23
1 Regulatory insight 6 November 2017 Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III

Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    5

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

1

Regulatory insight

6 November 2017

Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III

Page 2: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

2

Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview of the treatment of government-related private loans under different regulatory

frameworks. Our focus is on capital requirements for institutional investors who invest in these loans and who are

subject to FTK, Solvency II or Basel III regulations. We discuss the stand-alone capital requirements, but also the impact

of these requirements on the overall balance sheet and solvency position. This provides more insight into the relative

attractiveness of government-related private loans, compared with other asset classes, for institutional investors.

We can conclude that this asset class has potentially a very low capital requirement under the different regulatory

frameworks. Under FTK, the capital requirement is limited due to the underlying government guarantees, which leads

to low expected losses. Under Solvency II and Basel III, almost all government-guaranteed loans are exempted from

capital charges. This makes this asset class attractive from a capital point of view. In addition, the more illiquid nature

of these loans is also translated into additional returns compared to liquid sovereign or credit bonds with a similar

credit quality.

Government-related private loans: an introduction We here consider highly-rated private placements and bonds of predominantly European public entities. A private

placement is a debt agreement between a borrower and a lender, where the loan is not stock exchange listed. Through

a private contract, the debt obligation is acknowledged by the debtor.

Private placements are less liquid than traditional fixed income instruments, but compensate for this with attractive

additional returns. We focus in this article on highly-rated private placements to, or guaranteed by, public agencies,

both in the Netherlands and abroad. Borrowing entities typically include multinational institutions, social housing

associations, hospitals, municipalities and regional authorities. In the Netherlands, the largest lenders are the NWB

Bank1 (which specializes in arranging loans for the Dutch public sector), the Dutch Municipal Bank (BNG)2 and a few

large institutional investors. More recently, private placements via an export credit agency (ECA) have also

experienced an upswing. Examples are Atradius in the Netherlands, Euler-Hermes in Germany or Coface in France.

These ECAs provide trade financing to domestic companies for their international activities and are fully guaranteed

by their respective central governments.

FTK, Solvency II, Basel III Various regulatory frameworks exist for different institutional investors. For example: banks face Basel III regulations,

European insurance companies face Solvency II and Dutch pension funds FTK. Similar to Basel, three distinct “pillars”

are used under FTK and Solvency II in order to structure the regulatory process: (i) capital requirements, (ii) governance

& supervision and (iii) reporting & disclosure. This article focuses on the first pillar (i.e., capital requirements). Capital

requirements can be determined using a standard model approach or using an internal model. We use the standard

model approach in this article.

In practice, capital requirements will vary for different institutional investors due to:

Page 3: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

3

Another risk tolerance (e.g., a 1 in 200 year probability of a negative surplus under Solvency II versus 1 in 40

years under FTK);

Another balance sheet structure (e.g., short funding for property & casualty or health insurers versus long

funding for pension funds and life insurers);

Another historic development over time of the various regulatory frameworks.

We start with an overview of the expected returns used in this article. We then give an overview of the treatment of

government-related private loans for (i) Dutch pension funds (under FTK), (ii) European insurance companies (under

Solvency II) and (iii) banks (under Basel III). We start these sections with a global overview of the required capital

calculation for the entire balance sheet. We then give more information about the stand-alone required capital

calculation for government-related private loans. We conclude with the impact of investing in private loans on the

overall required capital and expected return.

Expected returns The expected returns in this article are according to the latest long-term economic forecasts by Aegon Asset

Management in The Netherlands.3 This forecast is for the period 2018-2021. We use the average expected return over

this four-year period. We consider three scenarios: a base scenario, a positive scenario, and a negative scenario:

In the base scenario, to which we attach a probability of 60%, we expect that economic growth in the US

leads to a tighter job market, resulting in higher wage inflation. This translates into higher price inflation and

gradually increasing interest rates. Higher interest rates will put pressure on corporate profitability due to

higher funding costs. It will also lead to a decline in asset values and a fall in consumer confidence and

spending power. As a result, we expect a minor slowdown of the US economy and a short-lived recession at

some point in the coming years. It seems unlikely that the Eurozone will be able to withstand our predicted

US slowdown. A major recession is, however, not likely, so emergence monetary measures are not expected

from the ECB in the coming years.

In the negative scenario, with a probability of 15%, the economy continues to grow aggressively, leading to

overheating and inflation exceeding the central bank targets. We expect that the Federal Reserve and the

ECB will then increase interest rates to counter high inflation. This fast and abrupt tightening of monetary

conditions will reduce investments, and cause consumer confidence to fall. Also, the combination of higher

corporate leverage and increased interest rates will have a strong effect on the profitability of corporations

which will in turn cause an economic recession around 2020, much more severe than the recession we predict

in our basis scenario.

In the positive scenario, with a probability of 25%, we expect economic momentum to continue until the end

of 2021 due to productivity gains. In this case, we do not foresee a recession during the forecasting period.

Also, inflation will increase but will remain at acceptable levels. This allows central banks to normalize

monetary policy cautiously without imposing negative effects on the economy.

We assume in these economic forecasts that government-related private loans generate an additional return of 0.8%

compared to core Eurozone government bonds.

Page 4: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

4

Capital requirements for Dutch pension funds: FTK

FTK: general capital requirements The set of regulatory rules for Dutch pension funds is commonly referred to as the “Financieel Toetsingskader”

(Financial Assessment Framework) or FTK. Under FTK rules, the solvency capital of a pension fund should be sufficient

to avoid a nominal funding ratio of less than 100% with a probability of 97.5% (i.e., 1 in 40 years) over a one-year

horizon. This risk tolerance has been translated into the following capital requirements.

