangels for information. God does not suffer from information over-load. There is no noise in God’s perception. The angels of heavenneed not rely on their own mastery of history. They rely on God.Thus, for the angels, the multiplication of humanity poses no organi-zational threat. They outnumber Satan’s host by two to one. Stars andangels are linked symbolically in Scripture. We read: “And thereappeared another wonder in heaven; and behold a great red dragon,having seven heads and ten horns, and seven crowns upon his heads.And his tail drew the third part of the stars of heaven, and did castthem to the earth: and the dragon stood before the woman which wasready to be delivered, for to devour her child as soon as it was born”(Rev. 12:3–4).24 Two-thirds were loyal.

A growing population creates problems for any creature whowould seek to control history. The addition of more humans createsproblems for Satan and his host. Men necessarily must represent eitherGod or Satan in history. Those who represent Satan are rebels, just ashe is. They cannot be trusted, just as he cannot be trusted. Thus, Satanbenefits from a growing population only insofar as he can keep themunder his covenant and entrap them. The threat of their rejection of hiscovenant grows ever-greater over time. More humans will join God’sforces, and more likelihood that God will send His promised days ofblessing.25

This is why the zero population growth movement and the abortion

Page 345: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

1284

movement can be accurately described as satanic. These movementsare not ethically neutral responses to widespread sociological forcesthat threaten mankind’s survival. They are religious movements thatare opposed to the positive blessings of God, which in turn promoteHis kingdom.

Israel’s Limits

The question for Israel was this: When these limits to populationgrowth were reached inside the nation’s geographical boundaries, howdid God expect the Israelites to overcome these population limits?There were either geographical limits or population limits. Walking tothe feasts placed geographical limits on Israel, but without limits onIsrael’s population, Israel’s geographical limits would be breached.Conclusion: God mandated another exodus beyond the borders ofIsrael when He established population expansion as His covenantalstandard. The Israelites were expected to move outside of the geo-graphical boundaries of Israel. This was the meaning of Christ’s meta-phor of new wine in old wineskins (Matt. 9:17): the fermenting newwine would burst its inflexible container. His people were alwaysintended to inherit the earth, not just the land of Israel.

For evildoers shall be cut off: but those that wait upon the LORD, theyshall inherit the earth (Ps. 37:9).

But the meek shall inherit the earth; and shall delight themselves in theabundance of peace (Ps. 37:11).

For such as be blessed of him shall inherit the earth; and they that becursed of him shall be cut off (Ps. 37:22).

Inheritance in Israel implied growth for obedient covenant-keepers:

Page 346: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

1285

growth in the number of heirs and growth in the value of theirindividual inheritances. But geographical limits – family land, triballand, national land – were judicially fixed by the terms of the conquest.A growing number of heirs necessitated a declining per capita landedinheritance within the Promised Land. This pointed to theeschatological nature of God’s covenantal laws of inheritance: atranscending of Israel’s geographical boundaries. The promised inheri-tance of covenant-keepers pointed to the breaking of the boundariesof the Promised Land. The limits to growth of confessional Israelwould not be the boundaries of geographical Israel. The originalconquest of Canaan would cease to be a limiting factor in the exten-sion of God’s covenantal boundaries.

Entropy

There is a trade-off between population growth and time remainingto mankind. The covenant-breaker understands this trade-off. Aboveall else, he wishes to escape final judgment, and understandably so.Thus, he seeks to find some way around the covenantal implicationsof population growth. One way of doing this is to deny that mankind’sgrowth will continue in history. It will stop, covenant-breakers insist,but this will not end history. Another way of doing this is to deny thathistory will end as a result of God’s Second Coming in final judgment.Instead, the universe itself will bring impersonal judgment to theprocesses of time: the heat death of the universe. This is the finaljudgment of the second law of thermodynamics: the one-waymovement of kinetic (potential) energy into heat. Entropy willsmother all life and motion, including time itself, in its frozen grip of

Page 347: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

26. Gary North, Is the World Running Down?: Crisis in the Christian Worldview (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1988), ch. 2.

1286

absolute zero.26 The covenant-breaker prefers this view of universal impersonal

death to the Bible’s view of personal death, meaning the second death:“And death and hell were cast into the lake of fire. This is the seconddeath. And whosoever was not found written in the book of life wascast into the lake of fire” (Rev. 20:14–15). Better the “heat death” ofthe universe – frozen wastes – than the eternal heat death of covenantbreakers.

Any attempt to place an absolute environmental limit aroundmankind’s long-term population growth, while simultaneously affirm-ing the extension of time beyond this absolute limit, is necessarily anattempt to deny or deflect the biblical doctrine of final judgment. It isthe inevitability of some final physical limit to the population growthof covenant-keepers that points to one of two things: (1) the futurebreaking of the corporate covenant, but without God’s temporaljudgments against covenant-breakers, and without the subsequentrestoration of His people, i.e., (a) a steady-state, zero-growthpopulation or (b) a shrinking population; or (2) the end of history,either because of (a) God’s final judgment or (b) the death of mankindas a species.

In order to affirm both the reliability and inevitability of God’scorporate, covenantal promises (i.e., His positive biological sanctions)in history, the Christian has to insist on the covenantal inevitability ofthe final judgment, when mankind will at last become a fixed host:covenant-keepers (New Heaven and New Earth) and covenant-breakers (lake of fire). Either man’s corporate growth will cease inhistory or history will cease. God’s covenantal promises point to thesecond option. The promises of God insist that corporate growth will

Page 348: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

27. Thomas Robert Malthus, An Essay on the Principle of Population (New York:Penguin Books, [1798] 1982), p. 71.

1287

not cease where men keep God’s covenant law-order. These promisesinclude the restoration in history of a formerly covenant-keepingsociety after its people have broken God’s law.

And I will restore thy judges as at the first, and thy counsellors as atthe beginning: afterward thou shalt be called, The city of righteous-ness, the faithful city (Isa. 1:26).

For I will restore health unto thee, and I will heal thee of thy wounds,saith the LORD; because they called thee an Outcast, saying, This isZion, whom no man seeketh after (Jer. 30:17).

Know therefore and understand, that from the going forth of thecommandment to restore and to build Jerusalem unto the Messiah thePrince shall be seven weeks, and threescore and two weeks: the streetshall be built again, and the wall, even in troublous times (Dan. 9:25).

The Malthusians

When Rev. Thomas Robert Malthus wrote his anonymous firstedition of his Essay on the Principle of Population (1798), he accel-erated a great debate over the desirability of population growth.Although in later editions of his famous essay he modified the starkenvironmentalism of the original, it is his original words that havebeen cited again and again: “Population, when unchecked, increasesin a geometrical ratio. Subsistence increases only in an arithmeticalratio.”27 Put another way, the population of the species man grows ata geometrical rate, while the populations that man consumes grow at

Page 349: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

28. The deep ecologists go beyond ecologists who want scientific planners to protect theenvironment in the name of mankind’s higher interests. The deep ecologists want natureto govern man, or at the very least, want scientific planners to sacrifice mankind’s desiresin the name of nature’s autonomy and therefore its authority over the wants of men.

29. Bill McKibben, The End of Nature (New York: Random House, 1989), p. 58.

30. Ibid., p. 174.

1288

an arithmetical rate. This indicates that man is something special increation: a species limited by its environment in a unique way. Also,geometrical (exponential) growth being what it is, mankind reaches itsenvironmental limits a lot faster than any other species does. How,then, can mankind keep growing? Why, by 1798, had not mankindlong since reached its limits to growth? Why was the population ofEurope accelerating rapidly by the time Malthus wrote his essay?There are no obvious answers, which may be why Malthus abandonedthis now-familiar phrase in the many subsequent editions of the essay.

From 1798 until today, there have been avid followers of someversion of Malthus’ error. They regard man as a cancer on a benignhost, nature. Western man is the most cancerous of all. Western manis dominion man, and this spells the end of nature, says “deep ecolo-gist”28 Bill McKibben: “We have deprived nature of its independence,and that is fatal to its meaning. Nature’s independence is its meaning;without it there is nothing but us.”29 He is correct: the Western worldstill lives intellectually in the shadow of Genesis 1:26–28. “The ideathat the rest of creation might count for as much as we do is spectacu-larly foreign, even to most environmentalists.”30 Man is seen by deepecologists as a uniquely destructive species in nature.

The question of man’s population growth is connected to thequestion of time. If man’s population growth remains positive, theneither time or space will run out eons before the heat death of the uni-verse brings its impersonal judgment on the universe. The humanist

Page 350: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

31. Ibid., p. 73.

1289

decries the first outcome – mankind’s filling up of his environmentalspace – because he recoils in terror at the thought of the second. Butman will fill the earth. This will fulfill a major aspect of the dominioncovenant (Gen. 1:28). After that comes the final rebellion and the finaljudgment (Rev. 20:7–9). This eschatological scenario alienateshumanists of both persuasions: mechanical and organic. It rests on apresupposition: the environment is under man. If true, then nature isnot autonomous.

The autonomy of nature implies the near-permanence of nature. Forthe humanist, man’s meaning must be subordinated to nature’spermanence. To save man from God’s judgments, man must submitto nature’s. McKibben writes: “The chief lesson is that the world dis-plays a lovely order, an order comforting in its intricacy. And the mostappealing part of this harmony, perhaps, is its permanence – the sensethat we are part of something with roots stretching back nearlyforever, and branches reaching forward just as far. Purely human lifeprovides only a partial fulfillment of this desire for a kind ofimmortality. . . . But the earth and all its processes – the sun growingplants, flesh feeding on these plants, flesh decaying to nourish moreplants, to name just one cycle – gives us some sense of a more endur-ing role.”31 It is nature’s cyclical processes within a temporallyunbounded universe that supposedly provide meaning to man, whoalone in the universe perceive nature’s meaning. If time is essentiallyunbounded but the environment is not, then man’s population must bemade bounded. A growing human population is a threat to this world-view: a worldview bounded by physical limits rather than temporal.Temporal limits are too dangerous, for they imply a God beyond timewho breaks into time, bringing final judgment.

The Malthusians challenge the possibility and therefore the legiti-

Page 351: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

32. Economists rarely discuss absolute limits. To them, all limits are marginal andrelative.

1290

macy of temporally unbounded compound growth. The idea that Godrewards covenantally faithful societies with expansion – numerically,economically, and geographically – appalls the Malthusians. Thegrowth-oriented secular economist is willing to challenge the Malthus-ian vision, but only because he refuses to discuss biological limits asabsolute limits.32 But there are biological limits, even though thehuman population may reach 30 billion or 40 billion or 500 billionbefore these limits are reached. The fact is, the biological limits tomankind’s growth on earth are measured in centuries, not eons. Thelimit of the speed of light restricts man’s geographical extension. Thisbrings covenant-breaking man face to face with one of two limits:biological expansion or temporal extension.

Conclusion

The fundamental economic issue is not population growth. It is notthe increase of food per capita. It is not capital invested per person.The fundamental economic issue is ethical: God’s covenant. Neverthe-less, the language of Leviticus 26:9–10 is agricultural. Why? Becausein an agricultural society, the mark of God’s blessing is food. Godpromised to provide bread for all. He also promised to increase theirnumbers.

This does not mean that He promised nothing else to them. Hepromised an agricultural people access in history to the city of God,the New Jerusalem (Rev. 21). The city of God is the image of a regen-erate society. The city is therefore not inherently evil. Urban life is notinherently depersonalizing. Covenant-breaking is evil and deper-

Page 352: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

33. Gary North, Millennialism and Social Theory (Tyler, Texas: Institute for ChristianEconomics, 1990), chaps. 4, 5, 9.

1291

sonalizing. Covenant-breaking is made less expensive in cities becauseof the higher costs of gathering information about individual actions,as well as the higher costs of imposing informal social sanctions. Theanonymity of urban life makes social pressures to conform to moralstandards much less effective than they are in rural or small-townregions. But covenant-breaking is not uniquely inherent to cities. Itcan be overcome through God’s grace.

If this were not the case, then the promise of population growthwould be a threat to the covenant. A covenantal blessing would inevit-ably become a covenantal curse. The grace of God would necessarilyproduce the wrath of God. This is the operational viewpoint of bothpremillennialism and amillennialism regarding church history, but it isa false view of history.33 While covenantal blessings can and have ledto corporate covenant-breaking, just as God warns (Lev. 26; Deut. 8;28), they do not inevitably lead to them. The covenant’s blessings areconditional; they do not continue indefinitely irrespective of corporateobedience. God’s negative corporate sanctions come in history, andthen society is given another opportunity to repent and rebuild: “Andthey shall build the old wastes, they shall raise up the formerdesolations, and they shall repair the waste cities, the desolations ofmany generations” (Isa. 61: 4).

The biblical view of history is growth-oriented. It not only pro-claims the possibility of population expansion and increasing wealthper capita, it also establishes these as mandatory corporate goals inhistory. Until mankind becomes a fixed host at the end of history –covenant-breakers in the lake of fire eternally (Rev. 20:14–15), cov-enant-keepers developing the New Heaven and New Earth (Rev. 21;22) – covenant-keeping mankind is expected by God to grow in

Page 353: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

1292

numbers, wealth, and influence.

Summary

The promise of multiplied people and food is ethically conditional.It is covenantal in the broad sense, i.e., Abrahamic rather than

Jacobic or Mosaic.It refers back to God’s promise to multiply Abraham’s seed

(plural).It is not a seed law in the tribal sense: an aspect of Jacob’s proph-

ecy regarding the seed of Judah (singular).This promise and its conditional sanctions – positive and negative

– are therefore universal in scope.Hunger is a major covenantal sanction; food is a major covenantal

blessing.Israelites could count on food to match mouths in times of obedi-

ence.Population growth need not be a threat.The growth of population and food is intended to confirm God’s

covenant.Modern intellectuals regard hunger as a threat. They also regard population growth as a threat, with or without

hunger.There is no threat of famine in most of the world today except in a

handful of backward, socialist, civil war-torn nations.There are limits to growth in a finite world.Long-term compound growth is a moral imperative, for it is the

result of covenantal obedience.As population expands, it will eventually press against environ-

mental limits: boundaries.

Page 354: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Limits to Growth

1293

This points to the end of history and final judgment: the ultimatetemporal boundary.

Modern humanists resent this temporal, covenantal boundary.Some critics call for zero population growth.Covenant-breaking men bring judicial limits in history: the final

judgment (Rev. 20:7–10).Man’s ultimate boundary limits are covenantal: moral, judicial, and

eschatological.Newtonian limits are spatial and temporal.Quantum mechanics may not have physical limits, some theorists

believe.Population growth of any species always has limits.There are social limits to growth.There must therefore always be hierarchy.A good analogy is standing on tiptoe at a sports event: the tallest

people will get the best view (hierarchy).There are positional goods: limits on simultaneous enjoyment or

use.Many poor people together can bid up the price of certain position-

al goods: e.g., scenic property.Rich people often use the State to establish legal claims on posi-

tional goods rather than competing economically with the masses forthem.

Angelic hosts are fixed in number; species are not.As men multiply, the noise in Satan’s hierarchy increases.The coordination problem in a centralized top-down economy or

hierarchy increases exponentially as men multiply.Satan cannot increase the number of demons to deal with multi-

plying covenant-keepers.As covenant-keepers multiply, they overload Satan’s hierarchy.A mass conversion to saving faith is a major threat to Satan’s hier-

Page 355: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 34 . . . Leviticus 26:9–10

1294

archical management of events.God’s promise of multiplication gave Israel the goal of worldwide

expansion and dominion.This testified to temporal limits on Israel’s geographical boun-

daries: new wine in old wineskins.God’s laws of landed inheritance would eventually be transcended.Confessional Israel would break the limits of geographical Israel,

if they kept the ethical terms of the covenant.There is a trade-off between time remaining to man and mankind’s

population growth.Covenant-breaking man wants to evade final judgment.He prefers the impersonal judgment of the heat death of the uni-

verse to God’s final judgment of the eternal heat death of the lake offire.

The blessing of population growth points to the end of growthwhen history ends and mankind becomes a fixed host, like the angels.

Man’s growth will cease because history will cease: either in God’sjudgment or the heat death of the universe.

Malthus’ 1798 essay came out against population growth.His intellectual heirs today regard mankind as a cancer.Some Malthusians have adopted faith in cyclical history as a way

out of the time-growth dilemma.The temporal limits of mankind’s compound population growth are

measured in centuries, not eons: exponential growth.The fundamental economic issue is ethical: the covenant.Covenant-keepers can enjoy food in their cities if they remain

obedient.The biblical view of history is pro-growth.

Page 356: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1295

35

GOD’S ESCALATING WRATH

I am the LORD your God, which brought you forth out of the land ofEgypt, that ye should not be their bondmen; and I have broken thebands of your yoke, and made you go upright. But if ye will nothearken unto me, and will not do all these commandments; And if yeshall despise my statutes, or if your soul abhor my judgments, so thatye will not do all my commandments, but that ye break my covenant:I also will do this unto you; I will even appoint over you terror, con-sumption, and the burning ague, that shall consume the eyes, andcause sorrow of heart: and ye shall sow your seed in vain, for yourenemies shall eat it. And I will set my face against you, and ye shallbe slain before your enemies: they that hate you shall reign over you;and ye shall flee when none pursueth you (Lev. 26:13–17).

The theocentric issue here is the fear of God, which is related toHis law and its negative sanctions.

Sanctions and Succession

This passage introduces that section of Leviticus 26 which lists thetypes of negative corporate sanctions in history that Israel couldexpect if God’s covenant people violated God’s law. As is true ofDeuteronomy 28, a parallel passage on corporate sanctions, the nega-tive sanctions greatly outnumber the positive sanctions. The Israeliteswere to understand the theocentric basis of wisdom: “The fear of theLORD is the beginning of wisdom: and the knowledge of the holy isunderstanding” (Prov. 9:10).

This section on sanctions appears in the fifth section of the Bookof Leviticus. The fifth point of the covenant deals with succession.

Page 357: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 35 . . . Leviticus 26:13–17

1. “And when Abram was ninety years old and nine, the LORD appeared to Abram, andsaid unto him, I am the Almighty God; walk before me, and be thou perfect” (Gen. 17:1).“And ye shall not walk in the manners of the nation, which I cast out before you: for theycommitted all these things, and therefore I abhorred them” (Lev. 20:23). “In the ninth yearof Hoshea the king of Assyria took Samaria, and carried Israel away into Assyria, andplaced them in Halah and in Habor by the river of Gozan, and in the cities of the Medes.For so it was, that the children of Israel had sinned against the LORD their God, which hadbrought them up out of the land of Egypt, from under the hand of Pharaoh king of Egypt,and had feared other gods, And walked in the statutes of the heathen, whom the LORD castout from before the children of Israel, and of the kings of Israel, which they had made” (IIKi. 17:6– 8).

1296

Why does a section on sanctions appear here? Because sanctions arelinked covenantally to succession. This is why eschatology cannot beseparated covenantally from theonomy, i.e., God’s law and its biblic-ally mandated sanctions. Sanctions determine who will inherit what:inheritance and disinheritance. God identifies Himself as the God ofthe covenant: deliverer, law-giver, and sanctions-bringer. God’s threatof temporal wrath is to redirect the attention of citizens of a holycommonwealth to the possibility of disinheritance in history: wrath asthe prelude to corporate disinheritance.

The Fear of God

The passage begins with a reminder: the God who threatens thesehistorical sanctions is the God of corporate grace in history. He ledthem out of bondage in Egypt. They had been bent under the yoke ofslavery, but He had broken their yoke and made them walk upright.This upright physical walk was analogous to an upright ethical walk.The language of walking before God is the language of covenantalobedience, both individual and corporate.1 The morally crooked walkis mirrored by the bent walk of the slave who is under a yoke.

The temptation is always disobedience to God’s standards (point

Page 358: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

God’s Escalating Wrath

1297

three of the biblical covenant model). “But if ye will not hearken untome, and will not do all these commandments; And if ye shall despisemy statutes, or if your soul abhor my judgments, so that ye will not doall my commandments, but that ye break my covenant.” This neces-sarily involves the threat of negative sanctions (point four). “I willeven appoint over you terror, consumption, and the burning ague, thatshall consume the eyes, and cause sorrow of heart.” The essence ofthis sanction is disinheritance (point five). “And ye shall sow your seedin vain, for your enemies shall eat it.” Invaders will inherit: “And I willset my face against you, and ye shall be slain before your enemies:they that hate you shall reign over you; and ye shall flee when nonepursueth you.” So fearful will God’s people become that they will fleewhen none pursue.

The covenantal issue is the fear of God. When men refuse to fearGod, He raises up others who will terrify them. Covenant-breakerswill thereby learn to fear God’s human agents of wrath, so that theymight better learn to fear God. The point is this: God is worth fearingeven more than military invaders. If the stipulations of the Creator arewidely ignored, then military invaders will become increasinglydifficult to ignore. In this regard, the covenant-breaking adult is asfoolish as a child. A father spanks a child when the child runs into abusy street. The real threat to the child is the street’s traffic, but thechild is fearless before this external threat. He must learn to fear hisfather in order to learn the greater fearfulness of the street. He fearsthe lesser threat more than the greater threat. Similarly, the sinningcovenant-breaker loses his fear of the Father – the far greater threat– and must be reminded to fear God by a lesser external threat. Themagnitude of God’s wrath is manifested by the magnitude of thethreat of military sanctions: God’s wrath is more of a threat than amilitary defeat. The lesser threat is imposed by God in order to remindmen of the greater threat.

Page 359: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 35 . . . Leviticus 26:13–17

1298

Softening Their Resistance

The first negative sanction is both psychological and physical:terror and consumption. This will produce sorrow. This defensivementality is the mentality of the slave and the prisoner. The secondthreatened negative sanction is military defeat. If this threat fails topersuade them to repent, the sanctions will escalate further. “And if yewill not yet for all this hearken unto me, then I will punish you seventimes more for your sins” (Lev. 26:18). The stated punishment isdrought. God’s wrath is manifested by His destruction of the coven-antal nation’s food supply. This was a major threat to a pre-modernagricultural society. “And I will break the pride of your power; and Iwill make your heaven as iron, and your earth as brass: And yourstrength shall be spent in vain: for your land shall not yield herincrease, neither shall the trees of the land yield their fruits” (Lev. 26:19–20). Drought was God’s means of softening up the resistance ofKing Ahab against Elijah’s message (I Ki. 17:1).

As in the case of Egypt, the next sanction involved the children:“And if ye walk contrary unto me, and will not hearken unto me; I willbring seven times more plagues upon you according to your sins. Iwill also send wild beasts among you, which shall rob you of yourchildren, and destroy your cattle, and make you few in number; andyour high ways shall be desolate” (Lev. 26:21–22). God sent beastsagainst those children who mocked the prophet Elisha: “And he wentup from thence unto Bethel: and as he was going up by the way, therecame forth little children out of the city, and mocked him, and saidunto him, Go up, thou bald head; go up, thou bald head. And heturned back, and looked on them, and cursed them in the name of theLORD. And there came forth two she bears out of the wood, and tare[tore] forty and two children of them” (II Ki. 2:23–24).

Page 360: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

God’s Escalating Wrath

1299

The judgments are again military: “And if ye will not be reformedby me by these things, but will walk contrary unto me; Then will I alsowalk contrary unto you, and will punish you yet seven times for yoursins. And I will bring a sword upon you, that shall avenge the quarrelof my covenant: and when ye are gathered together within your cities,I will send the pestilence among you; and ye shall be delivered into thehand of the enemy. And when I have broken the staff of your bread,ten women shall bake your bread in one oven, and they shall deliveryou your bread again by weight: and ye shall eat, and not be satisfied”(Lev. 26:23–26). Enemies laying siege outside the gates, pestilenceand hunger inside the gates: so shall covenant-breakers be remindedof the importance of God’s law.

But even this may prove futile. “And if ye will not for all thishearken unto me, but walk contrary unto me; Then I will walkcontrary unto you also in fury; and I, even I, will chastise you seventimes for your sins. And ye shall eat the flesh of your sons, and theflesh of your daughters shall ye eat” (Lev. 26:27–29). This wasfulfilled in the days of Elisha, during Ben-hadad’s siege of Samaria:

And it came to pass after this, that Ben-hadad king of Syria gatheredall his host, and went up, and besieged Samaria. And there was a greatfamine in Samaria: and, behold, they besieged it, until an ass’s headwas sold for fourscore pieces of silver, and the fourth part of a cab ofdove’s dung for five pieces of silver. And as the king of Israel waspassing by upon the wall, there cried a woman unto him, saying, Help,my lord, O king. And he said, If the LORD do not help thee, whenceshall I help thee? out of the barnfloor, or out of the winepress? And theking said unto her, What aileth thee? And she answered, This womansaid unto me, Give thy son, that we may eat him to day, and we willeat my son to morrow. So we boiled my son, and did eat him: and Isaid unto her on the next day, Give thy son, that we may eat him: andshe hath hid her son. And it came to pass, when the king heard the

Page 361: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 35 . . . Leviticus 26:13–17

1300

words of the woman, that he rent his clothes; and he passed by uponthe wall, and the people looked, and, behold, he had sackcloth withinupon his flesh (II Ki. 6:24–30).

Captivity

Destruction would come upon all the land, rural and urban. If menrefused to honor the sabbatical year of release, God promised to givethe land its rest through the captivity of the nation.

And I will make your cities waste, and bring your sanctuaries untodesolation, and I will not smell the savour of your sweet odours. AndI will bring the land into desolation: and your enemies which dwelltherein shall be astonished at it. And I will scatter you among theheathen, and will draw out a sword after you: and your land shall bedesolate, and your cities waste. Then shall the land enjoy her sabbaths,as long as it lieth desolate, and ye be in your enemies’ land; even thenshall the land rest, and enjoy her sabbaths. As long as it lieth desolateit shall rest; because it did not rest in your sabbaths, when ye dweltupon it” (Lev. 26:31–35).

The captivity of the people of Israel would be a negative sanctionagainst the people and a positive sanction for the land:

The land also shall be left of them, and shall enjoy her sabbaths, whileshe lieth desolate without them: and they shall accept of thepunishment of their iniquity: because, even because they despised myjudgments, and because their soul abhorred my statutes (Lev. 26:43).

This judgment was imposed by God in the days of Jeremiah:

Page 362: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

God’s Escalating Wrath

1301

And they [the Chaldeans] burnt the house of God, and brake down thewall of Jerusalem, and burnt all the palaces thereof with fire, anddestroyed all the goodly vessels thereof. And them that had escapedfrom the sword carried he away to Babylon; where they were servantsto him and his sons until the reign of the kingdom of Persia: To fulfilthe word of the LORD by the mouth of Jeremiah, until the land hadenjoyed her sabbaths: for as long as she lay desolate she kept sabbath,to fulfil threescore and ten years (II Chron. 36:19–21).

The people were to eat the fat of the land of promise. This wasGod’s promised positive sanction. They would feed on the land. Incontrast, the negative sanction of captivity was pictured as anotherkind of feast: the eating of the people by a foreign land. “And ye shallperish among the heathen, and the land of your enemies shall eat youup. And they that are left of you shall pine away in their iniquity inyour enemies’ lands; and also in the iniquities of their fathers shall theypine away with them” (Lev. 26:38–39).

Step by step, sanction by sanction, God would bring them face toface with the magnitude of their rebellion. The goal was theirrepentance: ”If they shall confess their iniquity, and the iniquity oftheir fathers, with their trespass which they trespassed against me, andthat also they have walked contrary unto me; And that I also havewalked contrary unto them, and have brought them into the land oftheir enemies; if then their uncircumcised hearts be humbled, and theythen accept of the punishment of their iniquity: Then will I remembermy covenant with Jacob, and also my covenant with Isaac, and alsomy covenant with Abraham will I remember; and I will remember theland” (Lev. 26:40–42). Negative corporate sanctions in history aredesigned to restore covenantal faithfulness on the part of God’speople. They are not judgments unto oblivion but judgments untorestoration.

Page 363: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 35 . . . Leviticus 26:13–17

2. Gary North, Treasure and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Luke, 2nd elec-tronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc., [2000]2003), ch. 28.

1302

Conclusion

God’s escalating wrath in history serves as a means of restoringdominion by covenant. These negative sanctions are positive in intent:restoring faithfulness and, in the case of captivity, providing rest to theland itself. These sanctions were part of the covenantal law-order ofIsrael. This is why the section listing the sanctions ends with thesewords: “These are the statutes and judgments and laws, which theLORD made between him and the children of Israel in mount Sinai bythe hand of Moses” (Lev. 26:46). There is no doubt that the sanctionswere part of the stipulations. There was no way for Israel to obeyGod’s law without imposing the required negative sanctions. If theauthorities refused to impose the stipulated negative sanctions, Godwould impose His stipulated negative sanctions. These negativesanctions would become progressively more painful. God’s negativesanctions were designed to persuade men of the integrity – theseamlessness – of God’s revealed law. If the people refused to learnfrom one set of punishments, God threatened to impose worsepunishments.

The principle underlying this escalation of negative sanctions issimple to state: “But he that knew not, and did commit things worthyof stripes, shall be beaten with few stripes. For unto whomsoevermuch is given, of him shall be much required: and to whom men havecommitted much, of him they will ask the more” (Luke 12:48).2 Theescalating sanctions in Israel were a form of covenant-affirmation:establishing the social predictability of God’s law. The reliability ofGod’s law was visible in the escalation of God’s corporate sanctions,

Page 364: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

God’s Escalating Wrath

3. Gary North, Millennialism and Social Theory (Tyler, Texas: Institute for ChristianEconomics, 1990), ch. 7.

1303

both positive and negative. Modern Christian theologians assume that the Mosaic Covenant’s

divine sanctions no longer operate in the New Covenant era.3 Fromthis idea (or at least paralleling it), they conclude that the Mosaic Cov-enant’s civil sanctions are no longer valid. This is logical, given theincorrect presupposition. The divine sanctions undergirded the Bible-revealed familial, civil, and ecclesiastical stipulations; if the authoritiesrefused to impose these mandatory sanctions, God would then imposeHis sanctions. If the threat of God’s corporate sanctions are removed,then the sanctions undergirding the institutional sanctions are absent.Without sanctions, there is no law. Biblical sanctions are inseparablefrom biblical stipulations: no sanctions = no law. Remove God’scorporate sanctions in history, and the legal order becomes judiciallyautonomous in history.

The autonomy of society from God’s Bible-revealed law is theagreed-upon agenda of an implicit alliance between the humanists andthe pietists. The humanists assume that God’s corporate sanctionshave always been mythological. Christian pietists assume that thesesanctions have been annulled by the New Covenant. This pair of falseassumptions serves as the judicial basis of the humanist-pietist allianceagainst the ideal of God’s theocratic kingdom in history: Christendom.

If God’s sanctions did not operate predictably in history, it wouldbe impossible to produce a self-consciously biblical form of socialtheory. Christians would have to rely on some version of pagannatural law theory in order to construct their social theories. This iswhat they have done for almost two millennia. With the collapse ofnatural law theory after Darwin, Christian social theory has floun-dered. Darwin’s target was William Paley’s providential and teleolo-

Page 365: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 35 . . . Leviticus 26:13–17

4. Gary North, The Dominion Covenant: Genesis, 2nd ed. (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1987), pp. 256–57.

1304

gical order; he hit his target.4 Everyone standing behind this target hasbeen epistemologically defenseless ever since.

Summary

God threatens His covenant people with negative corporate sanc-tions in history.

He is the God of grace in history: deliverance from Egypt.God’s people are to walk uprightly before Him.Disobedience brings corporate negative sanctions.The essence of these sanctions is disinheritance.The fear of God is the key issue.This fear was mediated by a fear of national invasion.Negative sanctions soften men’s resistance to God.Terror and consumption are sanctions.This is the slave’s mentality: defensive.Drought was listed: food supply threat.God threatened their children with wild beasts (later fulfilled).Family cannibalism is a threat (later fulfilled).The Promised Land would be left desolate: receiving its accumu-

lated sabbatical years (later fulfilled).The sanctions were supposed to pressure them to repent.The sanctions were inextricably linked to the case laws.Escalating corporate sanctions were imposed by God to establish

the predictability of His revealed law.

Page 366: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1305

36

THE PRIESTHOOD: BARRIERS TO ENTRY

Speak unto the children of Israel, and say unto them, When a manshall make a singular vow, the persons shall be for the LORD by thyestimation. And thy estimation shall be of the male from twenty yearsold even unto sixty years old, even thy estimation shall be fifty shekelsof silver, after the shekel of the sanctuary. And if it be a female, thenthy estimation shall be thirty shekels. And if it be from five years oldeven unto twenty years old, then thy estimation shall be of the maletwenty shekels, and for the female ten shekels. And if it be from amonth old even unto five years old, then thy estimation shall be of themale five shekels of silver, and for the female thy estimation shall bethree shekels of silver. And if it be from sixty years old and above; ifit be a male, then thy estimation shall be fifteen shekels, and for thefemale ten shekels. But if he be poorer than thy estimation, then heshall present himself before the priest, and the priest shall value him;according to his ability that vowed shall the priest value him (Lev.27:2–8).

The theocentric basis of this passage is that the God of the coven-ant does allow vows.

Vows and Succession

The question is, what kind of vow is in view here? This is one ofthe most peculiar passages in the Mosaic law. The rabbinical com-mentators do not do a better job than the Christians in explaining it,and the Christians are universally perplexed. It is obvious that vowswere involved. Money payments were also involved. We need to

Page 367: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

1. Ray R. Sutton, That You May Prosper: Dominion By Covenant, 2nd ed. )Tyler, Texas:Institute for Christian Economics, [1987] 1992), ch. 4.

2. Ibid., chaps. 1–5.

1306

answer two questions: What was the nature of the vow? What was thefunction of the money payment?

To begin to sort out this pair of problems, we must answer thisquestion: What is a vow? Biblically, a vow is a lawful invocation ofGod’s covenantal sanctions, positive and negative.1 To escape God’scorporate negative sanctions, there must be individual vows of repent-ance: covenant renewal. Covenant renewal involves a public reaffir-mation of God’s covenant: His sovereignty, authority, law, sanctions,and triumph (historical and eschatological). These are the five pointsof the biblical covenant model.2 A lawful public affirmation of God’scovenant always comes in the form of a vow. In order to set oneselfapart judicially before God, one takes a vow. Vows necessarilyinvolve sanctions. They are self-maledictory oaths that invoke God’ssanctions, positive and negative. Formal judicial separation is based ona vow; it always points to God’s sanctions in history. This is whyholiness (point three of the biblical covenant model) points tojudgment (point four).

The vows in this instance were ecclesiastical. The Hebrew wordthat describes these vows, pawlaw, is translated here as “singular.”The translation itself is singular: pawlaw is translated as “singular” inthe King James Version only in this singular verse. It is elsewheretranslated as “marvelous,” “wondrous,” or “separate.” Lawful vowsare always out of the ordinary, and these vows were very special vowsamong vows. They were marvelous vows. The question is: In whatway?

Commentators argue about the possible reasons for the placementof this chapter at the end of Leviticus. Why should a section on vows

Page 368: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

3. Gordon J. Wenham, The Book of Leviticus (Grand Rapids, Michigan: Eerdmans,1979), p. 336.

4. James B. Jordan, Covenant Sequence in Leviticus and Deuteronomy (Tyler, Texas:Institute for Christian Economics, 1989), p. 17.

5. Ibid., p. 39.

1307

appear at the end of a book on holiness? Gordon Wenham writes: “Itis a puzzle why ch. 27, which deals with vows, should appear in itspresent position, since ch. 26 with its blessings and curses would havemade a fitting conclusion to the book.”3 He offers two possibleexplanations, neither of them convincing.

I suggest the following explanation: the end of Leviticus marks atransition from a book that centers on point three of the biblical cov-enant model – holiness, boundaries – to a book that centers on pointfour: oaths, sanctions. But what about part five of the book, inheri-tance? Here is the central theme of this passage: the loss of inheritancein one tribe in exchange for inheritance in another tribe.

The previous chapter, Leviticus 26, deals with God’s positive andnegative corporate sanctions in history. The move from an emphasison point four of the biblical covenant model – sanctions – in Chapter26 to point five – succession – in Chapter 27 is appropriate.4 Negativesanctions in the context of Chapter 26 have to do with disinheritance.Chapter 26 presents a catalogue of God’s corporate covenantalsanctions. Chapter 27 begins with rules governing a particular type ofpersonal vow. This in turn raises the issue of covenantal continuity.Jordan writes: “Payment of vows relates to the fifth commandment,as we give to our Divine parent and thereby honor Him, and to thetenth commandment, since payment of vows and tithes is the oppositeof covetousness. Thus, this final section of Leviticus has everything todo with continuity.”5 The passage is where it belongs: in part five. Thevow relates to inheritance: family continuity over time.

Page 369: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

6. Wenham, Leviticus, p. 338.

7. Idem.

1308

Devoted to Temple Service: Irreversible

The text does not tell us what stipulations governed this type ofvow. The text also does not provide a context. This is why the com-mentators get so confused. The old line about “text without contextis pretext” is applicable. The law was addressed to priests: “the per-sons shall be for the LORD by thy estimation.” Whose estimation?The priests. Anything dedicated to the Lord is assumed by commen-tators to have been dedicated to or through the priesthood. The textis silent about the nature of the dedication; it speaks only of pricing.A gift of individuals was in some way involved because specific pricesare associated in the text with specific genders and ages.

Wenham discusses this law as symbolic of a man’s willingness topledge himself or those under his authority as temple slaves. The vow-taker could not really serve God in this way, Wenham argues. Accessto the temple was reserved to Levites and priests.6 Once the vow wasmade, Wenham says, the person who had made it was required toredeem himself and any other people under the vow’s authority bymaking an appropriate payment to the temple. These singular vowsspecifically invoked mandatory payments. “To free themselves fromthe vow, they had instead to pay to the sanctuary the price they wouldhave commanded in the slave market.”7 Once made, the vow had tobe paid. He cites Psalm 116: “I will pay my vows unto the LORD nowin the presence of all his people. Precious in the sight of the LORD isthe death of his saints. O LORD, truly I am thy servant; I am thyservant, and the son of thine handmaid: thou hast loosed my bonds. Iwill offer to thee the sacrifice of thanksgiving, and will call upon thename of the LORD. I will pay my vows unto the LORD now in the

Page 370: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

8. Idem.

9. Gary North, Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Deuteronomy,2nd electronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc.,[1999] 2003), ch. 57.

10. Chapter 31.

1309

presence of all his people” (Ps. 116:14–18).8 This was David’saffirmation of the law of vows, which states: “But if thou shalt forbearto vow, it shall be no sin in thee. That which is gone out of thy lipsthou shalt keep and perform; even a freewill offering, according asthou hast vowed unto the LORD thy God, which thou hast promisedwith thy mouth” (Deut. 23:22–23).9

We need to answer two questions. First, is Wenham correct aboutthe exclusively symbolic nature of this type of vow? Second, is hecorrect about the payment as a substitute for literal temple service?Most commentators have agreed with Wenham on this point. I do not.I argue that the terms of the vow were not symbolic, and the paymentwas not a substitute.

Devotion: Change in Legal Status

In the case of heathen slaves, Israelites possessed lawful title to theslave and the slave’s heirs (Lev. 25:44–45).10 There is no reason toassume that an Israelite could not transfer ownership of his slave to anindividual priest or to the temple. The tabernacle-temple alreadyemployed permanent pagan slaves: the Gibeonites. They were thehewers of wood and drawers of water for the assembly; hence, theywere involved in religious service. This permanent temple slavery hadbeen specifically imposed on them by Joshua as a curse: “Nowtherefore ye are cursed, and there shall none of you be freed from

Page 371: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

11. On “hormah,” see James B. Jordan, Judges: God’s War Against Humanism (Tyler,Texas: Geneva Ministries, 1985), pp. 10–12.

