Art Ingles2

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    1/24

    VICENTE ROYUELA and JORDI SURIN ACH

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND

    URBAN SIZE

    (Accepted 20 December 2004)

    ABSTRACT. Do cities have an optimal size? In seeking to answer this question,

    various theories, including Optimal City Size Theory, the supply-oriented dynamic

    approach and the city network paradigm, have been forwarded that considered a

    citys population size as a determinant of location costs and benefits. However, the

    generalised growth in wealth that has been experienced over the last 50 years in

    developed countries has changed what have traditionally been seen as mans needs.

    Thus, Ingleharts post-materialist approach and Maslows theory of human needs

    force us to re-examine the traditional costs and benefits of cities. Here, we assume

    that costs and benefits enter the utility function of households through the quality of

    life concept. The relation between the constituents of quality of life and traditional

    and new theories of city size are considered here. Finally, we test these relations

    empirically in a specific dynamic, local framework: the city of Barcelona (Spain) inthe period 19912000.

    INTRODUCTION

    Economic studies have long been concerned with seeking to under-

    stand why people prefer living in cities (Christaller, 1933; Losch,

    1940; von Thu nen, 1826), although until Alonso (1964) no systematic

    micro-economic analysis of the question had been undertaken.

    Today, some three billion people worldwide live in an urban centre

    (a population of more than 1000 people) and by 2030 that number isset to increase to five billion. Another clear indicator of this phe-

    nomenon is that the percentage of people living in cities in North

    America, South America, Europe, and Japan stands at between 75

    and 85%. There are, currently, 17 megacities around the globe: 11 of

    which are located in Asia, while the ones experiencing the most rapid

    growth are located in the tropics. The United Nations Population

    Division predicts the addition of four new megacities to this total by

    2015, namely Tianjin, Istanbul, Cairo, and Lagos. According to

    Social Indicators Research (2005) 74: 549572 Springer 2005DOI 10.1007/s11205-004-8210-0

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    2/24

    forecasts from the World Resources Institute (1994), the percentage

    of people living in cities is expected to rise even further in the

    forthcoming decades.

    People tend to concentrate in urban areas as they seek to satisfy

    their needs, and territorially speaking this can be best achieved by

    living in cities. In classic economics, the location of an individuals

    residence is studied in a static framework, in which the structure of

    the city is linear and where there is just one centre (the central

    business district). In this traditional model, urban size is considered

    to be the result of the equilibrium between production benefits and

    location costs. As these benefits and costs are, by definition, the same

    for all cities, every urban centre should be the same size.

    In taking this classical analysis a stage further, Henderson (1985)

    pointed out that cities produce different goods according to their size,

    which gives rise to externalities. As a result, different urban sizes

    develop reflecting these externalities related to the higher productivity

    that the agents enjoy by being nearer to other producers or other

    market agents. The inhabitants of larger cities enjoy additional

    benefits as a consequence of being resident there. However, there are

    certain amenities that are affected negatively as urban size increases:lower levels of environmental quality and increasing congestion,

    among others. Here, again, an equilibrium between benefits and costs

    means that there is an optimal urban size.

    It should be noted that increasing city size contradicts optimal

    city size theory, which holds that the advantages of agglomeration

    are weakened as a citys physical dimensions expand. According to

    this theory, medium-sized towns can be expected to grow in size, since

    the advantages associated with their physical dimensions are still

    greater than their location costs. Richardson (1972) called this into

    question, arguing that there are other determinants influencing urban

    agglomeration economies, in addition to physical size. This criticismwas incorporated in Capello and Camagni (2000), who assumed: (a)

    the influence of a citys physical size on its optimal size; but also took

    into consideration (b) the neoclassical and Christallerian city, com-

    plemented with the supply-oriented dynamic approach (Camagni

    et al., 1989), when analysing the different functions of each city, and

    (c) the network city paradigm (Camagni, 1993; Camagni and de

    Blasio, 1993) when seeking to explain why small or medium-sized

    cities might have higher-order functions.1

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH550

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    3/24

    Here, also, we incorporate all three approaches, in particular the

    fact that a citys benefits and costs are influenced by its size. However,

    we recognise that this representation is simplistic, as many other

    forces have a role to play. In order to obtain a holistic view, we

    consider a key concept: quality of life. Theoretically, we understand

    that all inhabitants in a region choose where they will live by seeking

    to maximise utility, a function in which the concept of quality of life

    is explicitly included (Giannias et al., 1999; Clark et al., 1988). In

    building a theoretical framework for this study, we explain the con-

    cept of quality of life in terms of Maslows theory of human needs.

    This leads to a reformulation of the way in which amenities and

    disamenities are considered in order to test the effect of city size.

    Finally, our objective is to test the influence of the components of

    quality of life on the city size theory in a local framework. Thus, we

    assume that city size is related to flows of migration, and that these

    occur more frequently within metropolitan areas than between them.

    In a relatively short period of time lets say 10 years a smaller

    territorial area would be more appropriate. Moreover, in the local

    framework of Spain, local migration is much more frequent than long

    distance flows, although clearly the critical factors that influence thesemovements are not the same as those influencing movements between

    metropolitan areas. This said, however, our procedure is not invali-

    dated, but rather enables us to conduct our future studies in a range

    of other territorial dimensions. In any case, we assume that our

    analysis do not pretend to analyze city growth in the world, and that

    our estimates are strictly limited to Barcelona and similar locales.

    In order to strengthen the territorial scope of our analysis, two

    contrary economic forces can be considered to be operating spa-

    tially: relative advantage and absolute advantage. The former, a

    frequent assumption in an international framework, is important

    when labour is not mobile and when parity between currencies canfluctuate. In a national framework, however, these two factors are

    considered unimportant, and as such, the absolute advantage takes

    on greater significance. Yet, migration between metropolitan areas

    is not a common phenomenon in the case of Spain, where various

    fiscal mechanisms operating at the national level mean that the

    absolute advantages of the regions are eliminated. Consequently,

    the importance of absolute advantage is much more marked at the

    local than at the regional level.