Table 1: Overview of current FTK stress test parameters4

FTK capital charges

Risk factor Risk event FTK shock

Interest rate risk (S1) 5 Downward/upward interest rate shocks 0.75 (for a 15-year

rate decrease)

Equity risk (S2) 6 Downward shock for developed equity markets 30%

Downward shock for emerging equity markets 40%

Downward shock for private equity 40%

Downward shock for non-listed real estate 15%

Currency risk (S3) 7 Downward currency shock ≈ 15%

Commodity risk (S4) Downward commodity shock 35%

Credit risk (S5) Upward spread shock for AAA rating (Euro gov.) 0%

Upward spread shock for AAA rating 0.6%

Upward spread shock for AA rating 0.8%

Upward spread shock for A rating 1.3%

Upward spread shock for BBB rating 1.8%

Upward spread shock for ≤ BB rating 5.3%

Actuarial risk (S6) Shock for actuarial risk of the liabilities No standard model

Liquidity risk (S7) 8 Shock for liquidity risk (by default 0) No standard model

Concentration risk (S8) Shock for concentration risk (by default 0) No standard model

Operational risk (S9) Shock for operational risk (by default 0) No standard model

Active equity risk (S10) 9 Shock for active equity risk

Formula Dutch

Central Bank

Table 1 summarizes the FTK stress test parameters for each risk factor. It should be noted that there is no prescribed

“recipe” to determine the required capital for actuarial risk, liquidity risk, concentration risk and operational risk (S6 -

S9), but pension funds should hold additional capital for these risks if they are material. Active equity risk (S10) only

applies for active equity portfolios with an ex-ante tracking error larger than 1%. The Dutch Central Bank has indicated

how the S10 shock can be calculated in this case, using a formula which depends on the tracking error and the total

expense ratio.10

The correlations between the risk scenarios are shown below. These correlations are used to aggregate the capital

requirements for the risk scenarios (S1 through S10) and determine the overall capital requirement.

Page 5: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

5

Table 2: Overview of stress test correlations under FTK11

FTK correlations

Correlation Risk factor Risk factor Current FTK

𝜌1 2 Interest rate risk (S1) Equity risk (S2) 0.4

𝜌1 5 Interest rate risk (S1) Credit risk (S5) 0.4

𝜌2 5 Equity risk (S2) Credit risk (S5) 0.5

All correlations which are not mentioned in Table 2 are equal to zero. Note, however, that correlations within the

credit (S5) module are assumed to be 1 (e.g., the correlation between AAA and BBB credit bonds).

The overall required capital can then be calculated, using the strategic weights of the assets. The following “S-formula”

is used for this purpose to determine the total capital requirement:12

As a final step, the available assets in the calculation are increased or decreased until the available capital becomes

equal to the required capital.13 This situation is typically reached in a few iterations. The advantage of this approach

is that the required capital is not depending anymore on the actual funding ratio of the pension fund. The required

capital thus becomes a measure for the strategic risk profile of the pension fund, when the available capital equals

the required capital.

FTK: capital requirements for government-related private loans

Government-related private loans must be treated using the credit risk module (the S5 stress test in Table 1) under

FTK. In this case, the applied spread shock depends on the rating. Note that we cannot apply a spread charge of zero

for the AAA government-guaranteed loans. A zero spread charge is only applicable for AAA euro sovereign debt, not

for debt guaranteed by AAA-rated euro member states.

An AAA-rated private loan thus receives an upward spread shock of 0.6%, whereas a BBB-rated private loan will receive

a spread shock of 1.8%. An example is given in Table 3 for a typical mandate for government-related private loans.14

This table shows that most private loans for this example have an AAA rating, followed by AA. No investments in

ratings below BBB are allowed in this mandate. This is an attractive feature from an FTK perspective, due to the severe

stress test for ratings below BBB (a 530 basis points spread increase).

Table 3: Breakdown of the FTK capital requirement for an example mandate of government-rated private loans

In the last column of Table 4 we shown the contribution of each rating class to the total capital requirement for this

example mandate. The securities with an AAA rating contribute most to the overall capital charge, due to the high

weight for this rating class.

Rating  Weight Spread shock Spread duration Capital charge

AAA 83.9% 0.6% 8.6 3.9%

AA 16.1% 0.8% 5.5 0.7%

Total 100% 8.1 4.7%

Page 6: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

6

Note that the interest rate sensitivity should also be taken into account under FTK, using the S1 stress test in Table 1.

On the total balance sheet of a pension fund, the interest rate sensitivity of these loans will, however, offset part of

the interest rate sensitivity of the liabilities. The overall effect on the capital requirements is thus positive.

FTK: impact of government-related private loans on overall required capital

As an example, consider a pension fund with €10bn assets and liabilities. The stylized asset mix is as follows:15

50% in equities (developed): required capital (equity risk) is 30%

35% in AAA/AA euro sovereign bonds (duration of 7.5 years): required capital (spread risk) is ≈ 1%16

15% in investment grade euro credit bonds (duration of 4.5 years): required capital (spread risk) is ≈ 9%

We assume for simplicity that interest rate risk and currency risk are hedged on the balance sheet; these risks

therefore do not lead to additional capital charges in this example.17,18 Note that we only have two (relevant) market

risks in this example: equity risk and spread risk. Equity and spread risk have a correlation of 0.5, see Table 3. The

required capital for market risk then becomes €1.592bn.19 For this pension fund, we can now easily calculate the

overall required capital using the “S-formula”. When we assume that the required capital for actuarial risk (the S6

component) is equal to €0.25bn, the overall required capital becomes equal to €1.611bn.20

As the final step, we change the total amount of assets in the calculation until the available capital becomes equal to

the required capital. In the first iteration, we set the available capital equal to the required capital by increasing the

total asset value from €10bn to €11.611bn. The asset mix is kept constant (50% equities, 35% sovereigns and 15%

credits). If we recalculate the required capital, we then arrive at €1.865bn. We subsequently increase the total asset

value to €11.865bn, which leads to a required capital of €1.905bn. By repeating this approach a few more times, the

required capital converges to €1.913bn.