1310

being bondmen, and hewers of wood and drawers of water for thehouse of my God” (Josh. 9:23). They were permanently set apart –devoted – for temple service. This was the result of their deception ingaining the vow of peace from Joshua (Josh. 9). The covenantal bless-ing – peace in the land – because of the Gibeonites’ deception becametheir covenantal curse: permanent slavery under the priests. They hadescaped God’s covenantal ban of hormah – either their totaldestruction or their permanent expulsion from the land – but theycould not escape His covenantal ban of temple servitude. Hormah(chormah) means “devoted.” Its frame of reference was God’s totaldestruction: “And the LORD hearkened to the voice of Israel, anddelivered up the Canaanites; and they utterly destroyed them and theircities: and he called the name of the place Hormah” (Num. 21:3). Acity devoted to total destruction was under hormah: a total ban. Thisdestruction was a priestly act.11

We conclude that there is nothing in the Mosaic Covenant toindicate that pagan slaves could not be assigned to temple service eventhough they could not lawfully assist with the sacrifices. They werenot allowed inside those temple boundaries that were lawfullyaccessible only to priests, but they still could work for the priestsoutside these boundaries. Thus, a symbolic transfer of ownership ofa pagan slave to the priests is not the concern of this passage. Thedeciding issue contextually cannot be priestly ownership as such. Theissue is also not the dedication or sanctification of household slaves.There was nothing special in Israel about the dedication of householdslaves – nothing “singular.” It has to be something more fundamental:service within the normally sealed boundaries of the temple.

Then who were the vow-governed individuals of Leviticus 27:2–

Page 372: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

1311

8? They were family members under the lawful authority of the vow-taker. The vow was a specific kind of vow, a vow of devotion. Devo-tion here was not an emotional state; it was a change in judicial status.

Devotion vs. Sanctification

At this point, I have to introduce a crucial distinction of the Mosaiclaw: devotion vs. sanctification. A sanctified item was set apart forGod’s use, though not necessarily on a permanent basis. A devotedthing was set apart permanently for priestly service or sacrifice. Thisdistinction is based on the law that appears later in this section ofLeviticus:

Notwithstanding no devoted thing, that a man shall devote unto theLORD of all that he hath, both of man and beast, and of the field of hispossession, shall be sold or redeemed: every devoted thing is most holyunto the LORD. None devoted, which shall be devoted of men, shallbe redeemed; but shall surely be put to death (Lev. 27:28–29).

Death here was not necessarily physical death; it was, however,necessarily covenantal death. This meant that the devoted item wasplaced within the irreversible boundaries of God’s ban. This form ofcovenantal death meant that the item was beyond human redemption.The devoted object came under God’s absolute control. In manypassages in Scripture, the Hebrew word for “devoted” (khayrem) istranslated as “accursed” or “cursed.” Such a cursed item could not beused for anything other than sacrifice to God. If it was subsequentlymisused – violated or profaned, in other words – the person whoviolated God’s boundary himself came under the ban: beyond humanredemption.

Page 373: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

12. Because Achan had violated the holy ban that God placed around Jericho’s spoils, heplaced his whole household under the ban. It was legally possible for a father to place hisfamily under God’s ban – disinheritance from the family’s land and legal status – throughcovenantal adoption into the priesthood. But in this case, Achan placed his family underhormah: God’s absolute ban of destruction. As the head of his household, he went throughan adoption process: not into the tribe of Levi, but rather into covenantal Jericho. Thus, itwas mandatory that the civil government execute his entire household, including theanimals, and bury all his assets with them (Josh. 7:24). See Appendix A: “Sacrilege andSanctions.”

13. “The law and the prophets were until John: since that time the kingdom of God ispreached, and every man presseth into it” (Luke 16:16).

1312

And the city [Jericho] shall be accursed, even it, and all that aretherein, to the LORD: only Rahab the harlot shall live, she and all thatare with her in the house, because she hid the messengers that we sent.And ye, in any wise keep yourselves from the accursed thing, lest yemake yourselves accursed, when ye take of the accursed thing, andmake the camp of Israel a curse, and trouble it (Josh. 6:17–18).

But the children of Israel committed a trespass in the accursed thing:for Achan, the son of Carmi, the son of Zabdi, the son of Zerah, of thetribe of Judah, took of the accursed thing: and the anger of the LORDwas kindled against the children of Israel (Josh. 7:1).12

But the people took of the spoil, sheep and oxen, the chief of the thingswhich should have been utterly destroyed, to sacrifice unto theLORD thy God in Gilgal (I Sam. 15:21).

It is worth noting that this Hebrew word is the very last word thatoccurs in the Old Testament, in the passage that prophesies thecoming of Elijah (John the Baptist), the man Jesus identified as the lastman of the Old Covenant.13 “Behold, I will send you Elijah theprophet before the coming of the great and dreadful day of the LORD:And he shall turn the heart of the fathers to the children, and the heart

Page 374: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

14. Gary North, Tools of Dominion: The Case Laws of Exodus (Tyler, Texas: Institutefor Christian Economics, 1990), pp. 218–19.

1313

of the children to their fathers, lest I come and smite the earth with acurse” (Mal. 4:5–6). This was God’s threatened negative sanction:covenantal disinheritance – fathers vs. sons – that involved God’scurse on Old Covenant Israel. As Jesus later warned: “Think not thatI am come to send peace on earth: I came not to send peace, but asword. For I am come to set a man at variance against his father, andthe daughter against her mother, and the daughter in law against hermother in law. And a man’s foes shall be they of his own household”(Matt. 10:34–36).

The devoted item could not be redeemed by the payment of a price.It had been permanently transferred covenantally to God as a sacri-ficial offering. This is the meaning of the singular vow. The singularvow was a vow whose stipulations were irrevocable. The devoted itemwas placed within the confines of an absolutely holy boundary: beyondhuman redemption. The vow was voluntary; the resulting transfer wasirrevocable: a singular vow.

Devotion Through Adoption

Could an Israelite lawfully devote his child to priestly service? Yes;as we shall see, Jephthah’s daughter was so devoted by her father.Once a person was adopted into the family of Aaron specifically orinto the tribe of Levi, he could not re-enter another Israelite tribe bya subsequent act of adoption. He had been devoted to the temple:beyond redemption. So had his covenantal heirs. If I am correct aboutthis, then in the context of marriage – another form of legal adoption14

– there was no option for an Israelite father to buy back his daughter

Page 375: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

15. The dowry remained with the wife in any case; it was her protection, her inheritancefrom her father.

16. Ibid., ch. 32: “Blood Money, Not Head Tax.”

1314

from her priestly husband by returning the bride price to his son-in-law.15 Similarly, there was no way for a man to buy back himself, hiswife, or his children from formally devoted service to God. In short,there was no redemption price for this kind of vow. This is why thevow was pawlaw: “singular.”

There is no indication that a man could place his adult male childreninto mandated priestly service. An adult son was not eligible forcompulsory adoption. He was a lawful heir to the land and the legalstatus of his tribe and family. He could not be disinherited at hisfather’s prerogative. The crucial legal issue for identifying adulthoodfor men was military numbering. An adult male was eligible to benumbered at age 20 to fight in a holy war: “This they shall give, everyone that passeth among them that are numbered, half a shekel after theshekel of the sanctuary: (a shekel is twenty gerahs:) an half shekelshall be the offering of the LORD” (Ex. 30:13). At age 20, a mancame under the threat of God’s negative sanctions: going into battlewithout first having paid blood money to the temple.16 Once hebecame judicially eligible for numbering as a member of his tribe, hebecame judicially responsible for his own vows. He became, as wesay, “his own man.” He became a member of God’s holy army. Afather could no longer act in the son’s name.

The Disinheritance of Jephthah’s Daughter

A daughter could not legally be numbered for service in God’sarmy. Thus, an unmarried daughter could be delivered into a priestly

Page 376: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

17. I accept the standard interpretation of this story: she was not literally executed by herfather.

18. Jordan, Judges, pp. 204–13.

19. Ibid., p. 205.

20. Chapter 38.

21. Or, in the case of a widow (Num. 30:9), she. Gary North, Sanctions and Dominion:An Economic Commentary on Numbers (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics,1997), ch. 16.

1315

family, as we see in the peculiar case of Jephthah’s daughter (Jud.11:34– 39).17 Jephthah’s vow to sacrifice the first thing to come outof his house could not legally be applied literally to a person. He couldnot lawfully burn a person, nor could the priests; therefore, any personwho came under the terms of such a lawful vow had to be devoted toGod in temple service.18 Jephthah had made a singular vow. It wasirreversible. This means that his daughter had to be disinherited.19 Shewas beyond redemption.

There was a distinction in Mosaic law between someone or some-thing dedicated (sanctified) to the priesthood and someone or some-thing devoted to the priesthood. The former could be redeemed by thepayment of the market price plus a premium of one-fifth (Lev. 27:13,15, 19).20 The latter could not be redeemed.

Disinheritance was permanent in Old Covenant Israel. This couldonly be by covenant: specifically, by covenantal death. This is whydisinheritance was a form of devoted giving. The head of the house-hold publicly gave his heirs over to God. He21 publicly broke thefamily’s covenant with such a person. There were only three means oflawful disinheritance in Old Covenant Israel: civil execution for acapital crime, expulsion from the congregation for an ecclesiasticalcrime, or adoption into another family or tribe. All three involvedbroken covenants: civil, ecclesiastical, and familial. In the third ins-

Page 377: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

22. North, Tools of Dominion, ch. 6: “Wives and Concubines.”

23. Jordan takes this approach: Judges, p. 210.

1316

tance, the broken family covenant was simultaneously replaced by anew family or tribal covenant. A daughter was normally disinheritedby her father in this way, and if she was to become a wife rather thana concubine, she was to receive a dowry from her father.22

Jephthah’s daughter was disinherited in a unique way: by legaltransfer into a priestly family. She bewailed her virginity (Jud. 11:37)because this was the mark of her unmarried condition, and thereforeof her eligibility for transfer into the tribe of Levi apart from her ownwill. The standard interpretation of the story of Jephthah’s daughterrests on the assertion that as a temple servant, she would have had toremain a virgin.23 I am aware of no evidence from the Book of Lev-iticus or any other biblical text regarding the mandatory and thereforepermanent virginity of female temple servants. Then why did shebewail her virginity? Not because she was bewailing her supposedfuture virginity, but because she was bewailing her present virginity.It was her virginity that bound her to the terms of her father’s vow;otherwise, her husband’s authority would have negated the father’svow.

Jephthah’s daughter was, as the phrase goes, “her daddy’s girl”: adynasty-coveting power-seeker. When her virginity cost her the inher-itance of her father’s political dynasty, she bewailed her virginity. Herheart was not right with God. What was an enormous honor –adoption into the tribe of Levi, the spiritual counsellors of the nation– she saw as a thing to bewail in the mountains for two months (Jud.11:37).

Jordan raises a question: “Why didn’t Jephthah substitute a moneypayment for his vow? These monetary substitutes are set out in

Page 378: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

24. Ibid., p. 206.

25. Ibid., pp. 206–7.

26. Jordan pointed out to me that the only other use of pawlaw – “singular,” as in singularvow – in the hiphil voice is found in Numbers 6:2, which relates to a Nazirite vow: “Speakunto the children of Israel, and say unto them, When either man or woman shall separatethemselves to vow a vow of a Nazarite, to separate themselves unto the LORD: He shallseparate himself from wine and strong drink, and shall drink no vinegar of wine, or vinegarof strong drink, neither shall he drink any liquor of grapes, nor eat moist grapes, or dried.All the days of his separation shall he eat nothing that is made of the vine tree, from thekernels even to the husk” (Num. 6:2–4).

1317

Leviticus 27:1–8.”24 He says that commentators who have addressedthis question have no easy explanation for it. He refers to Leviticus27:28–29: “Notwithstanding no devoted thing, that a man shall devoteunto the LORD of all that he hath, both of man and beast, and of thefield of his possession, shall be sold or redeemed: every devoted thingis most holy unto the LORD. None devoted, which shall be devotedof men, shall be redeemed; but shall surely be put to death.” Thus, heconcludes, Jephthah’s daughter could not be redeemed. “SinceJephthah vowed to offer this person as a whole burnt sacrifice, werealize that he was ‘devoting’ him or her to the Lord, and thus noransom was possible.”25 This is the correct interpretation.26 But thisanswer raises a more important question: If she could not legally beredeemed from this vow of temple service, how could anyone beredeemed from a vow of temple service? If the answer is that noperson could be redeemed from such a singular vow under Mosaic law– and this is the correct answer – then what are we to make ofLeviticus 27:2–8? What was the meaning of all those prices?

Not a Redemption Price

Page 379: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

27. In the first case, sacrificial animals, the cognate term for “sanctify” is used: kodesh,holy (vv. 9, 10).

1318

In the section of Leviticus 27 that follows this one, we read of theredemption price of animals that are set apart (sanctified) to be offeredas sacrifices (vv. 9–13). Then, in the section following that one, weread of the redemption price of a house sanctified to the priesthood(vv. 14–15). Finally, in the next section, the laws governing sanctifiedfields are listed (vv. 16–25). In the second and third cases, the term“sanctify” (kawdash, holy) is used.27 In all three cases, the redemptionprice was the market price at the time of the redemption plus 20percent (vv. 13, 15, 19).

Then comes Leviticus 27:26: “Only the firstling of the beasts, whichshould be the LORD’S firstling, no man shall sanctify it; whether it beox, or sheep: it is the LORD’S.” This law specifically denies thelegitimacy of sanctifying the animal. This means that no redemption ofthe animal was legal. It was a devoted animal, not a sanctified animal.Sanctification in this context meant “set apart until redeemed.” Thislegal condition was less rigorous than devotion. Devotion meant thatthe legal boundary around the object was permanent. The same is trueof the vow of Leviticus 27:2–8. In this passage, there is no mention ofa supplemental payment of one-fifth. This is evidence that what isbeing considered in verses 2–8 is not a series of redemption prices.Then what does this section refer to?

The preliminary answer was given in 1846 by Andrew Bonar. Heconcluded that the list of prices in Leviticus 27:2–8 is not a list ofredemption prices. “There seems to me a mistake generally fallen intohere by commentators. They suppose that these shekels of moneywere paid in order to free the offerers from the obligation of devotingthe person. Now, surely, the whole chapter is speaking of things trulydevoted to God, and cases of exchange and substitution are referred

Page 380: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

28. Andrew Bonar, A Commentary on Leviticus (Edinburgh: Banner of Truth Trust,[1846] 1966), p. 497.

29. This does not mean that the money could never go to the adopting family. Officersof the temple might choose to transfer the funds to an adopting family for various reasons,such as the education of young children who had been adopted, or the care of older people.

30. There were two exceptions: (1) when a family dedicated a piece of land to thepriesthood and then refused to redeem it before the next jubilee year; (2) when a familydedicated a piece of land to the priesthood but then leased the whole property to someoneelse (Lev. 27:16–21). Chapter 37.

1319

to in ver. 10, 13, 15. As for persons devoted, there was nosubstitution allowed. The mistake has arisen from supposing that thisamount of money was ransom-money; whereas it was an addition tothe offering of the person, not a substitution.” He pointed to the caseof Jephthah’s daughter as evidence.28

Bonar explained the additional monetary payment in terms of thegiver’s gratitude. A person who was really grateful to God, he said,would add money to the transfer. This misses the judicial point. Whatwe have here is an entry fee: a payment analogous to a marriagedowry. A person who desired to transfer himself or a member of hisfamily into the tribe of Levi had to provide a “dowry” – not to thefamily, but to the temple.29 Why a dowry? Because, theologicallyspeaking, the bride of God is not a concubine. She is a free wife. Thefree wife in Israel had to be provided with a dowry. Judicially speak-ing, the Levites were freemen in Israel. For anyone within anothertribe to become a member of the tribe of Levi, the person’s family –the head of the household – had to offer an additional payment. Thispayment was judicial. It established the person’s legal status: afreeman (wife) rather than a slave (concubine).

Members of the tribe of Levi could not normally own rural landoutside of 48 specified cities (Num. 35:7).30 Thus, any person whowas delivered by a vow and payment into temple service lost his or her

Page 381: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

31. North, Sanctions and Dominion, ch. 22.

32. Jordan, Judges, p. 205.

33. North, Sanctions and Dominion, ch. 15.

1320

claim to his or her ancestral land. We see this in the case of Jephthah’sdaughter, in an incident that has confused Bible commentators forcenturies. As his only child (Jud. 11:34), she was the lawful heir of hisland and its accompanying legal status, but only so long as she did notmarry outside his tribe (Num. 35:6–9).31 By being adopted into thetribe of Levi, she could not thereafter marry outside of the tribe ofLevi. Thus, she had to forfeit her inheritance from Jephthah. She couldnot extend her father’s dynasty, a point Jordan makes.32 A fatheralienated his family’s inheritance forever from his heirs if his malechildren were under age 20 or his daughters were unmarried at thetime he made his vow. This did not mean that they lost their legalstatus as freemen; Levites possessed freeman status. But the heirs didlose their claim on the family’s land.

Could the priest annul the vow? Yes. There was no compulsion thathe adopt someone into his family. The vow was analogous to the vowof a daughter or married woman: it could be annulled within 24 hoursby the male head of the household (Num. 30:3–8). The priests, actingin God’s name, as the heads of God’s ecclesiastical household, couldlawfully annul someone’s vow of adoption into the tribe. But if thevow was accepted by a priest in authority, the vow-taker and anyother members of his family covered by his vow were then adoptedinto the tribe of Levi if they could pay the entry fee. Once adopted bythe priest’s family, there was no way back into non-Leviticalfreemanship in Israel. At the time of the adoption, the adoptedfamily’s original inheritance had been forfeited to the kinsman-redeemer, the closest relative in their original tribe (Num. 27:9–11).33

Page 382: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

34. This is why Paul speaks of the double honor of those who labor in the word: “Let theelders that rule well be counted worthy of double honour, especially they who labour in theword and doctrine” (I Tim. 5:17). Gary North, Hierarchy and Dominion: An EconomicCommentary on First Timothy (West Fork, Arkansas: Institute for Christian Economics,2002), ch. 7.

35. This was the same as another judicial price: the formal bride price owed by a seducerof a virgin to her father. North, Tools of Dominion, pp. 649–57. It rests on an interpretationof the false accuser’s penalty of Deuteronomy 22:19: “And they shall amerce him in anhundred shekels of silver, and give them unto the father of the damsel, because he hathbrought up an evil name upon a virgin of Israel: and she shall be his wife; he may not puther away all his days.” One hundred shekels was double restitution.

36. The same price that was owed to the owner of a gored slave (Ex. 21:32)

1321

They could retain their status as freemen only as members of the tribeof Levi. Their family land was no longer part of their inheritance. Butthe makes were still members of God’s holy army. They were stillcitizens.

The Restrictive Function of Price

These prices were not market prices. They had nothing to do withcomparative rates of economic productivity. They were insteadbarriers to entry into the tribe of the priests. Primary judicial authorityin Israel was supposed to be inside the tribe of Levi, for the Leviteshad unique access to the written law of God. They were the spiritualand therefore the judicial counsellors in Israel.34 It was not easy togain access to this position of honor and authority. Adoption into thetribe of Levi was legal, but it was not cheap.

The entry price for an adult male was set at 50 shekels of silver.35

The price for an adult female was 30 shekels.36 The male child’s pricewas 20 shekels; the female child’s was 10 shekels. Very young child-ren’s prices were lower: five shekels (male) and three shekels

Page 383: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

1322

(female). For the elderly, the prices were 15 shekels (male) and tenshekels (female).

The formal prices of the sexes differed. Males were priced higherthan females in every age group. Similarly, old people were pricedhigher than very young children, but less than children age 5 to 20.Why? Did this have something to do with market pricing? These werenot cases of pure market pricing, but can the differences in formalprices be explained in terms of expected productivity, just as marketprices can be explained? Yes, but such an explanation is misleading.

Prices always serve as barriers. The question is: Were prices in thisinstance barriers to entry or barriers to escape; that is, were they entryprices or redemption prices? Were they based on the value of servicesto be redeemed or were they tests of authority to be honored?

Explanation: Economic Productivity

If we regard the prices as redemption prices, we are tempted toexplain the price differences in terms of the varying market value ofthe individuals. By adopting this explanation, we misunderstand thelegal nature of the transaction; nevertheless, we can make a plausibleeconomic case. We can interpret the passage in terms of the repur-chase value of the person whose services had been handed over to thetemple.

If economic redemption was the meaning of the price structure ofLeviticus 27:2–8, then the vow became a peculiar symbolic ritual:people were being handed over to God verbally, but then repurchasedfrom the temple economically. Such a ritual would have converted anotherwise simple monetary donation into the formality of a sacredvow. A lawful vow invoked God’s name and God’s sanctions in hist-ory. Why should God’s name have been formally invoked? Why didn’t

Page 384: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

37. Richard D. Fuerle, The Pure Logic of Choice (New York: Vantage, 1986).

1323

the person wishing to give money to the priests just give it? A strictlyeconomic analysis misses the judicial point: the singular vow produceda permanent alteration of someone’s legal status. The prices listed inthe text were not redemption prices; they were transfer pricesanalogous to dowries.

Still, it is quite tempting to think of these prices as redemptionprices. This is the way men think in a century dominated by variousforms of economic determinism, whether left wing (e.g., Marxism) orright wing (e.g., the pure logic of choice).37 If we begin with thisassumption of economic determinism, we are easily tempted toconclude that these prices were shadows of market prices. Here ishow we might reason:

Why were adult males priced highest of all? Because they are at thepeak of their economic value. Their training was behind them. Theyhad a lifetime of productive service ahead of them. In order to buyhimself back from lifetime service, the vow-taker had to pay a veryhigh price. What about the lower price for females in each age group? Thiswould also seem to have been governed by the principle of produc-tivity. For some reason or reasons, females were less valuable econo-mically than males. (See next paragraph.) But females producechildren. Weren’t these children assets? If they had become thepermanent, inheritable property of the owner, yes. This low formalprice for women is evidence that the duration of the vow’s conditionsdid not extend beyond the jubilee year. At that time, every heir of theconquest’s generation returned to his land. All servitude ended forthem. So, the children born of women protected by the jubilee lawwould not have been equally as valuable as inheritable slave children.The period available for capitalization was shorter.

Page 385: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

38. Felice N. Schwartz, Breaking With Tradition: Women and Work, The New Facts ofLife (New York: Warner, 1992), p. 59. She cites Martha O’Connell, “Maternity LeaveArrangements: 1981–1985,” Work and Family Patterns of American Women, CurrentPopulation Reports, series P–23, no. 165 (Washington, D.C.: Government Printing Office,March 1990).

39. Gary North, “The Feminine Mistake: The Economics of Women’s Liberation,” TheFreeman (Jan. 1971); reprinted in Gary North, An Introduction to Christian Economics(Nutley, New Jersey: Craig Press, 1973), ch. 24.

1324

Even in the late twentieth century – an era of federally legislated“equal pay for equal work” laws – the economics of motherhood havenot changed significantly. Women still are paid less than men. Why?Because their expected net economic returns are lower than men’s.They have children who must be cared for. From 1981 through 1985,30 percent of American women with paid maternity leave or otherbenefits did not return to the labor market after six months, while 56percent of women without maternity benefits did not return to work.38

The free market places a lower value on capital invested in women inthe work force. This lower return on investment is compensated for bylower wages paid to women. Any attempt to mandate equal wages bycivil law will produce unemployment for women in general, whilesubsidizing women with good looks or academic credentials.39

Why would older people be more valuable than very young children?Because they are on average more productive. Very young children arenet absorbers of scarce economic resources. It takes time for thepresent losses to be compensated by future returns. The net flow ofexpected future income discounted by the prevailing interest rate islow because the expected positive income stream is too many years inthe future. This was not true of those over age 4. The payoff would befaster. Why the difference? Those above age 4 are expected to becomenet producers sooner than those younger than 5. An older person wasless valuable than a child above age 4. The older person has skills andexperience, but he or she also can be expected to have infirmities. Theexpected net income stream is less for this reason and also because of

Page 386: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

40. North, Sanctions and Dominion, ch. 3.

1325

shortened life expectancy.

So, one can argue on the basis of economic analysis that these wereredemption prices. That is to say, one can see a loose correlationbetween the price differentials of Leviticus 27:2–8 and the freemarket’s pricing of labor services in the late twentieth century, andthen conclude that the Mosaic law’s stipulations were reasonably con-sistent with market forces. The evidence of varying prices seems to fitthe economic reality of age-specific and gender-specific economicproductivity. A person who believes in the continuing validity of thisMosaic statute, and who adopts this approach to explaining Leviticus27:2–8, is forced to conclude that these gender-related and age-related price differentials are permanent in New Covenant history,with or without human bondage (i.e., the capitalization of expectedlifetime net income). If the price differentials are based on productivitydifferentials, these productivity differentials have to be assumed to bepermanent – part of the human condition. This means that technolo-gical changes and educational changes can never overcome produc-tivity differentials, especially gender-based differentials. The initial assumption of this line of economic reasoning is incor-rect. The context of this law was not labor productivity, but ratherpriestly holiness. The focus of concern was not the capitalization ofeconomic productivity but rather the necessity of restricting accessinto the priesthood. God placed judicial boundaries around the temple.God’s presence in Israel was marked by a series of “no trespassingsigns” – restrictions on physical access – which became more rigorousas men approached the holy of holies. These boundaries were judicial.Lawful access across each boundary was based on a person’s judicialstatus, not his economic status.40 Vows marked a person’s move

Page 387: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

1326

across these judicial boundaries.

Explanation: Submission to Authority

Let us begin with another assumption: these prices were dowries,not redemption prices. Why was the highest entry price required of anadult male? Because the adult head of a household was a man whowas used to exercising family authority and perhaps other kinds ofcivil authority. By placing a high entry price on his adoption into thetribe of Levi, God protected His priestly servants from invasion bytwo groups: (1) power-seekers seeking to extend their authority intothe church;( 2) poor people seeking a guaranteed income as membersof the tithe-receiving tribe. The power-seekers first had to abandon alllegal claim to their original inheritance and also had to provide aconsiderable entry fee. Married men also had to pay for their wives’and minor children’s entry into the tribe of Levi. This further restrictedentry into the priestly class.

God established an entry fee higher for aged people – age 60 andover (v. 7) – than for very young children: under age 5 (v. 6). Why?Because old people tend to be more set in their ways, more used todeference from younger people, even priests. They would be moretrouble to govern than very young children. The very young childwould grow up in the presence of the Levites and the priests. Hewould learn to respect authority. He would not be a major threat tothe ecclesiastical hierarchy. There was less need for a monetary barrierto his entry into the household of the church.

God established lower prices for old men than for male childrenages 5–19 (v. 5). The prices for females, young and old, were thesame: 10 shekels. Why? The issue was authority: males had moreauthority than females did. Children of this age group reflected their

Page 388: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

1327

parents’ attitudes. The boys would have been more difficult to controlthan aged men. Young girls and old women were judged of equaldifficulty.

So, the discrepancies in these dowry prices can be explained interms of expected resistance to ecclesiastical authority. But whatabout the lower price for females in each age group? This is also con-sistent with the hypothesis that this law was imposed by God in orderto reduce the Levite adoptees’ resistance to ecclesiastical authority.Israelite women were accustomed to obey male heads of household.They were more likely to respect hierarchical authority. Thus, theywere less of a threat to the established ecclesiastical order. Thepayment could be smaller because the need to establish a barrier toentry was less.

Sonship Is Judicial

It was an honor to be a member of the tribe of Levi. This tribeguarded the law of the covenant, a guardianship symbolized by thetwo tablets of the law inside the Ark of the Covenant (Deut. 31:26).The priests were in charge of guarding the Ark. That is, the priestspoliced the boundaries between the Ark and the world outside.

Adoption is always an aspect of God’s law. This included adoptioninto the tribe of Levi, and even the family of Aaron. Sonship is judi-cial. Biblical sonship must always place covenantal faithfulness abovebiological relationships. When Eli elevated his sons to the priesthood,judicially ignoring the presence of faithful servant Samuel, God cut offEli’s inheritance by executing his sons. Eli had warned both of themwhat would happen, but they had refused to listen: “If one man sinagainst another, the judge shall judge him: but if a man sin against theLORD, who shall intreat for him? Notwithstanding they hearkened not

Page 389: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

41. Age 30 was the minimum age of service in the temple (Num. 4:3, 23, 30, 35, 39, 40,43, 47).

1328

unto the voice of their father, because the LORD would slay them” (ISam. 2:25). Eli refused to impose the negative sanction ofdisinheritance through excommunication, so God disinherited themthrough execution. He did this by subjecting the whole nation to amilitary defeat by the Philistines. A man of God warned Eli of whatwas about to happen (I Sam. 2:27–36), but Eli refused to takeeffective steps to evade God’s wrath. He could have adopted Samuelfrom the beginning, had his mother consented, which she wasobviously ready to do, having dedicated him to God for life (I Sam.1:11). At any time, Eli could have adopted Samuel in place of hissons, making him a priest at age 30.41 Instead, he honored biologicalsonship above adoptive sonship. Adoption is fundamental inestablishing covenant-keeping sonship; biology is not. Eli had decidedto maintain a boundary between Samuel and the altar; God thereforeplaced a boundary between Eli and his inheritance. Samuel could havebecome Eli’s heir; by honoring his sons, Eli chose to disinherit hisfamily’s name.

Eli’s decision cost Israel dearly, as priestly rebellion always does.Because Eli had made his sons the priests of Israel, Samuel laterbecame a prophet who brought God’s covenant lawsuit against Saul(I Sam. 15). Samuel, not the high priest, anointed David (I Sam. 16).Had Samuel been a priest, the priesthood would have retained moreof its temporal authority. God honored Samuel more than He honoredthe civil authority of the priesthood.

The Kinsman-Redeemer

Page 390: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

42. I do not think the price was paid to Levite families. Had the money gone to individualfamilies, there would have been a strong motivation for Levites to recruit new members ofthe tribe. The entry fee was to serve as a barrier to entry, not a motivation to recruit newmembers. If the money went directly to the temple, local Levites would have had far lessincentive to recruit non-Levites into the tribe. Aaronic priests would have possessed a vetoover adoption: the men with the greatest authority in Israel. Adoption in this case wastribal, not familial, analogous to circumcised resident aliens who were adopted into tribalcities if they were accepted to serve in God’s holy army.

1329

Leviticus 27:2–8 is the passage governing the conditions ofadoption into the tribe of Levi. There had to be a payment – theequivalent of a dowry – to the temple.42 In the case of a slave, hisowner had to provide the funds. If the adoptee was the head of ahousehold, he had to make the payment on his own behalf, or findsomeone to make it for him.

Who was the most likely person to make the payment for him if hecould not afford to pay? Both judicially and economically, there islittle doubt: the kinsman-redeemer. He would inherit title to the landleft behind by a newly adopted family. The entry price was high; noone else was likely to have the same incentive to make so large apayment. This points to the work of Christ as the Kinsman-Redeemerof Israel and mankind. He has paid the fee for all those who areadopted into the New Covenant priesthood. No one else has either theincentive or the ability to pay this price. In His case, the incentive isnot economic, for two reasons. First, Jesus Christ already is God theFather’s lawful heir in history and eternity. He will inherit everything.Second, the entry price is too high – far beyond the very high price of50 shekels in Old Covenant Israel. The price is the death of theKinsman-Redeemer. His motivation was grace, not profit. Christiansinherit as heirs of their Kinsmen-Redeemer, Jesus Christ. Everyoneelse is eternally disinherited.

Verse 8 reads: “But if he be poorer than thy estimation, then heshall present himself before the priest, and the priest shall value him;

Page 391: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

1330

according to his ability that vowed shall the priest value him.” Thehigh priest, Jesus Christ, has paid the maximum price for each of Hissaints – those set apart by God judicially for priestly service. Enteringwith nothing of our own, we do not need to plead before a priest fora lower entry fee. The high priest has paid it all.

Conclusion

If this analysis is correct, then it should be obvious that this law hasbeen annulled with the New Covenant’s change in the priesthood. Thepassage’s variations in price – young vs. old, male vs. female – havenothing to do with economic productivity. They are irrelevant for theeconomic analysis of labor markets. They were equally irrelevant forsuch analytical purposes under the Mosaic Covenant.

The prices listed in Leviticus 27:2–8 were not redemption prices;they were entry barrier prices. They were not based on the expectedeconomic productivity of people who were then immediatelyredeemed out of God’s ecclesiastical service; they were based on theneed to screen power-seekers and security-seekers from access toecclesiastical service. They were not market prices; they were judicialprices. They were not barriers to escape from ecclesiastical service;they were barriers to entry into ecclesiastical service. Thus, rather thanapplying economic analysis to the productivity of the groups specifiedin Leviticus 27:2–8, we should apply economic analysis to thequestion of the judicial boundary separating the tribe of Levi from theother tribes.

Summary

Page 392: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

1331

This law was a law of vows: self-maledictory oaths.These vows were ecclesiastical.These vows were unique.They appear at the end of the book of holiness.This is because the book following Leviticus – Numbers – is the

Pentateuch’s book of oaths (sanctions).Chapter 26 deals with corporate sanctions (point four).Chapter 27 deals with personal vows (point five).The economic value of a “singular” vow was to be estimated by the

priests.The vow established a change in someone’s legal status.This law’s context was service within the temple’s boundaries.Those affected by the vow were family members under the vow-

taker’s covenantal authority.A devoted thing was permanently set apart for priestly service-

sacrifice: beyond economic redemption.A sanctified thing was set apart for God’s use, but not necessarily

for priestly service: economic redemption was possible.A person devoted to God’s service died covenantally: a sacrifice.He was placed inside the boundaries of God’s ban (hormah):

beyond economic redemption.Anyone who stole an item placed under God’s curse would come

under the curse (e.g., Achan).The singular vow’s stipulations were irrevocable.An Israelite could offer his minor son to priestly service inside the

temple.The priest had to adopt him to confirm the parents’ vow.A daughter marrying a Levite could not be repurchased by return-

ing the bride price.Adult male children (numbered for military service: age 20) could

not be placed into priestly service by a father.

Page 393: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 36 . . . Leviticus 27:2–8

1332

An adult could not be disinherited from his father’s land-citizen-ship.

A daughter was not eligible for military service.She could be devoted to a priestly family by her father if she was

not married (e.g., Jephthah’s daughter).A father’s vow to do this was singular: irreversible disinheritance.Jephthah’s daughter bewailed her virginity because she had been

disinherited by her father.She could not inherit his power or kingdom.Being a virgin and eligible for priestly marriage, she could not be

bought back: the transfer was irreversible.The prices listed in Leviticus 27:2–8 were not redemption prices.Redemption prices were market prices plus 20 percent.The prices in this section were entry fees, analogous to a bride’s

dowry.The dowry was paid to the temple.This dowry established the legal status of freeman for the one being

adopted: a wife, not a concubine.Those so devoted by parents gained their freeman status from

membership by adoption into Levi’s tribe rather than from their birthtribes.

Levites were the legal advisors in Israel.Access to tribal membership was legal but not cheap.Redemption prices were based on market value (asset produc-

tivity).Devotion prices were judicial prices: tied to authority, not produc-

tivity.Any correlation between market prices and these entry prices is

illusory.The context is not economic productivity but priestly holiness.A high entry price on adult males restricted invasion by two

Page 394: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Priesthood: Barriers to Entry

1333

groups: power-seekers and guaranteed income-seekers.People over age 60 carried entry prices higher than young children,

ages one through four.The different prices reflected different degrees of difficulty in bring-

ing people under priestly authority.It was an honor to be a son of Levi.They were guardians of the boundaries.Sonship is judicial: by adoption rather than by biology.The kinsman-redeemer would have made the payment for a poor

relative who wanted to serve as a Levite or priest.Jesus Christ paid the dowry priest so that His adopted children

could serve as priests in His kingdom.His motivation was grace, not profit.This case law was annulled with the coming of the High Priest and

the new priesthood.

Page 395: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1334

37

THE REDEMPTION-PRICE SYSTEM

And if it be a beast, whereof men bring an offering unto the LORD,all that any man giveth of such unto the LORD shall be holy. Heshall not alter it, nor change it, a good for a bad, or a bad for agood: and if he shall at all change beast for beast, then it and theexchange thereof shall be holy. And if it be any unclean beast, ofwhich they do not offer a sacrifice unto the LORD, then he shallpresent the beast before the priest: And the priest shall value it,whether it be good or bad: as thou valuest it, who art the priest, soshall it be. But if he will at all redeem it, then he shall add a fifthpart thereof unto thy estimation. And when a man shall sanctify hishouse to be holy unto the LORD, then the priest shall estimate it,whether it be good or bad: as the priest shall estimate it, so shall itstand. And if he that sanctified it will redeem his house, then he shalladd the fifth part of the money of thy estimation unto it, and it shallbe his (Lev. 27:9–15).

The theocentric meaning of this passage is simple: God is to behonored by sacrifice.

Gifts to Priests

A person could give an animal or a piece of real estate to Godthrough the priesthood. If he changed his mind later and decided tobuy it back, he paid a redemption fee of one-fifth above the estimatedvalue of the gift. The recipient, the priest, made this original estima-tion. God was willing to allow men to change their minds regardingprevious sacrifices, but not at zero price. Once offered as a sacrifice,the property did change ownership: from the original owner to the

Page 396: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

1. There was an exception, as we shall see: a lessee paid a cash redemption price, but no20 penalty.

1335

priest. Whatever benefits the owner received from making the sacrifice– self-esteem, public acclaim, etc. – were purchased upon redemption:an additional payment of one-fifth.

This passage deals with the re-purchase of animals and houses thathad been given to priests either for ritual sacrifice or for resale by thepriests. Later in this chapter, I will consider the third redemptionpayment: fields. In each case, the cash redemption price required anadditional 20 percent payment.1 This was what distinguished aredemption price from the previous passage’s payment structure,which was not a redemption price but rather an entry fee into the tribedesignated by God for holy service. The visible difference between thetwo forms of voluntary payment to the priesthood – dedication anddevotion – was the presence of a penalty payment. The dedicated itemdid not become hormah: God’s whole burnt offering. With dedicationthere was a possibility of economic redemption: de-sanctification.

Pricing and Penalties

A beast was designated by its owner as a sacrifice. The ownerbrought it to the priest. The beast was then identified as havingbecome holy (kodesh). To be holy is to be set apart judicially, i.e.,sanctified (kawdash). But the degree of separation was less than in thecase of an offering that was devoted to God: it did not come under theban.

The priests were Israel’s agents of formal sanctification. They pos-sessed the authority to set apart certain beasts for sacrificial purposes.The individual could not sacrifice his animal on his own authority if he

Page 397: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

2. One of the fundamental institutional differences between magical religion and biblicalreligion is seen in this distinction between sanctified offerings and unsanctified offerings.The person who invokes magic believes that his formal incantations and rituals allow himto manipulate supernatural power directly and authoritatively. Biblical religion denies suchauthority to all those who have not been anointed, either by birth or adoption (OldCovenant priesthood or prophetic anointing) or by the laying on of hands (New Covenantministry-priesthood). The priest in the New Covenant does not offer a sacrifice to God(Heb. 9); rather, he offers to church members the sacramental means of covenant renewal:the Lord’s Supper.

1336

expected to establish it as a judicially valid offering; he had to bring itto the priests. This dependence on the priesthood to validatesacramental offerings to God reinforced the social and legal authorityof the priesthood. This arrangement did not limit men’s ability to makeeconomically significant offerings to God, but such unsanctifiedofferings were not sacramental. Laymen could show good faith, butthey did not have the power to invoke God’s sanctions authorita-tively.2

Once it had been dedicated – sanctified – the beast’s owner had theright to change his mind about sacrificing this particular beast. Forwhatever reason, he could choose to spare the life of this animal. Thepriest would then estimate the value of this beast according to itsmarket price. An additional 20 percent had to be paid by the owner:a redemption (buy-back) price. This specific redemption price is notestablished in the text, in contrast to verses 2–8, where specific pricesare stated. This is because the prices for sacrificial animals were notjudicial prices; they were market prices. They varied according tomarket conditions. The redemption price of an animal was tied to itsmarket price. This was also the case in the price of a house dedicatedto the temple (vv. 14–15).

The priest had the authority to fix the redemption prices of dedi-cated items (vv. 12, 15, 19) other than fields. If he set a price toohigh, the owner would not redeem the item. The priest would thenwind up owning an asset worth only what the free market determined,

Page 398: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

1337

when he could have had a market price plus 20 percent. He wouldthereby have forfeited the opportunity to enjoy what speculators calla quick turnaround. He was allowed to obtain the market price for theanimal by selling it back, keeping the extra 20 percent for himself. Thepresence of the 20 percent payment kept the priest’s pricing relativelyhonest, i.e., in close approximation to market prices. So, in thisinstance, the extra payment imposed in the redemption of sanctifieditems was not a penalty payment. It was more of a “keep the priests’redemption price valuations honest” payment. We should probablythink of it as a transaction fee. The giver proved his dedication to Godby dedicating the beast to a priest and then paying a 20 percenttransaction fee in order to redeem it.