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 551

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    4/24

    Thus, the main objectives of this study are :

    to incorporate quality of life theory within the relationship of

    amenities and disamenities that influence city size;

    to test this empirically within a local framework

    CITY SIZE, AMENITIES AND DISAMENITIES,

    AND QUALITY OF LIFE

    As discussed above, urban size can be seen as being the result of

    market forces that seek to maximise utility levels for residents and

    profits for firms. In the optimal city size theory, optimal size is

    computed as the result of maximum difference between a location

    cost curve and the aggregate agglomeration advantage curve (Fig-

    ure 1). Both utility and profits are affected by a diverse set of con-

    flicting amenities and disamenities. If the equilibrium between them is

    higher than that in other locations, reasonable individuals will choose

    to live there. By contrast, if this equilibrium is negative or lower than

    that in other locations, people will move out. This is the mechanism

    underlying the growth or decline of a city. It may be the case that a

    city has benefit curves due to their function in the territorial system

    (Figure 2, depicts the neoclassical supply-oriented dynamic ap-

    proach).

    Thus, it can be seen that size influences the number of amenities

    and disamenities in a city, which in turn influences city size. Similarly,

    it can be seen that every cost or benefit may be characterised by an

    optimal point in relation to city size. On just this issue, Burnell and

    Benefits

    Costs

    B, C

    D

    Figure 1. The optimal city size theory.

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH552

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    5/24

    Galster (1992) raise an interesting question: At what population

    may the disamenities of large size begin to outweigh the productivity

    advantages?.

    This questions has typically been addressed by regressing different

    measurements of benefits and costs on linear, or more complex,

    representations of city size:

    Costs f Size, Other factors 1

    Benefits f Size, Other factors 2

    It should be noted that these costs and benefits have traditionally

    been considered as economic factors with undoubted significance at

    the territorial level. Yet, non-economic factors are also important

    in the making of decisions concerning location. Thus, it can be

    seen that many advanced industrial societies have been able to

    increase their level of material well-being dramatically. This has

    given rise to the need to take into consideration post-materialist

    values, which view economic factors merely in relative terms within

    a much more complex vision of what drives peoples decision

    making (Inglehart, 1990)2

    . Thus, economic factors, such as distancefrom the central business district, may simply be another factor

    that needs to be taken into consideration when a household is

    pondering where to locate its residence. It is at this juncture, and

    in order to be able to comprehend fully the definition of quality of

    life, that the concept of human needs should be introduced. Thus,

    we can make an assumption: man is constantly striving to better

    himself, which assumes that certain needs have already been sat-

    isfied as a basis for seeking to satisfy other needs. And these new

    B3

    Costs

    Bi, C

    D

    B2

    B1

    Figure 2. Neoclassical supply-oriented dynamic approach.

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 553

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    6/24

    social needs have to be interpreted as a new means of satisfying the

    eternal needs we face in a new environment. Finally, the doubt

    remains, however: Do these needs really include everything that we

    express as needs?

    Maslows (1975) theory of human needs identifies five different

    kinds of needs, ordered from the objective to the subjective: (1)

    physiologic needs, (2) health and security, (3) ownership and love,

    (4) the need to be loved, and (5) self-realisation. In line with this

    theory, once we have satisfied the more basic, objective needs, we

    are then ready to try to fulfil our more spiritual needs. However, the

    linear nature that Maslow gives to his classification has been called

    into question by more than one author (Doyal and Gough, 1994),

    while some have sought to classify needs in line with Marxist

    thinking (Heller, 1978), and others have forwarded their own clas-

    sifications. Thus, there is no consensus concerning the nature, or the

    definition, of human needs. Therefore, following Royuela and Su-

    rin ach (2003), here, we take for granted the fact that if mans

    intention is to optimise these needs, we should be concerned with

    considering the overall number of needs. It is here where the con-

    cept of quality of life arises.Following Liu (1978), we understand quality of life in its social

    sense, that is: The optimal level of quality of life is produced only by

    combining both the physical and psychological inputs (). There-

    fore, the quality of life that each individual perceives is assumed to be

    directly dependent on his capability constraints to exchange and to

    acquire, while the major concern for a society is how to improve an

    individuals capability by shifting the constraint curve outward to the

    right. Additionally, following Dasgupta and Weale (1992), quality

    of life not only considers the constituents of well-being (health,

    welfare, freedom of choice, basic liberties) but also the determinants

    of well-being (availability of food, clothing, potable water, educationfacilities, health care and income in general). Thus, social welfare is

    not only considered from the perspective of each individual but also

    from that of society seen as a collective group; the opportunities

    enjoyed by this group are at least as important as those enjoyed by

    the individual.

    Quality of life is a multidimensional concept. According to Wish

    (1986), there may be many vectors to consider, and we will need to

    study all of them if we are to obtain a global definition of the quality

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH554

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    7/24

    of life. On the basis of this assumption, instead of computing func-

    tions (1) to (2), we are concerned with the following function:

    Quality of Life Component i f Size, Other factors 3

    where the Quality of Life Component iincludes all the constituents of

    quality of life. The variables denoted as Other factors are those that

    enable different functions to be taken into consideration for each city

    and the network city paradigm. Thus, as a first step, we understand

    that all the constituents of quality of life may be related to city size or

    city function theories. Clearly, this is not always the case. Climate, for

    instance, can be seen as a constituent of well being, but it is not

    directly dependent on city size or city function or the place of the city

    in the global network. Below, we test the relation between each

    constituent of quality of life and these theoretical variables.

    CITY SIZE, AND QUALITY OF LIFE IN THE BARCELONA

    METROPOLITAN AREA

    The Local Environment

    As Wish (1986) points out, even within the city, especially in the

    largest urban areas, there are acute differences. We analyse these in a

    local framework, within municipalities. Our study is undertaken in

    the province of Barcelona (NUTS III in the European administrative

    classification, and the largest province in the region of Catalonia,

    NUTS II), which is one of Spains most developed regions, located in

    the north-east of the country, and bordering France. The province of

    Barcelona had a population of 4,805,927 inhabitants in 2001 and is,

    together with Madrid, Spains most populated and urbanised prov-

    ince. It has 314 municipalities, organised in 11 administrative groups,

    named comarques. These municipalities are the basic unit of mea-surement in our study. Describing territorial groups is a key element

    in this study; elsewhere, we have used different territorial groups

    defined as urban systems and urban subsystems (see Arts et al.,

    1999). These aggregations were developed following commuting and

    service area criteria.

    Our local framework of 314 municipalities can be grouped in three

    territorial dimensions: urban subsystems (of which there are 48), ur-

    ban systems (24), and comarques (11). The 24 urban systems and their

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 555

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    8/24

    subsystems (if the former can be partitioned), together with their

    respective sizes, are shown in Table I. Figure 3 also shows the dis-

    tribution of the population among these urban subsystems, giving a

    Gini index of 0.54. This indicates that a substantial part of the total

    population is concentrated in a small number of municipalities: the

    city of Barcelona accounted for 31% of the total population of the

    province in the 2001 census. There are also differences in terms of

    urban development. Some systems and subsystems (those nearest

    Barcelona) are best described as urban areas or simply cities, while

    others (those furthest from Barcelona) can be considered rural areas.