We can now investigate the effect of adding government-related private loans to the asset mix. As mentioned above,

the required capital for this asset class is calculated in the spread risk (S5) module. As an example, we consider the

example government-related private loan mandate that has been discussed in the previous section. The required

capital for spread risk is thus 4.7%.

We allocate 10% of the assets to government-related private loans and study the effect on capital requirements and

expected return. The results are shown in Table 4.

Page 7: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

7

Table 4: FTK - Impact on required capital, required funding ratio and expected return when allocating assets to government-related private loans

Table 4 shows that the required capital increases only slightly (from €1.913 to €1.943bn, so by 2%) when we sell

sovereigns and buy government-related private loans. When we sell credits and buy government-related private loans,

the required capital decreases by 2%. Funding from all other asset categories also leads to a substantial (10%) decrease

in the required capital. An even stronger effect is visible by substituting equities with government-related private

loans. This is due to the low risk charge for this asset class (4.7%, instead of 30% for developed market equities). Similar

effects are visible in terms of the required funding ratio.

Comparing the expected return for the different portfolios, we see a positive effect (of ≈ 0.04% - 0.08%) in the base

scenario when substituting sovereigns or credits with government-related private loans. Substituting equities with

government-related private loans leads to a decreasing expected return in the base or positive scenario, but also a

much lower required capital, as mentioned above. Funding from all asset categories leads to results falling somewhere

in between.

FTK: conclusions

The required capital for spread risk is limited for government-related private loans under FTK (≈ 4.7%). The main

reason is that these loans are backed up by the government, leading to low expected losses. The overall required

capital under FTK therefore decreases if government-related private loans are funded from credits or other (risky)

assets. At the same time, the expected return will typically increase when we invest in government-related private

loans and use sovereigns or credits as funding, making an investment in this asset class also attractive from a return

perspective. Table 5 gives a schematic overview of these findings. Government-related private loans are thus clearly

an attractive alternative for sovereign bonds or credits.

Page 8: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

8

Table 5: Stylized overview of FTK results21

We now turn our attention to the capital requirements for government-related private loans for European insurance

companies under Solvency II.

Capital requirements for European insurance companies: Solvency II

Solvency II: general capital requirements22,23

As of January 1, 2016, Solvency II is the supervisory framework for European insurance companies. Under Solvency

II, the required capital is the amount of capital that an insurance company should hold to be able to withstand a

severe stress scenario (occurring once every 200 years). The required capital is equal to the basic solvency capital

requirement (BSCR) plus the required capital for operational risk (Op) and an adjustment for the loss absorbing

effect of technical provisions and deferred taxes (Adj), see Figure 1.

Figure 1: Structure of the overall required capital calculation24

The BSCR is the solvency capital requirement before any adjustments and combines the capital requirements for six

major risk categories. Note that these risk categories are typically broken down into more categories (e.g. market risk

is sub-divided into interest rate risk, equity risk, property risk, etc.).

Page 9: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

9

The capital charges associated with each of these risks are combined using a correlation matrix, which is prescribed

under Solvency II.25 The purpose of this correlation matrix is to produce an adequate overall capital charge for a one-

year time horizon. In practice, the correlation between the different components of the BSCR is assumed to be small.

For example, the probability of a (1 in 200 year) tail event occurring simultaneously for market risk and life risk is

assumed to be quite low (a correlation of only 0.25).

Due to the low correlation between the major risk categories it is possible to achieve a significantly lower required

capital by diversifying risk. Mortgages are in fact a very good required capital diversifier, because this asset class falls

under the counterparty default risk module instead of the market risk module. Market risk typically contributes heavily

to the overall required capital, whereas the contribution of default risk is much smaller.26 It therefore pays to transfer

risk from market risk to default risk in order to better exploit the low correlation (of 0.25) between these modules. An

example of this approach is given in Van Bragt (2017).

Solvency II: Capital charge for private loans without a government guarantee

The Solvency II capital charge for spread risk for private loans without a government guarantee is depending on the

rating and the (spread) duration, see Table 6 below.27,28

Table 6: Spread risk factors for bonds under Solvency II.

N.B. A credit quality step of 0 corresponds to an S&P AAA rating; 1 corresponds to AA; 2 to A; 3 to BBB; 4 to BB; 5 to B and 6 to CCC or lower.

As an example, we consider a private loan portfolio with 70% AAA-rated loans and 30% AA-rated loans. When

available, the instrument’s rating is based on the assessment of a credit rating agency. When an instrument does not

have a credit rating, a rating will be determined using an internal rating methodology.29 The (spread) duration of the

loans in this example portfolio is approximately 7. The capital charge (for spread risk) for AAA-rated loans is thus

4.5% + 0.5%*(7-5) = 5.5%, see Figure 2 (use a credit quality step of 0 for AAA). For the AA-rated loans the capital charge

is 5.5% + 0.6%*(7-5) = 6.7% (use a credit quality step of 1 for AA). This implies a capital charge of the entire portfolio

of 70%*5.5% + 30%*6.7% = 5.9%.