Priests and Fields

The jubilee law applied to houses in the 48 cities of the Levites andto the common land surrounding them (Lev. 25:32–33; Num. 35:7).These homes could not be permanently alienated from the families ofthe Levites. “Notwithstanding the cities of the Levites, and the housesof the cities of their possession, may the Levites redeem at any time.And if a man purchase of the Levites, then the house that was sold,and the city of his possession, shall go out in the year of jubile: for thehouses of the cities of the Levites are their possession among thechildren of Israel” (Lev. 25:32–33). The jubilee law of inheritanceapplied to the Levites’ homes in Levitical cities and to rural land inIsrael. The Levites could not lawfully be excluded from theirinheritance, but they were excluded from the other tribes’ inheritance.To maintain their own inheritance, they had to defend the inheritanceof the other tribal families. They had to preach the jubilee law. Godgave them an inheritance in their cities; this served as an economic

Page 399: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

1338

incentive for them to declare the jubilee year.Priests could not normally own rural land; it was not part of their

inheritance at the time of the conquest of Canaan. When enforced, thejubilee law made it impossible for the priesthood to extend its politicalinfluence into the other tribes apart from the exposition andapplication of the Mosaic law. The jubilee law was designed to keepa centralized ecclesiocracy from being formed. The jubilee land lawwas primarily a law of citizenship. It was designed to provide apermanent judicial veto for the tribes. The tribal system, when rein-forced by the jubilee law, decentralized political power in Israel.

Levites could lease rural properties. They could also receive ruralproperties as gifts until the next jubilee year. They were not prohibitedfrom subleasing these sanctified fields. These fields would haveprovided them with a stream of income. Within a predominantly ruraleconomy, this stream of income may have been significant, dependingon the size and productivity of the dedicated plots.

A Righteous Bribe to Unrighteous Priests

The jubilee law’s restriction on Levitical ownership of rural landwas not primarily economic. The jubilee law itself was not primarilyeconomic; it was judicial: a mark of freeman status for the heirs of theconquest. But there were economic incentives tied to the preservationof political freedom. A small but relevant aspect of these incentiveswas the law of the unredeemed field. Priests could in rare instancesbecome permanent owners of rural land when an owner or his heirsfailed to redeem a reclaimed dedicated plot. But in order for thistransfer of title to take place, the jubilee year first had to be declaredpublicly throughout the nation. “And if he will not redeem the field, orif he have sold the field to another man, it shall not be redeemed any

Page 400: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

3. On the moral legitimacy of bribing corrupt judges, see Gary North, “In Defense of Bib-lical Bribery,” in R. J. Rushdoony, The Institutes of Biblical Law (Nutley, New Jersey:Craig Press, 1973), Appendix 5. “A gift is as a precious stone in the eyes of him that hathit: whithersoever it turneth, it prospereth” (Prov. 17:8). “A gift in secret pacifieth anger:and a reward in the bosom strong wrath” (Prov. 21:14).

1339

more. But the field, when it goeth out in the jubile, shall be holy untothe LORD, as a field devoted; the possession thereof shall be thepriest’s” (Lev. 27:20–21).

The existence of a law that tied the jubilee year to a permanenttransfer of rural land to priestly members of the tribe of Levi deliveredan important tool of influence into the hands of covenant-keepingrural land owners. If covenant-keeping men suspected that the civilauthorities and the priests had conspired to avoid proclaiming theapproaching jubilee year, they had a way to encourage the ecclesias-tical authorities to proclaim the jubilee year on time. All the landowners had to do was dedicate some fields to the priests and thenreclaim the fields for themselves, refusing to redeem these fields withcash plus a 20 percent payment. To inherit these fields at the jubilee,the priests would have to proclaim the jubilee year. The Mosaic lawtherefore provided the other tribes with a legal way to bribe otherwisedishonest priests into covenant-keeping with respect to the proclama-tion of the jubilee year.3 This was an expensive way to persuadepriests to honor the jubilee year; effective bribes normally involveconsiderable losses. At least until the plots shrank in size and valuethrough population growth, this transfer of land could be significant.

Establishing the Redemption Price

The law governing sanctified fields provides one of the few casesof a specified price in the Mosaic law. This law identified a single crop

Page 401: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

4. Some commentators believe that this referred to the amount of seed the field wouldproduce (output view). Others think it means the amount of seed that a field would absorb(input view). Wenham, who follows R. de Vaux (Ancient Israel): “seed” refers to thefield’s output of barley seed, not its input of barley seed. Gordon J. Wenham, The Book ofLeviticus (Grand Rapids, Michigan: Eerdmans, 1979), p. 340n. I agree with this view.

1340

as the economic measure: barley. This law applied to a single case: afield voluntarily dedicated to a priest.

And if a man shall sanctify unto the LORD some part of a field of hispossession, then thy estimation shall be according to the seed thereof:an homer of barley seed shall be valued at fifty shekels of silver. If hesanctify his field from the year of jubile, according to thy estimationit shall stand. But if he sanctify his field after the jubile, then the priestshall reckon unto him the money according to the years that remain,even unto the year of the jubile, and it shall be abated from thyestimation. And if he that sanctified the field will in any wise redeemit, then he shall add the fifth part of the money of thy estimation untoit, and it shall be assured to him (Lev. 27:16–19).

What was the redemption price of a piece of land? If sanctified landhad been treated as if it had been any other capital asset, the freemarket would have informed owners and priests of its value. But thisunique case was not to be decided by an appeal to the free market.Instead, the calculation had to begin with an estimation of a quantityof barley seed. As we shall see, the appropriate unit of measurementto define the limits of a dedicated field was the field’s output: onehomer of barley seed per year. Nevertheless, the grammar of the textdoes not specify whether “seed” in this case law refers to input (seedsplanted) or output (seeds harvested).4 Because of input-output ratios,I accept the “output” interpretation (see below). Also, because pricesare established in terms of the expected value of a resource factor’sfuture output, I accept the output view’s interpretation of “seed.”

Page 402: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

5. See Chapter 36.

6. Wenham, p. 338, citing I. Mendelsohn, Slavery In the Ancient Near East (New York:Oxford University Press, 1949), pp. 117ff.

7. Wenham, idem., citing Mendelsohn, ibid., p. 118.

1341

This case law specifies a particular crop: barley seed. It alsospecifies a unit of volume: homer (pronounced “khomer”). It refers toa unit of money: a shekel of silver. It refers to a number: 50. We mustnow seek to make sense of the passage: the redemption value of theland.

A Perplexing Translation

From Leviticus 27:2–8, we know that 50 shekels of silver repres-ented a great deal of money. It was sufficient to serve as a majorbarrier against an adult male’s entry into the tribe of Levi (Lev. 27:3).5 Fifty shekels of silver bought an adult male slave in the ancientNear East.6 The average wage of a worker was one shekel of silverper month.7 We must bear this in mind as we study verse 16.

The literal text of the pricing clause of verse 16 is somewhatobscure: seed of homer of barley at fifty shekels of silver. The stan-dard interpretation of this clause links the price of a homer of barleyto the jubilee year. The difficult question is this: To what does thephrase “at fifty shekels of silver” refer? There is a sharp division ofopinion between translators and commentators. Translators link the 50shekels to the unit of measurement: the price of one homer of barleyseed. Commentators link the 50 shekels to the jubilee cycle: thecombined prices of an annual homer of barley seed through the cycle.

I side with the commentators. Here is my reasoning. It has beenestimated that in Mesopotamia, the familiar price of barley was one

Page 403: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

8. Ibid., p. 340. Wenham cites R. P. Maloney, Catholic Biblical Quarterly (1974), pp.4ff; P. Garelli and V. Nikiprowetsky, Le Proche-Orient Asiatique: Les Empiresmésopotamiens, Israel (University of Paris, 1974), pp. 273–74, 285–86.

9. Ibid., p. 339.

10. R. K. Harrison, Leviticus: An Introduction and Commentary (Downers Grove,Illinois: Inter-Varsity Press, 1980), p. 237.

11. Rabbi Solomon (Shlomo) Yizchaki (1040–1105).

12. Chumash with Targum Onkelos, Haphtaroth and Rashi’s Commentary, A. M. Silber-mann and M. Rosenbaum, translators, 5 vols. (Jerusalem: Silbermann Family, [1934] 1985[Jewish year: 5745]), III, p. 131b.

1342

shekel of silver per homer.8 Because the jubilee year occurred everyfiftieth year, it is tempting to conclude that the text really meansoutput (or perhaps input) per land unit of one homer of barley a yearfor 50 years. A homer is variously estimated at between 29 gallonsand 59 gallons.9 Wenham says that a field yielding (output) a homerof barley seed was valued at one shekel, or 50 shekels per jubileeperiod. Harrison takes the view that “seed” means input: “The landbeing vowed was valued by the priest in terms of the amount of seedrequired for sowing it annually, each homer of barley representing aprice of fifty shekels for the forty-nine year period. This is comparableto Mesopotamian practices, where a homer of barley cost a shekel.”10

The comment by Rashi11 is similar: “. . . an area requiring a Khor ofbarley seed . . . is redeemable by fifty shekels. . . .”12 All agree: 50shekels per jubilee cycle.

There is one minor problem with this interpretation: the maximumlegal planting period was not 50 years or 49 years but 42 years. Theseven sabbatical years were supposed to be honored. In the year priorto the sabbatical year of the jubilee year there would be a triple crop(Lev. 25:21), so the total output was the equivalent of 44 years ofcrops. If we figure from seed inputs, then the total is less: 42 years.

Page 404: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

13. Reasonable as in “more reasonable than the alternative.” The fact is, paying 50shekels of silver in cash at the beginning of the jubilee cycle for 44 years of output meantpaying far too much. The buyer-redeemer was forfeiting the interest that could have beenearned. The market value of the final harvested homer of barley 48 years later was a smallfraction of the value of a homer of barley at the beginning.

14. I say this on the authority of the highly efficient farmer who leased the Institute forChristian Economics’ farm in Maryland.

1343

The presumption has to be that a particular plot of ground that onaverage either can sustain (input view) a homer of barley seed or elsecan produce (output view) a homer of barley seed each year is to bevalued at the beginning of the 49-year period at 50 shekels of silver.This seems to be a reasonable interpretation of the 50-shekel require-ment.13

Output or Input?

My interpretation of the passage is that it refers to the crop’soutput of seeds rather than input of seeds. I begin with contemporaryunits of measurement. There are 8 gallons to the bushel. If the biblicalhomer was 59 gallons – the high estimate – this was about 7.3 bushelsof barley. With modern agricultural techniques, an acre of land canproduce up to 50 bushels of barley, or 6.8 homers.14 In the Old Testa-ment era, the land’s output would have been far lower. At one-quarterof today’s productivity, this would have been under 13 bushels peracre, or slightly under two homers. Using the high estimate of what ahomer of barley was, we conclude that the land required to grow onehomer was about half an acre. Using the lower estimate of 29 gallonsper homer, or slightly over three bushels, this output would haverequired a quarter of an acre. For a small farm – say, 10 acres – thisseems like a reasonably sized plot to dedicate to the priesthood.

Page 405: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

1344

If we are discussing seed inputs, a modern farmer can get almosta 20-to-one increase from seeds planted. This ratio of output to inputwould have been far less in ancient Israel, but still the amount ofacreage necessary to seed (input) one homer of barley would havebeen quite small. It therefore seems more likely that the text refers tooutput rather than input: the land required to produce one homer ofbarley.

The Economics of the Translators’ Version

Were the King James and other versions’ translators correct? Doesthe reference to 50 shekels mean “50 shekels per homer” rather than“50 homers of barley per jubilee cycle,” i.e., one shekel of silver times50? If the translation is correct, this redemption price wasastronomical: 50 times the average market price of a homer of barley,plus 20 percent. But this would have been only the beginning of theredemption burden. The field’s potential output of barley per year wasthen multiplied by 44: the years of production remaining until the nextjubilee year. So, the total number of homers of barley that a fieldcould produce was multiplied by 44 years, and this gross output figurewas then multiplied by 50 shekels. There was a prorated reduction inprice in terms of the number of years remaining until the jubilee, butwith these huge payments, such prorating would have beeneconomically irrelevant to most Israelites.

What was the redemption payment all about? It covered the caseof a person who had vowed to transfer a field or a field’s output to apriest. At some point before the jubilee, the original owner decided toreclaim the field for himself. To do this lawfully, he had to pay a cashredemption price to the priest at the time of the reclaiming. If theformal redemption price was established at 50 shekels per homer of

Page 406: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

15. Legally, the crop could not be harvested. Probably this would have been interpretedas a crop of zero output. If the estimation was made in terms of barley seed used forplanting, the price had to be zero, since it was illegal for anyone to plant in a sabbaticalyear or a jubilee year.

1345

barley, as the familiar translations suggest, then the typical ownercould afford to redeem his field only in the final sabbatical year beforethe jubilee, when the unseeded output of the field would be minimal,or in the jubilee year itself.15 If he or his surviving heirs decided not toredeem it, his family lost the field forever. The translators’interpretation of the 50 shekels – applying to a homer of barley –would lead us to the conclusion that the details of the proratedredemption payment structure were merely symbolic, for almost noone could have afforded to redeem his field much before the jubileeyear.

If the conventional translation is correct, we are led inexorably tothis unpalatable conclusion: once the owner dedicated the field to thepriesthood, he could not expect to redeem it until the jubilee year. Theprice would have been far too high. This seems to be too radical arequirement: a redemption price totally disconnected from the marketprice. Conclusion: the reference to 50 shekels of silver refers to thefixed judicial price of a field that would produce one homer of barleyper season through the entire jubilee cycle. The closer to the jubileeyear, the lower the field’s remaining redemption price. In short, theredemption price of a field capable of producing one homer of barleyper year was 50 shekels of silver at the beginning of the jubilee cycle,plus 20 percent.

My conclusion is that the commentators’ conventional interpreta-tion, not the translators’ conventional translation, is correct: the pro-rated redemption price was one shekel of silver per year remaininguntil the jubilee year per homer-producing unit of land. This meansthat translators should abandon the familiar translation: “[a] homer

Page 407: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

1346

[of] barley seed [shall be priced at] fifty shekels [of] silver.” It shouldbe translated as follows: “[A field producing a] homer [of] barley seed[per year shall be priced at] fifty shekels [of] silver [at the beginningof the jubilee cycle].” The problem is, such a translation imports somuch interpretive material into the text that translators probably willnever accept this translation. They will try to stick with the sparseHebrew text as closely as possible. But when they do this, theydestroy the economic relevance of the prorated land-redemptionsystem. They create a text that misinterprets the law.

Priestly Inheritance

We now return to the unique law governing the inheritance of ruralland by priests: “And if he will not redeem the field, or if he have soldthe field to another man, it shall not be redeemed any more. But thefield, when it goeth out in the jubile, shall be holy unto the LORD, asa field devoted; the possession thereof shall be the priest’s” (Lev.27:20–21).

There were only two ways that a priest could acquire rural propertyin Israel. The first case is easy to understand: the land’s owner haddedicated the field to the priesthood. He or his heirs then refused topay the priest its output, year by year, and also refused to pay theredemption price. The priest’s family automatically inherited it bydefault in the jubilee. On the other hand, if the priest took immediatecontrol of the dedicated plot, working the land himself or leasing itout, the owner would automatically receive it back at the jubilee. Herewas a risk for the owner. When the priests or their agents tookimmediate control over dedicated land, they had a short-term econo-mic incentive not to declare the jubilee year. They might prefer tokeep working these dedicated lands for themselves indefinitely. But

Page 408: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

1347

they would incur a long-term economic penalty for such lawlessness:land owners would be unlikely in the future to dedicate land to thepriesthood. The priesthood would also lose respect in the eyes of thenation.

The second case – leased land – is more difficult to understand. Thepassage is no longer clear to us grammatically. There are two ways ofinterpreting it. First, a man dedicated a field to a priest, but then hesold (leased long term) the field to another man. If we understand theeconomics of the dedicated field as a gift of the output of the field,with the owner of the field cultivating the land and giving the produceto the priest after each harvest, then the subsequent lease appears tobe a case of a default on the original pledge. The defaulting individualhad leased his pledged field to another man. This lease contract washonored by the priest, but in the year of the jubilee, the field revertedto the priest.

The second interpretation assumes that a man who had alreadyleased out his land to another person then dedicated a plot of groundto the priest. The lessor’s contract with the lessee was honored by thepriest. The lessee was allowed to use the field during the years remain-ing until the jubilee, but then ownership was transferred permanentlyto the priest.

In both interpretations, the claim of the lessor (land owner) tookimmediate precedence over the claim of the priest, but the priestbecame a permanent beneficiary in the jubilee year. I think bothinterpretations are plausible, but the first one seems more plausible.The land owner indebted himself to the priest: an implicit promise tofarm the property for the priest’s benefit. He subsequently sought toescape this debt burden without paying the field’s prorated redemptionprice (including the 20 percent penalty) before leasing the land toanother person. The new penalty was the permanent forfeiture of thefield. The original owner thereby disinherited his heirs of the value of

Page 409: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

1348

this property. The heirs still owned the remaining (non-dedicated)fields, but the economic value of the judicially sanctified field had beenpermanently removed from them.

Disinherited Sons and Priestly Heirs

The claims of the original owner were primary until the jubilee. Hecould evict a priest or the priest’s agent from previously dedicatedland. In times of famine, for example, an owner might decide to evictthe priest or stop paying the priest the output of the dedicated field.But if, by the time of the jubilee, he had refused to redeem the land bythe payment of one shekel of silver for every year of the eviction, plus20 percent, he lost ownership of the land.

The priests had the possibility of inheriting rural land if the vow-designated land was not redeemed by the vow-taker. In such cases,the potential beneficiaries obviously had an economic incentive tooppose the debasement of the shekel (Isa. 1:22). A shekel of fallingvalue would have made it less expensive for those who faced thepermanent loss of their land to redeem it prior to the jubilee.

Would the owner of rural land ever have dedicated all of its outputto a priest? Not unless he was willing to risk disinheriting his sons. Ifhe was subsequently forced by economic pressures to reclaim theland’s output, and then he or his sons failed to redeem the land at themandatory price, plus 20 percent, all of his land would go to the priestin the jubilee year. Thus, there was an economic restraint on the over-commitment of land to the priesthood. The heirs of the conquest wereto this degree protected. The only person who would have committedmost or all of his land’s output to a priest would have been a very richabsentee landlord who made his money in commerce. But to dedicateall of one’s land in a grand display of wealth was risky. This person

Page 410: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

1349

might subsequently fall into economic distress and be compelled tolease his property to another. The heirs of this individual would thenhave lost ownership of all the dedicated land. If their father hadpledged all of their land, they would have lost their guaranteed statusas freemen. Thus, the high risks of default would have tended toreduce the number of such large-scale pledges to priests.

Nevertheless, the possibility of disinheritance did exist. If a fatherwas so distressed by the ethical rebellion of all of his sons, he had theability to disinherit them. He could not disinherit one son among manyin this way, but he could disinherit all of them. He could do this bydedicating all of his landed inheritance to a priest. He would then doone of two things: lease this land to someone else, or reclaim theland’s output for himself. If his sons refused to redeem the land beforethe jubilee, or could not afford to, they lost their inheritance forever.The priest could not transfer the land back to the original owner. Todo so would have meant disinheriting the tribe of Levi. The Mosaiclaw made no provision for such repatriation to the original owner’sfamily. Once a piece of rural land passed into the possession of apriest, it had to remain there until he died. Then it passed to hisnearest of kin. Unredeemed dedicated land became devoted land at thejubilee. It could never again lawfully leave the jurisdiction of thepriesthood.

We have no historical example of this in Old Testament, but wehave the archetype example in the New Testament: the transfer of titleof the kingdom of God from the Jews to the church. How was thisaccomplished? First, Jesus announced that God the Father had prom-ised the kingdom’s inheritance to His new priesthood, the church.“Therefore I say unto you, The kingdom of God shall be taken fromyou, and given to a nation bringing forth the fruits thereof” (Matt.21:43). This was a formal announcement of God’s dedication of thePromised Land. But such a transfer of ownership could be made only

Page 411: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

1350

to a priest. Rural land could be lawfully transferred from the family ofone tribe to the family of another tribe only in this unique case: theformal dedication of the land’s output to a priest followed by a failureto deliver this output and a failure to redeem it.

This New Testament transfer of ownership was not to be to a singlefamily of the priesthood; rather, it was made to a new nation. Thatnation is the church, which constitutes a new priesthood: a kingdomof priests (I Pet. 2:9). The representative priest of this nation of priestswas the High Priest. The High Priest is Jesus Christ (Heb. 9). Thispublic dedication was legally secured for the church by the death ofJesus Christ, i.e., the death of the Testator. “For a testament is offorce after men are dead: otherwise it is of no strength at all while thetestator liveth” (Heb. 9:17). The publicly visible evidence of thetransfer of the High Priest’s inheritance to His heirs came when theHoly Spirit fell on the church at Pentecost (Acts 2).

Old Covenant Israel had refused to honor this dedication. Theycrucified the new High Priest. They did not redeem the land. Prior tothe next jubilee, the output of the land was not delivered to the newpriests, nor was the mandatory 20 percent redemption payment. Thatis, the dedicated output of the land was not redeemed by the heirswhose legal title had been at risk. The Jews not only did not pay thenew priesthood the mandatory redemption price of 20 percent; theypersecuted the church. This secured the irrevocable transfer of thekingdom to the new priesthood.

When was the next jubilee year after the dedication? When did thetransfer of legal title to the heirs of the High Priest take place? JamesJordan’s study of New Testament chronology dates Jesus’ death inA.D. 30 (Jewish year: 3960). Paul was converted shortly thereafter,after Pentecost. The next year, Jordan concludes from his study of thecalendar after the exiles’ return from Medo-Persia, was the seventh

Page 412: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

16. If Jordan is correct that Jesus was sacrificed in the year prior to the seventh sabbath,this would have been the year scheduled by God for the miraculous triple harvest. This wasthe year of the largest firstfruits offering, which was delivered to the priesthood atPentecost.

17. Jordan, “Jubilee, Part 3,” Biblical Chronology, V (April 1993), [p. 2]. See also,“Chronology of the Gospels,” ibid, IV (Dec. 1993).

1351

sabbath year in the final jubilee cycle.16 The jubilee came in 3962, theyear that Paul’s ministry to the gentiles began.17 This, I conclude, wasthe date of the transfer to the church of legal title to the kingdom ofGod: the fulfillment of Jesus’ prophecy in Matthew 21:43.

Old Covenant Israel’s failure to redeem this dedicated land wasGod’s means of disinheriting all of His rebellious Israelite sons. Theycould be legally disinherited only as a family unit; selective disinheri-tance by a father was not possible. As long as any of the family’s landremained in the father’s possession, all of his sons would have a pieceof the inheritance. Disinheritance would not remove them from theirtribe. Tribal membership secured their legal status as freemen. Thus,disinheritance was in this case economic, not judicial. The sons wouldhave no lawful claim on any portion of the land. In A.D. 70, the self-disinherited sons of God were evicted by Rome from the temple. AfterBar Kochba’s rebellion of A.D. 133–35, they were evicted by Romefrom the land. The diaspora began.

The idea so prevalent in modern fundamentalism that the modernState of Israel is in some way biblically entitled to God’s original grantof land to Abraham, which was secured by Joshua during theconquest, is inescapably a denial of the authority and binding characterof God’s revealed law. The Old Covenant sons of God forfeitedforever their legal title to the Promised Land and their guaranteedcitizenship in the kingdom of God by their persecution of the NewCovenant priests, the heirs of the dedication: the church. Thecovenantal heirs of these disinherited sons can reclaim their citizenship

Page 413: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

1352

in the kingdom only as adopted sons, i.e., as members of God’s NewCovenant church. There can never be a repatriation of either thePromised Land or the kingdom of God to the Jews. Once a dedicatedpiece of land passed into the possession of a priest at the jubilee, therewas only one way for it ever to be transferred back to the originalowner. The original owner had to become a priest, and not merely apriest: the nearest of kin to the priest who had been given the land. Hehad to be adopted by that priest. Only through the death of thisadopting kinsman-priest could the original owner legally regain pos-session of his former inheritance.

The Kinsman-High Priest made this offer of adoption to every Jewas well as to every gentile. “But as many as received him, to themgave he power to become the sons of God, even to them that believeon his name” (John 1:12). He still makes it. There is no other way tosecure a piece of the now-devoted inheritance in history, which ismandatory in order to secure it in eternity.

This means that the land comprising the modern State of Israel isnot the Promised Land of the Old Covenant. It also has no judicialconnection to the kingdom of God or any prophecy regarding thiskingdom. The kingdom of God had been connected to the land priorto Jesus’ ministry and death, but the legal transfer of the kingdomtook place at the time of the final jubilee, when the Jews redeemedneither land nor kingdom from the church. God transferred to thechurch, the new priesthood, lawful title to the kingdom at the resur-rection of Jesus (Matt. 28:18–20), but He allowed the Jews to stay incontrol over both the land and the temple until A.D. 70. When theyfailed to redeem the land from the church prior to the next (and final)jubilee, title automatically transferred to the new priesthood. The landceased to have any covenantal relevance in A.D. 70, when it came

Page 414: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

18. David Chilton, The Days of Vengeance: An Exposition of the Book of Revelation (Ft.Worth, Texas: Dominion Press, 1987).

1353

under God’s vengeance.18

Lessees: Exempt from Earthly Negative Sanctions

It was not just the original land owner who had the option ofrewarding the priests by a temporary donation of his land’s net output.So could the person who had leased land from an original owner. Buthis situation was judicially unique: he was spared the 20 percentredemption penalty. “And if a man sanctify unto the LORD a fieldwhich he hath bought, which is not of the fields of his possession;Then the priest shall reckon unto him the worth of thy estimation,even unto the year of the jubile: and he shall give thine estimation inthat day, as a holy thing unto the LORD” (Lev. 27:22– 23). This lawspecified that the field would return to the original owner in the jubileeyear (Lev. 27:24). The law protected the original land owner from theconsequences of vow-breaking by the lessee. The lesee could nottransfer ownership of something he did not own: land beyond thejubilee.

To Protect the Priests

The lessee also escaped the penalty of disinheritance. A lessee whobroke his vow of dedication and reclaimed the land was not threatenedby the loss of the land in the jubilee. In fact, this law specifies nopenalty at all. It does not state that the lessee must forfeit anequivalent quantity of his own land. This means that there was fargreater likelihood that he would break his vow of dedication, compar-

Page 415: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

19. Ludwig von Mises, Human Action: A Treatise on Economics (New Haven, Connec-ticut: Yale University Press, 1949), ch. 19.

1354

ed to an original owner. The question arises: Why was the lesseeexempt from the 20 percent penalty? If he was not subject to thethreat of losing the dedicated land – it was not his land – then whywasn’t the redemption penalty even greater than 20 percent? Whywere no penalties imposed? The text does not say. We can only guess.Let us guess intelligently.

The lessee owed the original owner regular payments unless he hadalready paid the owner in advance. This placed him in a weaker econ-omic position, other things being equal, than the original land owner.Either he bore greater contractual risk than an original owner wouldhave borne or, if he had already paid the owner in advance, he had lesscash available to redeem the land from the priest. Since the goal of aland-dedication vow was to reward the priests, excessive economicbarriers to redemption would have been a disincentive for such vows.Thus, the priest bore greater risk of having his plans disrupted by alessee than by an original owner. The lessee was more likely to reclaimthe dedicated property than an original owner was.

If he paid no 20 percent penalty for breaking his vow to the priest,what would have protected the priests? They were protected by theinescapable phenomenon of interest. The present value of futuregoods is less than the present value of identical present goods. Thisdiscount is called the rate of interest.19 The priest could lawfullydemand an immediate cash payment of all the shekels remaining to bepaid until the jubilee. But the present value of the money to beaccrued in the future is less than the present value of the same numberof monetary units paid today in cash. So, the lessee paid a penalty tothe priest: the difference between the present value of the cash shekelsand the present value of those shekels to come. This was not the 20

Page 416: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

20. Those who deny the universal phenomenon of time-preference (interest) will have toseek for another explanation of how the priests were protected from disruptions in theirplans: forfeited vows by lessees.

21. Samson Raphael Hirsch, The Pentateuch: Leviticus (part II), translated by Isaac Levy(Gateshead, England: Judaica Press, 1989), p. 825.

1355

percent penalty, but it was nonetheless a penalty.20

The fact is, however, the law provided no explicit earthly negativesanctions for a priest to impose on a lessee who reclaimed previouslydedicated land. The priest had to rely on the conscience of the lesseenot to reclaim it. We see here that the long-term sanctity of the landas inheritance judicially outweighed the short-term sanctity of theland in priestly dedication. Only original owners could bring thisunique sanction of disinheritance on their heirs.

A Judicial Price: Fixed by Law

Why not use a free market price in establishing the redemptionprice of dedicated land? Why did the text specify a specific price (50shekels of silver) and a specific crop (barley)? Samson RaphaelHirsch, the early nineteenth-century Orthodox Jewish commentator,offered this explanation: this case “was the one unique case, standingquite by itself, where a field could be sold and the purchase ultimatelybecome permanent. Hence for buying back, for the redemption of sucha field which could eventually become a permanent purchase therecould be no market price ascertained, so that the fixing of a universalfixed value was a necessity.”21 I do not accept his explanation, but Ido accept his identification of the uniqueness of this fixed price – anon-market price.

When a specific price is established by the Mosaic law, it becomes

Page 417: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

1356

a judicial price, not a market price. Hirsch acknowledged that this wasnot a market price. What is not plausible is his argument that themarket price in this case would have been difficult to ascertain. At thebeginning of a jubilee cycle, it would have been only slightly higherthan the lease price. The effect of discounting an income stream onyears beyond half a century is to reduce its present value greatly.

There was another reason for a judicial price in this instance. Theunderlying problem was the threat of monopolistic exploitation by thepriest – the possible misuse of his authority to declare arbitrarily aredemption price. The judicial price of 50 shekels protected the orig-inal owner. It was the priest’s responsibility in all the redemption casesto declare the price, to which a 20 percent payment was added. In thisunique case, however, the priest was given an opportunity to takepermanent possession of land belonging to a member of another tribe.The temptation to cheat would have been very high. If the priest delib-erately set the price too high, the original owner or his heirs could notafford to redeem the field until the jubilee year or the sabbatical yearimmediately preceding it. In those two years, the input of the land waszero – no seeding was legal – and the output was not legal forharvesting. Thus, even a supposed 50-shekel per homer price wouldnot have been a barrier to redemption. The legal market price of thecrop was still zero. But economic conditions might change prior to thejubilee year. The head of the family might be tempted later to lease itout if he needed money. The family would then lose the propertyforever at the jubilee year. The terms of redemption were thereforespecified by law, so that there could be no doubt on the part of thefield’s redeemer or the civil and ecclesiastical authorities concerningexactly what was owed by the redeemer to the priestly family.

Restricting the Accumulation

Page 418: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

22. Marc Bloch, Feudal Society (University of Chicago Press, [1940] 1961), pp. 208–9;R. W. Southern, Western Society and the Church in the Middle Ages (Grand Rapids, Mich-igan: Eerdmans, 1970), pp. 261–63.

1357

of Priest-Owned Land

In the European Middle Ages, deathbed transfers of land to thechurch were common. The church and especially its monastic ordersaccumulated huge tracts of land over the centuries as a result of theseand other forms of land transfer.22 In contrast, a deathbed legacy ofland to the priesthood on a permanent basis was almost impossible tomake in Israel. A dying man might dedicate a plot of land to a priest,but the man’s heirs could redeem it early or else wait for the jubileeyear. The only possible deathbed transfer that could permanently havealienated land was a deathbed legacy from an owner – probably debt-ridden – who had leased out his plot of land and who then dedicatedit to a priest. This assumes that the second interpretation of the leasedland default is correct, which I do not accept. If that interpretation iscorrect, then economically incompetent men were the most likelysources of such permanent transfers of rural land in ancient Israel. Butit was the wealthy medieval landowner, not the poor peasant, whowas the source of deathbed legacies.

C. W. Previté-Orton has commented on the two-fold threat to themedieval church in the twelfth century: too many lax men joining themonastic orders and too much wealth donated to these orders. “Theextraordinary growth of monasticism new and old in the century ofChurch reform undoubtedly brought too many into the cloister,whether as converts or oblates, who had no true or lasting vocationfor the ascetic life; and the enormous landed wealth lavished on themby the laity, either in devotion or in fear of Judgment Day, proved a

Page 419: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

23. C. W. Previté-Orton, The Shorter Cambridge Medieval History, 2 vols. (Cambridge:At the University Press, [1952] 1966), I, p. 506.

24. The fourth, exceptional price was the field dedicated by a leaseholder. He had to payin cash the fixed shekel payments remaining on the property until the jubilee year, a pricenot discounted by the rate of interest.

1358

dangerous ally of laxity and degeneration.”23 This was not true inMosaic Israel. First, the entry price system of Leviticus 27:2–8 re-duced the likelihood of the influx of poor people into the tribe of Levi.Second, the jubilee law, when coupled with the price of 50 shekels perbarley-producing land unit at the beginning of the jubilee cycle (Lev.27:16) and the permanent transfer law of Leviticus 27:20– 21,reduced the likelihood of deathbed transfers of land. Such a transferwas a penalty, not a righteous gift.

Conclusion

The redemption price of dedicated rural land was a judicial price,not a market price. It was somewhat arbitrary, although not excessive-ly so, given the conventional Mesopotamian price of one shekel ofsilver per homer of barley. It provided a rough means of estimating theredemption price of a piece of land.

The presence of a penalty payment of 20 percent identified asredemption prices three of the four prices in this passage: beasts,houses, and owner-dedicated fields.24 These three penalty paymentsalso served to keep the priests honest in making their estimation of theredemption price of any property. If the priests estimated the priceabove the market price, the potential redeemer would not buy it back,so the priest would forfeit the 20 percent bonus available to him.

The law governing the redemption of sanctified fields created a

Page 420: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

1359

unique opportunity for the priests: the right to inherit rural land. If thesanctified plot was subsequently reclaimed by the owner but notredeemed, it became the inheritance of the priest in the jubilee year.This law served as the land owners’ means of bribing a corrupt priest-hood into announcing the jubilee year. The priests could not inheritunredeemed sanctified land unless they proclaimed the jubilee year.Set apart once by vow, the land could not be reclaimed – de-sanctified– by the vow-taking owner except by a cash redemption payment plusa 20 penalty.

This law placed a major restriction on the ability of a land owner toleave land to a priest. His heirs had the right to redeem the land. Thus,deathbed transfers of rural land were highly unlikely. The land ownerwould have had to sanctify the land on his deathbed without his heirs’paying an ever-smaller redemption price as the jubilee yearapproached. The priests would not become owners of property amongthe other tribes.

Summary

The redemption price of 20 percent applied to animals, houses, andfields – dedicated items – that had been given to a priest, i.e. sanc-tified.

A dedicated item could be de-sanctified through a redemptionpayment.

A dedicated beast did not come under the ban: hormah.A priest sanctified the dedicated offering; the owner did not.Such a sanctified offering was sacramental.The redemption price in these three cases was a market-governed

price.There was economic pressure on the priest to avoid setting the

Page 421: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 37 . . . Leviticus 27:9–15

1360

redemption price too high: forfeited income.The 20 percent penalty payment pressured the priests to keep

redemption prices honest, i.e., in line with the market price.The priests had no inheritance in rural Israel.The jubilee land law was designed to prohibit the creation of an

ecclesiastical-political State.Priests were allowed to lease rural land in Israel.Priests could inherit unredeemed and dedicated rural land.To claim their inheritance, they had to declare the jubilee year.This made it possible for other tribes to bribe priests into declaring

the jubilee year: dedicate plots of land and then fail to redeem them.Because a priest was the potential heir of the field, the Mosaic law

specified a fixed (judicial) redemption price.The redemption price for dedicated fields was specified: 50 shekels

of silver, plus 20 percent, at the beginning of the jubilee cycle for eachfield capable of producing one homer of barley per year.

The conventional translation is incorrect: the specified price of thebarley was not 50 shekels of silver per homer.

The commentators are correct: the redemption price of a one-homer-per-year field was 50 shekels of silver at the beginning of ajubilee cycle.

A priest could inherit rural land (1) if the output of a dedicated fieldwas retained by an owner who subsequently refused to redeem it atthe jubilee, or (2) the owner leased the dedicated field to someoneelse, and then refused to redeem it.

A lessee could redeem his dedicated land by paying the full valueof its redemption price in cash, but not the 20 percent penalty.

Priests were compensated by the difference between the value ofthe cash and the present (discounted) value of future income: the rateof interest.

There were no earthly sanctions for priests to impose on lessees

Page 422: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

The Redemption-Price System

1361

who reclaimed dedicated land without paying a redemption price.Deathbed legacies of land to the priesthood were almost impossible

in Israel, for the heirs could normally redeem the land from the priestsbefore the transfer was sealed at the jubilee.

Page 423: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1362

38

TITHING: THE BENEFIT OF THE DOUBT

And all the tithe of the land, whether of the seed of the land, or of thefruit of the tree, is the LORD’S: it is holy unto the LORD. And if aman will at all redeem ought of his tithes, he shall add thereto thefifth part thereof. And concerning the tithe of the herd, or of theflock, even of whatsoever passeth under the rod, the tenth shall beholy unto the LORD. He shall not search whether it be good or bad,neither shall he change it: and if he change it at all, then both it andthe change thereof shall be holy; it shall not be redeemed (Lev.27:30–33).

We come at long last to the final and shortest exposition in thiscommentary. The theocentric meaning of this passage is that God, asthe owner of all things, deserves a tithe.

A Holy Tithe

The tithe is described here as being holy (kodesh). It was judiciallyset apart for God by the Levites. That is, the tithe was sanctified. Thetithe was not under the ban (see below). We know this because the 20percent redemption payment was present in this law. The Levitesenjoyed the tithe as God’s representatives.

In a purely monetary society, the redemption law of the tithe isirrelevant. No one is going to pay a 20 percent payment to buy backhis monetary tithe. This law is relevant only in a society in whichincome in kind is common: income measured in something other thanmoney. In such societies, goods are sometimes retained by their

Page 424: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Tithing: The Benefit of the Doubt

1. This is the economic equivalent of allowing a farmer to set aside from this year’s cropan amount equal to last year’s seed. A person pays the tithe on net output only once. Hedoes not keep paying on capital, i.e., replaced producer goods.

1363

producers to be used or enjoyed for themselves, not sold into themarket for money.

Why would someone pay a commission to redeem an object? Onlyif that object has special meaning or importance for him. If the qualityof grain in a tithed sack is identical to the grain in the other nine sacks,the tithe-payer is not going to pay a commission to buy back the tithedsack. The assumption behind this law is that the impersonal collectingof the tithe may produce a personally significant loss for the tithe-payer. In order to enable him to minimize this loss, the law allows himto pay a 20 percent commission to buy back the special item.

There is no indication that this law has been annulled by subsequentbiblical revelation. It applies only to agriculture, as the text indicates– primarily to herds of animals.

A Tithe on the Net Increase

The text reads: “And concerning the tithe of the herd, or of theflock, even of whatsoever passeth under the rod, the tenth shall beholy unto the LORD. He shall not search whether it be good or bad,neither shall he change it: and if he change it at all, then both it and thechange thereof shall be holy; it shall not be redeemed.” The tithe wascollected from the increase of the herd. It was not imposed as a tax oncapital. It was a tax on the increase. This increase was a net increase.If one animal of the herd had died since the time of the most recentpayment of the tithe, the herd owner was allowed to set aside areplacement from the animals born since the last payment.1 Had thisnot been the case, then losses from a disease that killed half a man’s

Page 425: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 38 . . . Leviticus 27:30–33

1364

herd could not be deducted when assessing the net annual increase.This would constitute a tax on capital.

