40
1314 Vol. 93 TMR ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS * By Charles R. Mandly, Jr. ** I. INTRODUCTION In popular literature, trademarks are hailed as instruments of consumer protection (indeed, of consumer empowerment), or vilified as instruments of consumer manipulation by venal corporations. 1 Our schizophrenic attitude toward trademarks is not limited to popular thought. In a recent case, the Court of Justice for the European Communities (ECJ) acknowledged that “[t]rade mark rights constitute an essential element in the system of undistorted competition which the [European Community] Treaty is intended to establish and maintain.” 2 On the other hand, the European Parliament has initiated an as yet to be reported European Commission study of “abuse of trade mark rights,” with particular emphasis on abuses arising from prohibiting importation into the Common Market of less expensive “grey market” branded goods. 3 This tension between the protection of trademark rights and the abhorrence of monopolies is not new. Even prior to the emergence of modern trademark law, trademarks were decried as monopolistic. 4 Nevertheless, in general, the history of modern trademark law is one of expanding protection. 5 * Copyright © 2003 Charles R. Mandly, Jr. The author’s moral rights, including the right of attribution, are asserted. ** Attorney-at-Law, Illinois, U.S.A., and Solicitor, England and Wales; partner Wildman, Harrold, Allen & Dixon LLP, London, England, Associate Member of the International Trademark Association. The author thanks Dr. Spyros M. Maniatis of the Queen Mary Intellectual Property Research Institute, University of London, for suggesting certain lines of inquiry which aided the preparation of this article. All views expressed herein, however, are solely those of the author. 1. Compare The Case for Brands, 360 The Economist, Sept. 8-14, 2001, 9 (U.K. ed.), with Naomi Klein, No Logo: Taking Aim at the Brand Bullies (1999). 2. Case C-206/01, Arsenal Football Club plc v. Reed, [2002] E.C.R. I-10273, [2003] 1 C.M.L.R. 12, ¶ 48. 3. European Parliament Resolution of Oct. 3, 2001, 2002 O.J. (C87/61) (Apr. 11, 2002); see Thomas Heide, Opinion: Trade Marks and Competition Law after Davidoff, 25 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 163 (Apr. 2003); see also Christopher Stothers, Political Exhaustion: The European Commission’s Working Paper on Possible Abuses of Trade Mark Rights within the EU in the Context of Community Exhaustion, 25 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 457, 457-61 (Oct. 2003). 4. See Blanchard v. Hill, 26 Eng. Rep. 692, 693 (Ch. 1742) (Hardwicke, L.C.); Frank I. Schechter, The Historical Foundations of the Law Relating to Trade-Marks 137-45 (photo.

ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    5

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1314 Vol. 93 TMR

ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS*

By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.**

I. INTRODUCTION

In popular literature, trademarks are hailed as instruments of consumer protection (indeed, of consumer empowerment), or vilified as instruments of consumer manipulation by venal corporations.1 Our schizophrenic attitude toward trademarks is not limited to popular thought. In a recent case, the Court of Justice for the European Communities (ECJ) acknowledged that “[t]rade mark rights constitute an essential element in the system of undistorted competition which the [European Community] Treaty is intended to establish and maintain.”2 On the other hand, the European Parliament has initiated an as yet to be reported European Commission study of “abuse of trade mark rights,” with particular emphasis on abuses arising from prohibiting importation into the Common Market of less expensive “grey market” branded goods.3

This tension between the protection of trademark rights and the abhorrence of monopolies is not new. Even prior to the emergence of modern trademark law, trademarks were decried as monopolistic.4 Nevertheless, in general, the history of modern trademark law is one of expanding protection.5

* Copyright © 2003 Charles R. Mandly, Jr. The author’s moral rights, including the right of attribution, are asserted.

** Attorney-at-Law, Illinois, U.S.A., and Solicitor, England and Wales; partner Wildman, Harrold, Allen & Dixon LLP, London, England, Associate Member of the International Trademark Association. The author thanks Dr. Spyros M. Maniatis of the Queen Mary Intellectual Property Research Institute, University of London, for suggesting certain lines of inquiry which aided the preparation of this article. All views expressed herein, however, are solely those of the author.

1. Compare The Case for Brands, 360 The Economist, Sept. 8-14, 2001, 9 (U.K. ed.), with Naomi Klein, No Logo: Taking Aim at the Brand Bullies (1999).

2. Case C-206/01, Arsenal Football Club plc v. Reed, [2002] E.C.R. I-10273, [2003] 1 C.M.L.R. 12, ¶ 48.

3. European Parliament Resolution of Oct. 3, 2001, 2002 O.J. (C87/61) (Apr. 11, 2002); see Thomas Heide, Opinion: Trade Marks and Competition Law after Davidoff, 25 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 163 (Apr. 2003); see also Christopher Stothers, Political Exhaustion: The European Commission’s Working Paper on Possible Abuses of Trade Mark Rights within the EU in the Context of Community Exhaustion, 25 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 457, 457-61 (Oct. 2003).