Page 10: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

10

Solvency II: Capital charge for private loans with a government guarantee

Private loans with a government guarantee are typically exempted from a (spread) capital charge. To be precise, no

capital requirement for spread risk applies to loans by or demonstrably guaranteed by:30

1. The national government of a state of the European Economic Area (EEA), issued in the currency of the

government;

2. A multilateral development bank, such as the European Investment Bank or the European Investment Fund;31

3. An international organization, such as the European Union, the International Monetary Fund, the Bank for

International Settlements, the European Financial Stability Facility, or the European Stability Mechanism;32

4. The European Central Bank.

To qualify for a zero spread shock, a guarantee by one of the above counterparties should be fully, unconditionally

and irrevocably. Government-backed loans by credit export agencies are also exempted from a spread capital charge.33

In addition, EIOPA has published a list of regional governments and local authorities, exposures to whom are to be

treated as exposures to the central government of the jurisdiction in which they are established.34 For example, for

the Netherlands, any province, water board or municipality is on this list.35 These direct exposures are capital

exempted. However, loans guaranteed by these regional governments and local authorities, so indirect exposures, are

not exempted from a capital charge.36

Loans that are guaranteed by so-called “guarantee funds” are capital exempted when loans are fully, unconditionally

and irrevocably guaranteed by the central government.37 Two important guarantee funds in the Netherlands are the

Stichting Waarborgfonds voor de Zorgsector (“WFZ”) and the Stichting Waarborgfonds Sociale Woningbouw (“WSW”).

The WFZ fund provides loans for the health sector and is fully guaranteed by the central Dutch government. WFZ loans

can thus be treated as solvency free (in the spread risk module) under Solvency II. The WSW fund provides loans for

the social housing sector and is partly guaranteed by the central Dutch government and partly by the decentralized

government (municipalities). In the Netherlands, this has led to an interesting discussion related to the particular

guarantee structure of the WSW fund, see the boxed text below.

Page 11: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

11

Solvency II: impact of government-related private loans on overall required capital

As an example, let’s consider a life insurer who has invested €10 bln. The asset mix is as follows:

10% in Dutch mortgages: SCR (default risk) is ≈ 5%38

20% in equities (developed): required capital (equity risk) is ≈ 39%39¸40

30% in core euro sovereign bonds: required capital (spread risk) is 0%41

40% in A/BBB-rated euro credit bonds (duration of 4.5 years): required capital (spread risk) is ≈ 9%42

We now study the effect of adding government-related private loans to the asset mix of this insurer. Our example

private loan portfolio has an SCR of ≈0.5%.43 The slightly positive SCR is be caused by an investment in a loan

guaranteed by a municipality. Such an indirect exposure to a local government is not solvency free, as we discussed

above. Note that without guarantees the capital charge for our example portfolio would be much higher (≈6%). The

underlying guarantees thus dramatically reduce the SCR.

Which guaranty matters most? The case of WSW.

In the Netherlands, the Stichting Waarborgfonds Sociale Woningbouw ("WSW") backs up private loans to social

housing corporations. This entity is guaranteed for 50% by the central government and for 50% by municipalities.

Since only the guarantee of the central governments ‘counts’ under Solvency II, and this guarantee is not fully,

one could argue that these loans are not exempted from a spread charge under Solvency II.

However, the central government of the Netherlands (hereafter: the “State”) will ultimately (i.e. in the course of

time) have to act as effectively the complete back-stop for the loans guaranteed by WSW. After all, the State will

have to continue issuing interest-free loans each month for 50% of WSW's liquidity deficit, until the deficit is

removed at WSW, and irrespective of whether the municipalities have (also) issued interest-free loans to WSW in

that regard.

So, even if the municipalities were not issuing any interest-free loans to WSW - whether or not in breach of their

contractual obligations - the State would still be under an ongoing obligation to keep issuing interest-free loans

for half of WSW's liquidity deficit each month, until the deficit has been halved so often (on a monthly basis) by

the State that the liquidity problem has actually been solved. WSW states that, based on this line of reasoning,

DNB has decided that WSW loans can be treated as solvency free (in the spread risk module) under Solvency II

(see WSW, 2016).

Note that, in principle, the State can almost, but never entirely, cancel a liquidity deficit; after all, a monetary

amount can never be halved to zero. For example, let assume the WSW runs a deficit of 10 mln. Euro. The State

and the municipalities should then both issue 5 mln. Euro of interest-free loans. If the municipalities do not

provide this funding, the remaining deficit will then be 5 mln. Euro one month later. The State then again funds

50% (2.5 mln. Euro). If the municipalities again do no provide funding, the remaining deficit will become 2.5 mln.

Euro, and so on.

Source: Legal opinion by Van Doorne (2015) on this matter, as requested by WSW.

Page 12: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

12

In the analysis, interest rate risk is assumed to be fully hedged with an interest rate swap overlay, so the SCR for

interest rate risk is equal to 0. All assets and liabilities are assumed to be denominated in euros, so the SCR for currency

risk is 0. The assets are assumed to be well spread over different counterparties, so the SCR for concentration risk is

also 0. We can now calculate the total SCR for market risk, using the correlation matrix in Table 7.

Table 7: Correlation matrix for the market risk SCR calculation44,45

Note that we only have two (relevant) market risks in this example: equity risk and spread risk. Within the market risk

module, equity risk and spread risk have a correlation of 0.75. The SCR for market risk thus becomes €1.077 bln.46 The

SCR for default risk, due to the exposure to mortgages, is equal to €10 bln.*0.1*0.05=€0.05 bln. Assume also that the

SCR for life underwriting risk is equal to €0.35 bln.47 Neglecting operational risk and the loss absorbing capacity of

technical provisions and deferred taxes, the overall required capital then becomes €1.228 bln.

As an example, we allocate 10% of the assets to government-related private loans and study the effect on capital

requirements and expected return. The results are shown in Table 8.

Page 13: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

13

Table 8: Solvency II - Impact on required capital, solvency ratio and expected return when allocating assets to

government-related private loans48

Table 8 shows that when we sell sovereigns and buy government-related private loans, the required capital remains

almost the same. We have only a slight increase due to the solvency charge of 0.5% for government-related private

loans. When funding government-related private loans with mortgages, the required capital decreases slightly (with

1%). When we sell credits and buy private loans, the required capital decreases more significantly (with 6%). This is

due to the low risk charge for private loans in our example (0.5%, instead of 9% for credits). Funding private loans

from all asset categories also leads to a substantial (8%) decrease. An even stronger effect is visible by substituting

equities with private loans.