    The province is similar to other areas in Europe, in which a large city

    has a relatively wide area of influence: its suburbs, its surrounding

    towns, industrial clusters, and so on.

    The main characteristic used in defining the systems or subsystems

    is not their homogeneity in terms of size, but the fact that they clearly

    form separate areas on the basis of commuting and services criteria. 3

    The Data

    In Royuela et al. (2003), the quality of life of these 314 municipalitieslying in the Barcelona province is analysed. Here we use the same

    extensive database4, and 18 basic quality of life components (see

    Table II). In the aforementioned study, a weighted (a priori) arith-

    metic average index of partial indicators is developed, which ex-

    presses the relative standardised position of each individual

    (municipality, subsystem or system) having combined the variability

    of all the variables with a Paasche-type temporal aggregation. Here,

    rather than focusing on the composite index, we deal with its con-

    stituents and determinants. The 18 indices are constructed on the

    basis of a number of basic variables, weighted in accordance with the

    opinions of policymakers (as in Drewnowski, 1974). This databaserefers to the period between 1991 and 2000. Finally we have to

    mention that several important dimensions of quality of life (such as

    crime) are not considered here due to the lack of complete data for all

    municipalities. We also assume that there are not subjective mea-

    surements of well being. These factors would improve without any

    doubt our database and consequently our final results.

    The function of each city was controlled using a dummy variable

    equal to 1 for cities that provide a minimum level of basic services,

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH556

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    9/24

    TABLE I

    List of urban systems and subsystems within the Barcelona province

    Urban systems (and their subsystems

    where the former are divisible)

    Size (1996

    inhabitants)

    Number of

    municipalities

    System of IAlt Penede` s 73,196 27

    Subsystem of Sant Sadurn 14,093 4

    Subsystem of Vilafranca 59,103 23

    System of IAnoia 86,964 33

    System of Bages 152,586 35

    Subsystem of Manresa 122,895 27

    Subsystem of Bages Nord 29,691 8

    System of Baix Llobregat Nord 123,778 12

    Subsystem of Esparraguera-Olesa 31,864 3

    Subsystem of Martorell 73,582 8

    Subsystem of Sant Andreu de la Barca 18,332 1

    System of Baix Montseny 22,792 9

    System of Barcelona 1,508,805 1

    System of Bergueda` 38,606 31

    System of Besos 413,106 8

    Subsystem of Badalona 231,514 4

    Subsystem of Sant Adria` del Beso` s 33,361 1

    Subsystem of Masnou 25,056 2

    Subsystem of Santa Coloma de Gramenet 123,175 1System of Cerdanyola, Montcada i Ripollet 106,474 3

    Subsystem of Cerdanyola 50,503 1

    Subsystem of Montcada i Reixac 27,068 1

    Subsystem of Ripollet 28,903 1

    System of Cornella` 82,490 1

    System of Delta del Llobregat 135,310 5

    Subsystem of Gava` 41,090 2

    Subsystem of Castelldefels 38,509 1

    Subsystem of Viladecans 55,711 2

    System of Garraf 90,435 6

    System of Granollers 173,168 23

    Subsystem of Pla de Granollers 159,659 19

    Subsystem of Congost 13,509 4

    System of Maresme Nord 59,537 7Subsystem of la Riera de Calella 33,843 4

    Subsystem of la Tordera 25,694 3

    System of Maresme Sud 213,771 18

    Subsystem of la Riera dArenys 28,799 5

    Subsystem of Mataro 145,570 10

    Subsystem of la Riera de Premia` 39,402 3

    System of Mollet-Parets 70,331 10

    Sistem of Osona 122,923 51

    Subsystem of Osona Nord 19,422 9

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 557

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    10/24

    such as health and education services. Two different levels of higher

    function cities were controlled. Thus, we selected 48 as basic func-

    tional cities, with 24 as central cities. These dummies were considered

    as being cumulative so that we might take into consideration a

    threshold effect. Finally, the network city paradigm was modelled

    using an indicator of installed telephone cells in 1996, as in Capello

    and Camagni (2000). We believe that in this particular year it would

    TABLE I

    Continued

    Urban systems (and their subsystems

    where the former are divisible)

    Size (1996

    inhabitants)

    Number of

    municipalities

    Subsystem of Vic 78,299 36

    Subsystem of Manlleu 25,202 6

    System of El Prat de Llobregat 63,255 1

    System of la Riera de Caldes 29,193 7

    System of Rub - Sant Cugat 101,295 2

    Subsystem of Rub 54,085 1

    Subsystem of Sant Cugat 47,210 1

    System of Sabadell 283,954 10

    Subsystem of Barbera` del Valle` s 42,542 2

    Subsystem of Sabadell 223,530 6

    Subsystem of Castellar 17,822 2

    System of Sant Boi 84,477 3

    System of Terrassa 177,824 6

    System of la Vall Baixa de Llobregat 415,430 9

    Subsystem of Esplugues i Sant Just 60,116 2

    Subsystem of Sant Feliu de Llobregat 35,797 1

    Subsystem of lHospitalet 255,050 1

    Subsystem of Molins 37,662 4

    Subsystem of Sant Joan Desp 26,805 1

    Source: Arts et al. (1999).

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    10-25 25-40 40-75 75-150 150-250 +250

    Thousands inhabitants

    Numberofsubsystems

    Figure 3. Population distribution among subsystems.