4. See Blanchard v. Hill, 26 Eng. Rep. 692, 693 (Ch. 1742) (Hardwicke, L.C.); Frank I. Schechter, The Historical Foundations of the Law Relating to Trade-Marks 137-45 (photo.

Page 2: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1315

Within the European Community there is a vital and powerful competition law governing monopolies. Intellectual property rights (of which trademarks are a subset) do not escape the reach of competition law. The exercise of intellectual property rights, in “exceptional circumstances,” can constitute an abuse of a dominant position6 in contravention of Article 82 of the Treaty Establishing the European Community.7

This essay examines the role and regulation of trademarks under Article 82. Although there is a significant body of literature analyzing the role and regulation of intellectual property rights generally under Article 82,8 little has been written specifically regarding trademarks. The author contends that by its very nature, a trademark neither constitutes a monopoly (or at least a monopoly cognizable under competition law), nor should its exercise be regulated under Article 82. If firms seek to use trademarks to “monopolize” products, or even non-source information, such issues can and should be resolvable within the trademark paradigm without recourse to Article 82.9 Consequently, regardless of the merits of regulating the exercise of other intellectual property rights under Article 82, trademarks should not be so regulated. Of course, prior claims that, vis-à-vis other intellectual property rights, trademarks occupy “a league of their own, being predominantly pro-competitive,” and therefore are non-monopolistic, have been dismissed as simplistic.10

reprint 1999) (Colum. U., Colum. Legal Stud., No. 1, 1925) (19th Century emergence of modern trademark law).

5. See, e.g., W.R. Cornish, Intellectual Property §§ 15-04 to 15-18 (4th ed. 1999); Mark A. Lemley, The Modern Lanham Act and the Death of Common Sense, 108 Yale L.J. 1687, 1697-703 (May 1999).

6. See, e.g., Cornish, supra n.5, at §§ 18-14 to 18-16; Rosa Greaves, Herchel Smith Lecture 1998: Article 86 of the E.C. Treaty and Intellectual Property Rights, 20 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 379, 381-83, 384-85 (Oct. 1998).

7. Treaty Establishing the European Community [E.C. Treaty] art. 82, 1997 O.J. (C 340) 3 (as of 1998). With the Treaty of Amsterdam, the E.C. Treaty was renumbered. For example, former Articles 85 and 86 became Articles 81 and 82 respectively. All text references are to current designations.

8. See, e.g., Steven D. Anderman, E.C. Competition Law and Intellectual Property Rights 148 (1998 & 2000); Inge Govaere, The Use and Abuse of Intellectual Property Rights in E.C. Law 1-12 (1996); Gregory V.S. McCurdy, Intellectual Property and Competition: Does the Essential Facilities Doctrine Shed Any New Light?, 25 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 472, 477-80 (Oct. 2003); Greaves, supra n.6, 379-85.

9. Cf., W.R. Cornish, Trade Marks: Portcullis for the EEA, 20 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 172, 177 (1998) (“Better by far to develop a fair rule within . . . trade mark law by which to distinguish acceptable exclusions from those which have no sufficient justification measured by the objectives of that law itself.”).

10. See Spyros M. Maniatis, Competition and the Economics of Trade Marks, in Intellectual Property and Market Freedom 65, 119-20 (Adrian Sterling ed., I.P. Unit, Queen Mary, U. London, Persp. on Intell. Prop. vol. 2, 1997); see also Glynn S. Lunney, Trademark Monopolies, 48 Emory L.J. 367, 478-80 (Spring 1999).

Page 3: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1316 Vol. 93 TMR

Nevertheless, the case for trademark exceptionality, if simple, also is compelling.

In order to evaluate what role, if any, should be played by Article 82 in the regulation of trademarks, this essay: (i) reviews Community competition law governing private economic activities; (ii) discusses arguments for trademark exceptionality; (iii) analyzes Article 82 violations; and (iv) examines the specifics of the role and regulation of trademarks under Article 82.

II. COMMUNITY COMPETITION LAW AND THE REGULATION OF PRIVATE COMMERCIAL ACTIVITY

Articles 81 and 82 of the E.C. Treaty constitute the core provisions of the Community’s competition law regulating private firms and traditional private commercial activity.11 Articles 81 and 82 “complement each other in order to ensure that competition in the Common Market is not distorted as required by Article 3(g) of the [E.C.] Treaty.”12 Articles 81 and 82 have a “direct effect” upon the national legal orders of the Member States.13 Consequently, “these Articles apply to relationships between individuals and create rights directly in respect of the individuals concerned which national courts must safeguard.”14