Comparing the expected return for the different portfolios in Table 8, we see a positive effect (of 0.08%) when funding

private loans from sovereigns. When we substitute credits by private loans, a positive effect is visible in the baseline

and negative scenario, but a negative effect for the positive scenario. When we substitute mortgages by private loans,

the expected return decreases, however. Funding private loans from all assets also leads to a slight decrease of the

expected return (but this also leads to a much lower required capital, as mentioned above). When funding from

equities, both the required capital and the expected return decrease significantly. We can thus conclude that

government-related private loans are particularly attractive as an alternative for sovereign or credit portfolios.

Solvency II: conclusions

Investing in government-related private loans can lead to a significantly lower Solvency II capital charge, due to the

underlying guarantees. In our example, the overall solvency charge only increases (very slightly) if private loans are

funded from euro sovereign bonds, which are not subject to a Solvency II credit risk charge. When private loans are

funded from other asset classes, the solvency charge will typically decrease substantially. From a return point of view,

government-related private loans are particularly attractive as an alternative for sovereign or credit portfolios. Table

9 sets out a stylized overview of these results.

Page 14: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

14

Table 9: Stylized overview of Solvency II results49

We now turn our attention to the capital requirements for government-related private loans for banks under Basel III.

Capital requirements for banks: Basel III

Basel III: general capital requirements50 Basel III is the third of the Basel Accords. Basel III is currently being phased in as the leading global regulatory

framework for banks. In response to the last financial crisis, Basel III has stepped up the capital requirements and

introduced additional limits on leverage and liquidity ratios.51

Full implementation of the Basel III accords has been delayed several times and is currently expected in 2019.52 In the

meantime, work is already underway on the successor to Basel III, Basel IV. We focus here on the current EU capital

requirements under Basel III.53 Note also that the capital requirements for banks are sometimes adopted in other

regulatory frameworks as well. For example, the Basel II credit risk approach has also been incorporated into the Swiss

Solvency Test (SST) for Swiss insurance companies.54

The capital adequacy ratio (CAR) of a bank is equal to the ratio of the total capital and the total risk-weighted assets

(RWA). The CAR must be higher than 10.5% according to the Pillar 1 requirements when Basel III is fully implemented

in 2019.55 Total capital is defined as Tier 1 plus Tier 2 capital. Tier 1 capital is the core capital of a bank, which includes

equity capital and disclosed reserves. Tier 2 capital consists of supplementary capital, like subordinated debt, and is

used to absorb losses in a case of a bankruptcy.

A bank can also be required to hold more capital as a result of the Supervisory Review and Evaluation Process (SREP),

as conducted by supervisor (the ECB). The SREP is tailored to the individual bank. In the SREP decision, the supervisor

may ask the bank to hold additional capital and/or set qualitative requirements (usually referred to as “Pillar 2”). The

latter could refer to the bank’s governance structure or its management.56 A bank can, of course, also hold an

additional buffer to ensure that the regulatory limit will not be breached.

In the remainder of this section, we neglect the impact of market and operational risk and focus on the impact of

credit risk on total RWA. The definition of the risk weights for credit risk for various assets is given in CRD IV / CRR

(2013).57 A short overview for the main asset classes is provided in the table below.

Page 15: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

15

Table 10: Overview of risk weights for credit risk for various assets under Basel III58

Note that the above risk weights apply for exposures to rated counterparties.

The risk weights for credit risk for government-related private loans are discussed in more detail in the next section.

Basel III: capital requirements for government-related private loans

We first consider direct exposures to government-related entities. The following government-related counterparties

are treated favorably under Basel III regulations:

Exposures to EU member states' central governments and central banks

These exposures are assigned a risk weight of 0% if they are denominated and funded in their domestic

currency.59

Exposures to multilateral development banks

Exposures to the following counterparties are assigned a risk weight of 0%: the World Bank Group - comprised

of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) and the International Finance

Corporation - the Inter-American Development Bank, the Asian Development Bank, the African Development

Bank, the Council of Europe Development Bank, the Nordic Investment Bank, the Caribbean Development

Bank, the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD), the European Investment Bank (EIB),

the European Investment Fund, the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency, the International Finance

Facility for Immunisation and the Islamic Development Bank.60

Exposures to international organizations

Exposures to the following international organizations are also assigned a risk weight of 0%: the European

Union, the International Monetary Fund, the Bank for International Settlements, the European Financial

Stability Facility and the European Stability Mechanism.61

Exposures to regional governments and local authorities

For exposures to regional governments and local authorities, the standard risk weight is 20%.62 But, if there

is no difference in exposure between local/regional and central government exposure, the local/regional

exposure can benefit from the 0% risk weight of the member state. The European Banking Association (EBA)

has produced a list disclosing this possibility for all member states. A short summary of this list is given in the

table below.

Page 16: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

16

Table 11: Overview of regional governments and local authorities (per country) which qualify for a 0% risk weight under Basel III63

Note that not all EU member states are on this list. For example, regional governments or local authorities in

France do not qualify for this list.

We now consider indirect exposures (i.e., exposures guaranteed by a third party). Under Basel III, risk mitigation

techniques fall into different categories, and each has its special requirements. The main distinction is between

“funded” and “unfunded” credit protection. Funded risk protection describes the case of transfer of property on

certain assets or collateral after a credit event. The unfunded risk protection comes from the existence of a third

party’s obligation to pay an amount in case of a specified credit event. We here consider exposures of the unfunded

type.