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH558

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    11/24

    TABLE II

    Quality of life components and their variables

    WI= Wealth index

    + per capita available family wealth

    + Average tax return per taxpayer

    + Average tax paid per taxpayer

    + per capita value added

    + Value added growth in last five years

    LI= Labour index

    + Labour activity rate

    + Rate of unemployment

    + Gini Index of economic activity concentration

    ) GI of workers (15 sectors) ) GI of social security contributors (10 sectors)

    + Labour formation index

    + Number of classes + Number of studentsELI= Educational level index

    + Average no of years studied per person

    MotI = Motorization index

    + Number of vehicles per 1000 inhabitants

    DI = Demographic index

    ) Mortality rate

    + Birth rate

    + Average age level index

    ) Average age level in the municipality

    )Average age level in the comarque

    HAI= Housing access index

    + Rate of house rental

    + No of houses completed last year per 1000 inhabitants

    + Rate of new subsidised houses

    ) House price index in the largest city in the system

    MigrI= Migration index

    + Rate of immigration in the municipality

    + Rate of immigration in the comarque

    + Population growth of the municipality

    SII= Sex inequality index

    + Sex inequality in education levels

    + Sex inequality in education labour activity

    OCI= Obligatory commuting index

    + Outside commuting index+ 1-rate of workers who commute to the Barcelona urban area

    + 1-rate of students who commute to the Barcelona urban area+ Distance from the

    nearest capital (as service centre)

    CongI= Congestion index) Automobile density

    SOASI= Social and old age services index

    + Number of old-age residences per 1000 old age inhabitants

    + Number of old-age cultural centres per 1000 old age inhabitants+ Number of old-age day residences per 1000 old age inhabitants

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 559

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    12/24

    TABLE II

    Continued

    HC= Housing characteristics

    + Index of housing conditions

    + Houses size per inhabitant

    + Rate of one-family houses

    + Housing services index (water, phone, etc.)

    PTI= Public transport index

    ) 1-Rate of public transport users among workers

    ) 1-Rate of public transport users among students

    + Train services+ Number of urban buses per potential users

    EFI= Educational facilities index

    + Educational services index

    + Pre-school school units + High school units

    + Primary school units + Special education units

    + Students per school unit index

    ) Pre-school school

    ) Primary school

    ) High school

    + University index

    + University courses per 10,000 inhabitants between 19 and 24

    + Universitys diversity of supply

    HFI= Health facilities index

    + Pharmacies per 1000 inhabitants+ Hospitals per 1000 inhabitants

    + Hospital beds per 1000 inhabitants

    + Outpatients health centers

    + Number of workers in the health sector per 1000 inhabitants

    CEI= Climate and environment index

    Environment index

    + Air quality index in Catalonia

    Climate index

    ) Yearly temperature range

    + Average temperature

    CFMMI= Cultural facilities and municipal media index

    Cultural facilities index

    + Theatres and theatre diversity

    + Museums and museum diversity+ Bookshops and bookshop diversity

    + Municipal archives and municipal archive diversity

    + Cinemas and cinema diversity

    + Art galleries

    + Sport centres and sport centre diversity

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH560

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    13/24

    have been a good indicator of the network paradigm. The basic

    descriptive statistics of all these variables are shown in Tables III

    and IV.

    The Estimation Results

    Using this data, we then proceeded to compute equation (3) for each

    constituent of quality of life. The functional form considered was a

    translog function so that we could also consider cross-effects betweenthe key variables:

    Quality of Life Component i g a1Size a2Function 1

    a3Network b1(1/2)Size2 b2Function 2

    b3(1/2) Network2 d1Size*Function 1

    d2Size*Function 2 d3Size*Network

    d4Network*Function 1 d5Network*Function 2 et

    Where Function)1 and Function)2 are two dummy variables

    related to basic functional cities and central cities, respectively;Network describes the number of telephone cells installed per 100

    inhabitants in 1996; Size refers to the municipal population in 1996;

    and the Quality of Life Component i is the measure that corresponds

    to each quality of life dimension identified by Royuela et al. (2003).

    All variables (except these dummies) are measured in logs. The esti-

    mation took into consideration the possibility of heteroscedasticity

    given the wide range of in size of the municipalities. Thus, the

    weighted least-squares method was used in order to estimate the

    TABLE II

    Continued

    Municipal media index

    + Written media

    + TV and radio

    + Municipal bulletins

    MFSI= Municipal financial state index

    ) Debt: payable passive/total active

    ) Taxes over total revenues

    )

    Taxes per capitaSource: Royuela et al. (2003).

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 561

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    14/24

    TABLEIII

    Descriptive

    statistics(1)

    Pop1996

    fun

    sub

    fun

    sis

    Telxha

    b

    WI

    LI

    ELI

    DI

    MOTIHAIM

    igrISSI

    OCI

    CONGISOASIHC

    PTI

    EFI

    HFI

    CEI

    CFMMIMFSI

    Min

    30

    0

    0

    125

    66,7

    32,1

    76,7

    71,3

    63,4

    85,67

    4,3

    87,1

    25,3

    82,1

    81,2

    30,12

    1,1

    78,0

    77,3

    67,3

    36,6

    39,4

    Max

    1508805

    1

    1

    1095,2177,3

    138,3

    137,7

    134,0

    217,9

    188,824

    3,5

    112,0

    109,4

    164,2

    150,8

    200,1168,9135,0121,1

    119,9

    156,5

    199,3

    Average

    14744,30,153

    0,076

    439,8

    92,1

    95,8

    90,9

    99,9

    106,4

    100,911

    1,0

    99,9

    88,1

    155,6

    120,4

    115,06

    0,0104,4

    94,2

    89,9

    62,6

    114,8

    Median

    2007

    0

    0

    414,7

    87,5

    97,2

    88,5

    99,9

    103,5

    99,210

    6,5

    99,9

    88,9

    164,2

    121,2

    115,65

    7,8104,5

    93,5

    90,0

    60,7

    101,1

    StdDev

    88774,8

    0,36

    0,27

    121,0

    416,31

    15,70

    9,80

    12,76

    14,25

    10,2118

    ,16

    3,26

    11,48

    24,51

    10,94

    16,2022,85

    8,82

    8,94

    9,82

    15,50

    28,03

    Kurtosis

    258,6

    1,8

    8,3

    5,32

    53,425

    0,614

    3,634

    )0,581

    11,26019,33010

    ,83

    1,889

    3,436

    5,052

    0,493

    5,3223,3720,7361,276)0,2943,602

    0,035

    Skewness

    15,51,939

    3,204

    1,70

    81,633

    )0,592

    1,628

    )0,185

    1,633

    3,0752,349

    )0,088

    )1,053

    )2,638

    )0,415

    )0,5341,3950,1831,036

    0,1811,131

    0,490

    Notes:FUNSIS:dummyvariablecorrespondingtothe24centralcitiesofthe

    province.FUNSUB:dummyvariablecorrespondingtothe48functionalcities;

    TELXHAB:installedtelephonecells;POB_

    96:1996populationofeverymunicipality;WI=

    WealthIndex,LI=

    LabourIndex,ELI=

    EducationalLevelIndex,

    DI=

    Demographic

    Index,MotI=

    Motorization

    Index,

    HAI=

    Housing

    AccessIndex,MigrI=

    MigrationIn

    dex,SII=

    Sex

    Inequality

    Index,

    OCI=

    ObligatoryCommutingIndex,CongI=

    CongestionIndex,SOASI=SocialandOldAgeServicesIndex,HC=HousingCharacteristics,PTI=

    Public

    TransportIndex,EFI=

    Education

    alFacilitiesIndex,HFI=

    HealthFacilitiesIndex,CEI=

    ClimateandEnvironmentI

    ndex,CFMMI=

    CulturalFacilities

    andMunicipalMediaIndex,MFSI=

    MunicipalFinancialStateIndex.

