52
An empirical An empirical characterization of the characterization of the market process market process (T (T he fractional volatility model) he fractional volatility model)

An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

An empirical An empirical characterization of the characterization of the

market processmarket process

(T(The fractional volatility model)he fractional volatility model)

Page 2: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Contents1. Market prices are non-differentiable2. Geometric Brownian motion ?3. Volatility as a process. Volatility models4. The induced volatility process5. Time scales and pdf’sAppendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula6. Option pricing. Risk-neutral approachMathExc1 – Stochastic integration with respect to fBm7. An option pricing equation using fBm stochastic integrationMathExc2 – An introduction to fractional calculus8. Leverage, fBm representation and fractional calculus interpretation

Page 3: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

1. Market prices are non-differentiable

Page 4: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Detrending is needed for stationarity

Page 5: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric
Page 6: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

The returns process

r(t)=log(S(t+1))-log(S(t))

Automatically detrended

)())(log( )(1 tStS dt

dtSdt

d =

Page 7: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

2. Geometric Brownian motion ?

?(a basis for most mathematical finance studies –Black-Scholes, etc.)Consequences:

(i)

Price changes would be lognormal

(ii)

Self-similar (Law(Xat)=Law(aH Xt)) with Hurst coefficient = 1/2

E S t S tS t

H( ) ( )( )

+ − − ≈Δ Δ Δμ

))(2

))(2

(lnexp(

)(21)(ln 2

22

2 tT

tTSS

tTSSp t

T

t

T

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−−−

−−

σμ

πσ

dWdtSdS

t

t σμ +=

Page 8: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

2. Geometric Brownian motion ?Empirical tests :

P(r1) is not lognormal

r1=log(S(t+1)/S(t))

Deviations from scaling

Larger deviations for high-frequency data

Page 9: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

σ is not constantReturn

Conclusion : Nor do returns follow geometric Brownian motionnor is σ constant (not even a smooth function of S and t)

Δ≈Δ−=Δ Δ− dtdS

SrSSr t

ttttt

1)()log()log()(

Page 10: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

“Stilized” experimental facts(i) Returns have nearly no autocorrelation(ii) The autocorrelations of |rt|d decline slowly withincreasing lag. Long memory effect(iii) Leptokurtosis : asset returns have distributionswith fat tails and excess peakedness at the mean(iv) Autocorrelations of sign rt are insignificant(v) Volatility clustering : tendency of large changes to follow large changes and small changes to follow smallchanges. Volatility occurs in bursts.(vi) Volatility is mean-reversing and the distribution isclose to lognormal or inverse gamma(vii) Leverage effect : volatility tends to rise more following a large price fall than following a price rise(viii) Why volatility is important : Uncertainty and riskare the driving factors for investors’ behavior

Page 11: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

3. Volatility as a processWhen the future is uncertain investors are less likely to invest. Therefore uncertainty (volatility) would have to be changing over time.“... build a forecasting model for variance and make it a well-definedprocess ...” (Robert Engle – 1982)Structural model

Conditional variance

Homoscedasticity = variance of errors is constantHeteroscedasticity = variance of errors is not constant

uxxy ++++= ...33221 βββ

termerrorufactors...,, 321 βββ

[ ],..., 2122

−−= tttt uuuEσ

Page 12: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

2. Volatility modelsARCH(q) (Autoregressive conditionally heteroscedastic)

GARCH (1,1) (Generalized ARCH)

IGARCH (Integrated GARCH)Leverage :GJR (Glosten, Jagannathan, Runkle)

EGARCH (exponential GARCH)

11 =+βα

2222

2110

2 ... qtqttt uuu −−− ++++= αααασ

21

2110

2−− ++= ttt u βσαασ

otherwiseuifIuI

tt

tttt

0;01)(

11

21

21110

2

=<=+++=

−−

−−− βσγαασ

⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡−+++=

−− πσ

ασ

γσβωσ 2)ln()ln(2

1

1

21

121

2

t

t

t

ttt

uu

Page 13: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Stochastic volatility modelsIn GARCH models, the conditional volatility is a deterministicfunction of past quantities. In Stochastic Volatility models it isitself a random process.Heston model