This law reveals that God gave the benefit of the doubt to the herdowner. An old beast that had died could lawfully be replaced by ayoung beast without the payment of a tithe. Presumably, this exchangewould have benefited the owner, since the newborn animal wouldhave had many years of productivity ahead of it. There would havebeen an increase of net productivity for the herd but not a net increasein the size of the herd. In some cases, however, the older beast wouldhave been more valuable, especially a prize animal used for breedingor a trained work animal. God, as sovereign over life and death,imposes net losses or gains on a herd’s productivity, irrespective ofthe number of beasts in the herd.

What was not tolerated by God was any attempt by the owner topick and choose from among the newborns. The owner could notlawfully select the best of the newborns to replace the dead animals,using the less desirable newborns to pay his tithe, thereby cheatingGod. Presumably, the birth order of the newborns would govern thereplacement of any dead beasts. The first newborn after the death ofanother member of the herd would have been segregated immediatelyfrom the other newborns as not being eligible for the tithe.

Under the Rod

Those newborn beasts that remained after the owner had replacedany dead animals constituted the net increase of the herd. In this caselaw, the herd owner lined up the newborns, probably in a pen, anddrove them one by one past the Levite. Each beast passed under a rod.Every tenth beast was taken by the Levite. The herd owner was notallowed to walk the beasts under the rod in any pre-planned order.

Page 426: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Tithing: The Benefit of the Doubt

1365

The same law that governed the voluntary sanctification of beastsgoverned the involuntary sanctification of beasts: “He shall not alterit, nor change it, a good for a bad, or a bad for a good: and if he shallat all change beast for beast, then it and the exchange thereof shall beholy” (Lev. 27:10). The owner was allowed to buy back any sanctifiedbeast, but only by paying the redemption price commission.

The herd owner was given the benefit of the doubt at the end of theline. Only the tenth beast was holy. If as many as nine of the finalgroup of beasts passed under the rod, the herd owner owed no titheon those nine beasts. Where the product could not be divided withoutdestroying the life or value of the item, the tithe applied only to dis-crete items. All those animals that passed under the rod after the finalgroup of 10 had been counted escaped the sanctification process.

Because God gave the benefit of the doubt to the tithe-payer, it wasespecially evil for him to arrange in advance the collection of the tithe,with or without the collusion of the Levite. The assembling processwas to be humanly random. Neither the tithe-payer nor the Levite wasto manipulate the crop or the herd to his own advantage, or to theother’s advantage. God owned the tenth; He alone was authorized toarrange the collection process. Any attempt by man to arrange theprocess was not only theft from God, it was an assertion of man’sautonomy. It was an attempt to manipulate the created order in a wayprohibited by God.

The Ban

What if a tithe-payer defied God and manipulated the tithe-collec-tion process? The tithed items came under the ban: “if he change it atall, then both it and the change thereof shall be holy; it shall not beredeemed.” The tithed item became hormah: devoted to God. This

Page 427: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 38 . . . Leviticus 27:30–33

2. By extension, the law of the military annihilation of all enemy males is also annulled(Deut. 20:13): no hormah.

1366

degree of sanctification was absolute; once within the boundaries ofGod’s possession, it could not lawfully be removed.

Why would a person manipulate the outcome of the collectionprocess? Because he was trying to cheat God. He was unwilling torisk paying the 20 percent commission that would be imposed if hesubsequently wanted to buy back a specific item. What was the pen-alty for this act of theft? Permanent loss. The very process of alteringthe outcome made the tithe holy – not holy as in sanctification, butholy as in devoted. The right of redemption ended.

There is no ban today – no hormah. That is because the New Cov-enant has annulled the sacrifice of animals. This aspect of the law isalso annulled.2

Conclusion

The tithe was paid on the net increase of the herd. The owner ofthe herd paid his tithe only out of the newborn animals that remainedafter he had set aside replacement beasts for the ones that had diedduring the year. He was required to run the remaining newborns undera rod. He could not lawfully order the line of newborns so that theoutcome of the tithe could be known in advance. The tenth beastbecame the property of the Levite. As in all cases of redemption, hecould buy back that beast for a payment of its market value plus anadditional payment of one-fifth.

If the owner violated this law by arranging the order of the beastsas they lined up, he could not buy back any of the animals. Theybecame devoted to God – beyond redemption.

Page 428: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Tithing: The Benefit of the Doubt

3. Chapter 17.

1367

There is no New Testament evidence that the economics of this lawhas been altered. The tithe on the increase of a herd should still behonored.

What about the rod? Was its use tied exclusively to the office ofLevite? The association with Moses and the rod indicates that its usewas in some way tied to the Mosaic covenant. Aaron’s rod was in theArk of the Covenant (Heb. 9:4), but the Ark has disappeared. Myconclusion is that there need be no rod in the process, but there mustbe a random distribution of the herd during the tithing process. We arenot allowed to cheat God. If a prize animal gets tagged for collectionby the church, the owner can pay its market price plus 20 percent. Thepresumption is, however, that prize animals of breeding age will besegregated in advance. The tithe on the net increase in prize animalsmust come from the segregated herd of prize animals. Suchsegregation was not lawful in Mosaic Israel (Lev. 19:19).3

If, after counting everything owed, there are up to nine beasts leftover, no tithe is imposed. God still gives herd owners the benefit ofthe doubt.

What about the ban? Today, we do not sacrifice animals to God.Thus, to place an animal under the ban is to misinterpret this law. Theowner can buy back the beast at a market price, but probably at publicauction. Then he pays an additional 20 percent to the church. Nocheating is allowed; whatever he pays for the animal, and however heobtains it, he pays 20 percent of what the purchase price had been atthe time of the auction or its initial sale by the church.

Summary

Page 429: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Chapter 38 . . . Leviticus 27:30–33

1368

This law still applies to agricultural productivity, especially herds.The tithe is collected on net increase.Newborn beasts can replace dead beasts on a one-for-one basis

without any tithe’s being owed.Birth order determines which beasts replace dead beasts.By implication, lost, stolen, or taxed crops can be replaced by new

crops without any tithe’s being owed.Those newborn beasts that constituted net increase were to be

selected randomly to pass under the Levite’s rod.The same principle applies: no deliberate tampering in advance with

the herd.Groups of animals within a species can lawfully be segregated

today, with the tithe taken from within each group.There is no tithe on the final nine members of the group.There is no ban today: no sacrifice of animals, no hormah.

Page 430: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1. Josephus, The Wars of the Jews, VI:ix:3.

2. David Chilton, The Great Tribulation (Ft. Worth, Texas: Dominion Press, 1987).

1369

CONCLUSION

Thrice in the year shall all your men children [males] appear beforethe Lord GOD, the God of Israel. For I will cast out the nationsbefore thee, and enlarge thy borders: neither shall any man desirethy land, when thou shalt go up to appear before the LORD thy Godthrice in the year (Ex. 34:23–24).

This was God’s ultimate visible evidence of His covenantallypredictable defense of Israel. The very boundaries of the land wouldbecome sacrosanct – sacred and set apart by God – during the threemandated annual festivals. God promised that during the Israelites’numerous corporate journeys to Jerusalem, which was the only auth-orized place of sacrifice on earth, their enemies would not even wantto invade the land. In their times of greatest military vulnerability,when the unarmed army of the Lord was marching to Jerusalem, thenation would be sheltered by the divine intervention of God. Thenation was holy: set apart by God. This included the land itself. Thesacrilege of military invasion during the mandatory feasts could nottake place for as long as God maintained His covenant with MosaicIsrael. Israel would not be profaned. The sign of God’s rejection ofIsrael would be a military invasion during a feast, especially Passover.

In A.D. 70, during Passover, the Roman legions surrounded theholy city and laid siege to it.1 This event was that which had beenforecast by Jesus (Luke 21:20–24): the Great Tribulation.2 When thecity fell, the Romans set fire to the temple. What would have been theultimate boundary violation under the Mosaic Covenant – the ultimatesacrilege – was not only permitted by God, it had been prophesied byGod. It was God’s answer to a heavenly prayer:

Page 431: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

3. See David Chilton, The Days of Vengeance: An Exposition of the Book of Revelation(Ft. Worth, Texas: Dominion Press, 1987), pp. 193–95.

1370

And I looked, and behold a pale horse: and his name that sat on himwas Death, and Hell followed with him. And power was given untothem over the fourth part of the earth, to kill with sword, and withhunger, and with death, and with the beasts of the earth. And when hehad opened the fifth seal, I saw under the altar the souls of them thatwere slain for the word of God, and for the testimony which they held:And they cried with a loud voice, saying, How long, O Lord, holyand true, dost thou not judge and avenge our blood on them thatdwell on the earth? And white robes were given unto every one ofthem; and it was said unto them, that they should rest yet for a littleseason, until their fellowservants also and their brethren, that shouldbe killed as they were, should be fulfilled. And I beheld when he hadopened the sixth seal, and, lo, there was a great earthquake; and thesun became black as sackcloth of hair, and the moon became as blood;And the stars of heaven fell unto the earth, even as a fig tree castethher untimely figs, when she is shaken of a mighty wind (Rev. 6:8–13).3

The fall of Jerusalem to the Romans was God’s final sign that theJews’ rebellion had terminated the Mosaic Covenant. Israel’s nationalboundary was definitively and permanently breached by Rome duringthe nation’s final Passover. The temple’s sacred boundaries wereeliminated. The sacrifices ended. These boundaries ceased to havecovenantal relevance because the Mosaic Covenant had ceased tohave any authority. God’s predictable, covenantal, negative corporatesanctions were thoroughly applied to that nation which had brokenHis covenant. Divine protection for the boundaries of the land wouldnever again defend Israel’s residents.

Page 432: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

4. Gary North, Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Deuteronomy,2nd electronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc.,[1999] 2003), ch. 8.

1371

Government and Sanctions

This raises a major question of biblical interpretation: What aboutthose aspects of the Mosaic law that applied to Israel’s civil govern-ment? Were they all annulled with the annulment of Israel’s geograph-ical boundaries? Were any of those laws cross-boundary phenomena?That is, did any of them serve as binding judicial standards for foreignnations? Deuteronomy 4:4–8 indicates that at least some of them did.4

Does this mean that these have been extended by God into the NewCovenant era? Are they still covenantally binding and thereforejudicial ideals toward which all nations should strive, and in terms ofwhich all nations are judged in history? My answer is the answerwhich is sometimes said to be the ultimate summary of all sociologicaltheory: some are, some aren’t. This answer in turn requires anadditional principle of interpretation, a theological means ofseparating: (1) the cross-boundary Mosaic Covenant civil standardsthat are still judicially binding on men and nations from (2) the temp-orally and geographically bounded Mosaic standards. In short, thecorrect answer requires a hermeneutic: a principle of interpretation.The Book of Leviticus forces serious Christians to search for thisbiblical hermeneutic. Without this hermeneutic, Leviticus becomes asnare that traps antinomians in their total dismissal of all of its laws,and traps legalists in their total acceptance.

In order to apply the Bible judicially to the governmental realm –personal, church, State, and family – we require two things: a princi-ple of institutional exclusion and the presence of negative sanctionsto enforce this exclusion. Exclusion and inclusion are two sides of thesame fence. Every boundary has an inside and an outside. So it is with

Page 433: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

5. Meredith G. Kline, By Oath Consigned: A Reinterpretation of the Covenant Signs ofCircumcision and Baptism (Grand Rapids, Michigan: Eerdmans, 1968).

6. Point one of the biblical covenant model: sovereignty.

7. Point four of the biblical covenant model: sanctions.

8. Point two of the biblical covenant model: hierarchy.

9. Point five of the biblical covenant model: inheritance.

10. Point three of the biblical covenant model: law.

1372

membership in God’s authorized covenantal institutions.

By Oath Consigned

Let us begin with the initial requirement for covenantal member-ship: the oath. There can be no lawful covenantal participation apartfrom a binding self-maledictory oath under God. A covenant is estab-lished only by a binding oath under God. People are, in the words ofMeredith Kline, by oath consigned.5 They are consigned by God6 toheaven or hell in terms of a personal oath7 of allegiance8 and also bytheir lifelong adherence – “the perseverance of the saints”9 – to itsjudicial stipulations.10

Let us consider political theory. People are consigned by an oath,either implicit or explicit, to membership in one State or another. Theprimary jurisdiction of the civil government is geographical. Every-thing within the boundaries of a particular State is under its juris-diction, although this jurisdiction is always shared in certain ways withthe other two covenantal institutions and usually shared also withregional civil governments within the jurisdiction of the larger civilgovernment. But one civil government has final civil jurisdiction, shortof lawful rebellion by lower levels of civil government – the Protestant

Page 434: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

11. John Calvin, Institutes of the Christian Religion (1559), IV:xx:31. See also MichaelR. Gilstrap, “John Calvin’s Theology of Resistance,” Christianity and Civilization, No. 4(1983), pp. 180–217; Tom Rose, “On Reconstruction and the Federal Republic,” ibid., pp.285–310.

12. In the United States, a person born in the United States or born of one United Statesparent need not take a formal oath in order to vote as American citizen at age 18.

1373

Reformation’s doctrine of interposition.11 In contrast to their automatic subordination by implicit oath of

obedience to the State on the basis of geography or birth, people mayor may not be consigned by implicit oath to a church or a family.Those people who refuse to accept as binding on them the ethical andjudicial terms of the covenantal oath in question cannot lawfully bepart of the covenantal institution in question. Those who refuse totake this oath are not allowed in, and those inside who break the termsof this oath must be expelled: negative sanctions. There cannot belawful government apart from oath and negative sanctions. Theperson’s oath may be implicit,12 but if the institution’s sanctions areexclusively implicit, then there is neither a covenant nor a government:no sanctions, no government.

The Adamic Covenant

Inclusion into God’s special covenant of redemption is by adoption.But there is another covenant, a more general covenant: the post-Edenic Adamic covenant. It was marked eucharisically (“graciously”)by God’s provision of animal coverings for Adam and Eve (Gen.3:21). This general Adamic covenant also has laws and sanctions. Itbrings men under condemnation in eternity. The covenantally disin-herited sons of Adam are still under its laws in history. Therefore, inorder to pursue a better world, covenant-breakers must conform

Page 435: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

13. Gary North, Dominion and Common Grace: The Biblical Basis of Progress (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1987).

14. On the difference between these two operations, see John Murray, The Epistle to theRomans, 2 vols. (Grand Rapids, Michigan: Eerdmans, 1959), I, pp. 72–76.

1374

themselves to God’s general covenantal law-order. The entire pre-Flood world should have repented. Similarly, Sodom should haverepented. Nineveh was also required to repent. There is no doubt thatGod through Jonah threatened Nineveh with negative corporate sanc-tions in history, just as He threatened Sodom through Abraham andthe angelic visitors. The threat of such sanctions against non-coven-anted nations testifies to the existence of covenantally binding laws.That is, the sanctions testify to the existence of general covenant lawsthat nations break at their peril.

The Ten Commandments and many of the Mosaic Covenant’s caselaws applied to the entire ancient world: cross-boundary laws. Thiswas a form of covenantal inclusion. It was not inclusion within God’sunique covenant of redemption, but it was inclusion within the generalpost-Eden Adamic covenant of temporal preservation: common grace.This grace is not given for the sake of covenant-breakers but for thesake of covenant-keepers.13

The existence of these general covenantal laws is affirmed by Paul’swords: “For when Gentiles who do not have the Law do instinctivelythe things of the Law, these, not having the Law, are a law tothemselves, in that they show the work of the Law written in theirhearts, their conscience bearing witness, and their thoughts alternatelyaccusing or else defending them, on the day when, according to mygospel, God will judge the secrets of men through Jesus Christ” (Rom.2:14–16; NASB). The work of the law is written on all men’s hearts– not the law itself, which resides only in the hearts of Christians(Heb. 8:10), but the work of the law.14 If this were not true, on what

Page 436: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

15. Cornelius Van Til, A Christian Theory of Knowledge (Nutley, New Jersey: Presby-terian & Reformed, 1969).

1375

legal basis could God condemn all covenant-breakers on the day ofjudgment and still remain faithful to His covenant with Adam? Theexistence of the universal sanction of death testifies to the continuingauthority the laws of the Adamic covenant (Rom. 5:12–14).

This does not mean that Spiritually unaided human reason candiscover the laws of the Adamic covenant. There is no such thing asSpiritually unaided human reason. God aids all men’s reason to somedegree in history. God grants varying degrees of common grace tomen so that they can sense some aspects of His general social laws.He restrains their moral and intellectual rebellion. But the mind ofcovenant-breaking man is in rebellion; so, as men become moreperverse – more consistent with their covenant-breaking presupposi-tions – they rebel against the knowledge they possesses by commongrace. They suppresses the truth that God constantly reveals to themin nature (Rom. 1:18–22). Therefore, covenant-breaking man’s logiccannot be trusted to persuade him of the truth. It can be trusted onlyto condemn him before God. His logic is as corrupt as his morals are.He has a flawed epistemology (theory of knowledge) because of hismoral rebellion.15 This is why all natural law theory rests on an illus-ion: the illusion of logically shared moral standards and sanctionsamong all mankind. Natural law theory is the creation of covenant-breaking men: Stoics of the late Classical period and Newtonians ofthe modern era.

Covenant-breaking man is by Adamic oath consigned to hell. He isfrom conception an oath-breaker in Adam, his legal representativebefore God (Rom. 5). He is a disinherited son: in time and eternity. Hehas been excluded from eternal life in history. “He that believeth onthe Son hath everlasting life: and he that believeth not the Son shall

Page 437: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

16. Greg L. Bahnsen, No Other Standard: Theonomy and Its Critics (Tyler, Texas: Ins-titute for Christian Economics, 1991).

17. Kenneth L. Gentry, Jr., The Greatness of the Great Commission: The ChristianEnterprise in a Fallen World (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1990), ch.10.

1376

not see life; but the wrath of God abideth on him” (John 3:36). To theextent that he and his fellow covenant-breakers live consistently inhistory with their broken oaths, they will become progressively morerebellious and progressively more threatened by God’s predictablecorporate negative sanctions in history.

Political pluralists emphatically deny this. They deny any legitimateNew Covenant judicial relationship between God’s righteousexclusion of covenant-breaking men in eternity and a civil govern-ment’s righteous exclusion of them from citizenship in history. Theyaffirm the civil legitimacy another standard and another oath. Towhich theonomists reply: By what other standard?16 By what otheroath?

Theocracy: Trinitarian vs. Non-Trinitarian

In the New Covenant, every civil oath must be Trinitarian, for theNew Covenant reveals that the God of the covenant is a TrinitarianGod. There is no other God whose oath is binding in history andeternity. The Great Commission requires that Christians work to seeto it that all nations are baptized into Christ (Matt. 28:18–20).17 Godrequires that every nation on earth be brought under His civil coven-ant’s administration through corporate affirmation: a Trinitarian oath.Civil magistrates are all supposed to be Christians.

A civil oath invokes God’s laws and sanctions in history. TheState’s jurisdiction is geographical and therefore comprehensive with-

Page 438: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

18. North, Political Polytheism, ch. 2: “Sanctuary and Suffrage.”

19. The problem for the American churches today is this: the United States of Americais officially covenanted constitutionally to the god of humanism, i.e., religious neutrality(Article VI, Section III). Ibid., pp. 385–92.

1377

in its boundaries – no separate jurisdictions. The only exceptions tothis rule are foreign embassies. Inside their boundaries their homenations’ laws prevail. I argue that no such grant of judicial immunityto any non-Trinitarian nation’s embassy is biblically valid within aChristian nation. Every non-Christian nation must come to God’snations “on bended knee,” to this extent: it is not entitled to a separatejurisdiction within the geographical boundaries of one of God’s cov-enanted nations. Any attempt to renounce the requirement of a Trini-tarian civil oath is necessarily an attempt to invoke another god’scovenant. But there can be no covenantal neutrality in history. Thus,inclusion in and exclusion from civil citizenship are required by Godto be based on public Trinitarian confession. Citizenship – the author-ity to render binding judgment in a civil court, which includes theballot box – must be based on restricted church membership (eccles-iastical boundaries) and a restricted franchise (civil boundaries).18 It isthis assertion regarding the civil oath which distinguishes Trinitariantheocratic movements (few and far between) from the broad range ofpost-Newtonian Christianity, i.e., political pluralism based on a sharedconfession of faith.19 This usually becomes a confession of faith inautonomous civil government.

Second, there must be the imposition of negative institutionalsanctions in history to defend the stipulations of this oath. These nega-tive sanctions are specified in the Mosaic covenant: formal warning orexcommunication (ecclesiastical) and either economic restitution,public whipping, loss of citizenship, or public execution (civil).Modern Christians do not readily accept these general exclusionary

Page 439: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

20. The Church of Christ denomination, following Alexander Campbell’s rejection ofPresbyterianism’s closed communion, holds the Lord’s Supper weekly, but then it deniesthe Supper’s covenantal relevance by refusing to exclude anyone from participating.

21. North, Political Polytheism, Part 3.

22. Russell E. Ritchey and Donald G. Jones (eds.), American Civil Religion (New York:Harper & Row, 1974); Robert V. Bellah, The Broken Covenant: American Civil Religionin Time of Trial (New York: Seabury Crossroad, 1975); Bellah and Frederick E. Greens-pahn, Uncivil Religion: Interreligious Hostility in America (New York: Crossroad, 1987);Sidney E. Mead, The Lively Experiment: The Shaping of Christianity in America (NewYork: Harper & Row, 1963); Richard V. Pierard and Robert D. Linder, Civil Religion andthe Presidency (Grand Rapids, Michigan: Zondervan Academie, 1988).

23. In 1989, at a conference of almost 400 evangelical American Protestant theologians,a majority refused to affirm the doctrine of hell. World (June 3, 1989), p. 9. See below:Appendix G, “The Covenantal Structure of Judgment,” footnote #1.

1378

requirements as legitimate if done in the name of Jesus Christ. Modernchurches rarely excommunicate members. Many churches celebratethe Lord’s Supper so infrequently that there is hardly anything to beexcommunicated from.20 It should therefore come as no surprise thatChristians who are unwilling to excommunicate theologically deviantmembers are also hostile to any concept of citizenship based on apublic, Trinitarian oath of allegiance. In this crucial judicial sense,modern Christians have become inclusivists. They have become civilUnitarians – belief in any god as sufficient for civil oath – and evencivil atheists: binding civil oaths without reference to God. That is,they have become pluralists.21 This ecclesiastical and civil inclusivismhas steadily been extended from modern politics – which isaccompanied by a common civil religion22 – into theology. Evangelicalleaders have begun to abandon the biblical doctrine of hell and thenlake of fire: the ultimate place of exclusion.23

Natural Law Theory

Page 440: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

24. Rousas J. Rushdoony, The Biblical Philosophy of History (Nutley, New Jersey:Presbyterian and Reformed, 1969), pp. 6–7; Gary North, The Dominion Covenant: Genesis,2nd ed.(Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, [1982] 1987), Appendix A: “FromCosmic Purposelessness to Humanistic Sovereignty.”

1379

While modern Christians accept in theory the legitimacy of formalexcommunications, however rare excommunications may be in ourday – surely not a testimony to widespread exemplary living byChristians in our day – they do not believe in civil excommunicationfrom the civil franchise on the basis of creedal confession. ProtestantChristians for over three centuries, and Anglo-American RomanCatholics for at least a century, have adopted political pluralism astheir civil ideal. This has required the adoption of a common-groundjudicial confession: natural law philosophy. Today, however, onlyChristians and a tiny handful of secular scholars still defend naturallaw theory.

Natural law theory is a defunct world-and-life view in modernhumanism. Charles Darwin and his followers by 1880 had destroyedthe epistemological foundations of natural law philosophy.24 Dar-winism has enshrined the doctrine of environmental determinism.Binding biological laws at any moment in history are explained as theresult of the conflict for survival: individuals vs. individuals, speciesvs. species, and species vs. geological environment. Similarly, bindingsocial laws at any moment are explained as the result of competitivesocial groups and their physical and social environments. There aretherefore no permanently binding social or moral laws in theworldview of Darwinism. The triumph of the Darwinian worldviewhas been almost universal, even among groups that do not acceptDarwin’s doctrine of exclusively biological evolution.

Faith in ancient Stoicism’s theory of a shared common-groundphilosophy that unites all rational men is now fading even amongChristians – its last defenders. This has left modern Christianity

Page 441: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

1380

judicially mute: judicial salt without savor, fit for being trampledunderfoot politically. This is exactly where God’s enemies want us.

What Christians need is an authoritative foundation for their knowl-edge. Without this, those who represent Jesus Christ in history willremain incapable of defending the judicially binding character Hisoath. They will remain impotent to bring God’s covenant lawsuitagainst covenant-breakers in every area of life. In short, they willcontinue to refuse to invoke God’s corporate sanctions in history.

The Laws of Leviticus

How does Leviticus fit into a program of covenantal sanctions?Can Christians confidently invoke the corporate sanctions of Leviticus(Lev. 26) as God’s continuing corporate historical sanctions, bothpositive and negative?

This commentary focuses on the narrow topic of economics. I havesurveyed the Levitical laws governing economics. I have also disting-uished temporary Mosaic laws of the land from permanent covenantallaws that crossed Israel’s geographical boundaries during the Mosaicera and then passed into the New Covenant. It is appropriate here toreview these laws.

I. Land Laws and Seed Laws

Land laws and seed laws were laws associated with God’s coven-antal promises to Abraham regarding his offspring (Gen. 15–17).There was a chronological boundary subsequently placed on the seedlaws: Jacob’s prophecy and promise. “The sceptre shall not departfrom Judah, nor a lawgiver from between his feet, until Shiloh come;

Page 442: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

1381

and unto him shall the gathering of the people be” (Gen. 49:10). AfterShiloh came, Jacob said, the scepter would depart from Judah. Theunified concept of scepter and lawgiver pointed to the civil covenant:physical sanctions and law. Jacob prophesied that the lawful enforce-ment of the civil covenant would eventually pass to another ruler:Shiloh, the Messiah.

The Levitical land laws were tied covenantally to the Abrahamicpromise regarding a place of residence for the Israelites (Gen. 15:13–16). These land laws were also tied to the Abrahamic promise of theseed. “In the same day the LORD made a covenant with Abram,saying, Unto thy seed have I given this land, from the river of Egyptunto the great river, the river Euphrates” (Gen. 15:18). The mark ofthose included under the boundaries of these seed laws was the coven-antal sign of circumcision (Gen. 17:9–14). Circumcision establisheda personal covenantal boundary. There were also family and tribalboundaries tied to the laws of inheritance. The ultimate inheritancelaw was above all a land law: the jubilee law (Lev. 25).

The fall of Jerusalem and the abolition of the temple’s sacrificesforever ended the Mosaic Passover. The five sacrifices of Leviticus1–7 also ended forever. There can be no question about the annulmentof the inheritance laws by A.D. 70. But with this annulment of theinheritance laws also came the annulment of the seed laws. Once theMessiah came, there was no further need to separate Judah from hisbrothers. Once the temple was destroyed, there was no further needto separate Levi from his brothers. There was also no further need toseparate the sons of Aaron (priests) from the sons of Levi (Levites).Therefore, the most important Mosaic family distinction within asingle tribe – the Aaronic priesthood – was annulled: the ultimaterepresentative case. The tribal and family boundaries of the Abra-hamic covenant ceased to operate after A.D. 70. This annulled theMosaic law’s applications of the Abrahamic covenant’s land and seed

Page 443: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

25. Infant baptism is not a confirmation of covenantal inheritance through biologicalinclusion but rather its opposite: the confirmation of covenantal inheritance throughadoption, i.e., adoption into the family of God, His church. The one who baptizes is anagent of the church, not an agent of the family. This was true under the Abrahamiccovenant, too: the male head of the household circumcised the males born into thathousehold, but as an agent of the priesthood.

26. Chapter 9.

27. Chapter 10.

1382

laws. The land and seed laws were aspects of a single administration:the Mosaic Covenant. The New Covenant – based exclusively andforthrightly on the covenantal concept of adoption25 – replaced theMosaic Covenant.

Land Laws

Biblical quarantine (Lev. 13:45–46). This law dealt with a uniquedisease that came upon men as a judgment. Only when a priestcrossed the household boundary of a diseased house did everythingwithin its walls become unclean. This quarantine law ended when thisjudicial disease ended, i.e., when the Mosaic priesthood ended.26

Promised land as a covenantal agent (Lev. 18:24–29). The land nolonger functions as a covenantal agent. That temporary office wasoperational only after the Israelites crossed into Canaan. That officewas tied to the presence of the sanctuary: the holy of holies.27

The laws of clean and unclean beasts (Lev. 20:22–26). This wasa land law, for it was associated with the land’s office as the agent ofsanctions. These laws marked off Israel as a separate nation. This istrue of the dietary laws generally, which is why God annulled them ina vision to Peter just before he was told to visit the house of Cornelius

Page 444: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

28. Chapter 21.

29. Chapter 24.

30. Chapter 25.

31. James Jordan, “Jubille (3),” Biblical Chronology, V (April 1993), [p. 2].

32. Chapter 26.

1383

(Acts 10).28

The national sabbatical year of rest for the land (Lev. 25:1–7).This was an aspect of the jubilee year. The law was part of God’soriginal grant of leaseholds at the time of the conquest. There is noagency of enforcement today. There has been no national grant ofland.29

The jubilee law (Lev. 25:8–13). This law applied only to nationalIsrael. It was a law uniquely associated with Israel’s conquest ofCanaan. It was in part a land law and in part a seed law: inheritanceand citizenship. It was more judicial – citizenship – than economic.The annulment of the jubilee law was announced by Jesus at thebeginning of his ministry (Luke 4:17–19). This prophecy was fulfilledat the final jubilee year of national Israel.30 This probably took placein the year that Paul’s ministry to the gentiles began, two years afterthe crucifixion.31

The jubilee law prohibiting oppression centered around thepossibility that the priests and magistrates might not enforce thejubilee law (Lev. 25:14–17). Thus, those who trusted the courts whenleasing land would be oppressed by those who knew the courts werecorrupt.32

The jubilee year was to be preceded by a miraculous year bringinga triple crop (Lev. 25:18–22). This designates the jubilee year law asa land law with a blessing analogous to the manna. The manna hadceased when the nation crossed the Jordan River and entered

Page 445: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

33. Chapter 27.

34. Chapter 28.

35. Chapter 33.

36. Chapter 11.

1384

Canaan.33

The prohibition against the permanent sale of rural land (Lev.25:23–24). This was a land law. This law did not apply in walled citiesthat were not Levitical cities.34

The law promising rain, crops, peace in the land, and no wildbeasts in response to corporate faithfulness (Lev. 26:3–6). This wasa land law. Nature’s predictable covenantal blessings were tied to theoffice of the holy land as the agency of sanctions.35

Seed Laws

Gleaning (Lev. 19:9–10). The gleaning law applied only to nationalIsrael, and only to farming. It was an aspect of the jubilee land laws:inheritance and citizenship. It was a means of establishing a majorform of charity in tribe-dominated rural regions. This law promotedlocalism and decentralization in Mosaic Israel.

The moral principle of gleaning extends into New Covenant timesas a charity law, but not as a seed law. The moral principle is this:recipients of charity who are physically able to work hard should.This law is not supposed to be applied literally today. There were noapplications in civil law. This law was enforced by the priesthood, notby the State, for no corporate negative sanctions were threatened byGod, nor would it have been possible for judges to identify preciselywhich poor people had been unlawfully excluded.36 This principle of

Page 446: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

37. Chapter 22.

38. Chapter 17.

39. Chapter 18.

40. Chapter 30.

41. Chapter 31.

1385

interpretation also applies to the re-statement of the gleaning law inLeviticus 23:22.37

The laws against allowing different breeds of cattle to interbreed(Lev. 19:19). This was a temporary seed law. It reflected the laws oftribal separation. So did the law against sewing a field with mixedseeds. Also annulled is the prohibition against wearing wool-linengarments.38

The law against harvesting the fruit of newly planted trees forthree years and setting aside the fourth year’s crop as holy (Lev. 19:23–25). This was a seed law. It was a curse on Israel because of thefailure of the exodus generation to circumcise their sons during thewilderness wandering. It is no longer in force.39

The law governing the enslavement of fellow Israelites (Lev. 25:39–43). This was a seed law, although by being governed by thejubilee law, there was an aspect of land law associated with it. Thereis no longer any long-term indentured servitude bringing a familyunder the authority of another family for up to 49 years.40

The law governing the permanent enslavement of foreigners (Lev.25:44–46). This must have been a seed law rather than a land law, forit opened the possibility of adoption, either by the family that ownedthe foreign slaves or by another Israelite family.41

The law governing the redemption of an Israelite out of a for-eigner’s household by the kinsman-redeemer (Lev. 25:47–55). This

Page 447: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

42. Chapter 32.

43. Chapters 1–7.

44. Chapter 8.

45. Chapter 36.

1386

was a seed law.42

II. Priestly Laws

The laws of five sacrifices (Lev. 1–7). These were all priestly laws.They are no longer in force.43

The law prohibiting wine drinking by priests while they were insidethe tabernacle or temple (Lev. 10:8–11). This law was exclusive topriests as mediatorial agents. The wine belonged to God. It had to bepoured out before the altar. This law was tied to the holiness of thetemple. It did not apply to Levites or priests outside of the temple’sgeographical boundaries.44

The law establishing the official prices of people who take vows(Lev. 27:2–8). This was a law governing access to the priesthood.These vows governed those who were devoted – irrevocably adopted– to priestly service.45

The law establishing vows to priests and the inheritance of ruralland (Lev. 27:9–15). This law was primarily priestly but secondarilya seed law: an aspect of inheritance. This law placed the negativesanction of disinheritance on those who vowed to support a priestthrough the productivity of a dedicated plot of land and then refusedto honor the vow. The land went from being dedicated to devoted:

Page 448: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

46. Chapter 37.

47. Chapter 12.

48. Chapter 13.

49. Chapter 14.

1387

beyond redemption.46

The final abolition of the Mosaic priesthood at the fall of Jerusalemended the authority of all of these laws forever. They were holinesslaws for the holy land. The holy land is no longer holy.

III. Cross-Boundary Laws

Cross-boundary laws are still in force under the New Covenant.These are properly designated as Deuteronomy 4 laws: designed byGod to bring men to repentance through the testimony of civil justicewithin a holy commonwealth.

Fraud and false dealing (Lev. 19:11–12). The laws against theftstill prevail. They had no unique association with either the land or thepromised seed.47

The law against robbing an employee by paying him later than theend of the working day (Lev. 19:13). This law protects the weakestparties from unfair competition: the ability to wait to be paid.

The law against tripping the blind man and cursing the deaf man(Lev. 19:14). The weaker parties are to be protected by civil law.48

The prohibition against enforcing laws that discriminate in termsof wealth or power (Lev. 19:15). This law had no unique associationwith Israel’s land or seed laws. Its theological presupposition is thatGod is not a respecter of persons: a theological principle upheld inboth covenants.49

Page 449: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

50. Chapter 16.

51. Chapter 19.

52. Chapter 20.

53. Chapter 29.

54. Chapter 34.

1388

The prohibition against personal vengeance (Lev. 19:18). Thisestablishes the civil government as God’s monopoly agency of vio-lence.50

The law prohibiting judicial discrimination against strangers inthe land (non-citizens) (Lev. 19:33–36). This law an aspect of the justweights law. Laws governing justice were not land-based or seed-based.51

The law against offering a child to Molech (Lev. 20:2–5). Thiswas a law governed by the principle of false worship, although itappears to be a seed law (inheritance) or perhaps a land law(agricultural blessings). It had to do with identifying the source ofpositive sanctions in history: either God or a false god. God’s nameis holy: sanctified.52 This will never change.

The jubilee law prohibiting taking interest from poor fellowbelievers or resident aliens (Lev. 25:35–38). This law was an exten-sion of Exodus 22:25. It was included in the jubilee code, but it wasnot derived from that code. In non-covenanted, non-Trinitariannations, however, Christians are the resident aliens. Thus, the residentalien aspect of the law is annulled until such time as nations formallycovenant under God.53

The law promising fruitfulness and multiplication of seed (Lev.26:9–10). This law was covenantal, not tied to the holy land or thetribal structure of inheritance. It was a confessional law, but becauseof its universal promise, it was a common grace law.54

Page 450: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

55. Chapter 35.

56. Chapter 38.

57. Vern Sheridan Poythress, “Effects of Interpretive Frameworks on the Application ofOld Testament Law,” in Theonomy: A Reformed Critique, edited by William S. Barker andW. Robert Godfrey (Grand Rapids, Michigan: Zondervan Academie, 1990), ch. 5.

1389

Negative corporate sanctions (Lev. 26:13–17). These were prom-ised to Israel, but they were not tied to either the holy land or thepromised seed. The governing issue was the fear of God, which is stillin force.55

The law of the tithe that applied to animals passing under a rod(Lev. 27:30–37). This law still applies, though it is no longer veryimportant in a non-agricultural setting. God still prohibits individualsfrom structuring tithes in kind (goods) from pre-collection rearrange-ments that favor the tither.56

The Principle of the Boundary

I have argued that Christians need a Bible-based hermeneutic inorder to interpret correctly the applications of the laws of the OldCovenant in the New Covenant era. This is also Professor Poythress’argument.57 By now the reader should understand what this biblicalprinciple of judicial interpretation is: the principle of the boundary.

This is a very long commentary. Most of it has been devoted to anexplanation of laws that are no longer binding: seed laws, land laws,and priestly laws. Why devote so much time, money, and space to astudy of things no longer relevant? Answer: in order to be confidentabout the laws that are still relevant.

A scholar spends most of his life examining records, experiments,books, and articles that do not apply to his immediate concerns.

Page 451: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

58. Greg L. Bahnsen, By This Standard: The Authority of God’s Law Today (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1985), p. 3.

59. By mandating the execution of rebellious adolescents and adult sons, this case lawdeclared war against any criminal class. The enforcement of this case law means that acriminal class cannot easily come into existence. R. J. Rushdoony, The Institutes of BiblicalLaw (Nutley, New Jersey: Craig Press, 1973), pp. 185–91.

1390

Scholarship is the process of sifting through what is, for a scholar,mostly irrelevant information. He sifts in terms of a principle – a herm-eneutic – which leads to scientific and intellectual breakthroughs. Soit is with the New Covenant student of the laws of Leviticus. Ourproblem today is that there is no agreement among Christiansregarding the proper principle governing this judicial sifting process.

Theonomists have a general principle of judicial interpretation:unless an Old Covenant law is in principle or specifically annulled bythe New Testament, it is still in force. Bahnsen writes: “The method-ological point, then, is that we presume our obligation to obey anyOld Testament commandment unless the New Testament indicatesotherwise. We must assume continuity with the Old Testament ratherthan discontinuity.”58 That is, the theonomist announces with respectto all Old Covenant laws: “Innocent until proven guilty.” An unchal-lenged Old Covenant law is said to have been granted citizenshipautomatically by the New Testament. No additional proof of citi-zenship is required by law. Unless its citizenship has been revoked bythe New Testament, a Mosaic law automatically crosses the boundarybetween the two covenants. The law’s adoption into the New Cov-enant kingdom of God is automatic. The representative rhetorical hardcase for this principle of interpretation is the law’s mandated stoningof rebellious sons (Deut. 21:18–21).59

All other schools of Christian biblical interpretation assert a rivaljudicial hermeneutic: any Old Covenant law not repeated in the NewTestament is automatically annulled. The non-theonomist announces

Page 452: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

60. See my response to Dan G. McCartney: Gary North, Westminster’s Confession: TheAbandonment of Van Til’s Legacy (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1991),pp. 211, 214.