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH562

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    15/24

    TABLEIV

    Descriptivestatist

    ics(2)correlations

    Pop_96funsubfunsisTelxha

    bWI

    LI

    ELI

    DI

    MOTIHAI

    M

    igrISSI

    OCI

    CONGISTASIHC

    PTI

    EFI

    HFI

    CEI

    CFMMIMFSI

    Pop1996

    1

    funsub0,313

    1

    funsis

    0,379

    0,677

    1

    telxhab

    0,042

    )0,067)0,020

    1

    WI

    0,081

    0,080

    0,048

    0,287

    1

    LI

    0,044

    )0,038

    0,013

    0,233

    0,419

    1

    ELI

    0,155

    0,174

    0,094

    0,267

    0,718

    0,350

    1

    DI

    0,002

    0,222

    0,095

    0,239

    0,509

    0,453

    0,587

    1

    MOTI)0,075)0,285)0,188

    0,292

    0,425

    0,412

    0,417

    0,258

    1

    HAI

    )0,014

    0,141

    0,147)0,060

    0,111

    0,092

    0,062

    0,038)0,113

    1

    MIgrI)0,101)0,139)0,130

    0,496

    0,395

    0,407

    0,362

    0,464

    0,337)0,005

    1

    SSI

    0,004

    )0,012

    0,006)0,006

    )0,115

    0,064)0,071

    0,083)0,030)0,115)0,020

    1

    OCI

    0,173

    0,490

    0,388)0,346

    )0,214)0,104)0,143

    0,083)0,332

    0,169)0,303

    0,116

    1

    CON-

    GI

    )0,378)0,778)0,664

    0,058

    )0,033

    0,024)0,127)0,219

    0,284)0,0840

    ,138)0,035)0,363

    1

    SOASI)0,310)0,353)0,240)0,074

    )0,210

    0,004)0,211)0,277

    0,098

    0,148)0,084)0,062

    0,011

    0,482

    1

    HC

    )0,155)0,321)0,243

    0,094

    0,186

    0,102

    0,180

    0,077

    0,348)0,0350

    ,161

    0,071)0,057

    0,353

    0,130

    1

    PTI

    0,291

    0,468

    0,310

    0,044

    0,145)0,067

    0,242

    0,333)0,236

    0,028)0,032

    0,011

    0,191)0,547

    )0,635)0,238

    1

    EFI

    )0,083)0,258)0,139)0,276

    )0,382)0,179)0,395)0,620)0,140

    0,094)0,406)0,111

    0,031

    0,233

    0,344

    0,044)0,312

    1

    HFI

    0,109

    )0,092)0,076)0,250

    )0,237)0,060)0,286)0,441)0,061

    0,071)0,374)0,136)0,010

    0,011

    0,146)0,085)0,093

    0,484

    1

    CEI

    0,171

    0,279

    0,210

    0,110

    0,259)0,093

    0,251

    0,260

    0,005

    0,0190

    ,231

    0,265

    0,174)0,296

    )0,431)0,066

    0,36

    4)0,377)0,341

    1

    CFM-

    MI

    0,402

    0,245

    0,181)0,018

    0,115

    0,208

    0,147

    0,239

    0,104)0,018)0,063

    0,133

    0,224)0,273

    )0,077

    0,066

    0,15

    1)0,059

    0,174

    0,024

    1

    MFSI

    )0,088)0,239)0,138)0,199

    )0,321)0,086)0,275)0,356)0,079)0,046)0,199)0,043)0,0550,270

    0,354

    0,024

    )0,2890,325

    0,300

    )0,325)0,120

    1

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 563

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    16/24

    translog functions of each of the 18 quality of life components. The

    weighting variable was municipality size, expressed in logs. Table V

    shows all our results.

    From these estimates, we can draw several conclusions about the

    relationship between size and the constituents of quality of life.

    Wealth Index: the relation computed is not very strong, although

    the relation with size is unmistakable. Thus, agglomeration

    economies play a significant role in generating higher wealth in

    the larger municipalities. Labour Index: here the relation is much weaker. Additionally,

    the more significant parameters of the translog function are

    those that are related with the variables from the network city

    paradigm. Thus, city size is much less important in attracting

    labour than the fact of being connected to the network city.

    Educational Level Index: this variable has a relatively strong rela-

    tion with the city size paradigm. The only parameters that are sig-

    nificant are those related with city size. Here the relation is

    unmistakable: people with a higher level of education live in the

    larger or medium-sized cities. Thus, in the long term, the greater

    possibilities of attaining a higher education in these cities meansmany more educated people tend to live there.

    Demographic Index: the municipalities with the highest demo-

    graphic potential are those that are of medium size. In addition,

    cities with a high function in the city system also present a high

    concentration for this index.

    Motorization Index: the proportion of vehicles per inhabitant

    clearly falls with city size. The most plausible reason for this

    is the greater need for private means of transportation among

    people living in small municipalities. There are two explana-

    tions: the greater need for transportation in order to have

    access to the same amount of services, and the poorer pro-

    vision of public transportation services in and around these

    small municipalities.

    Housing Access Index: a very weak relation was found with this

    index, which expresses the ease of finding a place in which to live

    and the city paradigms. Only one parameter of the translog

    function is significant: the cross-effect between size and high

    functions of cities has a negative effect on this index, showing a

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH564

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    17/24

    higher level of housing prices or a lower level of new homes or

    houses for rent.