Article 81 prohibits certain agreements, decisions and concerted practices among economic actors or “undertakings”15 “which have as their object or effect the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition within the common market. . . .”16 Any agreement, decision or concerted practice violating Article 81(1) is “automatically void.”17 Notwithstanding the forgoing, an otherwise prohibited agreement, decision or concerted practice may be exempted if it promotes, inter alia, economic efficiencies or technical progress.18

Unlike Article 81, Article 82 is not concerned per se with agreements, decisions or concerted practices involving multiple undertakings. Rather, Article 82 regulates “unilateral conduct by

11. See generally Richard Whish, Competition Law 46-47 (4th ed. 2001).

12. Guy Tritton, et al., Intellectual Property in Europe ¶ 11-001 (2d ed. 2002).

13. See Case 127/73, Belgische Radio en Televisie v. Société Belge des Auteurs, Compoiteurs et Éditeurs (SABAM), [1974] E.C.R. 51, [1974] 2 C.M.L.R. 238.

14. See Greaves, supra n.6, at 379-80.

15. Like Article 82, Article 81 regulates the conduct of “undertakings.” See E.C. Treaty arts. 81(1) & 82. “Undertaking” is undefined by the E.C. Treaty, but has been interpreted broadly to “encompass[] every entity engaged in an economic activity, regardless of the legal status of the entity and the way in which it is financed.” See Case C-41/90, Höfner & Elser v. Macrotron Gmb., [1991] E.C.R. I-1979, [1993] 4 C.M.L.R. 306, ¶ 21.

16. See E.C. Treaty art. 81(1).

17. See id. art. 81(2).

18. See id. art. 81(3).

Page 4: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1317

dominant firms which act in an abusive manner.”19 It is directed squarely at preventing the misuse of concentrated private economic power. In addition, again unlike Article 81, Article 82’s prohibition against abuse of a dominant position may not be exempted.20 On its face, therefore, Article 82 is a less discriminating, much blunter, economic regulatory instrument than Article 81.

Importantly, Article 82 does not prohibit dominant undertakings per se. Further, the ECJ “has acknowledged that since dominant undertakings can achieve a dominant position by virtue of greater efficiencies and innovativeness than competitors, they cannot be required to refrain from competing on the basis of legitimate competitive means even if such conduct has the effect of further weakening residual competition on a dominated market.”21

Neither Article 81 nor Article 82 should be interpreted “in isolation,” but rather must be understood in a wider Community context.22 Accordingly, Community competition law has been seen not merely as a vehicle to promote economic efficiencies, but also as a means to promote a wider set of policy objectives, most notably, the creation and maintenance of the single market, as well as broader social policies such as employment and consumer protection.23

One particularly controversial use of Community competition law has been its use to protect competitors, particularly small to medium size firms, from the adverse effects of the market.24 Although essentially discredited in current United States antitrust jurisprudence,25 and the subject of serious scholarly critique in the

19. See Whish, supra n.11, at 149.

20. Tritton, supra n.12, at ¶ 11-005.

21. Anderman, supra n.8, at 148, citing Case 85/76, Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v. Commission, [1979] E.C.R. 461, [1979] 3 C.M.L.R. 211, ¶ 91.

22. See Greaves, supra n.6, at 379.

23. See id.; Whish, supra n.11, at 15-19. The sweep of the Community’s social agenda is seen in Article 2 of the E.C. Treaty:

The Community shall have as its task, by establishing a common market and an economic and monetary union and by implementing common policies or activities . . ., to promote throughout the Community a harmonious, balanced and sustainable development of economic activities, a high level of employment and of social protection, equality between men and women, sustainable and non-inflationary growth, a high degree of competitiveness and convergence of economic performance, a high level of protection and improvement of the quality of the environment, the raising of the standard of living and quality of life, and economic and social cohesion and solidarity among Member States.

24. See Whish, supra n.11, at 17-18.

25. See, e.g., Richard A. Posner, Antitrust Law: An Economic Perspective 19-22 (1976); Robert H. Bork, The Antitrust Paradox: A Policy at War with Itself 205, 210-16 (1978); Whish, supra n.11, at 17-18.

Page 5: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1318 Vol. 93 TMR

Community,26 this policy is an intellectual legacy of the Freiburg School of ordoliberalism, which was active in Germany during the interwar period.27 The Freiburg School posited maintaining competition by smaller firms as a per se good necessary to avoid undesirable concentrations of economic power inherent in monopolists and cartels.28

III. THE CASE FOR TRADEMARK EXCEPTIONALITY

A. Trademarks as Intellectual Property

In a free economy, once a person has entered the market with a product, there is a right enjoyed by all to copy freely, and to compete for the sale of, that product. Intellectual property rights constitute legally sanctioned exceptions to this right to freely copy and compete.29

Intellectual property is the unsatisfactory rubric under which we traditionally gather patents, copyrights and trademarks.30 A patent is a “limited monopoly” granted by the state to an inventor (or other legally qualified applicant) as an incentive to publicly disclose the invention so that it can be worked by a “person skilled in the arts.” Among the Community’s Member States, the grant is an exclusive right to exploit an invention for a twenty-year term measured from the application date.31 To qualify, the invention must be new, involve an inventive step and be capable of industrial application.32

26. See Whish, supra n.11, at 18; see also Eleanor M. Fox, What is Harm to Competition? Exclusionary Practices and Anticompetitive Effect, 70 Antitrust L.J. 371, 404-05 (2002) (suggesting that although Community competition authorities have explicitly reject protection of competitors as a policy objective, such policy continues to underlie and influence Community competition law).