To effectively reduce risk, a guaranty must be eligible and meet some requirements before being taken into account.

Eligible protection providers include, among others, central and regional governments, local authorities, multilateral

development banks, international organizations (with a risk weight of 0%) and public sector entities.64 The guaranty

must however meet a number of conditions to be eligible. The main conditions are:65

the guarantee provides a direct protection;

the extent of credit protection is clearly defined and incontrovertible;

the guarantee does not contains any clause to reduce the extent of the guaranty (cancel protection, increase

cost of protection in case of a deterioration of credit, reduction of guaranty maturity);

the guarantee is legally effective and enforceable in all relevant jurisdictions.

To reduce the risk weight, the guarantor needs to have a reduced risk weight, for instance 0%. For the guaranteed

part of the loan, the risk weight of the guarantor applies, for the remaining part the risk weight of the obligor applies.

Note that partial guarantees are thus also accommodated under Basel III. This is another approach than under

Solvency II, where only full guarantees are acknowledged.

Table 12 gives some example of government-guaranteed loans which qualify for a 0% risk weight under Basel III.

Page 17: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

17

Table 12: Overview of government-guaranteed loans which qualify for a 0% risk weight under Basel III66

Basel III: impact of government-related private loans on overall required capital

As an example, consider a bank with €10bn assets and a total (Tier 1 plus Tier 2) capital of €0.6bn. The asset mix is as

follows:

10% in cash: risk weight is 0%; required capital (credit risk) is 0%

30% in mortgages: risk weight is ≈ 20%; required capital (credit risk) is ≈ 2.1%67

20% in short-term lending to investment grade banks: risk weight is 20%; required capital (credit risk) is 2.1%

10% in core euro sovereign bonds (rating ≈ AAA/AA): risk weight is 0%; required capital (credit risk) is 0%

30% in commercial loans to midsized companies (rating ≈ BBB/BB): risk weight is 100%; required capital

(credit risk) is 10.5%

We assume for simplicity that market risk and operational risk do not lead to additional capital charges. We can then

easily calculate the overall required capital and RWA by adding up the individual required capital and RWA numbers

for all assets. The overall required capital then becomes €0.42bn and the overall RWA becomes €4.0bn. With a total

capital of €0.6bn, this means that the capital adequacy ratio is equal to 15%.

We can now investigate the effect of adding government-related private loans to the balance sheet. All private loans

in our example mandate match the characteristics in Table 12.68 The risk weight of this mandate is thus equal to 0%.

As an example, we allocate 10% to government-related private loans and study the effect on the capital requirements

and expected return. Table 13 shows the results.

Page 18: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

18

Table 13: Basel III - Impact on required capital, risk-weighted assets, capital adequacy ratio and expected return when allocating assets to

government-related private loans 69

This table shows that the required capital decreases significantly (by 5-25%) when funding government-related private

loans from risky asset classes. Similar effects are visible in terms of the capital adequacy ratio. Government-related

loans can thus be used to free up capital on the balance sheet (if needed).

Comparing the expected return for the different portfolios, the added value of government-related private loans is

mixed. We mainly see a positive effect when adding government-related private loans at the expense of sovereigns.

In practice, banks will, however, probably hold on to their sovereign portfolios to keep enough liquid funds, so a major

switch from sovereigns to less liquid private loans is unlikely to be practical. Switching to private loans would also have

a negative effect of the net stable funding ratio. In the negative scenario, the government-related loans work well, by

giving the protection of government guarantees and providing an additional spread over sovereigns.

Basel III: conclusions

Government-related private loans do not require capital under Basel III and are thus an attractive asset class if capital

needs to be freed up. Looking at expected returns, the picture is more mixed. The limited liquidity of these loans is

also a point of attention under Basel III. See the stylized results in Table 14 for an overview.

Page 19: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

19

Table 14: Stylized overview of Basel III results70

Overall conclusions The required capital for spread risk is limited for government-related private loans under FTK. The main reason is that

these loans are backed up by the government, leading to low expected losses. The overall required capital under FTK

therefore decreases if government-related private loans are funded from credits or other (risky) assets. At the same

time, the expected return will typically increase when we invest in government-related private loans and use

sovereigns or credits as funding, making an investment in this asset class also attractive from a return perspective.

Investing in government-related private loans can lead to a Solvency II capital charge close to zero, due to the

underlying guarantees. When private loans are funded from more risky classes, the Solvency II charge will therefore

also decrease substantially. From a return point of view, government-related private loans are again particularly

attractive as an alternative for sovereign or credit portfolios.

Government-related private loans typically do not require capital under Basel III and are thus an attractive asset class

if capital needs to be freed up. Looking at expected returns, the picture is more mixed. The limited liquidity of these

loans is also a point of attention under Basel III.

Page 20: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

20

References

Basel (2013), Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, “Basel III Phase-In Arrangements”. Available at

http://www.bis.org/bcbs/basel3/basel3_phase_in_arrangements.pdf.

Basel (2015), Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, “Revisions to the Standardised Approach for Credit Risk -

Second Consultative Document”, December 2015. Available at http://www.bis.org/bcbs/publ/d347.pdf.

CRD IV / CRR (2013), Capital Requirement Directive (CRD IV) and Capital Requirements Regulation (CRR), “Regulation

(EU) No 575/2013 of the European Parliament and of the Council of 26 June 2013 on Prudential Requirements for

Credit Institutions and Investment Firms and Amending Regulation (EU) No 648/2012”, Official Journal of the

European Union, L 176, Volume 56, 27 June 2013. Available at http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-

content/EN/ALL/?uri=OJ:L:2013:176:TOC.