1391

with respect to every Old Covenant law: “Guilty until proven inno-cent.” An Old Covenant law is automatically turned back at the borderof the New Covenant unless it has had citizenship papers issued by theNew Testament. Its disinheritance is automatic unless it has beenexplicitly adopted into God’s New Covenant kingdom. Therepresentative rhetorical hard case for this hermeneutic is bestiality(Lev. 18:23; 20:15–16).60

A majority of the economic laws of Leviticus were turned back atthe covenantal border. But this rejection was not automatic. The geo-graphical and tribal promises that went to Abraham’s seeds (plural)were fulfilled with the coming of the prophesied Seed (singular: Gal.3:16) – the Messiah, Shiloh, Jesus Christ, the incarnate Son of God –who announced His ministry’s fulfillment of the judicial terms of thejubilee year (Luke 4:16–21). This fulfillment was confirmed throughHis death and resurrection – the ultimate physical liberation. Israel’spermanent disinheritance was prophesied by Jesus: “Therefore say Iunto you, The kingdom of God shall be taken from you, and given toa nation bringing forth the fruits thereof” (Matt. 21:43). This transferof the kingdom’s inheritance to this new nation took place atPentecost (Acts 2). The visible manifestation of the permanentrevocation of the Abrahamic inheritance to his biological heirs was thefall of Jerusalem in A.D. 70. Israel had failed to keep the terms of thecovenant. The predictable negative corporate sanctions came inhistory.

Discontinuity and Continuity

Page 453: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

1392

in the Levitical Sacrifices

The whole burnt offering was annulled by the New Covenant.There is no evidence that its underlying principle of sacrifice wasannulled: unblemished animal, the best of the flock, but only one. Thiswas a high-cost sacrifice, but it was nevertheless limited. Conclusion:man cannot pay God all that he owes. This judicial principle wasillustrated by the whole burnt offering, but it was not limited to it.

The meal offering was annulled, but not its underlying principle ofthe hierarchical authority of the priesthood. The salt of this earthlysacrifice is no longer lawfully administered by any priest; the eternalsalt of the covenant (Mark 9:47–49) is administered by the HighPriest, Jesus Christ. The judicial principle of the meal offering still isin force: if you do not bring a satisfactory offering to be salted andconsumed by the fire, then you will become that offering.

The peace offering is no longer eaten by the offerer at a meal heldinside the boundaries of the temple. But the economic principle of theleaven – the best a man can offer God from his “field” – has not beenremoved from the New Covenant’s voluntary offerings. Neither hasthe cultural principle of leaven: expansion over time.

The related principles of corporate responsibility and corporaterepresentation are no longer manifested in the sin offering, i.e.,purification offering. Nevertheless, they are clearly revealed in theAdamic covenant and the New Covenant. The biblical principle of thedelegation of earthly authority – from God to the people to theirrepresentative – was illustrated in the purification offering, but it wasnot inaugurated by this offering. It therefore did not perish with thisoffering. Also, we no longer bring an animal to serve as our trespassor reparation offering for a sin of omission, but the principle of thesacrifice proportionate to one’s wealth still applies, in church andState.

Page 454: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

1393

A thief’s reparation offering is no longer made by presenting a ramwithout blemish. But there is no indication that an offering comparablein value to a ram in the Mosaic economy should not still be presentedto a church by the self-confessed thief, nor should his victim be deniedthe return of the thing stolen plus a reparation payment of 20 percent.The judicial boundary between sacred and common still exists. Aviolation of such a boundary still constitutes a profane act. But sacredboundaries in the New Covenant are overwhelmingly judicial-ecclesiastical rather than geographical

The annulment of the Levitical sacrifices has not annulled the prin-ciples that underlay these sacrifices, any more than the annulment ofthe Mosaic priesthood has somehow annulled the principle of sacri-fice. The High Priest’s office still exists, but only one man holds it: theresurrected Jesus Christ. The mediatorial role of the Old Covenantpriest in offering a bloody sacrifice has been annulled by Christ’sperfect, one-time sacrifice (Heb. 9). This does not mean that the min-isterial, judicial, and educational role of the Levites has been annulled.The diaconate has replaced the Levites’ social role. Melchizedek, thepriestly king of Salem, offered Abraham bread and wine, and Abrahampaid his tithe to him (Gen. 14:18–20). The annulment of the Mosaicpriesthood did not annul this Melchizedekan ecclesiastical role. Thisis the inescapable message of the epistle to the Hebrews, which is theNew Testament’s book of priestly discontinuity.

There is both judicial continuity and discontinuity in the transitionbetween Old Covenant and New Covenant. Both of these principlesmust be forthrightly proclaimed and defended exegetically. Thiscommentary is long because Christians have too often only intuitivelyrecognized which features of the Mosaic law have been annulled andwhich are still binding. They have not applied a consistent herm-eneutic. It is long because it is exegetical. Most of all, it is longbecause we require casuistry to make sense of Leviticus: the applica-

Page 455: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

61. John Frame, “The One, the Many, and Theonomy,” in Theonomy: A ReformedCritique, p. 97.

62. H. Wayne House and Thomas D. Ice, Dominion Theology: Blessing or Curse(Portland, Oregon: Multnomah Press, 1988), pp. 127, 130. For a reply, see Greg L.Bahnsen and Kenneth L. Gentry, Jr., House Divided: The Break-Up of DispensationalTheology (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1989), pp. 93–96.

1394

tion of general law to specific cases, and the investigation of specificcase laws to discover the general legal principle governing any ofthem. Casuistry is a tiring, highly detailed process of discovery thatmust continue in every generation if God’s kingdom is to be extended.John Frame insisted in 1990, “all the exegetical work remains to bedone!”61 Not all. A great deal, no doubt, but not all. It is also worthnoting that the modern “school of the non-prophets,” which asserts anabsolute judicial discontinuity between the whole of Leviticus and theNew Covenant, has a great deal of work ahead of it, too.

I have said my piece regarding Leviticus. It has been a long piece.It is now my critics’ turn to say theirs. Then we shall see just howmuch discontinuity they can prove, and what the moral and culturaleffects of these alleged discontinuities will be. I suggest that theybegin with the Levitical case laws governing bestiality. One thing issure: if they turn to pre-Kant natural law as their suggested alternativeto the Mosaic law, they will have to show why Hume was wrong,Kant was wrong, Hegel was wrong, Darwin was wrong, and existen-tialism is wrong. If the only civil stipulation they leave us with is thedeath penalty in Genesis 9, they have not left us with much.62 Theyhave in fact left us judicially defenseless. If we cannot appeal to God’sjustice, as manifested in His Bible-revealed law, to what shouldChristians appeal? The dispensationalist answers, “the Rapture.” Theamillennialist answers, “the end of history.” But what happens to usif either event is delayed?

I answer: if we cling to a hermeneutic of personal judicial discon-

Page 456: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

1395

tinuity only, we should prepare for negative corporate sanctions.“Salt is good: but if the salt have lost his savour, wherewith shall it beseasoned? It is neither fit for the land, nor yet for the dunghill; butmen cast it out. He that hath ears to hear, let him hear” (Luke 14:34–35).

Conclusion

For three decades, the critics of theonomy have issued this chal-lenge: “Prove your case exegetically.” Rushdoony’s first volume ofThe Institutes of Biblical Law (1973) was theonomy’s frontal assault.He suggested hundreds of ways in which Mosaic case laws still apply.He used the Ten Commandments as his integrating principle. Bahn-sen’s Theonomy in Christian Ethics (1977) provided a technical apol-ogetic defense of theonomy, written in the arcane language called“theologian.” It has received more attention – most of it negative –from the theologians than Rushdoony’s Institutes because Bahnsenwrote fluently in their adopted tongue, which the rest of us have diffi-culty following without a dictionary and a grammar handbook. Ishowed in Tools of Dominion (1990) how the case laws of Exodusstill apply to economics and civil justice. These books all emphasizedcontinuity.

Our critics have not been satisfied. They have continued to com-plain: “You say that you have a hermeneutical principle of discontinu-ity. Let us see it in action.” They have implied that theonomistspossess no hermeneutic of discontinuity, other than the obviousannulment of the laws sacrifice by the Epistle to the Hebrews. If ourcritics are honest – a gigantic if – we should now begin to see amuting of this criticism, or at least a mutating. I am not counting onthis, however. I first published this in 1994. So far, no response.

A challenge appeared in the Spring, 1993, issue of the Bulletin of

Page 457: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

63. Edd S. Noell, “A Reformed Approach to Christian Economics: Christian Reconstruc-tion,” Bulletin (Spring 1993), p. 16.

1396

the Association of Christian Economists. Westmont College econo-mics professor Edd S. Noell, in a well-balanced summary of the theon-omic (i.e., my) approach to economic analysis, concluded with thischallenge to theonomists (i.e., to me): “They must more carefullydelineate the Old Testament laws that are abolished by the NewTestament and the exegetical basis for their position in this regard.They must consider more extensively the issue of the context of theancient agrarian economy of Israel in which the Mosaic law was given.There is more work to be done to convince fellow Christianeconomists of some of the specific exegetical conclusions they reach(in regard to monetary reform as well as other policy applications).”63

This commentary is part of my response to this criticism. I alsoinclude my economic commentaries on the Pentateuch and six NewTestament books, my Introduction to Christian Economics (1973),and two of my books in the Biblical Blueprint Series: Honest Money(1986) and Inherit the Earth (1987). So is my critique of Social Crediteconomics, Salvation Through Inflation (1993). So is my chapter inthe book edited by Robert Clouse, Wealth and Poverty: FourChristian Views of Economics (1985). I should also mention 20 yearsof my newsletter, Biblical Economics Today – over 1,600 double-spaced manuscript pages. There is, of course, always more work to bedone, more Bible passages to consider. There are always moretypesetting and printing expenses to pay. I plan to do the work andpay the expenses. But I think it is fair for me to ask my critics in 2006,as I asked in 1994: “Where have all the other Christian economistsbeen for the last 30 years? Unlike me, they are being paid goodsalaries by colleges and universities to write books and articles. Whereare all those explicitly Christian economics books and articles?”

Page 458: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

64. Douglas Vickers, Economics and Man: Prelude to a Christian Critique (Nutley, NewJersey: Craig Press, 1976). This was followed by his brief book, A Christian Approach toEconomics and the Cultural Situation (Smithtown, New York: Exposition Press, 1982),which in fact did not specify what this “Christian approach” is. For a response to Vickers,see Ian Hodge, Baptized Inflation: A Critique of “Christian” Keynesianism (Tyler, Texas:Institute for Christian Economics, 1986).

65. Gary North, “Economics: From Reason to Intuition,” in North (ed.), Foundations ofChristian Scholarship: Essays in the Van Til Perspective (Vallecito, California: RossHouse Books, 1976), ch. 5.

66. Noell, p. 10.

1397

The Association of Christian Economists has been around since themid-1980’s, but so far as I know, no other member has produced evenone volume of an economic commentary on the Bible. I also have seennothing like my book, The Coase Theorem (1992): an expresslyChristian critique of a Nobel Prize-winning secular economist. Otherthan the ill-fated attempts by Keynesian Christian economist DouglasVickers to refute my approach to the Bible and to economics,64 noother Christian economist has challenged me exegetically on the issuesI have been raising. No one has addressed the foundationalepistemological questions that I raised as long ago as 1976.65 Noellcomes close to admitting as much: “Outside of the Reconstructionistliterature, one searches in vain for more than a handful of thoughtful,Biblically-based critiques of non-Christian economic methodology.”66

Christian critics have made it clear that they do not like my approachto economics, but not one of them has offered a systematic, integratedmethodological alternative that he is willing to defend exegetically.The critics face the old problem of practical politics: they cannot beatsomething with nothing.

In this commentary, I have shown how the twin Mosaic principlesof land and seed – ultimately, laws of inheritance – were limited bothby time and geography. From the beginning, there were boundariesplaced by God around all those laws that were judicial applications of

Page 459: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

1398

the Abrahamic and Mosaic laws governing land and seed. There werealso priestly laws that perished with the New Covenant, taking partsof Leviticus with them.

Let me cite once again my comments in Chapter 17, “The Preser-vation of the Seed.”

* * * * * * * *

It is therefore mandatory on me or on another defender of theon-omy’s hermeneutic to do what Poythress says must be done: (1)identify the primary function of an Old Covenant law; (2) discoverwhether it is universal in a redemptive (healing) sense or whether (3)it is conditioned by its redemptive-historical context (i.e., annulled bythe New Covenant). In short: What did the law mean, how did it applyin ancient Israel, and how should it apply today? This task is notalways easy, but it is mandatory.

The question Poythress raises is the hermeneutical problem ofidentifying covenantal continuity and covenantal discontinuity. First,in questions of covenantal continuity, we need to ask: What is theunderlying ethical principle? God does not change ethically. The morallaw is still binding, but its application may not be. Second, this raisesthe question of covenantal discontinuity. What has changed as a resultof the New Testament era’s fulfillment of Old Covenant prophecy andthe inauguration of the New Covenant? A continuity – prophetic-judicial fulfillment – has in some cases produced a judicialdiscontinuity: the annulment of a case law’s application. A very goodexample of this is Leviticus 19:19.

I begin any investigation of any suspected judicial discontinuitywith the following questions. First, is the case law related to thepriesthood, which has changed (Heb. 7:11–12)? Second, is it relatedto the sacraments, which have changed? Third, is it related to the

Page 460: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

67. There are several other hermeneutical questions that we can ask that relate tocovenantal discontinuity. Sixth, is it an aspect of the weakness of the Israelites, whichChrist’s ministry has overcome, thereby intensifying the rigors of an Old Covenant law(Matt. 5:21–48)? Seventh, is it an aspect of the Old Covenant’s cursed six day-one daywork week rather than the one day-six day pattern of the New Covenant’s now-redeemedweek (Heb. 4:1–11)? Eighth, is it part of legal order of the once ritually polluted earth,which has now been cleansed by Christ (Acts 10; I Cor. 8)?

1399

jubilee land laws (e.g., inheritance), which Christ fulfilled (Luke4:18–21)? Fourth, is it related to the tribes (e.g., the seed laws), whichChrist fulfilled in His office as Shiloh, the promised seed? Fifth, is itrelated to the “middle wall of partition” between Jew and gentile,which Jesus Christ’s gospel has broken down (Gal. 3:28; Eph.2:14–20)? These five principles prove fruitful in analyzing Leviticus19:19.67

Let us ask another question: Is a change in the priesthood alsoaccompanied by a change in the laws governing the family covenant?Jesus tightened the laws of divorce (Matt. 5:31–32). The church hasdenied the legality of polygamy. Did other changes in the familyaccompany this change in the priesthood? Specifically, have changesin inheritance taken place? Have these changes resulted in theannulment of the jubilee land laws of the Mosaic economy? Finally,has an annulment of the jubilee land laws annulled the laws of tribaladministration?

* * * * * * * *

I hope the reader recognizes by now that there are principles ofinterpretation that are applicable to the laws of the Mosaic Covenant.The ultimate hermeneutic principle in the question of the continuityof the Old Covenant legal order in the New Covenant era is the prin-ciple of the boundary. Such a boundary does exist. There is discon-tinuity. But other boundary principles allow us to determine whether

Page 461: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Conclusion

1400

a law has been resurrected with Jesus Christ in the New Covenant.Those case laws that have been resurrected with Christ and adoptedinto the New Covenant law-order provide Christians with their toolsof dominion.

Page 462: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1. The Greek word for “sacrilege,” hierarsuleo, means “to rob a temple.” Walter Bauer,A Greek-English Lexicon of the New Testament and Other Early Christian Literature,trans. William F. Arndt and F. Wilbur Gingrich (University of Chicago Press, 1957), p.374. New Testament examples: “Thou that sayest a man should not commit adultery, dostthou commit adultery? thou that abhorrest idols, dost thou commit sacrilege?” (Rom. 2:22).“For ye have brought hither these men, which are neither robbers of churches, nor yetblasphemers of your goddess” (Acts 19:37).

1401

Appendix A

SACRILEGE AND SANCTIONS

So Joshua sent messengers, and they ran unto the tent; and, behold,it was hid in his tent, and the silver under it. And they took them outof the midst of the tent, and brought them unto Joshua, and unto allthe children of Israel, and laid them out before the LORD. AndJoshua, and all Israel with him, took Achan the son of Zerah, and thesilver, and the garment, and the wedge of gold, and his sons, and hisdaughters, and his oxen, and his asses, and his sheep, and his tent,and all that he had: and they brought them unto the valley of Achor.And Joshua said, Why hast thou troubled us? the LORD shall troublethee this day. And all Israel stoned him with stones, and burned themwith fire, after they had stoned them with stones. And they raisedover him a great heap of stones unto this day. So the LORD turnedfrom the fierceness of his anger. Wherefore the name of that placewas called, The valley of Achor, unto this day (Josh. 7:22–26).

Achan appropriated forbidden objects in Jericho. These objects hadbeen previously set aside by God for His temple. “But all the silver,and gold, and vessels of brass and iron, are consecrated unto theLORD: they shall come into the treasury of the LORD” (Josh. 6:19).This holy (set-aside) property is what Achan had appropriated. Hiswas therefore an act of sacrilege. Sacrilege is a profane act, but aspecific form of profanity: theft from a temple or a holy place.1 Jerichowas to be offered as the firstfruits sacrifice to God on God’s fiery

Page 463: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix A

2. James B. Jordan, Judges: God’s War Against Humanism (Tyler, Texas: Geneva Minis-tries, 1985), p. 93.

1402

altar. The entire city was to be burned. Its confiscated treasures wereto be set aside for God’s temple.

Because of Achan’s act of sacrilege, God killed 36 Israelites in thefirst battle of Ai (Josh. 7:5). They were not responsible for his act ofsacrilege, but God nonetheless imposed capital sanctions on them.This event was later used by Joshua in his strategy to take the city ofAi: “For they will come out after us till we have drawn them from thecity; for they will say, They flee before us, as at the first: therefore wewill flee before them” (Josh. 8:6). Nevertheless, the 36 dead men weredead because of a sin committed by a man in secret, a man who wasnot a representative civil ruler in Israel. Judicially, why did God killthem? Because of Achan’s representative position as a priest (Greek:hieros) of God in the national hierarchy (Greek: hierarch = highpriest).

Achan’s Priestly Role in a Holy War

In his capacity as a warrior-priest, Achan had committed sacrilege.Jordan is correct: “All of Israel were [sic] a nation of priests, and it isthe priests who prosecute holy war. God Himself had established aparallel between the war camp and the Tabernacle, both holy places.. . .”2 As a member of God’s holy army, Achan had been ordered tobring burning judgment against Jericho. His was not simply a run-of-the-mill capital crime of a father in his role as father; it was the sin ofa man who had personally appropriated forbidden objects that were tobe set apart for God, i.e., holy objects. His disobedience was a priestlyact. The nation burned the remains of Achan and his family. God’s

Page 464: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Sacrilege and Sanctions

3. Prostitution was not specified as a capital crime in Israel, except when committed bya priest’s daughter. “And the daughter of any priest, if she profane herself by playing thewhore, she profaneth her father: she shall be burnt with fire” (Lev. 21:9). This indicatesthat a connection to the priesthood placed special restrictions on individuals, and violationsbrought a unique sanction: execution by fire.

4. Wrote Sir Henry Spelman in the seventeenth century: “Thus it appeareth that Sacrilegewas the first sin, the master-sin, and the common sin at the beginning of the world, commit-ted in earth by man in corruption, committed in paradise by man in perfection, committedin heaven itself by the angels in glory; . . .” Spelman, The History and Fate of Sacrilege(1698); Eades edition (London: John Hodges, 1888), p. 1; cited by R. J. Rushdoony, Lawand Society, vol. 2 of Institutes of Biblical Law (Vallecito, California: Ross House, 1982),p. 33.

5. A fiery sword was placed by God at the entrance of the garden to keep out thesacrilegious priest and his heirs (Gen. 3:24). Achan’s remains were burned (Josh. 7:25).

1403

direct sanction against false worship by a priest was fire (Lev. 10:2);it was also His punishment for a non-priest who offered incenseillegally (Num. 16:35).3

The crime of sacrilege in the Old Covenant era carried with it abiblically unique degree of covenantal responsibility. The sanctionsimposed by God and by the State against this crime seem to haveextended to all those who were under the criminal’s legal jurisdiction.This analysis in turn suggests that Adam’s primary crime was alsosacrilege.4 He had eaten a prohibited communion meal by approp-riating fruit that had been explicitly set aside by God. Sacrilege wasthe original crime that brought all of humanity under God’s negativesanctions. Adam’s sons and daughters have received a death sentencebecause of the sins of their father. This sanction appears to be aunique judicial aspect of sacrilege in Adam’s case and Achan’s.5

The penalty imposed by Joshua and the court was the publicexecution of Achan, his family, and his entire inheritance. Even thestolen goods had become polluted through sacrilege, and thereforehad to be burned with fire, along with the corpses (Josh. 7:25). Godinstructed the people of Israel to do with Achan what they had been

Page 465: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix A

1404

instructed to do with Jericho. Worse; not even the silver and goldwere to be salvaged for the tabernacle. The fire would be all-encom-passing.

Fathers and Sons

There is no doubt that God sanctioned the execution of Achan andhis household, for He immediately withdrew His anger and Hisnegative sanctions (v. 26). Yet the targets of this public executionwere Achan’s family members. The crucial question is: Did theypartake in their father’s sin? If not, was this execution in violation ofDeuteronomy 24:16? That text announces: “The fathers shall not beput to death for the children, neither shall the children be put to deathfor the fathers: every man shall be put to death for his own sin.” Whywere the sons and daughters executed for the sin of the father? Thetext in Joshua does not say that they knew of the crime, although theymay have. It does speak of the burning of his tent. This indicates thatthe goods had been buried inside his tent. Those inside may haveknown what was going on. It is not stated specifically that some of thechildren were too young to know, nor does it state that some were oldenough to be in their own tents. The point is, inside the judicialboundary of Achan’s tent, everything had been polluted. The tentrepresented the judicial boundary of Achan’s authority as a householdpriest. Everything inside that boundary had become profane as a resultof his unauthorized and self-conscious trespass of holy objects.Everything inside was fit for destruction.

Surely the animals did not know. Why were even the animals underhis administration executed? What had these animals done to deservestoning? They had done nothing more than the animals had done inAdam’s representative Fall, yet they, too, had suffered the

Page 466: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Sacrilege and Sanctions

1405

consequences, as have their descendants. A cursed form of deathentered the animal kingdom as a judgment from God. The subordin-ates suffered as a result of their master’s act of defiance.

Because the text of Joshua 7 is not specific regarding the knowl-edge of Achan’s sons and daughters regarding their father’s act ofsacrilege, we cannot be sure that they did not know and understandwhat their father was doing. The fact that the family’s animals werestoned does indicate that a comprehensive ban – hormah – had beenplaced by God on his whole household, irrespective of their knowl-edge or consent. If Deuteronomy 24:16 is accepted as a universallybinding standard for Israel’s civil government, then we must concludethat they both knew and understood. If they did not know and under-stand, then we must conclude that Deuteronomy 24:16 did not applyin cases of sacrilege. The text of Joshua 7 does not definitively proveone interpretation over the other, but the execution of the animalsdoes suggest that sacrilege was a unique crime and therefore outsidethe judicial boundary of Deuteronomy 24:16 regarding innocent sonsand guilty fathers.

Holy War

The issue at stake was the conquest’s judicial character as auniquely holy war. God had directed the Israelites to destroy all thefamilies inside the boundaries of Canaan. “And when the LORD thyGod shall deliver them before thee; thou shalt smite them, and utterlydestroy them; thou shalt make no covenant with them, nor shewmercy unto them” (Deut. 7:2; cf. 7:16). They were not allowed toshow mercy, except to Rahab and her family, because she had cov-enanted with Israel before the holy army entered the land. Once thearmy had crossed over the boundary of the land, no other mercy was

Page 467: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix A

1406

to be extended to the inhabitants within that boundary. The normalrules of holy warfare did not apply. Israel was not allowed to offerterms of surrender to any Canaanite city, unlike wars outside the land(Deut. 20:10–11).

By stealing holy objects in Jericho – goods that God had approp-riated for Himself – Achan had not only stolen from God; he had alsounited himself and his family covenantally with Jericho. By stealingpart of God’s required first-fruits offering, Achan became a citizen ofJericho. He also became profane: the violator of a sacred boundaryplaced by God around the city of Jericho. He was therefore requiredto suffer the judgment of every citizen in Jericho: death. Achan’s cov-enantal citizenship extended down to his children and his property:the animals and the stolen goods. Just as Rahab had become a citizenof Israel by hiding the spies and placing the red string publicly in herwindow, so did Achan become a citizen of Jericho by hiding the ban-ned goods. Just as Rahab’s family had survived because of her cov-enant, so did Achan’s family perish because of his covenant. Achanand his family became Canaanites, and therefore the entire family cameunder the covenantal ban: hormah.

Aaron and His Sons

Aaron built the golden calf and thereby brought sin on the people(Ex. 32). All of the people had initiated his representative priestly sin,so three thousand of them suffered the deadly consequences as repre-sentatives of the nation (Ex. 32:28). By serving as executionersagainst them, the Levites removed from their tribe the curse of Jacob(Gen. 49:7), becoming the priestly, holy, set-aside, first-born tribe(Num. 1:47–53).

In contrast to their father, Aaron, Nadab and Abihu initiated their

Page 468: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Sacrilege and Sanctions

6. “Near-sacrilegious” may be too weak a designation. The event has the marks ofsacrilege, if I am correct in my thesis that numbering the people was a priestly act.

1407

own sins. God brought direct sanctions against them: “And Nadab andAbihu, the sons of Aaron, took either of them his censer, and put firetherein, and put incense thereon, and offered strange fire before theLORD, which he commanded them not. And there went out fire fromthe LORD, and devoured them, and they died before the LORD. ThenMoses said unto Aaron, This is it that the LORD spake, saying, I willbe sanctified in them that come nigh me, and before all the people Iwill be glorified. And Aaron held his peace” (Lev. 10:1–3). ThenMoses warned their father and their priestly successors not to displayany sign of grief, lest the people be subjected to God’s wrath. Thepeople were to bewail God’s sanctions against the two priests.

And Moses called Mishael and Elzaphan, the sons of Uzziel the uncleof Aaron, and said unto them, Come near, carry your brethren frombefore the sanctuary out of the camp. So they went near, and carriedthem in their coats out of the camp; as Moses had said. And Mosessaid unto Aaron, and unto Eleazar and unto Ithamar, his sons,Uncover not your heads, neither rend your clothes; lest ye die, and lestwrath come upon all the people: but let your brethren, the wholehouse of Israel, bewail the burning which the LORD hath kindled.And ye shall not go out from the door of the tabernacle of thecongregation, lest ye die: for the anointing oil of the LORD is uponyou. And they did according to the word of Moses (Lev. 10:4– 7).

David’s Numbering of Israel

Another example of a near-sacrilegious6 crime in which there wasa representative legal relationship was David’s numbering of the

Page 469: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix A

7. The intermediary agent between God and David was Satan: “And Satan stood upagainst Israel, and provoked David to number Israel” (I Chron. 21:1). Satan boreresponsibility for this action, as did David, but the Bible clearly says that God moved Davidto do it. Those who seek to assert a philosophical contradiction between God’s will andDavid’s actions need to listen to Paul’s warning against such a misuse of moral philosophy:“Thou wilt say then unto me, Why doth he yet find fault? For who hath resisted his will?Nay but, O man, who art thou that repliest against God? Shall the thing formed say to himthat formed it, Why hast thou made me thus? Hath not the potter power over the clay, ofthe same lump to make one vessel unto honour, and another unto dishonour?” (Rom.9:19–21).

1408

people. This census-taking was allowed by God only when the nationwas being set aside for holy war to bring God’s capital sanctionagainst His enemies (Num. 1:3). Thus, David could act legally only inhis capacity as senior military priest. He misused his civil authority asking to number the people, despite Joab’s strong warning (II Sam.24:3).

The people were at fault for numerous crimes, but not David’sparticular crime, which was only possible for Israel’s senior militaryleader to commit: high military priest of the holy army. But becausethere was no imminent holy war, David’s act was an act of theft:treating God’s holy army as if it were the king’s army. David’s priestlyact of sacrilege would bring all those under his jurisdiction under thethreat of God’s wrath. The text says that God wanted to punish Israel,and David was God’s means to that end. “And again the anger of theLORD was kindled against Israel, and he moved David against themto say, Go, number Israel and Judah” (II Sam. 24:1).7 The use of themetaphorical verb kindled points to His holy ban against them. It wasnevertheless David’s personal sin that he numbered them, for he wasnot preparing for holy war.

He soon recognized that he had sinned. “And David’s heart smotehim after that he had numbered the people. And David said unto theLORD, I have sinned greatly in that I have done: and now, I beseechthee, O LORD, take away the iniquity of thy servant; for I have done

Page 470: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Sacrilege and Sanctions

1409

very foolishly” (II Sam. 24:10). He asked God for forgiveness, andGod offered him the choice of one negative sanction among three.David told God that He should decide. That was what God had beenwaiting for and aiming toward: “So the LORD sent a pestilence uponIsrael from the morning even to the time appointed: and there died ofthe people from Dan even to Beer-sheba seventy thousand men” (IISam. 24:15). Only men died in this plague. Clearly, it was a judicialplague, not biological – analogous to the death of all the firstborn ofEgypt, who also were not contagious. Public health measures wouldnot have reduced the death rate.

The Bible does not say that all 70,000 men deserved the negativesanction of death. Some surely did; some probably didn’t. Men live insocieties, and as members of covenant-bound collectives, they becomesubject both to God’s negative sanctions and His positive sanctions.Jeremiah and Ezekiel went out in the Babylonian captivity, yet bothhad remained faithful to God. Individuals cannot always escape thenegative sanctions associated with corporate responsibility simply bytheir own righteous behavior. Good men can suffer in unrighteoussocieties, while bad men can prosper in righteous societies (Ps. 72).In any case, they did not deserve death for the crime of sacrilege; ifanyone did, David did, yet he was not punished directly. He waspunished representatively: through the decimation of his army. Hiskingdom was reduced by 70,000 men. Like the stolen goods inAchan’s tent that could never be used in the temple, so were these70,000 potential holy warriors. David had sought confirmation of hispower as king through the census. God reduced the nation’s power by70,000 potential holy warriors. They had become sacriligious. Theysuffered the consequences.

Page 471: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix A

1410

Jeroboam and the Priesthood

Consider Jeroboam’s revolt against Rehoboam. The revolt itselfwas not illegal. The subsequent problem for the Northern Kingdomwas that Jeroboam committed sacrilege after the secession, and thepeople consented. He appointed new priests to administer the sacri-fices. He appointed the dregs of society to these offices. “After thisthing Jeroboam returned not from his evil way, but made again of thelowest of the people priests of the high places: whosoever would, heconsecrated him, and he became one of the priests of the high places.And this thing became sin unto the house of Jeroboam, even to cut itoff, and to destroy it from off the face of the earth” (I Ki. 13:33–34).Once again, we see that sacrilege leads to the disinheritance of theoffender’s sons, even though they had not committed the originalcrime. Why was his decision an act of sacrilege? What had Jeroboamstolen from the temple? Jeroboam had stolen the actual rites of thetemple; he had stolen God’s lawful worship. He had violated themonopoly of worship that God had established for the entire nation,not just the Southern Kingdom.

He had also stolen God’s holy army of priests. Jeroboam removedGod’s holy army from the highways of the nation. No longer wouldthe holy army of Israel march three times a year to Jerusalem. Thepeople implicitly consented to Jeroboam’s sacrilegious decision: theycould have walked to Jerusalem to offer their sacrifices, but mostchose not to. They preferred Jeroboam’s local golden calves (II Ki.10:29). What the people saved in travel expenses and trouble,however, they more than lost when God brought negative sanctionsagainst them. Meanwhile, the lawful priesthood departed from Israel:

And the priests and the Levites that were in all Israel resorted to himout of all their coasts. For the Levites left their suburbs and their pos-

Page 472: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Sacrilege and Sanctions

1411

session, and came to Judah and Jerusalem: for Jeroboam and his sonshad cast them off from executing the priest’s office unto the LORD:And he ordained him priests for the high places, and for the devils, andfor the calves which he had made. And after them out of all the tribesof Israel such as set their hearts to seek the LORD God of Israel cameto Jerusalem, to sacrifice unto the LORD God of their fathers. So theystrengthened the kingdom of Judah, and made Rehoboam the son ofSolomon strong, three years: for three years they walked in the way ofDavid and Solomon (II Chron. 11:13–17).

Jeroboam brought negative sanctions against the lawful priests;God therefore brought negative sanctions against the Northern King-dom. The northern tribes of Israel accepted the representation of poli-tically appointed, profane priests, who in turn committed sacrilegedaily. The Northern Kingdom of Israel did not recover from thesepriestly acts of sacrilege. It was burdened by kings who were far morecorrupt and tyrannical than Judah’s kings, and it went into captivityunder a vicious nation, Assyria, over a century before Judah fell to themore tolerant Babylonians. Israel’s land was inhabited from then onby the Samaritans: foreigners who were brought into the land by theAssyrians to replace the captive Hebrews.

For the children of Israel walked in all the sins of Jeroboam which hedid; they departed not from them; Until the LORD removed Israel outof his sight, as he had said by all his servants the prophets. So wasIsrael carried away out of their own land to Assyria unto this day. Andthe king of Assyria brought men from Babylon, and from Cuthah, andfrom Ava, and from Hamath, and from Sepharvaim, and placed themin the cities of Samaria instead of the children of Israel: and theypossessed Samaria, and dwelt in the cities thereof (II Ki. 17: 22–24).

The people were at risk in the rebellion of their king, for the kingplaced them under the rule of a new priesthood. By consenting to the

Page 473: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix A

1412

decision of Jeroboam, the people became sacrilegious. It was theircontinuing consent to sacrilege rather than Jeroboam’s initial act ofsacrilege that eventually brought God’s permanent sanction of captiv-ity upon the Northern Kingdom.

New Testament Biblical Theology:The High Priest

The primary sin in history is sacrilege. The penalty for sacrilege isfire; so is the final negative sanction (Rev. 20:14–15). The repres-entative nature of sacrilege is the primary message of the gospel: fromthe first Adam to the second Adam, the curse of death was revealedin all men. The resurrection of Jesus Christ, the second Adam, re-vealed that He has representatively atoned for that original sin, whichhad brought all of mankind under the curse. Paul wrote: “Thereforeas by the offence of one judgment came upon all men to condem-nation; even so by the righteousness of one the free gift came upon allmen unto justification of life. For as by one man’s disobedience manywere made sinners, so by the obedience of one shall many be maderighteous” (Rom. 5:18–19).

The New Testament does not speak of the atoning work of JesusChrist in His capacity as king, but rather in His capacity as high priest.“But Christ being come an high priest of good things to come, by agreater and more perfect tabernacle, not made with hands, that is tosay, not of this building; Neither by the blood of goats and calves, butby his own blood he entered in once into the holy place, havingobtained eternal redemption for us” (Heb. 9:11–12). It was in Hisrepresentative office as high priest, not as king, that Jesus Christestablished the link between Himself and the covenant people, thesaints of God: those people who have come under God’s eternal posi-

Page 474: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Sacrilege and Sanctions

8. Keith Thomas, Religion and the Decline of Magic (New York: Charles Scribner’sSons, 1971), p. 97.

9. Ibid., p. 99.

1413

tive sanctions because Jesus Christ came under God the Father’s nega-tive sanctions.

Sacrilege in English History

Until the advent of the modern worldview, it was a common beliefamong Christians that sacrilege is always visited by God’s negativesanctions. An old English proverb appeared in several versions: “Evil-gotten goods lightly come and lightly go.” “Ill-gotten goods will notlast three crops.” “Ill-gotten goods would not last to the third heir.”8

It is therefore appropriate to refer at this point to the work of SirHenry Spelman.

Spelman wrote a popular book against laymen who impropriatedtithes, which are owed exclusively to the institutional church: De nontemerandis ecclessis (1613). It went through four editions. It empha-sized divine judgments against the sacrilegious. In 1632, he began astudy of the families that bought or inherited the church and monasticproperties that had been confiscated by Henry VIII in 1546. Helimited his research to ex-monastic estates within a 12-mile radius ofRougham in Norfolk.9 This study was published posthumously in1698: The History and Fate of Sacrilege. Webb and Neale in the mid-nineteenth century carried forward this suggestive research. Theyfound that of 630 families that inherited these lands, only 14 familiesstill survived, and that 600 had clearly come under special judgment.They asserted that there was a statistically significant factor in the

Page 475: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix A

10. Rushdoony, Law and Society, ch. 7. Rushdoony’s strong endorsement of Spelman’sthesis on sacrilege and its sanctions is curious, given Rushdoony’s firm commitment to theview that tithes do not belong to the institutional church, and that the layman can lawfullygive it to any kind of Christian charity. Rushdoony, “To Whom Do We Tithe,” in Rush-doony and Edward A. Powell, Tithing and Dominion (Vallecito, California: Ross House,1979), ch. 7. See Appendix B: “Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique.”

11. Degge, Observations upon the possessors of monastery-lands in Staffordshire.

12. Thomas, Religion, p. 99.

13. Ibid., p. 100.

14. Ibid., p. 101.

15. Ibid., p. 103.

1414

disasters that befell the 600.10 A similar though shorter study waswritten by Sir Simon Degge in 1699.11 Thomas remarks that “Degge’sconclusions were, like Spelman’s, regarded as too dangerous to bepublished at the time, and only appeared in print in 1717.”12

Nevertheless, throughout the seventeenth century, similar warningshad been offered by Catholic controversialists and many leadingAnglican scholars, including John Whitgift, Francis Godwin, LancelotAndrewes, Jeremy Taylor, Joseph Mede, Isaac Basire, and RobertSouth.13 There were also political leaders who warned their childrenagainst purchasing church lands: William Cecil (Lord Burleigh),Edward Hyde (Lord Chatham), and Thomas Wentworth (Earl ofStrafford).14 Others, including John Milton, denied any such a punish-ment for those who bought and sold “monkish lands.”15

John Winthrop and Oliver Cromwell

Two families that had profited from the confiscations and which stillsurvived in Spelman’s day were the families of Oliver Cromwell,

Page 476: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Sacrilege and Sanctions

16. Edmund S. Morgan, The Puritan Dilemma: The Story of John Winthrop (Boston:Little, Brown, 1958), p. 1.

17. Christopher Hill, God’s Englishman: Oliver Cromwell and the English Revolution(New York: Harper Torchbooks, [1970] 1972), p. 37.

18. Antonia Fraser, Cromwell: The Lord Protector (New York: Knopf, 1974), p. 13.

1415

Puritan England’s Lord Protector, and his contemporary John Win-throp, the first governor of the Puritans’ Massachusetts Bay Colony.Ironically, Winthrop’s ancestor, who had purchased from King Henryin 1544 the land of the monastery at Bury St. Edmunds, was namedAdam Winthrop – appropriate, if his crime was indeed sacrilege.16 Richard Williams, Oliver Cromwell’s ancestor, took the nameCromwell from his uncle, Thomas Cromwell, “hammer of the monks”and the architect of the English Reformation. Richard had acted asCromwell’s agent in the suppression of the monasteries, and hisreward was great: three abbeys, two priories, and the nunnery ofHinchinbrooke, which alone was worth some ^2,500 per year, animmense fortune. The fortunes on both sides of young Oliver’s familyhad been founded on the spoliation of the church.17 But the extra-vagances of Sir Oliver Cromwell, young Oliver’s uncle, who lived foralmost a century, led to the dissolution of much of the main family’sfortune, and Hinchinbrooke was sold in 1627, the year before youngOliver’s first election to Parliament.18 In any case, Oliver’s side of thefamily had not owned Hinchinbrooke, but it did own smaller, lessproductive former church lands.

Doctoral dissertations are seldom useful to anyone, let alone usefulto the kingdom of God, but a series of detailed dissertations on thefate of the families that bought these monastic lands, compared to thefate of families that did not, would be eminently useful. It would be avery difficult task, however, given the carnage and disruptions of thePuritan Revolution, 1642–59, and its aftermath in 1660, the

Page 477: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix A

19. Chapter 4.

1416

restoration of Charles II.

Conclusion

We have considered the crime of sacrilege at some length. Thereis no question that it invoked God’s direct sanctions, which immed-iately extended to those under the authority of the priestly trans-gressor: from Adam to his heirs, from Achan to his heirs, and fromDavid to 70,000 Israelites. Achan’s case indicates that the civil magis-trate was required to impose the capital sanction against the trans-gressor’s whole household, including animals. That there were OldCovenant corporate sanctions applied by God in history in responseto a representative agent’s sin is an inescapable conclusion, at least inthe case of sacrilege.