27. Whish, supra n.11, at 18; Valentine Korah, The Interface Between Intellectual Property and Antitrust: The European Experience, 69 Antitrust L.J. 801, 803 & n.9 (2002); see generally David J. Gerber, Constitutionalizing the Economy: German Neo-Liberalism, Competition Law and the “New” Europe, 42 Am. J. Comp. L. 25 (Winter 1994) (on Freiburg School).

28. See Whish, supra n.11, at 18.

29. See Cornish, supra n.5, at § 1-17; cf., Hodgkinson & Corby Ltd. v. Wards Mobility Services Ltd., 27 F.S.R. 169, 174-75 (Ch. 1995) (Applying English common law of passing off; “There is no tort of copying. There is no tort of taking a man’s market or customers. Neither the market nor the customers are the plaintiff’s to own. There is no tort of making use of another’s goodwill as such. There is no tort of competition.”).

30. See Cornish, supra n.5, at § 1-01. Intellectual property now embraces not merely these traditional categories, but also, inter alia, performer rights, sound recording rights, data base rights, appellations of origin, industrial design rights and trade secrets. See, e.g., Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS Agreement) open for signature Apr. 15, 1994, Part I, art. 1, ¶ 2 & Part II, §§ 1-7, 1867 U.N.T.S. 190.

31. See Lionel Bently & Brad Sherman, Intellectual Property Law 309 (2001).

32. See id. at 362.

Page 6: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1319

A copyright is an exclusive right conferred by the state upon authors, inter alia, to reproduce artistic, dramatic, literary or musical works. This right against copying is more limited than the patent monopoly because it does not protect the work from the independently created (i.e., non-copied) works of others. The protection afforded copyright within the Community is the author’s life plus 70 years.33 The precise qualifications for protection for copyrighted works vary under the laws of the Member States, although there appears to be emerging consensus toward a unitary Community standard that the work must embody “the author’s own intellectual creation.”34

A trademark is a different creature altogether. As Professor Michael Blakeney of the University of London observed:

Probably the principal difficulty in identifying the worthy subjects of intellectual property protection is the existence of trade marks as one of the principal categories. . . . The alleged policy of intellectual property law to provide a reward or incentive for intellectual creativity probably works for all categories of intellectual property right, with the exception of trade marks. One cannot gainsay the commercial importance of trade marks, but to dignify this institution as an intellectual property right provides a challenge for the theoretician.35

Blakeney’s discomfort regarding the place of trademarks in his pantheon is wholly warranted.

Under Community law, “[a] trade mark may consist of any sign capable of being represented graphically, particularly words, including personal names, designs, letters, numerals, the shape of goods or of their packaging, provided that such signs are capable of distinguishing the goods or services of one undertaking from those of other undertakings.”36 The essential function of a trademark “is to guarantee the identity of origin of the marked goods or services to the consumer or end users by enabling him, without any possibility of confusion, to distinguish the goods or services of others which have another origin.”37 Consequently, unlike other

33. See id. at 27.

34. J.A.L. Sterling, World Copyright Law ¶ 7.12 (1999). The traditional standard under United Kingdom law, generally perceived as less rigorous than the emerging Community standard, is that the work be the product merely of skill, labour or judgment. See id. at ¶ 7.09.

35. Michael Blakeney, Book Review, 21 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 420 (1999) (reviewing C.D.G. Pickering, Trade Marks in Theory and Practice (1998)).

36. First Council Directive 89/104/EEC of 21 December 1988 to Approximate the Laws of the Member States Relating to Trade Marks, art. 2, 1989 O.J. (L 40) (Feb. 11, 1989) (hereinafter “Trade Marks Directive”).