Two-time scales model (Perello, Masoliver)

Comte, Renault

W’ is fractional Brownian motion

')()(

0')(20

22 dWdtd

dWdWdWdtSdS

ttt

ttt

γσσσσ

ρσμ

+−Ω−=

<=+=

'')(0''')(

0')(

000000

0

dWdtddWdWdWdtd

dWdWdWedtSdS

tt

ttt

ttt

γξξξγξξξ

ρμ ξ

+−Ω−==+−Ω−=

<=+=

')ln()(ln)(

dWdtkddWdtSdS

tt

ttt

γσθσσμ

+−=+=

Page 14: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

4. The induced volatility processLet logSt be a stochastic process defined on a tensor product probability space Ω⊗Ω’logSt(ω,ω’) with Ω being Wiener space(M1) Then, if logSt(ω,ω’) is square integrable in Ω

for fixed ω’

σt(ω, ω’) is called the “Induced volatility”

(E1) Obtained from the dataσt

2 (·, ω’)≈ var(log St)/(T0 - T1)

(μ=0)

tt

t dBdtS

dS )',()',( ωσμω •+=•

Page 15: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

What does the data suggest for σt ?σt is not self similar

However Rσ(t) is Σ log σ(nδ) = β t + Rσ(t)H ≈ 0.8 - 0.9

E t tt

Hσ σσ

( ) ( )( )

+ − ≠Δ Δ

E R t R tR t

Hσ σ

σ

( ) ( )( )

+ − =Δ Δ

Page 16: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

What does the data suggest for σt ?Recall:If a process Xt has finite variance, stationary increments and is self-similar, thenCov(Xs,, Xt)=(|s|2H+|t| 2H-|s-t| 2H)E(X1

2)(M2) The simplest such process is a zero-mean Gaussian process, Fractional Brownian motion BH

twith long-range dependence for H>1/2Conclusion :log σt = β + (k/δ) ( BH

t - BHt - δ )

σt modeled by a stochastic exponential of fractional noise

Page 17: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

The fractional volatility model (FVM)Two coupled processes :

dSt = μ St dt + σt St dBt

log σt = β + (k/δ) ( BHt - BH

t - δ )

log σt driven by fractional noise, not by fractional Brownian motion

Page 18: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

5. Time scales and pdf’sFrom

log σt is a Gaussian process with mean β and covariance

Then

( ))()(ln δδ

βσ −−+= tBtBkHHt

( )⎥⎥⎦

⎢⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛−−−= H

tktBtBk 2

2

21)()(exp δ

δδ

δθσ

{ }HHH ussuuskus 2222

2

22

),( −−+−++−= δδδ

ψ

( )⎭⎬⎫

⎩⎨⎧ −−= −− 222

2

1 2logexp

21)( HH kk

βσδσπ

σδ

Page 19: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

5. Time scales and pdf’sand for the returns

with

The probability distribution of the returns depends on the observation time scale δ

⎪⎪

⎪⎪

⎪⎪

⎪⎪

Δ

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛Δ⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−

Δ=

Δ+

Δ+2

22

2 22

logexp

21)(log

σ

σμ

πσσ

t

t

t

tS

S

SSp

∫∞

Δ+Δ+ ≅0

)(log)()(logt

t

t

t

SSppd

SSP σδδ σσ

Page 20: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

5. Time scales and pdf’s (NYSE 1973-2000)H=0.83 k=0.59 β= - 5 δ=1 Δ=1

Page 21: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

6. Time scales and pdf’s (NYSE 1973-2000)

Page 22: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

6. Time scales and pdf’s (USD-Euro 05-06 2001)

Page 23: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

6. Time scales and pdf’s (Scaling ??)

Page 24: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

6. Time scales and pdf’s (Scaling ??)

Page 25: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Closed form and return asymptoticsFrom

one obtains

Asymptotic behavior :