If unintentional sins by the priests brought the assembly underGod’s negative sanctions,19 then how much greater was the corporatethreat of sacrilege? Sacrilege is far worse. This leads us to a politicalconclusion that breaks definitively with the Enlightenment: if God everprovides the historical circumstances in which His saints become thefounders of a new civil society or the inheritors of an old one, theymust maintain the sanctioning authority which God has publiclyentrusted to them. They must guard against acts of sacrilege in boththe ordained priesthood and the public at large. Sacrilege is not merelysin in general or an improper profession of faith; it is a specific kind ofsin: stealing God’s property. Those who believe that God will sit backindefinitely while the modern State or modern witches commitatrocities against the property of the church of Jesus Christ do not

Page 478: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Sacrilege and Sanctions

20. The Soviet Union persecuted the church. Robert Conquest (ed.), Religion in theU.S.S.R. (New York: Praeger, 1968); Gerhard Simon, Church, State and Opposition in theU.S.S.R. (London: C. Hurst, [1970] 1974). In 1991, the Soviet Union collapsed overnight:August 19–21.

21. In the twentieth century – perhaps throughout modern times – the events in the SovietUnion of August 19–21, 1991, best illustrate this principle of replacement. Theastoundingly inept attempted coup by the old guard Soviet leaders failed in a nearlybloodless series of events. The experiment in atheism, 1917–1991, had failed.

1417

understand Leviticus 4: God’s judgment will come in history.20 TheState is still required by God to defend the church against sacrilege.The State is not neutral.

As in the Old Covenant era, the moral integrity of the people, nottheir rulers, is judicially primary. The priests and civil rulers willeventually reflect the moral condition of the people, for priests andcivil rulers are the people’s ordained representatives. Those citizenswho remain covenantally faithful to God by obeying His law throughHis grace (Eph. 2:8–10) will find that their enemies are eventuallybrought under God’s negative sanctions. The covenant-breaker, if heis consistent, is eventually driven to commit sacrilege. At the banquetsof covenant-breakers, the holy treasures of the temple will be used ascommon plates: profanity. When this happens, the handwriting is onthe wall for the rulers and the social order they represent. They will bereplaced (Dan. 5).21

Because the function of civil government is to apply negative tem-poral sanctions against convicted transgressors in order to protect theentire society from God’s negative temporal sanctions, the sacrilegelaws are still in force in the New Covenant era. This means that thedeath penalty must still be imposed on people who commit sacrilege.On the other hand, the hormah of the Mosaic Covenant – a priestlyact of total destruction within the boundaries of geographical Israel –was required by God only during the original conquest of Canaan. Itdid not apply after Israel’s return from the exile, when strangers living

Page 479: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix A

1418

in the land were to be protected by the jubilee land laws (Ezek.47:21–23).

Sons and daughters can escape the fate of their father by declaringthemselves no longer his sons. The New Testament emphasizes God’sgracious adoption as more powerful in history than Adam’s sacrilegeand subsequent disinheritance. The sins of the sacrilegious parent donot extend to the children in the New Covenant era if the childrenbreak publicly with their father when they learn of his sacrilege.Furthermore, there is no evidence that this was not also the case in theOld Covenant. But what of a child too young to have understoodwhat his father had done, or one who did not discover the crime untilafter his father’s conviction? To escape execution, he would have tohave been adopted by another family. All those who remained withinthe family of the sacrilegious agent had to suffer the same penalty.This is still the way of escape for the sons of Adam: adoption by afamily whose head is untainted by the crime of sacrilege. There is onlyone such family: the family of God, redeemed by the Second Adam,Jesus Christ.

Page 480: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

1419

Appendix B

RUSHDOONY ON THE TITHE: A CRITIQUE

And, behold, I have given the children of Levi all the tenth in Israelfor an inheritance, for their service which they serve, even the serviceof the tabernacle of the congregation. Neither must the children ofIsrael henceforth come nigh the tabernacle of the congregation, lestthey bear sin, and die (Num. 18:21–22).

The text is clear: the Levites as a tribe were entitled to the entiretithe. That is, they had a legal claim on it: “all the tenth in Israel for aninheritance.” This inheritance was as secure legally in God’s eyes asthe landed inheritance of the other tribes. Of course, it was far lesssecure operationally; the men of Israel did not always pay their tithes.Those who refused to pay their tithes to the Levites were guilty ofrobbing God. As surely as it was theft to steal title to another man’sland, so was it theft to withhold any part of the tithe from the Levites.The first form of theft was active; the second form was passive; butboth were theft. “Will a man rob God? Yet ye have robbed me. But yesay, Wherein have we robbed thee? In tithes and offerings. Ye arecursed with a curse: for ye have robbed me, even this whole nation”(Mal. 3:8–9).

The context is equally clear regarding the legal basis of this entitle-ment: the Levites’ service as guardians of the tabernacle/temple’ssacramental boundary. They were required to stand at this sacramentalboundary and restrain (probably execute) anyone who trespassed it

Page 481: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

1. On the debate within modern Jewish scholarship on the Levites as executioners –Jacob Milgrom vs. Menahem Haran – see James B. Jordan, “The Death Penalty in theMosaic Law,” Biblical Horizons Occasional Paper No. 3 (Jan. 1989), Pt. 3. Milgromargues that the Levites were armed guards; Haran denies this. Jordan agrees with Milgrom.

2. Gary North, Sanctions and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Numbers (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1997), ch. 10.

3. For a detailed study of the sacramental basis of the tithe, plus additional informationon the background of Rushdoony’s theology of the tithe, see Gary North, Tithing and theChurch (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1994).

4. Ray R. Sutton, That You May Prosper: Dominion By Covenant, 2nd ed. (Tyler, Texas:Institute for Christian Economics, [1987] 1992), chaps. 10, 11.

1420

(Num. 18:1–22).1 The Levites’ entitlement and the Levites’ task asboundary executioners were explicitly linked by the Mosaic law.2

There can be no doubt: the Levites were entitled to the whole tithe.I ask again: On what legal basis? The text answers: their service in thetemple. But which form of service: Sacramental or social? I answer:sacramental. Rushdoony’s answer: social. On this seemingly minorissue, the Christian Reconstruction movement divided in 1981. It willremain divided until one side or the other gives up its view of thejudicial basis of the tithe, or until one of them disappears. Contrary tothose people who blame all institutional divisions on personalityconflicts – even God vs. Satan, I suppose – the dividing issue here isecclesiology: the doctrine of the church, and has been since 1981.3

Church and Tithe

The theology of the tithe is not a minor issue; it is central to biblicalecclesiology. It is also important for a proper understanding of thecovenant – specifically, the church covenant.4 The tithe is an aspect ofjudicial authority in the church, i.e., point two of the biblical covenant

Page 482: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

5. Similarly, the office of civil magistrate, called “minister” by Paul in Romans 13:4, isalso based on point four: sanctions, in this case, negative sanctions. He punishes evil-doers(v. 4).

6. North, Tithing and the Church, ch. 10.

1421

model, hierarchy-representation, which Sutton argues in Chapter 2.This representation is both substitutionary (“Who or what in historydies in my place?”) and judicial (“Who in history declares me judiciallyacceptable before God?”).

The proper performance of this representative ecclesiastical officedoes mandate certain social services – charity, for example – but thecovenantal-judicial basis of the eldership is not social; it is sacramental(point four of the biblical covenant model: oath-sanctions).5 A man isnot a minister of the gospel just because he calls himself one orbecause he is charitable. He is a minister only because he has beenordained by a lawful church. Ordained ministers guard the sacramentsagainst profane acts: boundary violations. That is, they control lawfulaccess to the sacraments. They include some people and excludeothers. The following four aspects of a church are judicially linked: theformal ordination of ministers by other ministers (i.e., no self-ordination or ordination exclusively by laymen), hierarchical authority(an appeals court system), ministerial control over legal access to thesacraments, and the local institutional church’s exclusive authority tocollect and distribute all of its members’ tithes in God’s name. Todeny any one of these aspects of the church is to call into question allfour. So it was under the Mosaic Covenant; so it is under Christ’sNew Covenant. Rushdoony has implicitly denied the first two pointsby defending ecclesiastical independency, and he has emphaticallydenied the other two. He is consistent (or at least he was until 1992).6

His theological critics had better be sure their theological positions areequally consistent.

Page 483: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

7. My last year as editor of The Journal of Christian Reconstruction was in 1981.

8. Jordan’s master’s thesis had been accepted by Westminster Theological Seminary(Philadelphia). The offending passage – on the circumcision of Gershom by Zipporah –appears on pages 85–86. An expansion of this observation was later published by Jordanin his book, The Law of the Covenant: An Exposition of Exodus 21–23 (Tyler, Texas:Institute for Christian Economics, 1984), Appendix F, “Proleptic Passover.” Rushdoonyinitially demanded that I defend my observation in greater detail, which I did. He then saidmy defense was insufficient. He then fired me as editor of The Journal of Christian Recon-struction. I later published a larger version of this defense: “The Marriage Supper of theLamb,” Christianity and Civilization, No. 4 (1985). No other critic has ever written toJordan to challenge his essay as heretical. I have never received a single letter from anyoneother than Rushdoony, pro or con, regarding my essay. The whole incident was officiallybased on a trifle. In this appendix, I deal with what I regard as the unstated dividing point:Rushdoony’s view of the institutional church.

9. R. J. Rushdoony, The Institutes of Biblical Law (Nutley, New Jersey: Craig Press,1973), pp. 427–29. On the close connection between Rushdoony’s comments and my own,see North, “Marriage Supper,” p. 218.

1422

The Doctrine of the Church in Christian Reconstruction

The major dividing issue within Christian Reconstruction has beenthe doctrine of the institutional church. Officially, the movement splitin 19817 over Rushdoony’s outrage regarding a minor theologicalpoint in an essay I submitted as my monthly column in the ChalcedonReport. I had relied on a passage in James Jordan’s 1980 master’sthesis.8 Rushdoony had made a very similar observation in the Insti-tutes, which he probably had forgotten making.9 I find it difficult tobelieve that this blow-up on Rushdoony’s part was based merely ona brief section in Jordan’s master’s thesis. Jordan had sent him a copyof it over a year before the blow-up; he had remained silent about it.I believe that the real offense was our view of the institutional church,which we had begun to promote vigorously through the fledgling

Page 484: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

10. There is a subordinate question: the third-year tithe and the poor tithe. Were theseseparate, additional tithes? Rushdoony argues that they were. Rushdoony, Institutes, p. 53.

1423

Geneva Divinity School. There was an irreconcilable division over thecorrect answer to this question: What is the fundamental institutionin the long-term process we call Christian reconstruction? Rush-doony has repeatedly answered: “the family,” along with its subor-dinate agency, the Christian school. The “Tyler wing” of the ChristianReconstruction movement answered: “the church.” There is no wayto reconcile these views.

If this dispute were simply over the percentage of men’s incomeowed to God, it would not be a major dividing issue in our day. Thereis nothing unique about Christians today who dismiss as “legalism”any suggestion that they owe 10 percent of their net income to God.But Rushdoony, as the co-founder of Christian Reconstruction, couldhardly take this antinomian approach to the question of the tithe. TheBible is clear about the tithe’s mandatory percentage: men owe 10percent of their net income to God.10 The argument is not over thetithe’s percentage; the argument is over which agency (if any) pos-sesses the God-given authority to collect it and then distribute it. Thedebate within Christian Reconstruction is over this question: Whereis the locus of God’s delegated sovereignty over the allocation oftithe: In the tither or the institutional church? I answer: with the insti-tutional church. Rushdoony answered: with the tither.

Church and Tithe

From 1965 until the publication of his two-volume SystematicTheology in 1994, Rushdoony sporadically attempted to cobbletogether his doctrine of the institutional church in order to support his

Page 485: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

11. He never commented on I Corinthians 8: “Howbeit there is not in every man thatknowledge: for some with conscience of the idol unto this hour eat it as a thing offered untoan idol; and their conscience being weak is defiled. But meat commendeth us not to God:for neither, if we eat, are we the better; neither, if we eat not, are we the worse” (vv. 7–8).

12. James B. Jordan (ed.), “The Reconstruction of the Church,” Christianity and Civ-ilization, No. 4 (1985). This is posted on www.freebooks.com.

1424

view of the tithe. His view of the tithe is that Christians can lawfullysend the tithe anywhere they wish; therefore, the institutional churchhas no lawful claim to any portion of the tithe, or at least not abovethe tenth of a tenth that went to the Aaronic priesthood under theMosaic law. He needed a doctrine of the church in order to defendsuch a thesis theologically. In this appendix, I examine the connectionsbetween his view of the tithe and his view of the institutional church.

This has not been an easy task. Rushdoony never wrote a book onthe doctrine of the church, for reasons that will become clear as youread this appendix. (This refusal to go into print was even more trueof his defense of the continuing authority of the Mosaic dietary laws:not so much as one full page of exegesis devoted to the topic, despiteits great importance for him personally as a distinguishing mark of histheology.)11 There is no issue of Chalcedon’s Journal of ChristianReconstruction devoted to the doctrine of the church. I assure thereader, this was not my decision as the editor of the first fifteen issues,1974–1981. In Tyler, I participated in a symposium on “theReconstruction of the Church” in 1985, which my monetary offeringabove my required tithe financed.12 Rushdoony forbade me to publishany issue of the journal devoted exclusively to the church. This wasthe only rule that he ever set forth for my editing.

Church and Family

Page 486: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

13. R. J. Rushdoony, “The Nature of the Church,” Calvinism Today, I (Oct. 1991), p. 3.This journal is published in England: P. O. Box 1, Whitby, North Yorkshire YO21 1HP.

14. I would call any social theory emanationist which traces the origin of church, State,or family to one of the other institutions. Christian social theory must be Trinitarian,insisting on the covenantal uniqueness of each of the three institutional covenants.

1425

Late in his career, Rushdoony attempted to trace the institutionalchurch back to the family – not just chronologically but covenantally.This theory of ecclesiastical origins is the heart and soul of this, hismost important theological error. He writes: “The father of the churchwas Abraham, with whom God made a covenant (Gen. 15), andthrough whom the covenant sign, circumcision, was instituted (Gen.17). The covenant with Israel in Exodus 20 is a continuation of thesame covenant, a covenant of grace and law. The church thus beganas a family, and the structure of both the covenant nation and congre-gation retained this same character.”13 The church began as a family,Rushdoony said; hence, the family in both his theology and his socialtheory is the central institution: the master covenantal model. Rush-doony’s social theory is familiocentric. He regarded the institutionalchurch as an extension of the family.14 In his view, the great war forthe minds of men is the war between family and State. The Bibleteaches otherwise.

Rushdoony failed to recognize that the priesthood did not originatewith Abraham. It originated with Melchizedek. Abraham paid his titheto Melchizedek (Gen. 14:20), and he received bread and wine fromhim (Gen. 14:18). Christ’s high priestly office was grounded inMelchizedek’s primary priesthood, not Levi’s secondary and judiciallysubordinate priesthood (Heb. 7:9–10). Here is the fatal flaw in Rush-doony’s familiocentric argument: Melchizedek had no parents (Heb.7:3). I take this literally: Melchizedek was therefore a theophany. Atthe very least, he had no genealogy; his authority was not derived inany way in the family. Melchizedek is the refutation of Rushdoony’s

Page 487: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

1426

ecclesiology and his familiocentric social theory.

The Biblical Position: Ecclesiocentrism

I disagreed with Rushdoony on the centrality of the family inChristian society. The fundamental institution in history is not thefamily; it is the church, which extends beyond the final resurrection asthe Bride of Christ (Rev. 21). The family does not: there is no mar-riage in the resurrection (Matt. 22:30). Jesus made it plain: the falseideal of the sovereign family is a far greater threat to Christianity thanthe false ideal of the sovereign State. Jesus never spoke this harshlyregarding the State:

Think not that I am come to send peace on earth: I came not to sendpeace, but a sword. For I am come to set a man at variance against hisfather, and the daughter against her mother, and the daughter in lawagainst her mother in law. And a man’s foes shall be they of his ownhousehold. He that loveth father or mother more than me is not worthyof me: and he that loveth son or daughter more than me is not worthyof me (Matt. 10:34–37).

The family is temporary, limited to history: no marriage in the res-urrection. “For in the resurrection they neither marry, nor are given inmarriage, but are as the angels of God in heaven” (Matt. 22:30). TheState is temporary, also limited to history: no suppression of evil(Rom. 13:4) in the post-resurrection, sin-free world. But the churchis eternal. The church is therefore the central human institution. Thefamily and the State are legitimate covenantal institutions in history,but they do not possess the most important authority given by God toany institution: the power to excommunicate. Why is this the mostimportant sanction? Because it alone is binding in eternity. Breakingthe family bond by death or divorce is not binding in eternity; physical

Page 488: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

1427

death through execution is not binding in eternity. In contrast, lawfulexcommunication is binding in eternity. Christian social theory mustaffirm without compromise or qualification that the true sacramentsof baptism and the Lord’s Supper are more important in history thanthe democratic State’s imitation sacrament of voting or the family’simitation sacrament of sexual bonding.

Rushdoony understood the relationship between church authorityand excommunication, so in order to defend his sociology of familism,he denied that the church possesses the authority to excommunicate,as we shall see. He thereby denied the existence of the keys of thekingdom – the judicial authority of the institutional church in history(Matt. 16:19). He did this in the name of Christian orthodoxy, as weshall see.

The Conservatives’ Position: Familiocentrism

Why do social and political conservatives traditionally identify thefamily as the central institution of society? There are two primaryreasons. First, because they reject the liberals’ assertion that the cent-ral social institution is the State. In this they are correct. Such a viewis necessary but not sufficient for accurate social theory. Second,because conservatives adopt natural law theory. We must examineboth assumptions: one incomplete and the other incorrect.

Anti-Statism

Conservatives regard the family as the only institution with suffi-cient authority and respect to challenge the State successfully on along-term basis. One of the strongest statements to this effect was

Page 489: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

15. Chesterton, “The Story of the Family,” in The Superstition of Divorce (1920); TheCollected Works of G. K. Chesterton, vol. 4 (San Francisco: Ignatius Press, 1987), p. 256.His reference to eternity betrays his confused social theology: neither the human family northe state is eternal; the church is (Rev. 21, 22).

1428

written by G. K. Chesterton. The family, he wrote, “is the only checkon the state that is bound to renew itself as eternally as the state, andmore naturally than the state.”15 They view the social function of theinstitutional church as an adjunct to the family, just as liberals see thechurch as an adjunct to the State. Conservatives rarely view the insti-tutional church as a covenantally separate institution possessingsuperior authority to both family and State. This is a serious error.

The authority to excommunicate is the greatest judicial authorityexercised in history. The lawful negative sanctions of the rod (family)and the sword (State) are minor compared to the sanction of excom-munication (Matt. 16:19). But because formal excommunication doesnot impose bodily pain in history, modern man dismisses the church’sauthority in both history and eternity. This includes modern conserva-tism. It also includes most Protestant churches, who refuse to honoreach other’s excommunications. They thereby deny Jesus’ words:“And fear not them which kill the body, but are not able to kill thesoul: but rather fear him which is able to destroy both soul and bodyin hell” (Matt. 10:28). The only agency in history that lawfullyannounces a person’s condemnation to hell – short of repentancebefore physical death – is the institutional church. This authority isimplicitly recognized by the modern Western State. A condemnedcriminal on his final walk to the place of execution cannot legally beaccompanied by his spouse or his political representative; he can beaccompanied by a minister.

The battle between patriarchalism and statism in the West has beengoing at least since the rise of the Greek city-state, an outgrowth of

Page 490: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

16. Fustel de Coulanges, The Ancient City: A Study on the Religion, Laws, andInstitutions of Greece and Rome (Garden City, New York: Doubleday Anchor, [1864]1955).

17. C. Gregg Singer, The Unholy Alliance (New Rochelle, New York: Arlington House,1975). This book is a detailed history of the Federal Council of Churches and its successor,the National Council of Churches.

1429

clans and family sacrifices.16 The problem is, the family always losesthis battle as a covenant-breaking society advances over time becausethe family does not have the power possessed by the State: themonopoly of life-threatening violence. Step by step, the State replacesthe family in the thinking of most members of covenant-breakingsociety. The State possesses greater power; in the power religion ofhumanism, this justifies the expansion of the State.

The family fights a losing defensive battle when it fights alone. Itsauthority is steadily eroded by the State. For example, the divorce raterises when the State replaces the family’s functions, especially itswelfare functions. Therefore, if the familiocentric view of the churchwere true – the church as an adjunct to the family – the church wouldinevitably lose alongside of the family. This view of the church iswidely held today. Result: those people inside various church hierar-chies who seek power have increasingly allied themselves and theirchurches with the State.17

Natural Law Theory

An implicit natural law theory undergirds conservatism’s socialanalysis: belief in the existence of moral absolutes that are discover-able by universal logical principles. This faith in moral-logical uni-versals undermines the judicial authority of the church. The Trinitarianchurch is not universal in human history; the State and family are.

Page 491: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

18. Gary North, Political Polytheism: The Myth of Pluralism (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, 1989), Part 3.

19. George Washington and Abraham Lincoln spoke of religion and morality as greatbenefits for society. Neither of them was willing to profess personal faith in the work ofJesus Christ as the sole pathway to eternal life. Religion in their view is instrumental ratherthan foundational. See Paul F. Boller, George Washington & Religion (Dallas: SouthernMethodist University Press, 1963). Washington refused to take the Lord’s Supper: self-excommunication. Lincoln avoided commenting publicly on his religion except in the 1846Congressional campaign, when he issued a handbill admitting that he was not a churchmember, but assured voters that they should not vote for a man who scoffs at religion.“Handbill Replying to Charges of Infidelity,” The Collected Works of Abraham Lincoln,edited by Roy P. Basler, 8 vols. (New Brunswick, New Jersey: Rutgers University Press,1953), I, p. 382. See also his “National Fast Day Proclamation” (Aug. 12, 1861), where hespoke of “the Supreme Government of God.” Ibid., VI, p. 482.

1430

“Religion” and “the sacred” are undeniably universal in history; thechurch is not. Because the family and the State appear to be the un-iversal institutions, and because the church exists only where Chris-tianity has made inroads, conservatives conclude that the war forliberty can be won only if the family is strengthened against the State.The church is regarded by conservatives as a useful ally in the family’sbattle against the State. The church serves as social cement; this ispreferred to political cement. Whenever the church claims more thanthis subordinate role for itself, American conservatives become leery.This is why the primary authors of the U.S. Constitution – right-wingEnlightenment humanists18 – were willing to mouth words of praisefor “religion,” but never for Jesus Christ as the incarnate SecondPerson of the Trinity, nor for His church.19 Religion in general iselevated; the church in particular is demoted.

This view of the church implicitly places world history abovechurch history because the institutional church has been narrower inits influence than mankind up to this time. The most widely acceptedopinions and logic of “mankind in general” – the covenantal sons ofAdam – are assumed by natural law theorists to be the legitimate

Page 492: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

20. Gary North, Dominion and Common Grace: The Biblical Basis of Progress (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1987), ch. 6.

1431

moral and judicial standards for all societies. This implicit and some-times explicit humanism of natural law theory is contrary to theBible’s revelation of God’s work in history through His covenantpeople. Covenant-breakers are adjuncts to covenant-keepers in his-tory, just as the lake of fire (Rev. 20:10) will be an adjunct to the cul-mination of the New Heaven and New Earth (Rev. 21:1) in eternity.Covenant-keepers rather than covenant-breakers are the focus ofhistory. Israel was central to the ancient world, not the great empires.The exodus is central to human history, not the fall of Troy. The angelof death is central to human history, not the Trojan Horse. The Pen-tateuch is central to human history, not The Iliad, The Odyssey, andThe Aeneid. Moses is central to human history, not Plato and Aris-totle. Special grace is central to history, not common grace.20 Naturallaw theory, whatever its specific ethical content may be – on thiscrucial point, natural law theorists disagree – is the outworking ofcommon grace. Bible-revealed law, not natural law, is central tohistory. Looking back from eternity, all men will recognize this. Menare required by God to evaluate history in terms of what He hasrevealed about eternity, not evaluate eternity in terms of what menassume about history. Humanism denies this. So does natural lawtheory.

Rushdoony’s Ecclesiology

We come now to Rushdoony’s doctrine of the church. He subord-inated it to the doctrine of the family. In doing so, he adopted familio-centrism, though not natural law theory. This abandonment of theon-

Page 493: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

21. For a good example, see Rushdoony’s editorial, “Copycat Churchianity,” ChalcedonReport (June 1992).

1432

omy in favor of traditional conservatism undermined the covenantalfoundation of his theology. His view of church and family was ananomaly in his original theology – an error no larger than a man’shand. Like Elijah’s cloud, it grew into a mud-producing storm after1981.

Rushdoony systematically avoided developing a doctrine of theinstitutional church. He offers one chapter in the Institutes (XIV) andone in Systematic Theology (XII), but both are incomplete. Neitheraddresses in detail the judicial issues of the ordination of ministers andpublic excommunication by ordained church officers. This is especiallyabsent in Systematic Theology, completed in 1984 but not publisheduntil mid-1994. He had broken not only with the WestminsterConfession of Faith (which he officially had to affirm until he resignedfrom the ministry of the Orthodox Presbyterian Church in 1970) andthe 39 Articles of Episcopalianism (which he officially affirmed after1973), but with all of Trinitarian orthodoxy from the Council of Niceaforward.

Critics of the church’s lawful, God-ordained claim on every indiv-idual’s lifetime commitment again and again seek to elevate “Chris-tianity” and dismiss “the church,” as if there could somehow be Chris-tianity without the church and its mandated sacraments. One sign ofa person’s move away from historic Christianity’s doctrine of thechurch to conservative humanism is his adoption of the pejorativeword, Churchianity.21 The person who dismisses “churchianity” isoften a defender of his personal ecclesiastical autonomy: a sovereignindividual who judges the churches of this world and finds them allsadly lacking. In his own eyes, all the churches fall short of his almostpure and nearly undefiled standards. No church announces God’s

Page 494: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

22. The Chalcedon Report (Jan. 1992) published an article by Rushdoony, “The Life ofthe Church: I Timothy 5:1–2.” That essay was introduced as follows: “Note: The Life of theChurch was a communion sermon at the Chalcedon Chapel evening service, October 27,1991.”

1433

authoritative word to him; rather, he announces God’s authoritativeword to the churches. No church officer represents him before God;instead, he represents himself. Like the foolish defense lawyer whohires himself as his own advocate in a court of law, so is the man whois contemptuous of “churchianity.” He confidently excommunicates allchurches for failing to meet his standards. All congregations havefailed to measure up, except (should he deign to begin one) his own.He ignores the obvious: a self-excommunicated person is no lessexcommunicated.

Rushdoony’s views on the institutional church became adjuncts tohis theory of the tithe. Prior to his assertion in 1991 of the ChalcedonFoundation’s status as a church (initially, he called it a chapel)22 aswell as a governmentally chartered educational organization, his viewson the tithe were fully consistent with his views regarding the visiblechurch. They constituted a single, consistent, and monumental error.This error, if applied retroactively to the conclusions of Volume 1 ofThe Institutes of Biblical Law, would destroy the covenantal basis ofRushdoony’s theology and therefore also his social theory.

The fact is, his three-fold error came late in his career. This shift intheology began shortly before he left the Orthodox PresbyterianChurch in 1970, but it was not completed until the early 1980’s. Inother words, what Volume 1 of The Institutes hath given, Volume 2need not take away. Only small traces of his error are visible in Vol-ume 1; this error can and must be separated from that foundationalbook. Because of this, I find it necessary to challenge the book that he

Page 495: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

23. Edward A. Powell and Rousas John Rushdoony, Tithing and Dominion (Vallecito,California: Ross House, 1979).

24. Gary North, The Dominion Covenant: Genesis, 2nd ed. (Tyler, Texas: Institute forChristian Economics, [1982] 1987), ch. 3.

25. There are parent-child economic requirements, but these are intra-familyrelationships.

26. This would include those fictitious legal individuals known as corporations. One wayto solve the problem of tithing on retained earnings would be for 10 percent of the commonshares of all new corporations to be assigned to a specific church from the beginning. Thechurch would automatically participate in all dividends and capital gains.

1434

and Edward Powell co-authored, Tithing and Dominion (1979).23 Thechapters are identified as to which author wrote which. I refer hereonly to Rushdoony’s chapters. (Rushdoony broke decisively withPowell shortly after he broke with me and Jordan.)

Tithing and Dominion

With respect to dominion the Bible teaches, first, that the dominioncovenant was established between God and the family. God hasassigned to the family the primary dominion task in history (thoughnot in eternity): to be fruitful and multiply (Gen. 1:26–28) – a biolo-gical function.24 Second, as we shall see, the tithe is a mandatory pay-ment from man to God through a covenantal institution: the church.Therefore, if the tithe were the basis of dominion, God’s law wouldmandate a tithe to the family, the agency of dominion. But there is noGod-specified mandatory payment to the family, i.e., no legal entit-lement. On the contrary, it is the productivity of individuals, families,and other voluntary associations that is the source of both tithes andtaxes. This is inevitable: the source of the funding cannot be entitledto funding.25 The individual26 or family is the source of the funding.

Page 496: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

27. When I served as a Board member of the Chalcedon Foundation in 1975, Rushdoonywas directing his own tithe into Chalcedon, as he told me. I was a paid staff member at thetime. He did not ask me to follow his lead, nor did I volunteer to do so. I have no reasonto believe that he subsequently re-directed his tithe to a local church, since he did notbelong to a local church.

28. North, Tithing and the Church, ch. 10.

29. R. J. Rushdoony, Systematic Theology, 2 vols. (Vallecito, California: Ross House,1994).

1435

The tithe is therefore owed to the institutional church by the individualor the family.

Rushdoony defended the tithe as the foundational basis of biblicaldominion. He also described the church as an unproductive organi-zation, as we shall see. Conclusion: if the tithe is foundational todominion, and if the church is unproductive, then it is the tithe ratherthan the church which is the source of Christianity’s cultural produc-tivity. In terms of such a perspective, the institutional church’simportance in the dominion process is secondary to the tithe’s impor-tance. This is exactly what Rushdoony began saying publicly after1973.27

It is not clear to me whether his doctrine of the church and hisdoctrine of the tithe originally stemmed from his decision to redirecthis own tithe money into the Chalcedon Foundation and to removehimself from the authority of any local church, or whether his shift intheology came first. These events surely paralleled each other chron-ologically.28 He did not bother to articulate his views until the late1970’s. By 1991, however, it was clear that his published doctrine ofthe church was an extension of his published doctrine of the tithe. Heconstantly wrote about the tithe. Until his 1991 essay in CalvinismToday, he steadfastly refused to write clearly about the institutionalchurch.

In June, 1994, his two-volume Systematic Theology appeared.29

Page 497: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

30. United States. citizens living outside the country must pay income taxes on theirsalaries. As of 2006, the first $80,000 is exempt.

1436

The manuscript had been completed in 1984. Chapter 12, “The Doc-trine of the Church,” was more radical and confrontational againstCalvin’s doctrine of the church than had been Chapter 14, “TheChurch,” in Institutes of Biblical Law. But what came later, in theearly 1990’s, was more radical and confrontational than SystematicTheology.

Sometime in the late 1960’s, Rushdoony warned me of not dealingearly with a heresy in one’s career. He used the example of a Calvinistpublisher and amateur economist, Frederick Nymeyer, who paid fortranslations of the works of the Austrian economist, Eugen vonBöhm Bawerk. From 1953 to 1960, he published a low-circulationmagazine, originally called Progressive Calvinism, but later calledFirst Principles In Morality and Economics. It was an attempt topresent the economics of Böhm-Bawerk as being consistent withChristianity. There was a lot of good material in this magazine, but itwas far more Austrian than Christian. Then, in 1967, he wrote andpublished a book called No Civil War in the Cave. Rushdoony regard-ed it as Pelagian. He told me, “If a man does not deal with a heresyearly in his career, it will dominate his thinking as he grows older.”

Church and Sanctions

In contrast to the family, both State and church are lawfully entitledto economic support from those who are under their respectivecovenantal authorities. The State’s jurisdiction is territorial (e.g., overnon-covenanted resident aliens) and judicial (e.g., over its covenantedcitizens who live outside the State’s territory30). The church’s jurisdic-

Page 498: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

31. R. J. Rushdoony, “The Tax Revolt Against God,” Position Paper 94, ChalcedonReport (Feb. 1988), pp. 16–17.

32. Ibid., p. 16.

1437

tion is equally judicial, though not (in Protestant societies) territorial.Both institutions have lawful covenantal claims before God over asmall portion of the net productivity of all those who live voluntarilyunder their jurisdiction. Their God-given authority to impose negativesanctions against those who refuse to pay is the outward mark of theircovenantal sovereignty. To deny the right of either church or State tobring such sanctions is a denial of their God-delegated covenantalsovereignty.

Rushdoony understood this with respect to the State; he thereforeopposed the tax revolt or “patriot” movement.31 But he denied thatany payment is automatically owed to the institutional church. Nochurch can lawfully compel its members to pay it their complete titheor even any portion thereof, he insisted. “It is significant, too, thatGod’s law makes no provision for the enforcement of the tithe byman. Neither church nor state have [sic] the power to require the titheof us, nor to tell us where it should be allocated, i.e., whether toChristian Schools or colleges, educational foundations, missions,charities, or anything else. The tithe is to the Lord.”32 He then citedMalachi 3:8–12. With respect to the tithe, Rushdoony believed in thedivine right of the individual with respect to the institutional church:no earthly appeal beyond conscience. This was not an error of logicon his part; it was a consistent application of his ecclesiology.

The existence of a mandatory payment to the church is evidence ofa covenantal relationship: a legal bond established by a self-male-

Page 499: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

33. Sutton, That You May Prosper, pp. 83–91. Rushdoony refused to discuss the self-maledictory oath as the judicial basis of all four biblical covenants: personal, church, State,and family. He defined the covenant as God-given law rather than as oath-invoked God-given law. This unique judicial oath formally invokes God’s sanctions. Without this formalinvocation, there is no redeeming covenant bond possible. There is only the general,Adamic covenant bond: a broken covenant. Rushdoony’s definition does not acknowledgethis fact. He wrote: “In the Biblical record, covenants are laws given by God to man as anact of grace.” Rushdoony, “Covenant vs. Contract,” Chalcedon Report (June 1993), p. 20.If correct, this definition would make the covenants universal, since biblical laws governeverything in history, as he argued for years. But if he were to discuss the sanctions-invoking oath as basis of the four covenants, he would have to discuss oath-breaking in thechurch and its formal sanctions: the doctrine of excommunication. He would also have todiscuss in detail Article VI, Section III of the U.S. Constitution, which prohibits religioustest oaths for Federal (national) office. This is why the U.S. Constitution is an atheistic,humanistic document – a fact which Rushdoony refused to accept for over three decades.See North, Political Polytheism, Appendix B: “Rushdoony on the Constitution.”

34. This obligation does not apply to gifts from husbands to wives and vice versa; nordoes it apply to intra-family gifts to minors. Parents who feed their children need not setaside a tithe on the food so consumed. The obligation is covenantal, and the institutionalpayment of the tithe by the head of the household serves as a representative payment forall of its members.

35. At worst, a pastor who is convicted of adultery is suspended for a year or two. I knowof at least one case where an admitted adulterer was asked by his presbytery only totransfer to another presbytery. The members’ idea of negative sanctions was limited to “Notwith our wives, you don’t!” He voluntarily left the ministry. I bought part of his library.

1438

dictory oath 33 which each church member takes either explicitly orrepresentatively (by parents). The church has a lawful claim on a titheof every member’s net increase in income.34 Unlike the State, whichis ruthless in collecting taxes owed, the church rarely enforces its law-ful claim. This is not surprising: the modern church rarely enforcesanything under its lawful jurisdiction.35 The State has arrogated powerto itself in the face of the churches’ defection. In our day, most Christ-ians regard this as normal and even normative. They prefer to think ofthe church as judicially impotent. They prefer to think of the State’sphysical sanctions as the greatest possible sanctions. They refuse toregard formal excommunication as threatening them or anyone else

Page 500: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

36. Rushdoony, Law and Society, Vol. 2 of Institutes of Biblical Law (Vallecito, Cal-ifornia: Ross House, 1982), p. 129.

1439

with eternal consequences. Like the humanists, they prefer to fear menrather than God. They stand in front of the local church and in effectchant the child’s challenge: “Sticks and stones can break my bones,but names [‘excommunicant’] can never hurt me!”

Neither the State nor the church is a profit-seeking organization.This is why both possess lawful claims on a small part of the netproductivity of their members. Therefore, they cannot be primaryagencies of dominion in history. They are secondary agencies of dom-inion. This is why the Great Commission of Matthew 28:18–20 is notstrictly an extension of the dominion mandate of Genesis 1:26–28. Asmall portion of the fruits of dominion are brought to the institutionalchurch. The church is not the source of these fruits. The institutionalchurch, through its authority to declare someone as an adopted son ofGod, brings covenant-breakers formally into the eternal household ofGod, but the institutional church is not itself a family. It possessesgreater authority than the family. Thus, the tithe cannot be a primaryaspect of dominion. It is a secondary aspect.

Productivity

This is not to say that church and State are not economically prod-uctive. They are the source of God’s authorized covenantal sanctions:the negative sanctions of the sword (State) and the positive andnegative sanctions of the keys of the kingdom (church). Rushdoony’slanguage is seriously misleading when he writes that “church and stateare not productive agencies.”36 This is the language of secularlibertarianism, not Christianity. Nevertheless, he made an important

Page 501: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

37. Idem.

38. Gary North, Cooperation and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Romans, el-ectronic edition (West Fork, Arkansas: Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 2002), ch.11.

39. Rushdoony, Law and Society, p. 128.

1440

point: “The state is a protective agency whose function is to maintaina just order, to insure restitution for civil wrongs, and to protect thepeople from external and internal enemies. . . . The church’s functionis protection and nurture by means of its ordained ministry.”37 Whatis the biblical meaning of “protection”? Civil protection means thedefense of boundaries – judicial rights against invasion, either byindividuals or by the State itself. Protection by the State is achieved byits enforcement of negative sanctions against evil-doers (Rom.13:1–7).38 Biblically speaking, the State provides no lawful positivesanctions, e.g., nurture. Protection by the church is also achievedthrough its imposition of negative sanctions (e.g., I Cor. 5). Nurtureby the church is the product of positive sanctions (e.g., II Cor. 8).

Rushdoony mistakenly contrasted these beneficial covenantalfunctions with what he calls “productivity.” His view of productivityis incorrect. These covenantal functions are basic to productivity, butthey cannot be financed unless those under their authority remainproductive. The income of both church and State must come from theoutside: from God through the individual and the corporate entitiesthat are under the respective jurisdictions of church and State.

Rushdoony discussed the non-productivity of the church in a chap-ter on the Lord’s Supper (Holy Communion). He made a catastrophictheological error by denying the sacramental basis of the church. “Theproblem in history has been the unhappy sacramentalization of churchand state.”39 He rightly castigated the idea of a sacramental State, butthen wrote: “Similarly, the church sees itself as the sacramental body

Page 502: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

40. Idem.

41. The nominalist acknowledges no judicial authority beneath the words that define thesacraments. Thus, the sacraments become a mere memorial. This was Zwingli’s view ofthe Lord’s Supper. It is also the Baptist view.

42. John Calvin, “Brief Instruction for Arming All the Good Faithful Against the Errorsof the Common Sect of the Anabaptists” (1544), in Treatises Against the Anabaptists andAgainst the Libertines, edited by Benjamin Wirt Farley (Grand Rapids, Michigan: Baker,1982), p. 65.

43. Calvin, Treatises, p. 65.

1441

and preempts Christ’s role. Communion is thought of as a church riterather than Christ’s ordinance.” This contrast implicitly assumes thatHoly Communion is not a church rite, i.e., not a biblically mandatoryritual: a false theological assumption if there ever was one. Hereduced communion to a “feast of charity” or a “love feast.”40 Henever acknowledged the sacrament of the Lord’s Supper as a divinelyempowered covenant-renewal ceremony of the institutional church,a ceremony that invokes God’s positive and negative sanctions inhistory and eternity.