37. Case C-206/01, Arsenal Football Club plc v. Reed, [2002] E.C.R. I-10273, [2003] 1 C.M.L.R. 12, ¶ 48.

Page 7: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1320 Vol. 93 TMR

intellectual property, a trademark does not protect the fruits of the creative mind (e.g., an invention or artistic work).38 A trademark is merely a symbol of commercial origin,39 or, in the words of Edward S. Rogers, “[t]rade-marks are nothing but reputation symbolized.”40

A trademark may serve as a source indicia regardless of whether the consumer knows the actual identity of the proprietor; it is sufficient that the consumer recognizes the goods originate from a single, albeit anonymous, source.41 Further, the term source does not necessarily refer to either geographic or production derivation; goods manufactured in disparate places and by different manufacturers may be said to have a common trade identity or source. The unity of source arises from the fact that the public associates the branded goods with the same source as branded goods they previously knew.42 Unlike other intellectual property rights,43 trademarks may be perpetual, potentially lasting as long as does the underlying goodwill.44

Trademarks have been characterized as “monopol[ies] conferred by the state.”45 It is true that trademark registration is a state conferral of rights upon the trademark proprietor.46 It long has been an important tenant of at least Anglo-American jurisprudence, however, that the underlying right protected—the goodwill symbolized by the trademark—is the creation of the individual trademark proprietor, protectable with or without the

38. See, e.g., Bently & Sherman, supra n.31, at 660.

39. See, e.g., Beverly W. Pattishall, Trade-Marks and the Monopoly Phobia, 50 Mich. L. Rev. 967, 970-83 (May 1952) (distinguishing rationale for trademarks from those for patents and copyrights); Edward S. Rogers, Good Will, Trade-Marks and Unfair Trading 50-53 (1914) (same).

40. Edward S. Rogers, The Social Value of Trade-Marks and Brands, 37 TMR 249, 249 (1947).

41. See In re McDowell’s Application, 43 R.P.C. 313, 337 (C.A. 1926) (Warrington, L.J.); see also Frank I. Schechter, The Rational Basis of Trademark Protection, 40 Harv. L. Rev. 813, 814-17 (1927), reprinted in 60 TMR 334 (1970); but see Associated Newspapers Ltd. v. Express Newspapers, The Times, June 17, 2003, at 33 (Ch. June 11, 2003) (Laddie, J.) (“It was sufficient for the proprietor of a trade mark to show that it had a distinctive character rather than having to prove that it was a unique identifier denoting only one proprietor”!).

42. See Schechter, supra n.41, at 814-16; cf., Case C-206/01, Arsenal Football Club plc, ¶ 48 (single entity must stand behind the mark to guarantee quality).

43. But cf., Sterling, supra n.34, at ¶ 8.08 (perpetual moral rights under French copyright law).

44. See Case 192/73, Van Zuylen Frères v. Hag A.G., [1974] E.C.R. 731, [1974] 2 C.M.L.R. 127, ¶ 11 (“Hag I”); see also William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Economics of Trademark Law, 78 TMR 267, 285-86 (1988).

45. See Anselm K. Sanders & Spyros M. Maniatis, A Consumer Trade Mark: Protection Based on Origin and Quality, 11 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 406, 406, 411 (1993).

46. See, e.g., Ruth Annand & Helen Norman, Blackstone’s Guide to the Trade Marks Act 1994, at 16 (1994).

Page 8: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1321

state conferral of registration.47 Moreover, rather than being state creations, it would seem fairer to characterize trademarks as having emerged organically over centuries from the commercial world.48 Thus, in contrast to either patents or copyrights,49 trademarks seem no more the sovereign’s gift than either the institutions of private property or marriage.50

Although long pigeonholed as intellectual property, the law of trademarks has its origins in the law of fraud rather than trespass to property.51 More than fifty years ago, Beverly W. Pattishall suggested that one source of the “monopoly phobia” surrounding trademarks was the characterization of trademarks as property. Property suggests a broader scope of right in the component symbols of the trade indicia than that suggested by a right to be free from probable confusion of source.52

Moreover, the classification of trademarks as intellectual property has obfuscated the subject. Thus:

The rationale for trade mark protection will never be properly understood as long as preconceptions about the theoretical bases of patents and copyrights are allowed to obscure one’s thinking, for the rationale of trade mark protection is quite different. Trade marks are not protected to create incentives to invent brand new names or symbols. Trade marks are not protected so that one person can gain a monopoly in using a word or symbol in certain context. Trade marks are protected because of the significance that they acquire in the course of trade. . . . [T]he trade mark is a marketing symbol and its purpose comes from how it is used in the market place.53

In light of the clear tension between the underlying rationale for the protection of trademarks and that for “other” intellectual

47. See, e.g., C.D.G. Pickering, Trade Marks in Theory and Practice 57 (1998); Cornish, supra n.5, §§ 15-04 to 15-12; Milton Handler, Trade-Marks and Anti-Trust Laws, 38 TMR 387 (1948), reprinted in 88 TMR 440, 442 (1998).

48. See Schechter, supra n.4, at 19-121; Edward S. Rogers, The Lanham Act and the Social Function of Trade-Marks, 14 Law & Contemp. Probs. 173, 173-74 (Spring 1949); Sidney A. Diamond, The Historical Development of Trademarks, 65 TMR 265, 265-90 (1975); Gerald Ruston, On the Origins of Trademarks, 45 TMR 127, 127-44 (1955); Ida Madieha-Azmi, et al., Distinctive Signs and Early Markets: Europe, Africa and Islam, in The Prehistory and Development of Intellectual Property Systems 123, 132-41 (Alison Firth ed., I.P. Unit, Queen Mary, U. London, Persp. on Intell. Prop. vol. 1, 1997).