( )2

20222

2)(8θ

λδθ β

Δ−Δ=== − rrkCe H

∫∞

Δ=Δ0

))(()())(( rppdrP σδδ σσ

21

log1

1)(1

41))((

2

=

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −−

−Γ

Δ=Δ

z

dzd

CH

zek

rPλ

δ λδθπ

( )2log111))((λ

δ λCerP

Δ≈Δ

Page 26: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Appendix:Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula

Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric Brownian motion defined by

where Wt is a Wiener process with constant drift μ and volatility σ. 2) It is possible to short sell the underlying stock. 3) There are no arbitrage opportunities. 4) Trading in the stock is continuous. 5) There are no transaction costs or taxes. 6) All securities are perfectly divisible (i.e. it is possible to buy any fraction of a share). 7)It is possible to borrow and lend cash at a constant risk-free interest rate. 8) The stock does not pay a dividend

Page 27: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Let V(S,σ) be the value of a call option. By Itō's lemma we have

Now consider a trading strategy under which one holds one optionand continuously trades in the stock in order to hold

shares. At time t, the value of these holdings will be

The composition of this portfolio, called the delta-hedge portfolio, will vary from time-step to time-step. Let R denote the accumulated profit or loss from following this strategy. Then over the time period [t, t + dt], the instantaneous profit or loss is

Substituting dV and dS from the equations above we are left with

Page 28: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

This last equation contains no dW term. That is, it is entirely riskless (delta neutral). Thus, given that there is no arbitrage, the rate of return on this portfolio must be equal to the rate of return on any other riskless instrument. Assuming the risk-free rate of return to be r we must have over the time period [t, t + dt]

If we now insert the expression for П and divide through by dt we obtain the Black–Scholes PDE:

This is the law of evolution of the value of the option. With the assumptions of the Black–Scholes model, this partial differential equation holds whenever V is twice differentiable with respect to Sand once with respect to t.

Page 29: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Solution of the Black-Scholes equationFor a call option the PDE above has the boundary condition

Introduce the change-of-variables

Then the Black–Scholes PDE becomes a diffusion equation

Page 30: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

After some algebra we obtain

where

and Φ is the standard normal cumulative distribution function.The formula for the price of a put option follows from this via put-call parity

)()(),()( tStPTtBKtV +=⋅+

Page 31: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

The Greeks under Black–Scholes:

)()( tVtC = )()( tPtC =

Page 32: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Option pricing in FVM. “Risk-neutral approach”

Page 33: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Option pricing in FVM. “Risk-neutral approach”

Page 34: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Option pricing in FVM. “Risk-neutral approach”

Page 35: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Option pricing in FVM. “Risk-neutral approach”

Page 36: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric
Page 37: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

The option pricing equation in FVM

Page 38: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

The option pricing equation in FVM

Page 39: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

The option pricing equation in FVM

Page 40: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Option pricing in FVM. Numerical solutions

Page 41: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

Option pricing in FVM. Numerical solutions

Page 42: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

The option pricing in FVM. Analytical solution

Page 43: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

10/23/2008

8. Leverage and the fractional calculus interpretation

Page 44: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

10/23/2008

Page 45: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

10/23/2008

Page 46: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

10/23/2008

Fractional Brownian motion and fractional calculus

Page 47: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

10/23/2008

Page 48: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

10/23/2008

Page 49: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

10/23/2008

The fractional calculus interpretation of the FVM

Page 50: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

10/23/2008

Page 51: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric
Page 52: An empirical characterization of the market process · Appendix: Derivation of the Black-Scholes formula Assumptions: 1) The price of the underlying instrument St follows a geometric

ReferencesR V M and M. J. Oliveira; A data-reconstructedfractional volatility model, Economics, discussionpaper 2008-22R V M and M. J. Oliveira; Fractional volatility andoption pricing, arxiv:cond-mat/0404684R. V. M.; The fractional volatility model: An agent-based interpretation, Physica A: Stat. Mech. and Applic. 387 (2008) 3987-3994R. V. M.; A fractional calculus interpretation of the fractional volatility model, Nonlinear Dynamics, doi:10.1007/s11071-008-9372-0