    Migration Index: this index has a relatively strong relation with

    the controlled city paradigms. Thus, we see that medium-sized

    cities with a high function in the city system receive more people

    than very large or small municipalities. This index clearly

    TABLE V

    Estimation results from equation (3)

    WI=

    Wealth

    Index

    LI=

    Labour

    Index

    ELI=

    Educational

    Level

    Index

    DI =

    Demographic

    Index

    MotI =

    Motorization

    Index

    HAI=

    Housing

    Access

    Index

    (Intercept) 0,260 0,161 0,428 0,404 0,299 0,122

    1,22 )0,81 5,88*** 2,64*** 3,33*** 1,84*

    POB_96 9,651 5,284 20,559 18,644 11,733 3,813

    )3,55***

    )0,73

    )4,12***

    )0,59

    )4,52*** 0,3

    FUNSUB 0,000 )1,500 1,500 )1,000 0,500 )2,000

    )1,7* )1,96* )1,35 )0,6 )0,9 0,04

    LTELX-

    HAB

    0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000

    1,2 2,17** )0,46 )0,41 0,42 0,7

    SIZE_2 0,224 0,416 0,000 0,009 0,001 0,066

    2,38** 0,37 2,24** 2,25** )2,9*** )0,81

    FUNSIS 0,000 0,465 0,000 0,559 0,000 0,766

    2,68*** 1,22 1,05 3,85*** 0,43 )0,17

    NETW_2 0,090 0,051 0,177 0,547 0,368 0,967

    )1,46 )2,09** )0,11 0,59 )1,31 )0,77

    SIZE_F1 0,233 0,031 0,644 0,685 0,676 0,486

    )1,33 0,81 )0,92 )2,05** 0,36 0,59

    SIZE_F2 0,018 0,710 0,026 0,025 0,004 0,421)1,31 )1,6 )0,94 )1,51 0,49 )1,72*

    SIZE_-

    NET

    0,008 0,225 0,294 0,000 0,671 0,863

    3,17*** 0,73 4,21*** 0,21 6,03*** 0,14

    NET_F1 0,146 0,037 0,912 0,556 0,192 0,445

    )2,5** )1,45 )0,92 )3,59*** )0,52 0,11

    NET_F2 0,185 0,416 0,356 0,041 0,718 0,557

    2,14** 2,54** 1,65 1,03 0,81 0,48

    R2 0,260 0,161 0,428 0,404 0,299 0,122

    Adj R2 0,233 0,131 0,407 0,383 0,274 0,090

    F 9,651 5,284 20,559 18,644 11,733 3,813

    Sig 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000

    Weighting

    potency

    of WLS

    0 )1,5 1,5 )1 0,5 )2

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 565

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    18/24

    indicates a more complex relation between city size and quality

    of life components, because city size changes as people move

    from one place to another.

    Sex Inequality Index: this variable, which expresses the different

    amounts of social capital in the municipalities, is clearly not

    related with any of the controlled paradigms. Thus, it can be

    TABLE V

    Continued

    MI=

    Migration

    Index

    SII=

    Sex

    Inequality

    Index

    OCI=

    Obligatory

    Commut-

    ing Index

    CongI=

    Congestion

    Index

    SOASI=

    Social and

    Old Age

    Services

    Index

    HC=

    Housing

    Character-

    istics

    (Intercept) 0,467 0,063 0,481 0,815 0,301 0,394

    3,14*** 10,69*** 1,86* 10,68*** 5,1*** 0,24

    POB_96 24,084 1,853 25,453 120,579 11,805 17,821)1,44 )0,17 3,06*** )0,21 1,72* 1,41

    FUNSUB )2,500 1,000 )2,000 3,000 1,000 )2,500

    0,23 )0,19 1,7* 4,36*** 0,89 )0,09

    LTELX-

    HAB

    0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000

    )1,45 0,19 )0,12 0,02 )0,48 1,27

    SIZE_2 0,002 0,000 0,064 0,000 0,000 0,810

    )1,3 )0,3 )2,7*** )0,64 )1,29 )5,65***

    FUNSIS 0,152 0,867 0,002 0,831 0,086 0,161

    2,58** )0,48 )4,45*** )2,77*** )1,91* )2,72***

    NETW_2 0,818 0,848 0,091 0,000 0,373 0,929

    1,49 )0,3 0,16 )0,1 0,66 )1,37

    SIZE_F1 0,148 0,846 0,902 0,986 0,632 0,205

    )0,63

    )1,46 2,92*** 6,65*** 2,46** 3,54***

    SIZE_F2 0,196 0,767 0,007 0,522 0,198 0,000

    )0,6 1,12 )1,16 )15,3*** )4,28*** 0,67

    SIZE_-

    NET

    0,010 0,629 0,000 0,006 0,057 0,007

    2,29** 0,47 )1,91* 0,4 )1,58 0,87

    NET_F1 0,138 0,764 0,874 0,924 0,511 0,172

    )2,61*** 0,82 4,07*** 1,48 1,5 2,05**

    NET_F2 0,529 0,145 0,004 0,000 0,014 0,000

    )0,12 )0,14 )1,36 )0,71 0,21 )0,11

    R2 0,467 0,063 0,481 0,815 0,301 0,394

    Adj R2 0,448 0,029 0,462 0,808 0,275 0,372

    F 24,084 1,853 25,453 120,579 11,805 17,821

    Sig 0,000 0,045 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000

    Weightingpotency

    of WLS

    )

    2,5 1)

    2 3 1)

    2,5

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH566

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    19/24

    TABLE V

    Continued

    PTI=

    Public

    Transport

    Index

    EFI=

    Educa-

    tional

    Facilities

    Index

    HFI=

    Health

    Facilities

    Index

    CEI=

    Climate

    and

    Environ-

    ment

    Index

    CFMMI=

    Cultural

    Facilities

    and

    Municipal

    Media

    Index

    MFSI=

    Municipal

    Financial

    State

    Index

    (Intercept) 0,530 0,328 0,277 0,283 0,140 0,273)1,15 6,87*** 2,49** 5,64*** 0,24 )0,19