49. See Cornish, supra n.5, §§ 3-04 to 3-12, 9-01 to 9-05.

50. See Thorstein Veblen, The Beginning of Ownership, 4 Am. J. Soc. 352, 352-65 (Nov. 1898); Thorstein Veblen, The Barbarian Status of Women, 4 Am. J. Soc. 503, 503-14 (Jan. 1899).

51. See Schechter, supra n.4, at 137-38, 141-43, 152; Bently & Sherman, supra n.31, at 657-58; see also Pattishall, supra n.39, at 983-84 (analyzing the relationship of trademark law to the law of forgery).

52. See Pattishall, supra n.39, at 985-87 & n.41.

53. Pickering, supra n.47, at 157-58.

Page 9: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1322 Vol. 93 TMR

property, perhaps we would be better served by striking trademarks from the list of intellectual property and recognizing trademarks as a wholly separate jurisprudential field.

B. Trademark Utility

“Trade marks . . . have become nothing more nor less than the fundament of most market-place competition.”54 The reasons for this are clear. It is an essential premise to the rational functioning of a competitive market economy that consumers have fulsome information on products and their characteristics.55 For simple goods, such information may be obtained by direct observation prior to purchase.56 Where goods possess material unobservable features, however, it is likely that the seller will have much better product information than the buyer. Such “information asymmetry” in a market for undifferentiated products makes it a matter of mere chance whether the buyer obtains the product with the unobservable qualities desired.57 It further rewards “firms . . . produc[ing] products with the cheapest possible unobservable qualities[] because high levels of unobservable qualities would not add to a firm’s ability to sell at a higher price and realize a higher profit.”58 Under such conditions, market failure is inevitable.59

By tying goods to a single, albeit perhaps anonymous, source, trademarks differentiate goods in a manner allowing buyers to discriminate among products based upon unobservable features.60 “Trade marks provide a cipher linking information acquired by experience or from other sources to a product, thus aiding judgments about quality.”61 This linkage between the trademark and goods of a known consistent quality has the further utility of reducing consumer search costs associated with identifying desirable goods.62 Producers are given an incentive to produce consistent quality goods under the trademark because, once the buyers associate the branded product with goods of the desired

54. Cornish, supra n.5, § 15-04.

55. See W.R. Cornish & Jennifer Phillips, The Economic Function of Trade Marks: An Analysis with Special Reference to Developing Countries, 13 IIC 41, 46 (1982).

56. See Pickering, supra n.47, at 86.

57. See Nicholas S. Economides, The Economics of Trademarks, 78 TMR 523, 526 (1988); see also Pickering, supra n.47, at 86.

58. Economides, supra n.57, at 526 (footnote omitted).

59. See George Akerlof, The Market for “Lemons”: Quality Uncertainty and Market Mechanism, 84 Q.J. Econ. 488, 488-500 (1970) (classic analysis of market failure resulting from information asymmetry in market for used cars); Pickering, supra n.47, at 90; Rogers, supra n.48, at 175-76.

60. See Economides, supra n.57, at 527.

61. Cornish & Phillips, supra n.55, at 46 (footnote omitted).

62. See Landes & Posner, supra n.44, at 271-72.

Page 10: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1323

quality, the producer will obtain greater profits due both to repeat sales and to sales to new customers who learn of the quality reputation from others. These enhanced profits are the result of both higher sales volume and consumer “willing[ness] to pay higher prices in exchange for lower search costs and greater assurance of consistent quality.”63 Failure to maintain the consistent quality which buyers associate with the mark, for example, through the producer’s conscious decision to obtain a windfall profit by reducing costs associated with producing the expected higher quality, will destroy the value of the mark to the producer as buyers become aware of the change in quality and cease their purchases.64

But for trademarks, external regulation of product quality would be necessary to assure consumers that a product met at least a minimum quality.65 The cost and complexity of such a regulatory system, embracing the whole of the consumer products market, cannot be overstated.66 Moreover, even if it were possible to imagine a regulatory scheme embracing all basic categories of consumer products, it is virtually inconceivable that such a regulatory system could accommodate the degree of product differentiation which is demanded (rightly or wrongly) by Western consumers.67

Finally, in addition to the case for trademark utility, it should be remembered that “it is only fair to protect a man in the reputation he has built up for himself and his products, and [to] prevent other people from appropriating it. . . .”68

C. Trademarks: The Thin “Monopoly”

As previously discussed, the utility of a trademark comes directly from its tying goods to a single, albeit perhaps anonymous, source. It is self-evident, therefore, that use of a trademark by a person other than the source previously associated by consumers with that symbol is antithetical to the symbol’s source indicating function, at least to the extent that the junior user’s use leads consumers to associate the junior user’s use with that of the senior 63. Id., at 272; see also Pickering, supra n.47, at 88-89.