The institutional church has only one ultimate means of discipline:excommunication, i.e., excluding a person from the rite of the Lord’sSupper. Without the positive sanction aspect of the Lord’s Supper,the negative sanction of exclusion is judicially meaningless. Those whohold a nominalist view41 of the Lord’s Supper strip the institutionalchurch of its disciplinary authority. Calvin wrote that “it is certainly ahighly reprehensible vice for a church not to correct sins. Besides, Isay our Lord will punish an entire people for this single fault. Andtherefore let no church, still not exercising the discipline of the ban,flatter itself by thinking that it is a small or light sin not to use the banwhen necessary.”42 He also wrote: “But this is not to say that anindividual is justified in withdrawing from the church whenever thingsare contrary to his will.”43 Calvin was not a defender of the

Page 503: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

44. Rushdoony, Systematic Theology, p. 732.

1442

individual’s autonomy in relation to the institutional church. He fullyunderstood what the sole basis of a declared Christian’s judicialseparation from the institutional church has to be: excommunication.

The Sacraments

The sacraments are means of bringing God’s sanctions in history onHis people: blessings and cursings. They are covenant signs. They areoath signs. Rushdoony insisted that the sacraments are family rites,not rites administered under the exclusive jurisdiction of the institu-tional church. He replaced the sacramental church with the sacra-mental family.

Baptism

Rushdoony saw baptism as a covenant sign, which it is. But affirm-ing covenant in general is not sufficient. A covenant sign must beadministered. Which institution has been granted this monopoly byGod: church, State, or family? For two almost thousand years, thechurch’s answer has been clear: the church. This opinion, Rushdoonysaid, is a sign of the hardening of the church’s arteries. “Baptism is acovenant fact. The church has converted it into an ecclesiastical fact.Circumcision in the Old Testament is a family rite, because the familyis the primary covenant institution; the family gives birth to and rearsthe child.”44 But physical birth is Adamic; Adam’s sons need adoption.

Was circumcision a family rite? No; it was an ecclesiastical, priestlyrite. The head of a household may have administered this rite as ahousehold priest in a nation of priests (Ex. 19:6). If so, was this done

Page 504: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

1443

in his judicial office of father or priest? The issue here is covenantalauthorization. The question of covenantal authority is easy to decide.Answer this question: Who possessed the sole authority to annul therite of circumcision by the excommunication of covenant-breakers?The answer is obvious: a Levitical priest, not the father. Covenant-breakers were to be cut off from the church and therefore fromcitizenship by excommunication.

How do we know that the father did not possess this authority?Because excommunication mandated family disinheritance. But a fa-ther had no authority to disinherit his son. “If a man have two wives,one beloved, and another hated, and they have born him children, boththe beloved and the hated; and if the firstborn son be hers that washated: Then it shall be, when he maketh his sons to inherit that whichhe hath, that he may not make the son of the beloved firstborn beforethe son of the hated, which is indeed the firstborn: But he shallacknowledge the son of the hated for the firstborn, by giving him adouble portion of all that he hath: for he is the beginning of hisstrength; the right of the firstborn is his” (Deut. 21:15–17). If he couldnot disinherit the hated wife’s son, surely he could not disinherit theloved wife’s son. Rushdoony commented on this passage several timesin Institutes of Biblical Law, but he failed to make the judicialconnection linking circumcision, excommunication, and disinheritance.All were exclusively priestly acts.

As a household priest, the father may have circumcised his sons.We are not told this specifically regarding the Mosaic era. Surely,without specific revelation, we should not draw revolutionary eccles-iastical conclusions from the mere possibility that the father circum-cised his son. But if he did, he did so a delegated agent of the Leviticalpriesthood. He did not retain the authority to excommunicate, i.e.,judicially revoke the covenant. This points to the two-fold judicialreality of circumcision. It was priestly in two senses: general and

Page 505: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

45. Rushdoony, Systematic Theology, p. 734.

46. Ibid., p. 735.

1444

special. First, the father representatively invoked the covenant oath inthe name of his son through the rite of circumcision. He had a lawfulrole as a father: a general Israelite priest (Ex. 19:6). Second, in invok-ing the covenant oath, he affirmed the law of the covenant. As ageneral priest, perhaps he could lawfully do this. But a special priestof the tribe of Levi, not the head of the household, would determinewhether the circumcised son met the stipulations of the covenant:confession of faith and outward obedience to God’s law. This identi-fies both sacraments as ecclesiastical.

Having defied the entire history of the church by proclaiming bap-tism as a family rite, Rushdoony then condescendingly announced:“Having said all this, let me add that much of the church’s teachingson baptism are [sic] very important. The error has been to limit itsimplications to the society of the church, and membership therein.”45

This was as persuasive as a statement from some dedicated socialist:“Having said all this, let me add that much of the Austrian Schooleconomists’ teachings on the free market are very important. Theirerror has been to ground their system on the idea of private property.”

The Lord’s Supper

Having announced the transfer of the authority to baptize from thechurch to the marital family, he immediately moved to a discussion ofthe Lord’s Supper. He began: “As we have seen, baptism is in to [sic;he means into] the covenant of our God.”46 This was never a matterof dispute. What is a matter of dispute is which covenantal agencypossesses the right to baptize. This is a dispute between Rushdoony

Page 506: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

47. Idem.

48. Rushdoony, Institutes, p. 46.

1445

and (in round numbers) all the theologians in the history of the church.He then moved to the Lord’s Supper: “Like baptism, the Lord’s Tableor communion is rooted in the Old Testament, in the Passover.”47 Heappealed to Jesus: “Our Lord’s institution of this rite came with thePassover celebration and with His interpretation of the meaning ofPassover as fulfilled in Himself.”

Let us pursue this assertion for a moment. The move from Passoverto the Lord’s Supper came in the upper room on the night beforeJesus’ crucifixion, as Rushdoony affirmed in Institutes of BiblicalLaw.48 Let me ask an obvious question: Where were the wives andchildren of the apostles? Peter had a mother-in-law (Matt. 8:14);presumably, he also had a wife. His wife was not in the upper room,nor was his mother-in-law, who dwelt in his household. Unless Rush-doony is ready to affirm the celibacy of the apostles, he faces a monu-mental problem: Passover was in no way a family rite in the sense ofa marital family. The Head of a new household of faith administeredthe rite that night. This household was confessional. Something radi-cal had taken place in the exterior form of Passover that night, but notjudicially. Jesus did not violate the Mosaic Passover.

Unless the Lord’s Table was a judicially radical break with Pass-over – which Rushdoony denied – then this change in outward formpoints to an inescapable conclusion: the judicial-covenantal agency offinal authority over the Passover was never the marital family. To theextent that the family administered certain aspects of this rite, it didso, as in the case of baptism, under authority delegated from thepriesthood.

The Lord’s Supper honors this judicial fact. The special priesthoodof the institutional church still possesses authority over the rite; the

Page 507: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

49. Rushdoony, Systematic Theology, p. 736.

50. Rushdoony, Institutes, p. 752.

1446

general priesthood is still subordinate. This was always the case judici-ally in Mosaic Israel; the Lord’s Supper makes this visible. Rushdoonyremained silent about the implications of this transformation ofoutward celebration. Had he ever discussed the change in celebration,he could not readily have come to this conclusion: “As we examinethe Lord’s Table or eucharist from the perspective of Scripture, wemust recognize that it is the Christian Passover. The Passover ofExodus is a family rite; it was oriented to admitting the smallest childable to speak and understand into the joy of salvation and the meaningof salvation (Ex. 12:21–27). It is no less a family celebration in theNew Testament; the family is now Christ’s family.”49 In the Institutes,he called this a family service.50

Judicially, this statement is correct, but it proves the opposite. TheLord’s Supper is no less a family celebration than Passover was underMosaic law because, judicially speaking, Passover never was a riteunder the authority of a marital family. It was always a rite of God’sadopted family: the institutional church. This is why all the families ofIsrael had to journey to a central location to celebrate Passover (Deut.16:6–7). Passover in Israel was never celebrated at home. It wascelebrated outside the geographical jurisdiction of a family’s tribebecause it was celebrated under another tribe’s authority. Thisauthority was national because it was Levitical: the tribe of Levi. Itwas therefore under the authority of the special priesthood. The 12non-priestly tribes could not claim any originating authority overPassover. This means that the general priesthood of Israel, i.e.,members of the 12 non-Levitical tribes, could not lawfully administerPassover apart from the presence of the special priesthood: the Lev-ites. Like King Jeroboam (I Ki. 12:25–33), Rushdoony ignored this.

Page 508: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

51. Rushdoony, Law and Society, p. 129.

52. On this question, Zwingli was an Anabaptist.

1447

Jeroboam, however, was not a familist.We return to the question of excommunication. No one who had

been excommunicated could lawfully attend Passover. The physicalmark of circumcision was judicially irrelevant; the officially declaredjudicial status of the excommunicate was the only relevant legal issue.Only the Levitical priesthood had the authority to excommunicate.Furthermore, the father or other household head did not have theauthority to invite an excommunicated son or daughter to celebratethe Passover. The excommunicate was considered covenantally dead.(Some Orthodox Jewish sects continue to this day to have public buri-als of those sons who have converted to a rival religion.)

Rushdoony’s view of the local church affected his doctrine of thesacraments. He neglected – and his exposition necessarily denies – thesacramental basis of the local church’s authority to collect the tithe.“As against an empty rite, Christian fellowship in Christ’s calling,around a table, is closer to the meaning of the sacrament.”51 But if thejudicial rite of the Lord’s Supper is not backed up (sanctioned by) thepromise of eternal sanctions, both positive and negative, then it is trulyan empty rite: judicially empty – the nominalist-fundamentalist-memorialist view of the sacraments: Anabaptism.52

Rushdoony’s post-1973 published view of the church is non-cov-enantal: the church as a fellowship without judicial sanctions ratherthan an institution possessing the judicial keys of the kingdom. Heeven insisted that a church has no lawful authority to discipline thosemembers who refuse to attend its worship services: “We are urged notto forsake ‘the assembling of ourselves together, as the manner ofsome is’ (Heb. 10:25), but the church is not given authority to punish

Page 509: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

53. Rushdoony, “The Nature of the Church,” Calvinism Today, I (Oct. 1991), p. 3.

1448

those who do.”53 Then who is? Only God, apparently. There is sup-posedly no appeal beyond the individual’s conscience: the “divineright” of a non-attending church member. Then what judicial authoritydoes the institutional church possess? In Rushdoony’s view, none.What meaning does church membership have? Less than membershipin a local social club, which at least requires the payment of dues formembership. In Rushdoony’s theology, a local flower arrangementsociety possesses more authority over its members than a local churchpossesses over its members.

Rushdoony’s view of church discipline represents a fundamentalbreak from the history of the church, including the theology of theProtestant reformers and especially Calvin. Rushdoony insisted (with-out any citations from the Bible) that a Christian has the God-givenauthority to remove himself indefinitely from a local congregation andcease taking the Lord’s Supper, but without ecclesiastical judicialconsequences. This necessarily implies that self-excommunication,which is a form of excommunication, is not an actionable offensewithin the church. This is a denial of Holy Communion, for it is adenial of excommunication.

From Calvinism to Autonomy

Calvin was clear about the keys of the kingdom in history. He citedMatthew 16:19: “And I will give unto thee the keys of the kingdomof heaven: and whatsoever thou shalt bind on earth shall be bound inheaven: and whatsoever thou shalt loose on earth shall be loosed inheaven.” He then commented that “the latter applies to the disciplineof excommunication which is entrusted to the church. But the church

Page 510: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

54. John Calvin, Institutes of the Christian Religion (1559), IV:XI:2. Edited by FordLewis Battles, 2 vols. (Philadelphia: Westminster Press, 1960), II, p. 1214.

55. Rushdoony, “Nature of the Church,” p. 3.

56. Ibid., p. 4.

1449

binds him whom it excommunicates – not that it casts him intoeverlasting ruin and despair, but because it condemns his life andmorals, and already warns him of his condemnation unless he shouldrepent. . . . Therefore, that no one may stubbornly despise the judg-ment of the church, or think it immaterial that he has been condemnedby the vote of the believers, the Lord testifies that such judgment bybelievers is nothing but the proclamation of his own sentence, and thatwhatever they have done on earth is ratified in heaven.”54 This is whythe sacrament is a monopoly, the church is sacramental, and the titheis owed to the church. Rushdoony denies all three conclusions.

Rushdoony had ceased being a Calvinist by the late 1970’s. Hebecame a predestinarian Congregationalist without a local congre-gation (until he announced his own in 1991), a man who holds a Bap-tist view of church hierarchy: “Another aspect of jurisdiction is this:every church, small or great, is Christ’s congregation, not man’s. Itsloyalty must be to God in Christ, and to His law-word, not to a den-omination nor a sister church.”55 Late in his career, Rushdoony beganto issue his Baptistic anathemas against all church hierarchies: “Thereis in this an implicit and sometimes unconscious heresy. Heresy is astrong word, but nothing less can describe the problem. This authori-tarian attempt to control other churches is revelatory of a lack of faithin the triune God and an unseemly faith in the power of man. Itassumes the virtual non-existence of the Holy Spirit.”56 Those whohold a hierarchical view of church government are members of a mod-ern Sanhedrin, he says. “We must separate ourselves from modern

Page 511: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

57. Ibid., p. 8.

1450

Sanhedrins.”57 This is a strange line of theological reasoning from someone who

retained the title of minister of the gospel only through his ordinationby a tiny Episcopalian denomination (total number of congregationsin the denomination: two, both of them located hundreds of milesaway from Rushdoony). During his years of ministry in this officiallyhierarchical denomination (“sanhedrin”?), he refused to attend anylocal church. He continued to avoid taking the Lord’s Supper. Heclearly abandoned Calvin’s doctrine of the church. This is why Cal-vinists who started out with him in the early 1970’s (or in my case, theearly 1960’s) have been excluded from his presence. Their view of thechurch is, in his eyes, anathema, and so are they. He did not tolerateopposition on this point.

Defining the Institutional Church

The church possesses the authority to include and exclude peoplefrom the sacraments: “binding” and “loosing.” The Bible teaches thatthe tithe is judicially grounded solely in the covenantal authority of thechurch, which in turn is grounded on its unique sacramental monop-oly. We see this connection between tithing and sacramentalism in thefirst biblical example of tithing: Abraham’s tithe to Melchizedek, thepriest of Salem, who gave Abraham bread and wine (Gen. 14:18). Itwas not Melchizedek’s office as king of Salem that entitled him toAbraham’s tithe; it was his priestly status, which authorized him todistribute the positive sanction of Holy Communion: bread and wine.Rushdoony discusses Melchizedek briefly, but only with respect to theauthority of the priesthood generally; he does not mention the tithe or

Page 512: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

58. Rushdoony, Law and Society, p. 368. He does not mention Melchizedek in Volume1 of the Institutes.

59. Ibid., p. 337.

60. Rushdoony, Systematic Theology, p. 777.

1451

Holy Communion.58

What is noticeable about Rushdoony’s avoidance of any clear def-inition of the church is that he long refused to define the institutionalchurch as the exclusive source of the sacrament of the Lord’s Supper.Instead, he focused on the church in the broadest sense, i.e., thekingdom of God. He wrote in Law and Society: “Second, the churchis the City or Kingdom of God. It is thus more than any church (as wecall it) or state can be. The boundaries of God’s church include every‘church,’ state, school, family, individual, institution, etc. which isunder Christ’s royal law and rule. But it includes far, far more.”59

Notice that he placed church in quotation marks when referring toinstitutional churches – organizations possessing the authority toexcommunicate. He did not do this with the following words: state,school, family, individual, institution. Do these quotation marks indi-cate an underlying contempt for local institutional churches?

What, then, of the lawful role of the institutional church? UntilSystematic Theology, he had avoided dealing with two crucial issues:a judicially binding ecclesiastical hierarchy and the uniquely sacra-mental nature of the church. The real issue is this: the church as anoath-bound, covenantal, hierarchical institution whose elders possessthe power to excommunicate those who rebel against church author-ity. Rushdoony carefully avoided a covenantal-judicial definition of thechurch, substituting a functional definition. “It should be apparent bynow that our concern is less with the church as an institution and morewith the church as the witness to and the evidence of the life and thework of the triune God in history.”60 In Law and Society, he wrote:

Page 513: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

61. Ibid., p. 337.

62. Ibid., p. 341.

63. Ibid., p. 343.

64. Ibid., p. 368.

1452

“Very clearly, the church in Scripture means the Kingdom of God, notmerely the worshipping institution or building. . . . It includes godlymen and their possessions, and the earth they subdue in the name ofthe Lord.”61 He then launched into a chapter titled, “ChurchImperialism.” It is a long attack on bishops and church hierarchy,which he insisted are pagan in origin: “ecclesiastical totalitarianism.”62

Familism

In Chapter 75, “Kingdom Courts,” he returned to his fundamentalsocial theme: familism. He had already equated the church with thekingdom of God. “In the Kingdom of God, the family is in history thebasic institution.”63 The unique, central social institution is not theinstitutional church, he insists; rather, it is the family. The familypossesses an authoritative court, he insisted – indeed, the authoritativecourt in history. In contrast, Rushdoony rarely discussed in Law andSociety the existence of authoritative church courts except in thecontext of family courts, which possess superior authority, he said,since the pattern of all government is based on the family. Jethro’shierarchical appeals court in Exodus 18 “utilized an already existingfamily office, the eldership. The elders are mentioned before Jethrospeaks, in Exodus 18:12. They were heads of families, clans, andtribes.”64 Notice that Rushdoony adopted the term elder, used in theNew Testament to designate an ecclesiastical office, to identify what

Page 514: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

65. Rushdoony, Institutes, p. 740.

66. Rushdoony, Systematic Theology, p. 369.

67. Ibid., p. 389.

68. Walter Bauer, A Greek-English Lexicon of the New Testament and Other EarlyChristian Literature, translated by William F. Arndt and F. Wilbur Gingrich, 4th ed.(University of Chicago Press, [1952] 1957), pp. 706–7.

69. Kittel, vol. VI, pp. 651–83.

1453

he insists was a “family office, the eldership.” This was a denial ofwhat he had written in the Institutes: “The elder, first, was what thename indicated, an order man in a position of authority. The elder wascomparative, so it could mean a man ruling over his household.”65

What it could mean, he said in 1973, it always means, he said in 1984.He went on: “Scripture gives us the basic ingredients for success: thegodly family, and the system of elders.”66 In his chapter, “TheTheology of the Family,” he wrote that “the family is a community,the central community. . . . The family is the Kingdom of God inminiature when it is a godly family. . . .”67 It is God’s civilization.

No Evidence Offered

To prove this, he offered no evidence. There is no verse in the NewTestament that refers to elder as the head of a family. Luke 15:25refers to an older son. Presbuteros usually refers to a church office.Bauer’s definitive lexicon offers no example of presbuteros as a headof family, either in the New Testament or Greek literature. The wordmeans what it means in English: older.68 This grammatical assessmentis supported by the long entry in Kittel’s Theological Dictionary ofthe New Testament.69 Rushdoony in 1984 rested his argument on anassertion for which there is no grammatical evidence.

Page 515: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

70. Rushdoony, Systematic Theology, p. 683.

71. Kittel, vol. II, pp. 88–89.

1454

He then compounded his error: “Another office, that of deacon, isthe name for a family servant.”70 Not according to Bauer or Kittel, itisn’t. It means simply servant. It usually refers in Greek literature tosomeone who waits on a table, just as its context indicates in Acts 6.The author in Kittel lists six general uses for the term in the NewTestament: waiter at a meal, servant of a master, servant of a spiritualpower, servant of Christ, servant of God, servant of the church. Heoffers no example of household servant.71 It is always dangerous tobase an important theological point on an appeal to grammar. It issometimes legitimate, but risky. When you do this, make sure there isas least some grammatical evidence.

Training in the Family

Why should the family be regarded as the “kingdom of God inminiature”? Why not the State? Why not the church? The fact is, thereis no “kingdom of God in miniature” – no single institution thatuniquely represents God’s kingdom. The kingdom of God is the holyrealm of God’s dominion in history through formal covenanting by Hispeople and their faithfulness in extending this dominion.

Rushdoony insisted on the judicial separation of the New Testa-ment office of elder from the institutional church. “Moreover, there isno reason to restrict Paul’s counsel concerning the election of elders(or bishops) to the institution for worship. Paul’s church is theKingdom of God, the assembly of the redeemed. His counsel setsforth the requirements for eldership in every realm, church, state,

Page 516: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

72. Ibid., pp. 368–69.

73. R. J. Rushdoony, “The Life of the Church: I Timothy 5:1–2,” Chalcedon Report (Jan.1992), p. 15.

74. Law and Society, p. 389.

1455

school, etc.”72 With such a broad definition of elder as a ruler in gen-eral, the eldership loses its sacramental character. This was Rush-doony’s oft-stated goal: the de-sacramentalization of the institutionalchurch.

There are two enormous theological risks inherent in such a viewof the church: (1) the attempted de-sacramentalization of society, i.e.,secular humanism; (2) the attempted sacramentalization of either Stateor family. The fact is, sacramentalization is an inescapable concept.It is always a question of which institution becomes elevated tosacramental status. Unfortunately, Rushdoony did not understand thatsacramentalization is an inescapable concept. He sought to de-sacramentalize the institutional church, but he remained silent aboutany substitute. He did not see the Lord’s Supper as an ecclesiasticalmatter, but rather fundamentally a family matter: “The central sacra-ment of the Christian faith is a family fact, a common sharing of breadand wine from the Lord’s Table.”73

Which institution becomes the prime candidate for sacramentali-zation in place of the church? In Rushdoony’s theology, there is nopossibility of the sacramentalization of the State, but why not thefamily? Rushdoony moved dangerously close to this conclusion. Inbetween his assertion of the family as the kingdom of God in miniatureand his discussion of the office of elder as “first of all a familyoffice,”74 this disconcerting statement appears: “Our regenerationestablishes a union with the Lord. Our every sexual act is an essential

Page 517: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

75. Idem.

76. Ibid., p. 345.

1456

step which makes us a member of the other person.”75 Rushdoony needed to qualify his language covenantally. It is

legitimate to describe Christ’s love for His church as the love of a hus-band for his wife, as Paul does in Ephesians 5:23–33, but not whenyou begin with a theory of the church as an extension of the family.Also, not when you personally refuse to take the sacrament of theLord’s Supper, for this refusal raises the issue of a substitutesacrament. Biblically, there is no form of covenant renewal for thefamily except through membership in the institutional church andparticipation in the Lord’s Supper. But if the uniquely sacramentalcharacter of the institutional church is denied, then what is to preventthe substitution of sexual bonding for the Lord’s Supper?

There is no court of earthly appeal beyond the family, Rushdoonysaid. Here is his defense of patriarchalism – and therefore of clannism.“The strength of family government is that the godly family, whilehaving numerous problems and disputes, settles these within its owncircle. The family is the institution of strength. To go outside thefamily is to deny the family and to break it up.”76 This means thedivine right of the family – no earthly appeal beyond it, either tochurch or State. Although he never mentioned the word, this is thedivine right of the patriarch. He presented this novel thesis as an exe-gesis of I Corinthians 6:1–8, where Paul enjoins members of theCorinthian church not to go before pagan civil courts. In short, heargued for the divine right of the individual against the institutionalchurch (the tithe issue), but not against the hierarchical family.

The Family as the Central Institution

Page 518: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

77. Rushdoony, Systematic Theology, p. 678. The chapter seems to have been writtenprior to 1984.

78. Ibid., p. 680.

79. Idem.

80. Gary North, Hierarchy and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on First Timothy(West Fork, Arkansas: Institute for Christian Economics, 2002), ch. 3.

1457

His Systematic Theology makes his familiocentrism explicit. “Thefamily is central to the covenant and therefore to every Christian insti-tution, church, state, school, and all things else.”77 Rushdoony againcited Exodus 18 to prove his contention that the family is the centralinstitution. Exodus 18 established a hierarchical chain of appealscourts. The problem for Rushdoony’s argument is that this was civilgovernment. It did not apply explicitly to Aaron, the priest. It appliedto the tribes. Rushdoony insisted that “both the synagogue and thechurch were ruled by elders; obviously both saw this as God’s require-ment.”78 With no footnote, he infered from unnamed extra-biblicalsources that only elders served as leaders of the synagogue. There isno biblical evidence about the synagogue, presumably a post-exilicinstitution. But even if this eldership was required, this does not leadto his conclusion, namely, “The office of elder was more than tribal:it originated in the family; the head of the family was its elder. Godthus ordained that the family be the nucleus of government.”79 Wheredoes it say in the Bible that only family heads may be civil rulers?Nowhere. Rushdoony did not cite a single biblical law to support hiscontention. Fact: Samson was an unmarried civil judge for manyyears.

What about the church? Here, there is biblical evidence that a manmust be a successful ruler of his own household before being ordainedby a church as a minister of the gospel, a point Paul made clear (I Tim.3:1–11).80 This no more makes the family the nucleus of all

Page 519: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

81. Ibid., p. 681.

1458

government than a requirement that a man must be able to read inorder to vote in a civil election makes literacy the nucleus of allgovernment. The family is a training ground for learning how togovern. There is nothing revolutionary in this observation. The churchis to use the family as a surrogate. If a man cannot rule well in hisfamily, Paul said, do not make him a leader in the church. The oddsare against his success. That this requirement governs ordination tothe pastorate is clear to everyone except seminary professors andchurches that ordain unmarried seminary graduates. They have substi-tuted term papers for family rule as the screening criteria. This hasbeen disastrous for the church.

First Timothy 3 does not make the family the nucleus of all govern-ment. Self-government is the nucleus of all government. This is whythere will be a day of final judgment in which each person will bejudged by God. God will not ask where your parents are, or yourchildren, or your ministers, or your rulers. God will ask only what youthought of His son, Jesus. The reason why Paul specified the family asthe screening institution is that family government makes visible aman’s skills of self-government in the context of a nearly universalhierarchy. There are more heads of families than heads of civil govern-ment. If the family were the nucleus of all government, somewhere inthe Bible there would be a law making marriage a requirement for civiloffice. Nowhere does such a law appear. But Rushdoony’scommitment to patriarchalism was greater than his commitment tobiblical law. Hence, he wrote in 1984: “The biblical form ofgovernment requires that men and the families be trained to govern.The basic government is on the family level, and all other forms ofgovernment rest thereon.”81

In Politics of Guilt and Pity (1970), he wrote: “The basic govern-

Page 520: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

82. Rushdoony, Politics of Guilty and Pity (Fairfax, Virginia: Thoburn Press, [1970]1978), p. 144.

83. Rushdoony, Institutes, p. 240.

84. Ibid., p. 772.

85. Idem.

1459

ment is man’s self-government. Other governments of man include thefamily, the church, the school, his business, and many privateassociations as well as public opinion.”82 This was the ideal of govern-ment that had attracted his early associates. In Institutes of BiblicalLaw, he also began with self-government under God. “Governmentmeans, first, self-government, then the family, church, state, school,calling, and private associations as well as much else.”83 But later inthe book, and perhaps three years later in terms of when he wrote thispassage, he began to modify his earlier position. “The basic govern-ment of man is the self-government of Christian man.”84 A hint of ashift in his perspective immediately followed: “The family is an impor-tant area of government also, and the basic one. The church is an areaof government, and the school still another.”85 Notice: he used theword basic for both self-government and family government. Thisequality could not survive indefinitely. In Systematic Theology, hemoved the family to first place. This was a major shift away from hisoriginal theology. He now placed an institution at the center of bothhis social theory and his theology; before, his social theory had restedon the principle of self-government under God’s law. This proposedcentral institution is not the church. It is the church’s oldest rival, theone Jesus had warned against most strongly (Matt. 10:34–37).

The Rhetoric of Contempt

Page 521: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

86. R. J. Rushdoony, “Reconstructing the Church,” Calvinism Today, II (July 1992), p.24.

87. Idem.

1460

Rushdoony in 1991 delivered a lecture, “Reconstructing theChurch,” at the Third International Conference on Christian Recons-truction, held in England. He briefly summarized the traditional Prot-estant and Reformed three-fold definition of the church: orthodoxpreaching, administering the sacraments, and disciplining. He calledthis definition “reductionism.”86 Its limitation, he said, is that it focuseson the institutional church, not the members and their responsibilities.He then quoted William Booth, founder of the Salvation Army – aworldwide parachurch organization that closely resembles a churchbut does not offer the sacraments. Rushdoony favorably cited Booth’sdescription of the late-nineteenth-century church in England as a“mummy factory.”87 This was a clever remark made by a “General”whose organization’s publicly recognized symbols are neither thecross of Christ nor a communion cup but instead are: (1) a large bassdrum beaten by a lady wearing a funny hat; (2) a black cooking potand a hand-wrung bell jingling for our cash each Christmas. Let mesay it early: the church has never been a mummy factory. This truthwas learned by the Pharaoh of the exodus, who never became amummy. He drowned instead. Local churches may produce somespiritual mummies in certain eras, but the church is God’s bride.Rushdoony’s rhetoric here is suicidal.

What is extremely significant is this: in his earlier days, Rushdoonyhad forthrightly affirmed the familiar three-part definition of thechurch, defending all three points as crucial in the war againsthumanism. In his 1983 book, Salvation and Godly Rule, he includeda chapter on “Outlaw Cultures.” The essay’s internal evidence indi-

Page 522: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

88. Whenever Rushdoony includes newspaper citations, the date of the latest citation isprobably close to the time he wrote the essay. Prior to his move to Vallecito, California, in1975, he threw out his lifetime collection of newspaper clippings. (What I would have paidfor this collection had I known in advance he intended to trash it!) The chapter cites a localSouthern California newspaper, The San Gabriel Tribune: June 26, 1972. He had manydisciples in the San Gabriel Valley in this period. One of the attendees of his eveninglectures in Pasadena (in the San Gabriel Valley), held in the late 1960’s, probably sent himthe newspaper clipping. There is no footnote reference in the book to anything publishedlater than 1973. So, I think it is safe to conclude that the chapter was written no later thanthe publication date of Volume 1 of The Institutes: 1973. That he could write these chaptersin the early 1970’s, several apparently in late 1972 and early 1973, while he wascompleting the manuscript of The Institutes, indicates his continuing productivity in1970–73 period. Compare the tightly written chapters in Volume 1 with those in Volume 2, Law andSociety (1982), whose newspaper citations cluster noticeably around 1976–77. These post-1973 chapters are shorter, relying heavily on footnote references to Bible commentaries andreligious encyclopedias, with few references to scholarly journals and scholarlymonographs: a visible contrast with the footnotes in his pre-1974 books. The theologicalstructure and integrating theme of Law and Society are difficult to discern, unlike Volume1. With 160 brief chapters plus appendixes, it could hardly be otherwise.

89. R. J. Rushdoony, Salvation and Godly Rule (Vallecito, California: Ross House,1983), p. 160.

1461

cates that it was written in 1972.88 Rushdoony wrote eloquently andto the point that “the marks of a true church, i.e. a body of worship-pers, have been defined for centuries as the faithful preaching of theword of God, the faithful administration of the sacraments, and theapplication of Biblical discipline. Without these things, we are nottalking about the church in any historical or theological sense. Instead,a purely humanistic ideal of a denatured church is given us. Such achurch is simply a part of the City of Man and an outlaw institution atwar with the City of God.”89

I agree completely with his excellent summary of the marks of atrue church and the humanistic implications of any denial of it. Theproblem is, nineteen years after he wrote it, eight years after he pub-lished it, Rushdoony openly repudiated it, and more than repudiatedit: became contemptuous of it, ridiculing it . The transformation of

Page 523: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

90. R. J. Rushdoony, “Editorial,” Chalcedon Report (April 1993), p. 2.

1462

his theology during the 1980’s was extensive – a fact not widelyperceived by his followers or his critics. He replaced his originalcommitment to the theology of Calvin and the Protestant reformerswith something resembling Anabaptism – and, in some cases, theolo-gical liberalism, as we shall see. This transformation centered in hisdoctrine of the church, but it was not confined to it.

In 1977, Rushdoony adopted sharp rhetoric regarding amillennialthough theologically orthodox churches. In a 57-page book titled,God’s Plan for Victory: The Meaning of Postmillennialism, he refer-red to the mythical “Orthodox Pharisees Church” (p. 9), whose initialswere OPC, the same as the Orthodox Presbyterian Church.Rushdoony had openly begun to burn his ecclesiastical bridges behindhim. He never stopped burning them. This is what I call the RogerWilliams syndrome: no church meets his standards. He finds himselfworshipping in smaller and smaller settings, always led by himself. Atthe end of his life, it was only family members and employees ofChalcedon who regularly attended his Bible studies – or, as he hadcalled them only after late 1991, church worship services.

Having invoked the phrase “mummy factory” with respect to themodern church, he then rallied to the defense of parachurch ministries,referring to “the common and contemptuous use of the term para-church. . . . People who rail against parachurch activities want to limitChrist’s work to what they can control.”90 Well, that all depends. Ifthe particular parachurch ministry deliberately and self-consciouslyconducts pseudo-worship meetings but without the sacrament of theLord’s Supper during the hours when churches normally conductworship meetings – the Salvation Army comes to mind, as doesChalcedon’s Bible studies (1968–1991) – then the critics have a legiti-mate complaint. Also, if a parachurch ministry actively solicits tithes

Page 524: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

1463

that belong solely to the institutional church, then the critics have alegitimate complaint: opposing the theft of the tithe by interlopers.The issue is to be decided by an appeal to God’s revealed word, notto rhetoric, i.e., the institutional church as a “mummy factory.”

A Question of Jurisdiction

What Rushdoony ignored after 1973 should be obvious to anyonewith any familiarity with the West’s judicial theology and Reformationhistory. Protestantism’s definition of the church as an institution wasa means of identifying the church’s lawful jurisdiction. That is to say,the traditional Protestant definition places judicial boundaries aroundthe church as an institution – a major goal of the ProtestantReformation, especially the limiting of the sacraments to baptism andthe Lord’s Supper. Like the U.S. Constitution’s limitation of thenational government’s jurisdiction, this traditional Protestant definitionwas designed to place boundaries around what the institutional churchcould rightfully claim as its area of legitimate covenantal authority. Itis no more meaningful to criticize the familiar three-fold definition ofthe institutional church – i.e., that this definition does not describewhat church members should do – than it is to criticize the U.S.Constitution because it does not specify what citizens are supposed todo. The judicial question is this: What is the institutional churchauthorized by God to do as His designated monopoly?

It is therefore misleading – I would call it deliberately, self-cons-ciously subversive – for a theologian of Rushdoony’s stature tocriticize the traditional Protestant definition of the institutional churchon this basis: that the definition does not tell us what church membersare supposed to do. Church members can and should do lots of won-derful things; but they can also avoid doing lots of wonderful things

Page 525: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

91. You cannot take the Lord’s Supper if you do not attend a local church. Rushdoonyattended no local church except as a guest lecturer after he ceased preaching for theAnglican Orthodox Church in the mid-1960’s. I attended Chalcedon’s Sunday meetingsfrom the beginning, though irregularly, 1965–71. I was employed by Chalcedon, 1968–81,and I spoke at its meetings each month, 1973–75, as did Greg Bahnsen. Not once didRushdoony offer the Lord’s Supper at a Chalcedon meeting when I was in attendanceduring the years that I attended them or spoke at them. David Graves, who tape recordedevery Chalcedon weekly meeting from 1972 to 1981, has stated in writing that never wasthe Lord’s Supper served at any Sunday Chalcedon meeting. I reprinted Mr. Gravesstatement in Tithing and the Church, p. 150. I mention this in response to Rushdoony’s

1464

and still remain members in good standing – and not be contempt-uously dismissed as mummies. The judicial issue is what is crucialhere: defining what the institutional church must do in order to be afaithful covenantal organization under God. At this absolutely crucialpoint in his theology, Rushdoony in 1991 abandoned historic Protes-tantism’s judicial theology in favor of a definition of the church basedon “fellowship” and “good works” – the traditional view of theolog-ical liberalism.

Having misled his readers on this point, Rushdoony then went onto mislead them even more. He said that the church must perform theGreat Commission: establish the crown rights of King Jesus, baptizenations, and teach them to obey God’s word. Notice: not one refer-ence to the sacrament of the Lord’s Supper. While Matthew 28:18–20mentions only baptism, the establishment of the church requires theLord’s Supper. Any theologically accurate discussion of the GreatCommission must assume the accuracy of the three defining judicialmarks of the institutional church. But if you have just ridiculed theinstitutional church as a mummy factory, your reader may not noticewhat you are really doing: removing respect for the judicial authorityof the institutional church as the sole legitimate source of the sacra-ments. Was this Rushdoony’s goal in 1991? I think it was. Rushdoonyin mid-1991 had not taken the Lord’s Supper, except when lecturingat some distant church, for over two decades.91

Page 526: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

insistence that there is no evidence for any accusation against his ideas regardingcommunion, and that those people who say such critical things must “provide evidences ofthe charges,” and if they refuse, they should be denounced “as liars and slanderers, becausethey cannot produce the evidences.” Rushdoony said that he would no longer answerquestions about this matter. Rushdoony, “Random Notes,” Chalcedon Report (Oct. 1993),p. 31. I can hardly blame him for not answering: the truth is embarrassing.

1465

The Legal Basis of the Tithe

The judicial foundation of the tithe is not its supposedly primaryrole as an aspect of dominion; it is rather based on the church’s cov-enantal role as the monopolistic guardian of the sacraments, whichestablishes its possession of the keys of the kingdom. In this sense, thechurch’s authority is the same as the Levites’ authority under theMosaic covenant: guardian of the holy. Its ultimate means of disciplineis excommunication: separating former members from the communiontable. There is no church authority apart from the sacraments. Removerespect for the sacraments, and you thereby remove respect forchurch discipline. This has been the pattern of modern fundamen-talism, and Rushdoony was in this regard a dedicated fundamentalist,not a Calvinist. Calvinism is not merely a belief in predestination.Luther believed in predestination (The Bondage of the Will), but hewas surely not a Calvinist. Luther and Calvin divided over the issue ofthe Lord’s Supper: a sacramental issue. Calvin devoted the longestsection of his Institutes to a study of the church: Book IV. Break withCalvin on his doctrine of the church, and you have broken with Calvin.This is what Rushdoony did. This is a major reason why Rushdoony’stheology is rejected without a fair hearing by pastors and theologianswithin the Calvinist world. They see him for what he was after 1980:an ecclesiastical independent who happens to believe inpredestination and infant baptism.

Page 527: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

92. Gary North, Priorities and Dominion: An Economic Commentary on Matthew, 2ndelectronic edition (Harrisonburg, Virginia: Dominion Educational Ministries, Inc., [2000]2003), ch. 47.

93. Gary North, “Dominion Through Subordination,” Biblical Economics Today, XV(Aug./Sept. 1993).

1466

Dominion and Subordination

The requirement to exercise dominion is a requirement to seek aprofit. On this point, see Jesus’ parable of the talents (Matt. 25:14–31),92 which immediately precedes His description of the final judg-ment. The tithe is paid out of the net increase of our efforts. In short:no increase = no tithe. Individuals and families produce net increases;churches, at best, invest excess funds in profit-seeking, non-churchendeavors. The family, not the church, is the primary agency ofdominion, and because of this, the family is not granted any economicentitlement by God. The church is entitled to the tithe; non-churchagencies are not. Dominion has nothing to do judicially with the God-given authority to collect the tithe. Dominion does have something todo with paying the tithe, however: a public acknowledgment of one’sinstitutional subordination to God’s church.

That Rushdoony wrote of tithing and dominion as judicially linked,and then announced that the church is not a productive institution,points to his anti-ecclesiastical conclusion: a denial that the institu-tional church has a legitimate claim on the tithe. But the fundamentaltopic is not tithing and dominion. Rather it is tithing and subordin-ation. When we get this clear, and only then, should we begin toconsider the next topic, subordination and dominion.93 Only to thedegree that Christians are subordinate before God through member-ship in His institutional church are they fully empowered by God to

Page 528: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

94. Rushdoony, “The Foundation of Christian Reconstruction,” in Tithing and Dominion,p. 9.

95. A former employee of Chalcedon, Rev. Douglas F. Kelly, has made the case for thechurch’s tax immunity: “Who Makes Churches Tax Exempt?” in Christianity and Civili-zation, No. 3 (1983), published by the Geneva Divinity School Press in Tyler, Texas.