    POB_96 30,933 13,389 10,538 10,849 4,480 10,297

    1,25 5,54*** 2,42** )2,56** )0,28 5,04***

    FUNSUB )1,000 2,500 )1,500 0,500 )0,500 )0,500

    )0,81 )0,6 )1,28 )0,43 0,58 0,86

    LTELX-

    HAB

    0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000

    1,52 )0,6 0,29 )1,97** i 0,7

    SIZE_2 0,249 0,000 0,013 0,000 0,808 0,849

    0,01 )4,24*** )0,67 0,08 0,29 )3,63***

    FUNSIS 0,214 0,000 0,016 0,011 0,777 0,000

    2,09** )2,41** )1,86* 1,32 )1,94* )3,31***

    NETW_2 0,420 0,548 0,203 0,670 0,564 0,389

    )1,2 1,22

    )0,07 1,39

    )0,85

    )0,12

    SIZE_F1 0,130 0,551 0,770 0,049 0,395 0,486

    )2,15** 1,02 0,52 )1,02 )0,3 3,69***

    SIZE_F2 0,996 0,000 0,502 0,937 0,770 0,000

    3,13*** 0,27 3,08*** 0,52 1,85* )0,55

    SIZE_-

    NET

    0,038 0,017 0,064 0,187 0,053 0,001

    )0,86 )4,82*** )2,6*** 3,16*** 0,2 )4,24***

    NET_F1 0,230 0,224 0,942 0,166 0,396 0,903

    )1,75* 2,3** 1,78* )1,16 2,06** 2,66***

    NET_F2 0,033 0,307 0,603 0,309 0,766 0,000

    )0,03 0,56 0,5 0,3 )1,11 )0,74

    R2 0,530 0,328 0,277 0,283 0,140 0,273

    Adj R2 0,513 0,303 0,251 0,257 0,109 0,246

    F 30,933 13,389 10,538 10,849 4,480 10,297Sig 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000 0,000

    Weighting

    potency

    of WLS

    )1 2,5 )1,5 0,5 )0,5 )0,5

    Note: * Significant at 10%; ** Significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%. The t-statistic is

    shown in italcs. POB_96: Size. FUNSUB Function_1. LTELXHAB: Network. SIZE_2_

    Size2. FUNSIS: Function_2. NETW_2: Network. SIZE_F1: Size*Function_1. SIZE_F2:

    Size*Function_2. SIZE_NET: Size*Network. NET_F1: Network*Function_1. NET_F2:

    Network*Function_2.

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 567

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    20/24

    concluded that sex inequalities are distributed independently of

    the city paradigms.

    Obligatory Commuting Index: here the index is quite well ex-

    plained in terms of the city paradigms. As a citys size increases, its

    inhabitants do not have to commute so much in order to travel to

    work or to enjoy public or private services.

    Congestion Index: This index, computed as the density of

    automobiles, is much higher in big cities than in small munici-

    palities. In addition, the dummy variables that control the city

    functions are those that account for this congestion. It is inter-

    esting to see how high function cities have more congestion than

    those with more simply functions.

    Social and Old Age Services Index: This variable clearly falls path

    as city size increases. In addition, high function cities have, dif-

    ferentially, a lower level of social and old age services.

    Housing Characteristics: this function, which is relatively well

    explained, presents a marked parabola that decreases in size after

    reaching the mid-point. Furthermore, functional cities have a

    higher level of housing characteristics than high function cities.

    A relation might be established here with the higher MigrationIndex that can be found in medium-sized cities, where new

    houses, with higher characteristics, have been built in recent

    years.

    Public Transport Index: this variable clearly increases with size

    and city function. Thus, larger and more functional cities are

    much better connected to public transport than smaller, less

    functional cities.

    Educational Facilities Index: this variable does not increase

    markedly with size as one would expect. Although educational

    facilities increase with city size, high function cities have a rela-

    tively lower level. This is due to the fact that, although there aremore services, there are also more individuals that require these

    services. This leads to a certain level of congestion.

    Health Facilities Index: the situation here is similar to that re-

    corded for educational services. There are more services in larger

    cities, but there is also greater population pressure on them.

    Climate and Environment Index: this index, which not only in-

    cludes the environment but also includes the climate, presents a

    positively sloped relation with city size. Thus, although one

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH568

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    21/24

    might believe that large cities are much more heavily polluted,

    we also see how people tend to concentrate spatially in places

    with a good climate.

    Cultural Facilities and Municipal Media Index: this index pre-

    sents a weak relation with city paradigms. Although a positive

    relation with city size does develop, city function plays an

    uncertain role, with the functional cities presenting the highest

    levels of this index.

    Municipal Financial State Index: finally, the financial state of

    municipalities presents a negatively sloped relation with city size.

    It would seem that as municipalities increase in size, they have to

    increase the amount of public services they provide without

    benfitting from scale economies.

    These results show a majority of well-behaved curves, with a

    diversity of levels of adjustments. In addition, the positive effect of

    city size is reflected in the economic index. Agglomeration econo-

    mies were found to play a significant role in this metropolitan

    area. A positive effect of city size was also seen in the economies

    of scale and the indivisibilities of public services. This was the case

    of public transportation, which means people do not to have to bethe private owners of increasing numbers of automobiles. We have

    also seen how people migrate to large or medium-sized munici-

    palities and that the demographic potential here is greater, with

    more young people and higher birth rates.

    Nevertheless, several costs were also identified as a consequence of

    size. Congestion arises, of course, in terms of the density of automo-

    biles, but also in terms of the provision of such basic services as edu-

    cation and health. The provision of these public services by the

    municipalities also serves to weaken their financial circumstances. In-

    deed, what we find is that several services are insufficient in larger cities,

    as is the case with social services and those for the elderly. Here, a

    process of the territorial substitution of services arises, as residences for

    the elderly, for instance, become concentrated at some distance from

    more populated cities.

    It should be noted that the city network paradigm was found only

    to be of importance in the case of the labour index, but this dem-

    onstrates the significance of this paradigm in its relation with eco-

    nomic activity.

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 569

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    22/24

    In addition, the neoclassical supply-oriented dynamic approach,

    which emphasises city functions, has shown itself to be an important

    factor. Marked differences in benefits and costs are recorded

    according to the function of each city in the city system. Thus, effi-

    cient city size presents itself as a more important concept than opti-

    mal city size: costs and benefits depend on what the city produces and

    how it produces them.

    CONCLUSIONS

    This study has focused its analysis on the application of three city

    paradigms: optimal city size theory, the supply-oriented dynamic

    approach, and the city network paradigm. We have taken into con-

    sideration the costs and benefits to cities in terms of household utility

    rather than applying a production function. In this context, the

    quality of life concept and its constituents are particularly pertinent.

    By adopting this framework, we have been able to see the influence of

    each specific paradigm on each of the 18 controlled components of

    quality of life.Our most significant finding is that agglomeration economies were

    shown to play a significant role, especially in the economic index.

    Economies of scale and the indivisibilities of public services were also

    found to be significant, as were public transportation services. In the

    case of costs, we have seen how congestion occurs in terms of the

    density of automobiles as well as in the provision of education and

    health services. The provision of public services by municipalities also

    serves to weaken their financial condition. Furthermore, we have evi-

    dence of a process of territorial substitution of services whereby social

    services and those for the elderly are pushed out from the larger cities.