64. Landes & Posner, supra n.44, at 272; see also Benjamin Klein & Keith B. Leffler, The Role of Market Forces in Assuring Contractual Performance, 89 J. Pol. Econ. 615, 615-37 (1981); Carl Shapiro, Premiums for High Quality Products as Returns to Reputation, 98 Q.J. Econ. 659, 659-79 (Nov. 1983).

65. See Economides, supra n.57, at 530; see also Cornish & Phillips, supra n.55, at 46.

66. See Economides, supra n.57, at 530; see also Carl A. Auerbach, Quality Standards, Informative Labeling, and Grades Labeling as Guides to Consumer Buying, 14 Law & Contemp. Probs. 362 (Spring 1949) (a trademark-less post-war United States that might have been).

67. See Economides, supra n.57, at 530.

68. See Rogers, supra n.40, at 249 (emphasis added).

Page 11: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1324 Vol. 93 TMR

user. “If the law does not prevent it, free riding will eventually destroy the information capital embodied in the trademark. The prospect of free riding may therefore eliminate the incentive to develop a valuable trademark in the first place.”69 To prevent free riding (i.e., trading upon the goodwill of another) and the fraud inherent in allowing one person to pass off his or her goods as those of another, historically the law has afforded protection against the use of marks likely to cause confusion.70

The “exclusive right” recognized by trademark law (i.e., to be free from confusingly similar marks) is very different from the exclusive right in a patented invention or the protection from copying in a copyrighted work. As previously discussed,71 the trademark right protects not the good itself, but rather the indicia of source for that good (or, more accurately, the goodwill symbolized by the indicia). But even as to the source indicia, the “exclusive right” is quite limited.

The threshold for establishing a protectable trademark interest in a symbol can be relatively demanding. By its very terms, Community law denies trademark protection to a symbol which, inter alia, “consist[s] exclusively” of elements constituting trade designations of “kind, quality, quantity, intended purpose, value, geographic origin or the time of production of the goods . . . or other characteristics of the goods . . .”72 or which have become “customary in the current language or in . . . the practices of the trade.”73 This prohibition is qualified, however, because trademark protection may be accorded to a descriptive symbol upon a showing that it has acquired a “distinctive character” through use.74 It follows, therefore, that trademark protection is accorded as a matter of right under Community law75 only where the symbol, although pre-existing, has no linguistic meaning in relationship to the product (i.e., an arbitrary mark such as KIWI for shoe polish)

69. Landes & Posner, supra n.44, at 272; see also Sanders & Maniatis, supra n.45, at 411 & nn.42-43.

70. See Schechter, supra n.41, at 820-22; see also Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property of March 20, 1883 (as amended), art. 10bis (3)(1), 828 U.N.T.S. 305 (hereinafter “Paris Convention”).

71. See supra at Section III.A.

72. Trade Marks Directive art. 3, § 1.(c); Council Regulation (EC) No. 40/94 of 20 December 1993 on the Community Trade Marks, art. 7, § 1.(c), 1995 O.J. (L 303) 1 (Dec. 15, 1995) (hereinafter “CTM Regulation”).

73. Trade Marks Directive art. 3, § 1.(d); CTM Regulation art. 7, § 1.(d).

74. Trade Marks Directive art. 3, § 3; CTM Regulation art. 7, § 3.

75. Subject, of course, to earlier conflicting rights, Trade Marks Directive art. 4; CTM Regulation art. 8, other absolute prohibitions, see Trade Marks Directive art. 3, § 1.(f)&(g); CTM Regulation art. 7, § 1.(f)&(g), and making use of the symbol in a manner in which the public will understand it to be an indicia of origin, see Case C-299/99, Koninkijke Philips Elecs. NV v. Remington Consumer Prods. Ltd., [2002] E.C.R. I-5475, [2002] 2 C.M.L.R. 52, ¶¶ 63-64.