EIOPA (2011), “EIOPA Report on the Fifth Quantitative Impact Study (QIS5) for Solvency II”, Report EIOPA-TFQIS5-

11/001, 14 March 2011, Graph 35, p. 67. Available at

https://eiopa.europa.eu/Publications/Reports/QIS5_Report_Final.pdf.

EIOPA (2014), “Technical Specification for the Preparatory Phase (Part I)”, Report EIOPA-14/209, 30 April 2014, p.

120. Available at https://eiopa.europa.eu/Publications/Standards/A_-

_Technical_Specification_for_the_Preparatory_Phase__Part_I_.pdf.

EU (2015), “Commission Delegated Regulation (EU) 2015/35 of 10 October 2014 supplementing Directive

2009/138/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council on the taking-up and pursuit of the business of

Insurance and Reinsurance (Solvency II)”, Official Journal of the European Union, January 17 2015. Available at

http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=uriserv%3AOJ.L_.2015.012.01.0001.01.ENG.

EY (2016), “CRD V/CRR II - Revisions to the Capital Requirement Directive and the Capital Requirement Regulation”,

December 2016. Available at

http://www.ey.com/Publication/vwLUAssets/CRD_CRR/$FILE/CRD%20CRR%20Revisions%20Dec%202016%20appro

ved%20for%20external%20distribution%20121216.pdf.

Van Bragt, D. (2017), “Capital Requirements for Mortgage Loan Investments under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III”,

Regulatory Insight, Aegon Asset Management. Available at

https://www.aegonassetmanagement.com/globalassets/asset-management/netherlands/news-

insights/documents/2017/regulatory-insight-supervision-mortgage-investments.pdf.

Page 21: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

21

About the authors

This article is written by David van Bragt of Aegon Asset Management and Rémi Lamaud of La Banque Postale Asset

Management (LBPAM). Aegon Asset Management and LBPAM have a strategic, long-term partnership to jointly

develop and sell investment products. LBPAM is France's fifth largest asset manager.

David van Bragt is a senior consultant in the Investment Solutions team at Aegon Asset Management. Rémi Lamaud

is Head of Regulation and ALM at LBPAM. The authors advise institutional investors about ALM, LDI, risk

management and regulatory developments.

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank Gerard Moerman, Eddo van den Bogaard, Hendrik Tuch and Niek Swagers for their

useful suggestions when preparing this article.

More information

Sander van der Wel, Head of Financial Institutions

Aegon Asset Management Netherlands

T. + 31 (0)6 19 30 33 32

E. [email protected]

Frank Drukker, Sr. Business Development Director

Aegon Asset Management Netherlands

T. + 31 (0)6 10 13 28 25

E. [email protected]

Disclaimer Aegon Investment Management B.V. is registered with the Netherlands Authority for the Financial Markets as a licensed fund management

company. On the basis of its fund management license Aegon Investment Management B.V. is also authorized to provide individual portfolio

management and advisory services.

The content of this document is for information purposes only and should not be considered as a commercial offer, business proposal or

recommendation to perform investments in securities, funds or other products. All prices, market indications or financial data are for illustration

purposes only.

Although this information is composed with great care and although we always strive to ensure accuracy, completeness and correctness of the

information, imperfections due to human errors may occur, as a result of which presented data and calculations may differ. Therefore, no rights

may be derived from the provided data and calculations.

Page 22: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

22

1 In Dutch, NWB stands for Nederlandse Waterschapsbank. 2 In Dutch, BNG stands for Bank Nederlandse Gemeenten. 3 See https://www.aegonassetmanagement.com/en/netherlands/news-and-insights/long-term-scenarios-2018---2021/ for more information. 4 See http://www.toezicht.dnb.nl/en/2/51-202138.jsp for a detailed specification of the standard required capital calculation under FTK. 5 The S1 capital charge is calculated according to a (multiplication) factor for each maturity, e.g. the multiplication factor for a 15-year interest rate decrease is 0.75. 6 The S2 capital charge is calculated according to a correlation matrix for all (4) types of equity. 7 The S3 capital charge is calculated according to a correlation matrix for all open currency positions. 8 The S7, S8 and S9 capital charges are by default 0 but should be added when these risks are substantial. 9 The S10 capital charge for active equity portfolios can be calculated using the tracking error and total expense ratio. 10 See http://www.toezicht.dnb.nl/en/3/51-232413.jsp. 11 See http://www.toezicht.dnb.nl/en/2/51-202138.jsp. 12 See http://www.toezicht.dnb.nl/en/2/51-202138.jsp. 13 See http://www.toezicht.dnb.nl/en/3/51-232925.jsp. 14 We use the AEAM Government Related Investment Fund of Aegon Asset Management as our reference portfolio here. 15 This example is based on data for all Dutch pension funds. See https://www.dnb.nl/statistiek/statistieken-dnb/financiele-instellingen/pensioenfondsen/toezichtgegevens-pensioenfondsen/index.jsp for the underlying data. 16 With 85% AAA-rated sovereigns (with a capital charge of 0) and 15% AA-rated sovereigns. 17 Most Dutch pension funds only partially hedge the interest rate risk on their balance sheet. The overall required capital will thus typically be higher in practice. Replacing credits or equities with private loans could also require additional interest rate hedging, due to the higher interest rate sensitivity of our example private loan portfolio. 18 For simplicity, transaction costs, management fees and additional hedging costs are not considered in this article, although they may be important in practice. 19 The required capital for market risk is, in this example, equal to

√(𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦2 + 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑

2 + 2 ∗ 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦,𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 ∗ 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦 ∗ 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑). 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦 is here €10bn*0.5*0.3=€1.5bn; 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 is

€10bn*(0.35*0.01+0.15*0.09)=€0.17bn and 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦,𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 is 0.5.