1467

extend His comprehensive dominion. Subordination (point two of thebiblical covenant model) precedes dominion (point three). Rushdoonydenied this covenantal reality in his writings and his actions after 1974.

Social Services vs. Judicial Sanctions

Rushdoony defended his view by separating the Levites’ sacra-mental function from their cultural and social functions. He arguedthat the Levites performed many social services, “providing godlyeducation, music, welfare, and necessary godly assistance to civilauthorities.”94 Thus, Rushdoony concluded, it was their provision ofthese social services that justified their collection of the tithe. They didnot possess a legal claim on the tithe, Rushdoony argued. If they failedto provide these cultural services, Israelite church members had anobligation to cut them off financially. They still do, he insisted.

It is worth noting that this view of church authority is shared by themodern American liberal. The modern liberal’s acceptance of the ideaof tax exemption is based on his theory of useful social services. Theliberal allows the State to grant tax exemption to churches on thesame basis that it grants tax exemption to non-profit, government-chartered charitable foundations such as Chalcedon. The liberal cate-gorically rejects any suggestion that the Trinitarian church is auto-matically tax-immune, based on its separate covenantal status as aGod-ordained government – a government that possesses the author-ity to impose judicial sanctions.95 Analogously, Rushdoony regarded

Page 529: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

96. Rushdoony, “Tithing and Christian Reconstruction,” Tithing and Dominion, p. 3.

97. Idem.

1468

the church as having no lawful claim to Christians’ tithes based on itsseparate covenantal status as a God-ordained government that pos-sesses the authority to impose judicial sanctions. In his theology, thechurch has no legal claim on members’ money greater than their desireto support it because of the social services it provides them. In short,Rushdoony’s theology of the church’s claim on the tithe is the sameas the liberal’s theology of the church’s claim to tax exemption. Theyboth ask the church the same question: “What have you done forsociety lately?”

“This tithe belongs to God, not to the church, nor to the produ-cer.”96 This observation is irrelevant for any discussion of the tithe. Ofcourse the tithe belongs to God; everything belongs to God (Ps. 50:10). The question is this: What institution possesses the God-givenmonopolistic authority to collect the tithe from covenant-keepers?That is, which institution possesses the God-given authority and res-ponsibility to revoke voting membership for any head of householdwho refuses to pay a tithe? The biblical answer is obvious: the church.Rushdoony disagreed with this answer. He wanted to remove from theinstitutional church any legal claim to the tithe.

He raised the spurious issue of an apostate church in order to des-troy the legal claim of all churches: “It cannot be given to an apostatechurch without being given thereby against God, not to Him.”97 Thisis quite true; it is therefore an argument for a person to leave an apos-tate church. In fact, the best indicator to a church member that heshould transfer his membership to another church is that he can nolonger in good conscience pay the tithe to the church that now pos-sesses lawful authority over him. The individual has the God-givenauthority and responsibility to decide which church to join; he does

Page 530: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

98. Idem.

99. Ibid., p. 5.

1469

not have the authority to decide not to tithe to this church. But in aworld filled with non-tithing Christians, Rushdoony’s doctrine ofchurch and tithe finds many supporters.

Church and Kingdom

Rushdoony argued that the individual has the God-given authorityto decide where his tithe money should go. As a statement of the God-delegated authority of the believer, this is true, but only in a veryspecific and limited way: his authority to transfer his membership toanother congregation. But Rushdoony was not talking about this formof conscience-based authority before God. The decision Rushdoonyspeaks of is a decision made not on the basis of where the Christianchooses to have his local church membership, but rather on the basisof the Christian’s assessment of the broadly defined cultural perform-ance of the church’s officers. “The priests and Levites, to whom it [thetithe] was originally given, had charge of religion, education, andvarious other functions.”98 The tithe, he said, must constitute thefinancing of every aspect of Christian reconstruction, not just thepreaching of the word and the administration of the sacraments: “Butthe law of the tithe makes clear it is God’s money and must go toGod’s causes, to Christian worship, education, outreach, and recon-struction. . . . And the tithe must bear the whole burden of Christianreconstruction.”99 This is clearly incorrect. Everything that a personowns is supposed to be devoted to Christian reconstruction: heart,mind, soul, and capital. The tithe is only one-tenth of one’s netincrease. It is a token of our subordination to God as the Cosmic

Page 531: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

100. Rushdoony, “The Foundation of Christian Reconstruction,” ibid., p. 9.

101. Idem.

102. North, Sanctions and Dominion, ch. 3.

103. Through common grace, it is extended even by covenant-breakers. North, Dominionand Common Grace.

1470

Owner, not the primary fund for reconstruction. He continued: “Whatwe must do is, first, to tithe, and, second, to allocate our tithe togodly agencies. Godly agencies means far more than the church.”100

The Levites provided education, music, and so forth. “The realm ofthe godly, of the Christian, is broader than the church. To limitChrist’s realm to the church is not Biblical; it is pietism, a surrenderof Christ’s kingship over the world. The purpose of the tithe must beto establish that kingship.”101

It is clear why Rushdoony refused to cite the texts in Numbers thatestablished the legal basis of the claim of the Levites to the tithe.These passages explicitly link the tithe to the office of ecclesiasticalguardian. It was not the Levites’ social services that entitled them tothe tithe; it was their boundary service as the tabernacle’s and temple’sagents of execution: guardians of what was sacramentally holy.102

Rushdoony made a valid Protestant point: the kingdom of Christ islarger than the institutional church. As he said, limiting the kingdomto the institutional church is indeed the essence of pietism. But hecreated great confusion in his own mind and his followers’ minds byequating the tithe and charitable giving to the broader kingdom. Thisview of the tithe is equally pietistic: it limits the financing of thekingdom. The kingdom of Christ in history is comprehensive. It mustbe extended by every bit of productivity at the disposal of covenant-keepers.103 When a Christian makes a profit or earns a wage, all of thisis to be earmarked for extending the kingdom of Christ, broadly

Page 532: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

104. He wrote in 1967: “The property tax came in very slowly, and it appeared first inNew England, coinciding with the spread of Deism and Unitarianism, as well as atheism.Such anti-Christian men saw the state as man’s savior, and as a result they favored placingmore and more power in the hands of the state. The South was the last area to accept theproperty tax, and it was largely forced on the South by post-Civil War era, conservativeelements limited it to the county and retained the legal requirement that only owners of realproperty could vote on the county level.” Rushdoony, Chalcedon Newsletter #24 (Sept.1967). Reprinted in Rushdoony, The Roots of Reconstruction (Vallecito, California: RossHouse, 1991), p. 606.

105. Gary North, Is the World Running Down? Crisis in the Christian Worldview (Tyler,Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1988).

106. There is a third way: military conquest. But this method of dominion is not primary.It lawful only when it is the result of successful defensive campaigns that producecomprehensive victory in wars launched by God’s enemies.

1471

defined: education, entertainment, the arts, leisure, capital formation,etc.

The kingdom of Christ is not extended primarily by charitableinstitutions. The kingdom of Christ is extended through dominion, andthis is financed by Christians’ net productivity. Rushdoony understoodthis “net productivity” principle with respect to taxation: the Statemay not lawfully tax capital, only net income. This is why he longopposed the property tax as anti-Christian.104 But he did notacknowledge that this same principle also applies to the tithe. Neithertithes nor taxes are the basis of dominion; productivity is. That is,growth is the basis of dominion. Where there is no doctrine ofprogressive dominion in history, there is no doctrine of economicgrowth.105 This growth of God’s kingdom comes primarily throughtwo processes: (1) the confiscation of Satan’s assets through God’sadoption of Satan’s human disciples; (2) the economic growth enjoyedby God’s human disciples, which enables them to redeem the worldthrough purchase.106

The kingdom of Christ, broadly defined, must be equated with thetotal efforts of covenant-keepers: heart, mind, and soul. What is my

Page 533: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

107. Gary North, Inheritance and Dominion: An Economic Commentary onDeuteronomy, electronic edition (Tyler, Texas: Institute for Christian Economics, 1999),ch. 67.

108. E. Calvin Beisner, Prospects for Growth: A Biblical View of Population, Resources,and the Future (Westchester, Illinois: Crossway, 1990).

109. This is one reason why a Christian should instruct his heirs not to put him on a life-support system once two physicians say that it is unlikely that he will recover. The capitalof most estates in the U.S. is used up in the last six months of an aged person’s life. It isbetter to die in bed at home six months early and leave capital behind. Christians must buyback the world, generation by generation. This requires a growing supply of capital.

110. North, Political Polytheism, p. 553.

1472

conclusion? First, all of the tithe goes to the local church. Second,gifts and offerings can go to other charities. Third, the kingdom ofChrist is extended by total productivity, including economic produc-tivity. Fourth, total economic productivity, not charity, is the primaryeconomic means of extending God’s kingdom in history. This is whyGod promises long-term economic growth to covenant-keeping soc-ieties (Deut. 28:1–14).107 More wealth per capita should come fromcovenant-keeping men than is used up by them.108 Covenant-keepersshould leave a positive economic legacy to their grandchildren.109 “Agood man leaveth an inheritance to his children’s children: and thewealth of the sinner is laid up for the just” (Prov. 13:22).

Sovereignty

If you want to find out where sovereignty lies in any social systemor social theory, you must do two things: (1) identify the sacraments;(2) follow the money.110 In Rushdoony’s theology, the kingdom ofGod is based on a compact between God and the individual Christian.The institutional church is without covenantal authority in this God-

Page 534: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

111. Rushdoony, “Foundation of Christian Reconstruction,” Tithing and Dominion, pp.8–9.

1473

and-man compact. Church officers must take whatever they receivefrom church members and be thankful to the donors for whatever thisis. Rushdoony’s ecclesiology allows church officers no legitimateinstitutional sanctions to impose on those members who send all or aportion of their tithe money elsewhere.

The judicial question surrounding the tithe is this: Who lawfullyretains sovereign control over the allocation of the tithe? Rush-doony’s answer: the individual Christian, not the officers of thechurch. “The Christian who tithes, and sees that his tithe goes to godlycauses, is engaged in true social reconstruction. By his tithe moneyand his activity he makes possible the development of Christianchurches, schools, colleges, welfare agencies, and other necessarysocial functions.”111 (And, he might have added, non-profit education-al foundations, but this would have appeared self-serving.) He did notmean that Christians retain ultimate control over the allocation of theirtithes by choosing which local congregation to join; rather, they retainimmediate allocational authority in their capacity as church membersor even as non-church members.

If this were true, then Rushdoony might have asked: What if theChristian can locate no agency that meets his standards of socialaction? Can the Christian then lawfully tithe to himself in order to fundthe doing of his own good deeds? Why not? More to the point, can heset up his own church and tithe to it? As of 1991, Rushdoonyapparently believed that this is the case. He claimed that Chalcedonhad somehow become a church. (Then what are the members of whatwas formerly its Board of Trustees: Ruling elders? There was neverany restriction against women serving on Chalcedon’s Board ofTrustees; Rushdoony’s wife Dorothy so served when I was a Trustee

Page 535: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

112. Because churches have refused to do this, they have forfeited enormous influenceand authority in modern culture. See Gary North, “Royal Priests, Tin Cups in Hand,”Biblical Economics Today, XIV (June/July 1992).

113. Rushdoony, “To Whom Do We Tithe?” Tithing and Dominion, p. 30.

114. Pre-1992. He did not put into print what he believed regarding the institutionalchurch after 1991.

1474

in the 1970’s. Can women now become elders in his new church? Orhave Chalcedon’s By-Laws been rewritten to exclude women?)

I have argued that tithe money can and should go to all kinds ofcharitable services, but it is church officers who are invested with theGod-given authority to decide which of these endeavors to supportand in what proportion.112 Rushdoony asserted that it is the tithe-payer’s God-given authority to make these decisions. “Since the titheis ‘holy unto the Lord’, it is our duty as tithers to judge that church,mission group, or Christian agency which is most clearly ‘holy untothe Lord’.”113 Rushdoony did not define the holiness of the recipientorganizations as legal holiness – a formal, judicial, covenantal, settingapart by God through His written revelation – but rather as socialholiness, to be judged by individual tithers. In Rushdoony’secclesiology, the church cannot bring judgment against individualswho refuse to transfer to the church 10 percent of their net income; onthe contrary, they bring judgment against the church by withholdingthese funds and sending them elsewhere, such as to a non-profit, Fed-erally tax-exempt, incorporated educational foundation located incentral California.

Here is where the rubber of Rushdoony’s anti-ecclesiastical world-view114 meets the covenantal road. The primary issue here is authorityover money. In Rushdoony’s published theology, lawful authority overthe distribution of the tithe lodges in the individual Christian. He whopays the piper calls the tune, and the piper-payer in Rushdoony’s

Page 536: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

1475

theology of the tithe is the individual Christian. Rushdoony’s theoryof the proper financing of the kingdom of God is therefore indivi-dualistic, despite his affirmations to the contrary.

High Priest and King of Kings

The New Testament affirms that Jesus Christ is both King of kingsand High Priest. His absolute sovereignty is revealed institutionally inhistory through the existence of biblically compulsory payments totwo covenantal institutions: State and church. The State has a lawfulclaim on a portion – under 10 percent (I Sam. 8: 15, 17) – of theproductivity of those under its jurisdiction. Why? Because the civilmagistrate is a minister of God (Rom. 13:4). The church has a legalclaim on 10 percent of its members’ net income. Why? Becausechurch officers are ministers of God. In both cases, the officers’ministerial function is what identifies these two institutions as sover-eign. Compulsory taxes go to the kingly institution; members’ com-pulsory tithes go to the priestly institution. Both institutions arecovenantal. Both are entitled to a portion of our income. A person canno more legitimately allocate his tithe than he can legitimately allocatehis taxes. He does not have the authority to do so; in both cases, he isunder the threat of institutional sanctions, meaning he is under thethreat of God’s sanctions.

It is a major weakness of Rushdoony’s social theory that he failedto identify anywhere in his writings the judicial and economic dis-tinctions between Christ as High Priest and Christ as King of kings.The Bible teaches clearly that the tithe is mandatory. It goes to thechurch, and only to the church. Why? Because Jesus Christ is the highpriest after the order of Melchizedek (Heb. 7). In Rushdoony’s socialtheory, Christ’s office as High Priest has no institutional sanctions.

Page 537: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

115. I am not referring to Rushdoony’s 1992 anointing of Chalcedon as a church. I amspeaking of his published theology and his two-decade absence from a local church and itscommunion table until 1992, when he began serving communion to himself and his family.

1476

In one limited sense, he is correct. The church technically cannotexcommunicate people who, like Rushdoony, refuses to join a localcongregation or take the Lord’s Supper. But the church does not needto bring formal sanctions against those who are self-excommuni-cated.115 Self-excommunication is excommunication. It is sufficientthat the church publicly identify self-excommunicated people asexcommunicates. (Rarely does any local church do this.) Churchofficers who serve the Lord’s Supper to such self-excommunicatedindividuals have denied their holy offices as guardians of the sacra-ments. It is not surprising that a loose view of the sacraments isnormally accompanied by a loose view of the church and a loose viewof the tithe.

The Chaldedon Foundation

Rushdoony for decades paid his tithe to his own educationalfoundation, Chalcedon. He did not belong to any local church untilearly 1991, when he declared Chalcedon to be a church. Problem: hispublished theology of the tithe rests on a fundamental confusionbetween the sacramental function of the church and its educationaland nurturing function. His published theology of the tithe does notacknowledge the judicial requirement of the individual Christian tofinance the sacramental aspect of the kingdom by means of his tithe,and the dominion and kingly aspects by means of voluntary donationsabove the tithe to non-ecclesiastical organizations.

Prior to 1991, Chalcedon, like the Institute for Christian Econom-

Page 538: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

116. The ICE was legally chartered as a charitable trust, not a foundation.

117. On this point, see my response to John R. Muether in Gary North, Westminster’sConfession: The Abandonment of Van Til’s Legacy (Tyler, Texas: Institute for ChristianEconomics, 1991), pp. 289–92.

118. Rushdoony, Law and Society, p. 127.

1477

ics, was kingly rather than priestly in its calling.116 Neither organiza-tion was entitled to any portion of the tithe except at the discretion ofchurches that collect tithes and then donate the money to eitherorganization. (As the saying goes, “Don’t hold your breath.”) Thedonor owes his local church his tithe; he does not possess the author-ity to allocate his tithe money (priestly, sacramental money) to otherorganizations. Chalcedon, ICE, and all other parachurch and educa-tional ministries owe it to their supporters to warn them never to sendin donations unless they first tithe to a local church.117 This limitationwould keep most of them quite tiny to the extent that they arefinanced by tithes, since very few Christians tithe. Rushdoony in thelate 1970’s invented a theology of the tithe that justified Chalcedon’scollection of part or all of Christians’ tithes. This self-interested theo-logical confusion undermined his theology of the kingship of Christand the dominion covenant.

Rushdoony’s theology of the tithe rests on an economic distinctionwithin the calling of the Levites: sacraments vs. social works. TheMosaic tithe, he says, was owed primarily because of the sociallyimportant services that were performed by the Levites. Only the onepercent going to the priests directly constituted the sacramentalportion; nine percent went for social services. “Only a handful ofLevites were engaged in temple service, as against the vast numberswhose work was instruction (Deut. 33:10).”118 Note: his focus is oninstruction. This is consistent. Chalcedon until 1991 was a strictlynon-profit, government-chartered educational institution.

Page 539: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

119. Rushdoony, “The Nature of the Church,” Calvinism Today (Oct. 1991), p. 3.

1478

He has made his views clear, that “nowhere in Scripture is man orthe church given the power to require or enforce tithing.”119 On thisweak theological reed he built his theology after 1979. (Ironically, itwas my tithe to my church that was used to finance the publication ofTithing and Dominion.)

A Single Storehouse

The Bible does not speak of multiple storehouses of the tithe; itspeaks of only one storehouse. If a society violates this single store-house principle of the mandatory tithe, it brings itself under God’snegative corporate sanctions. If it obeys this principle, it gains God’spositive corporate sanctions.

Will a man rob God? Yet ye have robbed me. But ye say,Wherein have we robbed thee? In tithes and offerings. Ye arecursed with a curse: for ye have robbed me, even this wholenation. Bring ye all the tithes into the storehouse, that there maybe meat in mine house, and prove me now herewith, saith theLORD of hosts, if I will not open you the windows of heaven,and pour you out a blessing, that there shall not be room enoughto receive it. And I will rebuke the devourer for your sakes, andhe shall not destroy the fruits of your ground; neither shall yourvine cast her fruit before the time in the field, saith the LORD ofhosts. And all nations shall call you blessed: for ye shall be adelightsome land, saith the LORD of hosts (Mal. 3:8–12).

Note that the word is storehouse (singular), not storehouses

Page 540: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

120. Rushdoony, “The Tithe in Scripture,” Tithing and Dominion, p. 17.

1479

(plural). But this is not how Rushdoony summarized the text: “Thetithe was given to the Levites, who stored the animals and grain instorehouses (Mal. 3:10) until they could either be used or sold. It is asilly and self-serving modernism which leads some clergymen to insistthat the storehouse is the church. . . . The Levites had very broadfunctions in Israel: they were the teachers (Deut. 33:10), themusicians, the judges at times, the medical authorities and more;superintending foods and their cleanliness was a part of their duty.”120

But the issue is not, in Rushdoony’s phrase, “self-serving modernism.”The issue is the actual text of Scripture. Men must not become self-serving when they read the text of Scripture – liberals or conser-vatives. The text speaks of a storehouse: singular.

What Rushdoony always ignored in this connection was that theLevites protected the place of sacrifice. While they did indeed providelegal advice and other services, the office of Levite was defined inconnection to the tithe as a judicial office: guardian of the temple. Hethen calls self-serving and modernist all those theologians who haveidentified the storehouse with the church: the receptacle of the tithe.Almost three decades of sending his own tithe to Chalcedon waspresumably not self-serving, in his opinion. But those who say that thetithe belongs only to the local church are modernists and pietists. Youknow: modernists such as John Calvin, who commented on Malachi3:10 by describing any withholding of the tithe from the priests as aform of sacrilege: “They had been sufficiently proved guilty ofrapacity in withholding the tenths and the oblations; as then thesacrilege was well known, the Prophet now passes judgment, as theysay, according to what is usually done when the criminal iscondemned, and the cause is decided, so that he who has beendefrauded recovers his right. . . . Bring, he says, to the repository (for

Page 541: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

121. John Calvin, Commentaries on the Twelve Minor Prophets, 5 vols. (Grand Rapids,Michigan: Baker, [1559] 1979), V, p. 588.

1480

this is the same as the house of the treasury, or of provisions) all thetenths, or the whole tenths. We hence learn that they had not with-holden the whole of the tenths from the priests, but that they fraud-ulently brought the half, or retained as much as they could; for it wasnot without reason that he said, Bring all, or the whole.”121

Calvin understood exactly what crime against God was involved inwithholding the full 10 percent from the Levites: sacrilege. Paying thepriests their tenth of the tithe was not sufficient to avoid the crime ofsacrilege, Calvin said. They had to pay the entire remaining nine-tenthsto the Levites. Sacrilege is an attack on God’s sacramental institution,the church – an attack on the sacraments. Calvin also understoodclearly that the tithe went to the Levites and priests because of theirjudicial offices as guardians and administrators of the sacraments. Thiseconomic entitlement was grounded judicially in the sacraments, andonly in the sacraments. Any other duties performed by the Levites andpriests were incidental to their administration of the sacraments.Calvin never referred to these supplemental social activities.Rushdoony, in sharp contrast, categorically denies any sacramentalauthority to the institutional church. He has abandoned the theologyof Calvin and the Puritans in the name of Calvin and the Puritans.Rushdoony has moved from Calvinism to Anabaptism. Nowhere isthis clearer than in his published view of the tithe.

Rushdoony’s Social Gospel

We can see Rushdoony’s break with Calvinism in his false distinc-tion between the Levites’ task as educators and the place of sacrifice,

Page 542: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

122. Rushdoony, Institutes, p. 55.

123. Rushdoony, Intellectual Schizophrenia: Culture, Crisis and Education(Philadelphia: Presbyterian and Reformed, 1961), p. 42.

1481

the sanctuary. “Education was one of the functions of the Levites (notof the sanctuary).”122 To prove this supposed separation of religiouseducation from the sanctuary in the Levitical calling, he would haveto identify the judicial basis of the Levites’ separation from the othertribes in terms of their provision of social services. This cannot bedone textually. Numbers 18 is clear, as we have seen: the separationof the Levites from the other tribes was based on their unique accessto the temple and its sacrifices. This separation was based on a geo-graphical boundary – legal access to the tabernacle/ temple – and noton their provision of social services, especially educational services.

Is the education of children lawfully a function of the church, theState, or the family? Rushdoony always denied the legitimacy ofeducation by the State, but he was ambivalent regarding the educa-tional authority of church and family. “The Christian school is amanifestation of the visible church, and at the same time, an extensionof the home.”123 But which one possesses institutional sovereignty?Economically, the answer is clear: the agency that funds education.What about judicially? On this point, Rushdoony was ambivalent. Butthis much is clear: if education was the function of the Levites, andthis function was separate from the sanctuary (i.e., the sacrifices), ashe insisted was the case, then the Levites as educators were under theauthority of families if families paid for education by allocating theirtithes. This is exactly what Rushdoony’s theology of the titheconcludes. This means that pastors as Levite-educators (i.e., as tithe-receivers) are under the authority of families. Since he denied thesacramental character of the church, he stripped the church of allcovenantal authority. It cannot impose sanctions for non-payment of

Page 543: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

124. Rushdoony, Institutes, p. 57.

1482

tithes. Once again, we are back to familism-clannism.Rushdoony’s voluntaristic view of the tithe is shared by most of the

modern church and most of its members, which is why the modernchurch is impotent, both judicially and economically. This is whystatism has visibly triumphed in our day. Rushdoony admitted thiswhen he wrote that “the abolition of the tithe has opened the way fortruly oppressive taxation by the state in order to assume the socialresponsibilities once maintained by tithe money.”124 But he erred onceagain: the fundamental issue is not money; it is the sacramental char-acter of the church. The fundamental issue is the judicial basis of thelocal church’s claim on 10 percent of the net productivity of itsmembers. This claim is sacramental-judicial, not social-economic.

Rushdoony always discussed the primary role of the church(“Levites”) as a social agency, openly denying its sacramental charac-ter. He was wrong, and this single error has produced more harm forthe Christian Reconstruction movement than anything else in hiswritings. He had no respect for the sacrament of the Lord’s Supper,and it shows. Without covenantal sanctions in history, there could beno covenant: church (keys), State (sword), or family (rod). He triedto strip the institutional church of her lawful negative sanction –excommunication – by stripping divine sanctions from the Lord’sSupper. He wrote himself out of the church, 1970–1991, in order tojustify his self-excommunication from the church.

The Case of the Missing Theology

In this respect, Rushdoony became a consistent defender of a socialgospel. His pietist critics have recognized this, although their view of

Page 544: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

125. Rushdoony, Institutes, p. 513.

1483

the tithe is rarely better than his, and their view of the sacraments isonly slightly better. Rushdoony’s theology does defend gospel preach-ing as a function of the church, thereby avoiding the liberal version ofthe social gospel. But the institutional church has three aspects: thepreaching of the gospel, the administration of the sacraments, and theauthority to police access to the sacraments, i.e., church discipline (thekeys of the kingdom). One searches in vain in Rushdoony’s writingsfor even one page devoted to a theological exposition of thediscipline of the church. He steadfastly refused to discuss the meaningof the keys of the kingdom. This is why he never published so muchas a chapter on the doctrine of the church: sacraments, tithe, anddiscipline.

Rushdoony’s view of the church is not even remotely Reformed.He used Calvinist phrases, but he long ago abandoned Book IV ofCalvin’s Institutes. Rushdoony’s ecclesiology is completely wrong.

The Fatal Flaw in Rushdoony’s Theology

Rushdoony began to develop the rudiments of his theology of thetithe in the late 1960’s, after Chalcedon had received its tax-exemptstatus from the U.S. Internal Revenue Service. In The Institutes ofBiblical Law (1973), he wrote: “Moreover, the modern church callsfor tithing to the church, an erroneous view which cuts off education,health, welfare, and much else from the tithe.”125 He understood thathis view of the tithe transfers power to the members, who are suppos-edly under no judicial requirement to pay their tithes to the church: “Ifthe church collects the tax, the church rules society; if the statecollects the tax, the state rules society. If, however, the people of God

Page 545: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

126. Ibid., p. 514.

127. North, Tithing and the Church, ch. 3.

1484

administer the tithe to godly agencies, then God’s rule prevails in thatsocial order.”126 The central legal issue is administration: Who has theGod-given authority to allocate the tithe? The Bible is clear: thechurch. Rushdoony was equally clear: the tithe-payer.

Notice Rushdoony’s implicit assumption: because God says that Heis entitled to a tithe, a godly society is determined economically by theagent who distributes it. The biblical fact is very different: the judicialstatus of a godly society is determined covenantally in terms of whichagency collects and then distributes the tithe, for this identifies whichgod rules in society by which representatives. A Christian society isidentified biblically by the widespread presence of churches thatcollect the tithe, i.e., churches that possess and exercise their God-given authority to impose negative sanctions against members whorefuse to pay the tithe. My view is that the proper negative sanctionto be used against non-tithing members is their removal from the listof voting members. They would not be allowed to impose sanctionson church officers.127 God blesses covenantally faithful societies.Tithing to God’s church is a primary mark of covenantal faithfulness.Cause and effect move from law (boundaries) to sanctions (blessingsand cursings). But the judicial issue is God’s delegated authority: Whoowes what to whom? In short, who lawfully holds the hammer? Is thefundamental authority of the kingdom of God primarily economic,with Christian individuals holding the hammer, or is it primarilyjudicial, with church officers holding it?

Compulsory Support

Page 546: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

128. Bill Moyers, “God and Politics: On Earth as It Is in Heaven,” Public AffairsTelevision (1987), p. 5.

1485

Christians have always acknowledged that individuals owe taxes tothe State. Render unto Caesar the things that are Caesar’s, Jesus said(Matt. 22:21). The individual does not lawfully decide how his taxeswill be spent; the State’s officers do. Christians have alwaysacknowledged that Children owe support to parents. This is notoptional. Even priests must pay, Jesus said. No priest can escape thisobligation by crying, “corban,” as if this obligation were a voluntarygift (Mark 7:11–13). (Corban is the Hebrew word used in Leviticus2:1 to describe the meat [meal] offering, i.e., the second sacrifice.)

Then what about the church? Does the tithe-payer have the God-given authority to decide to pay the tithe to any organization otherthan the institutional church? No. Paying the tithe to the institutionalchurch is each church member’s legal obligation before God. In allthree covenantal institutions, paying money is not a matter of choice;it is a matter of legal obligation. The allocation of the money socollected is not the decision of those who pay.

Rushdoony misidentified this authority structure. In his view, econ-omics, not God’s covenantal law of the church, is determinative: agodly society, he said, is financed by the tithe. Again, his libertarianpresuppositions are obvious. He was not exaggerating when heannounced on national television in 1987: “I’m close to being a liber-tarian. . . .”128 As he saw it, the success or failure of God’s non-profitkingdom institutions will be determined by God’s sovereignty bymeans of the decisions of individual Christians regarding where to paytheir tithes – decisions made without any legitimate threat of insti-tutional sanctions from the recipients. Sanctions – positive or negative– are imposed by individual Christians on the recipient institutions; theinstitutions have no legitimate negative sanctions of their own. Theinstitutional church is described by Rushdoony as being little more

Page 547: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

1486

than an income-seeking business that competes for the consumers’money. This view of church financing removes the power of the keysfrom the church. This conclusion is completely consistent withRushdoony’s pre-1991 view of the sacrament of the Lord’s Supper:a rite without covenantal sanctions.

Rushdoony’s libertarianism and individualism are both visible in hisview of the tithe. On this topic, Rushdoony was an economic determ-inist. He said, in effect: “He who controls the allocation of the tithecontrols Christian society. The individual Christian lawfully controlsthe allocation of the tithe, so he should control Christian society. Theinstitutional church has no lawful authority to compel such paymentby any threat of sanctions. Hence, the individual is judiciallyautonomous in the allocation of the tithe. Only God can imposenegative sanctions against him.” This is the libertarian theology knownas the divine right of the individual. Divine-right theology alwaysrests on a presupposition that someone – the king, the legislature, orthe individual – is beyond legitimate institutional sanctions in history.Rushdoony’s radical individualism is clearly seen here. He rejectedcovenant theology in favor of Anabaptist theology.

Rushdoony wrote repeatedly that individualism always leads tostatism. The humanist State can compel payment of taxes, can demandobedience, and therefore it possesses divine rights. That is, thehumanist State claims autonomy from (and therefore authority over)every rival institution. To challenge such a view of the State, there hasto be an appeal to another authority with authority that is equal to theState’s in many areas and superior to it regarding the collection offunds from its members. In short, the authority of the church to collecttithes from its voting members prior to the tax collector’s extractionof money from church members must be affirmed in civil law. Thechurch must have legal priority over the State’s authority in the

Page 548: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

129. This is acknowledged implicitly judicially in the U.S. tax code. The taxpayer isallowed to deduct tithes and offerings from his gross income before estimating his incometax (though not his FICA or Social Security tax). He pays income taxes only on the moneythat remains after charitable giving. This is not true in most European countries, where theState has primary claim on income, with the church taking whatever remains.

130. R. J. Rushdoony, The One and the Many: Studies in the Philosophy of Order andUltimacy (Fairfax, Virginia: Thoburn Press, [1971] 1978), p. 130.

1487

involuntary collection of money.129 Only if some other covenantalinstitution possesses comparable authority over its members’ moneycan we identify an agency with comparable covenantal authority.

Rushdoony’s theology of the tithe denies such authority to thechurch. This leaves only the family as a rival covenantal institution.But, biblically speaking, the family possesses neither the sword nor thekeys of the kingdom. This is the fatal flaw of Rushdoony’s socialtheory. Rushdoony’s anti-ecclesiastical theology can offer only twofutile alternatives to the divine right of the State: radical individualismor patriarchalism-clannism. The State historically has overcome bothof these alternatives, from ancient Greece to the present. He pointedthis out in The One and the Many. “In early Greek and Romancultures, paternal power was religious power, a power continuouswith all being and essentially divine, requiring duties of the father andconferring him with authority. The father, as Fustel de Coulanges hasshown, in The Ancient City, was under law; but, it must be added, hewas not only under law but a part of that law and continuous with itin the chain of being. He was thus to a degree the law incarnate, inthat he possessed a measure of the ultimate law in his person. Thismanifestation of law moved steadily from the father to the state, sothat the state, originally the creature of the family and of the fathers,made itself the father, and the source of law, with the family turnedinto its creature.”130

By rejecting a sacramental defense of both the church and the tithe,

Page 549: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

1488

Rushdoony converted his theology into a conservative version of thesocial gospel. The legitimacy of the church, manifested in Rush-doony’s ecclesiology only by its ability to persuade church membersto donate money to it, is grounded on the good deeds that churchesperform in society. This is the U.S. Internal Revenue’s view of non-profit status, the liberal’s only reason for allowing the church toescape the tax man.

Rushdoony’s view of the church is libertarian. He viewed thechurch strictly as a voluntary society. In his view, the church is notfounded on a self-maledictory oath before God, for such an oathwould transfer judicial authority to church officers as God’s monop-olistic agents. They could then lawfully compel payment of the titheby members.

His view of church authority creates a divine right of the individualchurch member. The individual alone supposedly is God’s designatedagent who lawfully controls the distribution of the tithe rather than thechurch’s ordained authorities. Beyond him there is no ecclesiasticalappeal.

The alternative to a Christian view of society that places the churchcovenant at the center of its social theory is either a statist view ofsociety or a patriarchal view of society. Rushdoony, faithful to anArmenian heritage that did not survive the second generation of immi-grants – his generation – chose the latter view. Patriarchalism cannotsurvive for even three generations in a society that prohibits arrangedmarriages and allows easy divorce.

It also cannot survive the biblical view of marriage. It was Romanlaw, with its intense patriarchalism, that kept the clans alive. TheEnglish common law heritage was, from the twelfth century onward,utterly hostile to the revived Roman law’s view of marriage and familyauthority, which steadily gained new respect and power on the

Page 550: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

131. Alan Macfarlane, Marriage and Love in England: Modes of Reproduction1300–1840 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1986), ch. 7: “Who Controls the Marriage Decision?”

132. See North, Tithing and the Church, pp. 156–57.

1489

Continent.131 That Rushdoony should be regarded as soft on divorce,which in some cases he was,132 is ironic: nothing undermines a patriar-chal society – the family as sacramental – faster than the widespreadacceptance of divorce on demand. His own sad experience with hisfirst marriage, like the similar experiences of his brother and his sister,should have warned him.

Conclusion

The Levitical cultural and social services that Rushdoony lists asthe basis of the Levites’ reception of the tithe were all subordinateaspects of their primary judicial function: to guard the sacramentalboundary around the tabernacle/temple. Secondarily, Levites were todeclare God’s law and to help the priests administer some of thesacrifices and some of the liturgies of worship – what Rushdoonydismissed as mere “rites.” Numbers is clear: the tithe was based on theLevites’ sacramental separation from the people – in other words,their holiness. “And, behold, I have given the children of Levi all thetenth in Israel for an inheritance, for their service which they serve,even the service of the tabernacle of the congregation. Neither mustthe children of Israel henceforth come nigh the tabernacle of thecongregation, lest they bear sin, and die” (Num. 18:21–22). I com-ment on this in Chapter 10 of Sanctions and Dominion.

The New Testament has not abrogated the Old Testament. Thechurch’s hierarchical authority is grounded on the same judicialfoundation that the Levites’ authority was under the Mosaic law: their

Page 551: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

133. Rushdoony, Law and Society, p. 337.

1490

God-ordained service as guardians of a sacramental boundary. Therequirement of each church member to tithe exclusively to the institu-tional church that lawfully administers the sacraments rests today, asit did in the Mosaic law, on the uniquely sacramental character of thechurch. The mark of the church’s institutional sovereignty is its con-trol over lawful access to the sacraments. This control necessarilyinvolves the enforcement of a boundary: the right to exclude. Thechurch’s authority to exclude people from the Lord’s Supper is theultimate judicial basis of its discipline. Excommunication meansexclusion from Holy Communion: the Lord’s Supper. Because theinstitutional church possesses this sacramental monopoly, it alonepossesses the authority to collect the full tithe of every member.

This authority to exclude is imparted to church officers by meansof their possession of the keys of the kingdom. “And I will give untothee the keys of the kingdom of heaven: and whatsoever thou shaltbind on earth shall be bound in heaven: and whatsoever thou shaltloose on earth shall be loosed in heaven” (Matt. 16:19). Withoutaccess in history to the keys of heaven, there can be no kingdom ofChrist in history: no heavenly keys = no earthly kingdom. The keysinvoke heavenly sanctions; often, they invoke visible earthly sanctions.A king without sanctions in history is not a king in history. The mostimportant sanctions in history are in the hands of those who controlthe keys to the kingdom: officers of God’s visible church.

Rushdoony poured out his verbal wrath on the institutional churchin his attempt to broaden the definition of the church to include thefamily and non-profit educational institutions, and, in his words, “far,far more.”133 This is why Rushdoony’s view of the visible church hasundermined his theology of the kingdom of God in history. Volume2 of The Institutes of Biblical Law undermines Volume 1. What was

Page 552: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Rushdoony on the Tithe: A Critique

1491

a flaw no larger than a man’s hand in Volume 1 became a whirlwindin Volume 2. It stripped him of his doctrine of the church covenant –a covenant grounded in an oath before God (baptism) – for everycovenant must have negative institutional sanctions. His theologyallows no formal negative sanctions for the church. If a Christian can,without consequences, decide that he does not need to take HolyCommunion in a local church for a quarter of a century, then whatthreat is excommunication? The correct answer is: he cannot do thiswithout consequences. It is an answer Rushdoony refused to acceptuntil 1991.

Rushdoony’s view of the tithe stripped him of his Calvinism, for itled to his rejection of the authority of the institutional church. Thiswas a heavy price to pay. It is not easy to be taken seriously as aCalvinist theologian when you promote an Anabaptist or patriarchalview of the Lord’s Supper, a Baptist ecclesiology, and a social gospeldefinition of the church. It would have been far cheaper for him justto have paid a tithe to some local congregation and have been donewith it from 1964 until 2001 – cheaper, that is, for a person willing tosubmit himself to another pastor. But, after 1964, Rushdoony refusedto do either.

Rushdoony paid a heavy price: the bulk of his life’s work is con-veniently and illegitimately dismissed by serious churchmen as thework of a theological and personal screwball. By cutting his ties in1970 with any denomination that was more than a few years old, heforfeited his ability to transfer his intellectual inheritance to someoneof his choice. Only the institutional church survives intact until the dayof judgment. Only the institutional church offers God-guaranteedcovenantal continuity in history. If the institutional church rejects aman’s work, then that work cannot stand the test of time. It will beweighed in the balance and found wanting.

To the extent that Rushdoony’s work does survive, it will survive

Page 553: An Economic Commentary on Leviticus Volume 3 Gary North · 2016-07-13 · And ye shall hallow the fiftieth year, and proclaim liberty throughout all the land unto all the inhabitants

Appendix B

1492

only because of the continuity provided by those who remain insidethe institutional church, pay their tithes to the institutional church, andreceive the Lord’s Supper from men who have been lawfully ordainedby other lawfully ordained men: the laying on of hands. This is true ofevery Christian’s legacy. If the institutional church refuses toincorporate and develop a man’s ideas in history, these ideas will notcome to positive fruition in history. If a Christian’s spiritual heirsremain peripheral to the institutional church, his legacy will remainperipheral in history. This truth may not seem relevant to a premillen-nialist or amillennialist who sees the cultural effects of the gospel inhistory as marginal, but it is extremely relevant to a postmillennialist,or should be.

Contempt for God’s institutional church is theologically fatal.God’s church is not now, nor has it ever been, a mummy factory. Theinstitutional church, for all her flaws, is God’s bride. God has noother.

End of Volume 3