    The city network paradigm played a significant role in the labourindex, which has an obvious relation with economic activity. Simi-

    larly, the neoclassical supply-oriented dynamic approach, which

    places an emphasis on city functions, was also shown to be an

    important factor.

    The next step in this research will require conducting analyses that

    take into account the spatial relationships between all municipalities

    and those within higher function cities.

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH570

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    23/24

    NOTES

    1 Additional approaches have been made on the analysis of the economy of cities, in

    which more subjective processes are considered, for instance taking into account

    conditions such as the need to provide help to elderly relatives. As an example of this

    literature see Jacobs (1979, 1984).2 The accepted social materialist vision of reality is the instrumental nature of

    economic activities that enables people to earn resources that are used in other

    activities that give rise to satisfaction. By contrast, the post-materialist vision claims

    that in societies characterised by abundance, resources are not infinite, but rather

    sufficient, so that choices are made in terms of opportunity costs. Thus, a job can also

    be highly valued in terms of factors other than the earnings it produces.3 Each system or subsystem has basic health or educational services that are not

    shared with other systems or subsystems. So global services such as Universities and

    large hospitals are not considered as defining features of the urban systems or sub-

    systems. An additional exploration of this method of grouping municipalities

    according to social criteria can be seen in Royuela and Roman (2004).4 We use more than 500 basic variables, referring to all 314 municipalities and, in the

    main, to different time periods between 1991 and 2000. These figures indicate the size

    of the database.

    REFERENCES

    Alonso, W.: 1964, Location and Land Use (Harvard University Press, CambridgeMA).

    Arts, M., J. Surin ach, E. Pons, J. Roman, V. Royuela and M. Reyes: 1999, Sistemes

    i Subsistemes Urbans a la Provncia de Barcelona, Working Paper 99-R02 (Ana` lisi

    Quantitativa Regional Research Group. Universitat de Barcelona i Diputacio de

    Barcelona).

    Burnell, J.D. and G. Galster: 1992, Quality-of-life measurements and Urban Size: an

    empirical note, Urban Studies 29(5), pp. 727735.

    Camagni, R.: 1993, From city hierarchy to city network: reflections about an

    emerging paradigm, in T. Lachmanan and P. Nijkamp (eds.), Structure and

    Change in the Space Economy (Springer Verlag, Berlin), pp. 6090.

    Camagni, R. and de Blasio (eds.): 1993, Le reti di citta` (Franco Angeli, Milan).

    Camagni, R., L. Diappi and Leonardi, G.: 1989, Urban growth and decline in a

    hierarchical system: a supply-oriented dynamic approach, Regional Science and

    Urban Economics 16, pp. 145160.Capello, R. and R. Camagni: 2000, Beyond optimal city size: an evaluation of alter-

    native Urban Growth patterns, Urban Studies 37(9), pp. 14791496.

    Christaller, W.: 1933, Die Zentralen Orte in Su ddeutsch (Gustav Fisher Verlag,

    Berlin) and [The Central Place of Southern Germany. Prentice Hall, Englerwood

    Cliffs, NJ: 1966].

    Clark, D. J. R. Kahn and Ofek, H.: 1988, City size, quality of life, and the

    urbanization deflator of the GNP: 19101984), Southern Economic Journal 54(3),

    pp. 701714.

    Dasgupta, P. and M. Weale: 1992, On measuring quality of life, World Develop-

    ment 20(1), 119131.

    CONSTITUENTS OF QUALITY OF LIFE AND URBAN SIZE 571

  • 8/2/2019 Art Ingles2

    24/24

    Doyal, L. and I. Gough: 1994, Teora de las necesidades humanas (Icaria/FUHEM,

    Madrid).

    Drewnowski, J.: 1974, On Measuring and Planning the Quality of Life (Mouton,

    Paris).

    Giannias, D., P. Liargovas, and G. Manolas: 1999, Quality of life indices for

    analysing convergence in the e uropean Union, Regional Studies 33(1), pp. 2735.

    Heller, A.: 1978, Las teoras de las necesidades en Marx (Pennsula, Madrid).

    Henderson, J.: 1985, Economic Theory and the Cities (Academic Press, Orlando,

    FL).

    Jacobs, J.: 1979, The economy of cities. Random House, New York.

    Jacobs, J.: 1984, Cities and the wealth of nations. Random House, New York.

    Liu, B.C.: 1978, Variations in social quality of life indicators in medium metro-politan areas, American Journal of Economics and Sociology 37(3), 241260.

    Losch,A.: 1940, Die Ra umliche Ordnung der Wirtschaft (Gustav Fisher, Vienna) [The

    Economics of Location. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT 1954.]

    Maslow, A.H.: 1975, Motivacio n y personalidad (Sagitario, Barcelona).

    Myers, D.: 1988, Building knowledge about quality of life for urban planning,

    Journal of the American Planning Association 54, pp. 374358.

    Richardson, H.W.: 1972, Optimality in city size, systems of cities and urban policy: a

    sceptics view, Urban Studies, pp. 2948.

    Royuela, V. and J. Roman: 2004, Agrupacions Municipals a Catalunya (ODECAT,

    Barcelona).

    Royuela, V. and J. Surin ach: 2003, Como entender mejor nuestras ciudades. Los

    indicadores sociales como fin y como instrumento, in J.M. Casas and A. Pulido

    (eds.), Informacio n Econo mica y te cnicas de ana lisis en el siglo XXI (INE, Ma-

    drid).

    Royuela, V., J. Surin ach and M. Reyes: 2003, Measuring quality of life in small

    areas over different periods of time. Analysis of the province of Barcelona, Social

    Indicators Research 64(1), pp. 5174.

    Von Thu nen, J. H.: 1826, Der Isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirtschaft und

    Nation-alo konomie (Perthes, Hamburg) [Pergamon Press, The Isolated State,

    Oxford 1966].

    Wish, N. D.: 1986, Are we really measuring the quality of life? Well-being has

    subjective dimensions, as well as objective ones, American Journal of Economics

    and Sociology 45(1), pp. 9399.

    World Resources Institute: 1994, People and the Environment (Oxford University

    Press, Oxford).

    Quantitative Regional Analysis Research Group

    (AQR, www.ub.es/dpees/aqr/index.htm)

    University of Barcelona

    690 Avenida Diagonal

    Barcelona, 08034

    Spain

    E-mail: [email protected]

    VICENTE ROYUELA AND JORDI SURIN ACH572