20 The required capital is, in this example, equal to √(𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑚𝑎𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑡2 + 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑙𝑖𝑓𝑒

2 + 2 ∗ 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑚𝑎𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑡,𝑙𝑖𝑓𝑒 ∗ 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑚𝑎𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑡 ∗ 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑙𝑖𝑓𝑒). 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑚𝑎𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑡 is here

€1.592bn; 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑙𝑖𝑓𝑒 is €0.25bn and 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑚𝑎𝑟𝑘𝑒𝑡,𝑙𝑖𝑓𝑒 is 0.

21 This table is a highly stylized version of the results in Table 4. Please refer to Table 4 for the quantitative results. 22 See EIOPA (2014) and EU (2015) for a detailed specification of the standard required capital calculation under Solvency II. 23 This section has been published earlier in Van Bragt (2017). 24 See EIOPA (2014), p. 121. 25 See EIOPA (2014), p. 126. 26 See for example typical (average) numbers for life insurers from the QIS-5 impact study for Solvency II. See EIOPA (2011), graph 35, p. 67. 27 EU (2015a), Article 176/2. 28 We do not consider the impact of interest rate risk under Solvency II in this article. In general, private loans offset part of the interest rate risk of the liabilities for a life insurer, leading to a lower capital charge compared to a cash investment. The opposite effect occurs for an insurer with short-dated liabilities (like a health or property & casualty insurer), leading to a higher capital charge compared to a cash investment. 29 Insurers that use internal models can use internal credit ratings to assess the capital requirements of unrated instruments under Solvency II. The regulator should, however, give approval of the internal credit rating processes and the governance surrounding them. 30 EU (2015a), Article 180/2. 31 EU (2013), Article 117/2. 32 EU (2013), Article 118. 33 EU (2015a), Article 215. 34 EU (2015b), Article 1. 35 Dutch water boards (in Dutch: “waterschappen” or “hoogheemraadschappen”) are regional government bodies charged with managing water barriers, waterways, water levels, water quality and sewage treatment in their respective regions. 36 See http://www.toezicht.dnb.nl/3/50-234971.jsp for more background information (in Dutch). 37 See http://www.toezicht.dnb.nl/3/50-234971.jsp for more information (in Dutch). 38 For See Van Bragt (2017). 39 For simplicity, we here ignore the symmetric adjustment mechanism. This mechanism increases the magnitude of the equity shock in case of an upward equity market (and vice versa). 40 The average allocation to equities is ≈ 5-10% for a typical European insurer, so this is an example of a more aggressive asset allocation. 41 EU (2015), Article 169(1).

Page 23: Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK ... · Analysis of government-related private loans under FTK, Solvency II and Basel III In this article we give an overview

23

42 EU (2015), Article 176(2). 43 We use the AEAM Government Related Investment Fund of Aegon Asset Management as our reference portfolio here. 44 Source: EIOPA (2014), p. 158. 45 The factor A in Figure 3 is 0 in case of an interest rate increase and 0.5 in case of an interest rate decrease.

46 The SCR for market risk is, in this example, equal to √(𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦2 + 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑

2 + 2 ∗ 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦,𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 ∗ 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦 ∗ 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑).

𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦 is here €10 bln.*0.2*0.39=€0.78 bln.; 𝑆𝐶𝑅𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 is €10 bln.*0.4*0.09=€0.36 bln. and 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟𝑒𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑒𝑞𝑢𝑖𝑡𝑦,𝑠𝑝𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑑 is 0.75.

47 Based on typical (average) numbers for life insurers. See: EIOPA (2011), graph 35, p. 67. 48 Expected returns for the period 2018-2021 according to the latest long-term economic scenario forecast by Aegon Asset Management. 49 This table is a highly stylized version of the results in Table 8. Please refer to Table 8 for the quantitative results. 50 See CRD IV / CRR (2013) for a detailed specification of the standard capital requirements under Basel III. 51 The so-called liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) and the net stable funding ratio (NSFR). 52 See Basel (2013) for more details about the Basel III phase-in arrangements up to 2019. 53 As specified in CRD IV /CRR (2013). Proposals by the European Commission to amend CRD IV/CRR (2013) in line with the final Basel III regulations are summarized in EY (2016). 54 See https://www.finma.ch/FinmaArchiv/bpv/download/e/SST_techDok_061002_E_wo_Li_20070118.pdf for more details. 55 See CRD IV / CRR (2013), Article 92. The common equity Tier 1 ratio should at least be 4.5% and the total Tier 1 capital ratio should at least be 6%. The total (Tier 1 plus Tier 2) capital ratio should at least be 8%. An additional capital conservation buffer of 2.5% is currently phased in and should be available in 2019. 56 See https://www.bankingsupervision.europa.eu/about/ssmexplained/html/srep.en.html for more information about the SREP.

57 See also Basel (2015) for the latest proposals with respect to the risk weights. 58 See CRD IV / CRR (2013). 59 See CRD IV / CRR (2013), Article 114(5). 60 See CRD IV / CRR (2013), Article 117. 61 See CRD IV / CRR (2013), Article 118. 62 See CRD IV / CRR (2013), Article 115(5). 63 See https://www.eba.europa.eu/-/eba-publishes-lists-for-the-calculation-of-capital-requirements-for-credit-risk. 64 See CRD IV / CRR (2013), Article 201. 65 See CRD IV / CRR (2013), Articles 213 and 215. 66 See CRD IV / CRR (2013. 67 See Van Bragt (2017) for more details about the mortgage portfolio used here. 68 We use the AEAM Government Related Investment Fund of Aegon Asset Management as our reference portfolio here. 69 Expected returns for bank loans are based on the expected money market rate for the period 2018-2021. Expected returns for commercial loans are based on the expected return for European investment grade credit bonds for the period 2018-2021 plus an additional spread of 0.85%. 70 This table is a highly stylized version of the results in Table 13. Please refer to Table 13 for the quantitative results.