Page 12: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1325

or did not previously exist and was created specifically to serve as a trademark (i.e., a coined mark such as XEROX for photo-copiers), or where the symbol, while having some linguistic relationship to the product, is “merely allusive or suggestive” of the goods rather than being directly descriptive thereof (e.g., BABY-DRY for disposable diapers).76

As previously noted, a descriptive symbol may be protected under Community law where it becomes distinctive of the adopter’s goods through use. The more descriptive the symbol, the greater the evidentiary showing must be before trademark protection is accorded.77 Some terms are so descriptive, being understood by consumers as the “apt” or “common name” of the goods, that no degree of acquired distinctiveness will be sufficient to make them protectable trademarks.78

Even where a symbol is deemed worthy of trademark protection, such protection does not confer an absolute right in the symbol. Community law explicitly provides that a trademark right shall not entitle the owner to prohibit third party trade use of descriptive terms provided that such usages are “in accordance with honest practices in industrial or commercial matters.”79 In other words, “just as the owner of the ‘Vittel’ trade mark cannot prohibit another producer from stating in good faith that its water is bottled at Vittel, . . . Proctor & Gamble[, owner of the ‘Baby-Dry’ trade mark for disposable diapers, cannot] prevent a rival from claiming that its diapers ‘keep your baby dry.’”80

The “exclusive” trademark right does not even extend to prevention of third party use of the mark to describe the third party’s goods vis-à-vis the trademark owner’s goods. Thus, Community law also explicitly provides that a trademark right shall not entitle the owner to prohibit third party trade use of the trademark itself “where it is necessary to indicate the intended purpose of a product . . ., in particular as accessories or spare

76. See Case C-191/01 P, O.H.I.M. v. Wm. Wrigley Jr. Co., [2003] E.C.R. ___, [2003] E.T.M.R. 88, ¶¶ 56-57 (10 Apr. 2003) (Opinion of Jacobs, A.G.) (DOUBLEMINT); Cornish, supra n.5 §17-30.

77. See Joint Cases C-108 & 109/97, Winsurfing Chiemsee Produktions und Vertriebs GmbH v. Huber, [1999] E.C.R. I-2779, [1999] E.T.M.R. 585, ¶¶ 47-53; see also Spyros M. Maniatis, Aspects of Trade Mark Use and Misuse, in Trade Marks Retrospective 231, 252-54 (Norma Dawson & Alison Firth eds., I.P. Unit, Queen Mary, U. London, Persp. on Intell. Prop. vol. 7, 2000) .

78. See JERYL LYNN Trade Mark, 26 F.S.R. 334, 497-98 & 504 (Ch. 1998) (Laddie, J.). Whether a term is an unprotectable generic designation, however, should not be determined in the abstract, but rather should turn upon consumer understanding of the term in connection with the subject goods or services. See Trade Marks Directive art. 3, §§ 1 & 3; CTM Regulation art. 7, §§ 1 & 3.

79. See Trade Marks Directive art. 6, § 1; CTM Regulation art. 12.

80. Case C-383/99 P, Procter & Gamble Co. v. O.H.I.M., [2001] E.C.R. I-6251, [2002] E.T.M.R. 17, ¶ 48 (Opinion of Jacobs, A.G.) (“BABY-DRY”).

Page 13: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1326 Vol. 93 TMR

parts,” again subject to the requirements of commercial morality.81 The “exclusive” trademark right even has been found not to preclude trade use of the mark to describe directly competitive goods as being of the same kind as the trademark owner’s goods.82 Moreover, whether through the trademark owners own misuse of the trademark, or simply because the public independently comes to perceive the mark as the “apt” or “common name” of the product, previously valid trademark rights in a symbol may be forfeited (e.g., CELLOPHANE, ASPIRIN, ESCALATOR).83

The “exclusive” trademark right basically extends no further than to preclude uses likely to cause source confusion.84 The likelihood of confusion must be among a material number of potential consumers and be determined through a global appreciation of relevant factors.85 Accordingly, trade identity protection within the bounds of likelihood of confusion does not prevent any use of the subject symbol beyond that necessary to prevent consumer source deception. “[T]o the extent that its corresponding use by others is likely to result in confusion of source with the prior user, that much the prior user’s individual trade identity should be protected and use denied to another—no more, no less.”86

The monopoly specter is particularly raised by extending trademark protection to three-dimensional objects, including product shapes.87 Under Community law, if a three-dimensional object has a distinctive character (either inherent or acquired), then it is capable of distinguishing the goods of one person from 81. See Trade Marks Directive art. 6, § 1; CTM Regulation art. 12; see also Case C-63/97, Bayerische Motorenwerke AG (BMW) v. Deenik, [1999] E.C.R. I-905, [1999] 1 C.M.L.R. 1099, ¶¶ 39-64 (1999); Spyros M. Maniatis, supra n.77, at 254-56.

82. See Case C/2/00, Hölterhoff v. Freiesleben, [2002] E.C.R. I-4187, [2002] F.S.R. 52, ¶¶ 16-17.

83. See Trade Marks Directive art. 12, § 2; CTM Regulation art. 50, § 1; see also JERYL LYNN Trade Mark, 26 F.S.R. at 497-98.

84. See Trade Marks Directive art. 5, § 1; CTM Regulation art. 9, § 1(a)-(b). Thus, it may be possible for two different individuals to own valid trademark rights in the same mark, albeit for wholly dissimilar goods. See, e.g., L.E. Waterman Co. v. Gordon, 72 F.2d 272, 273 (2d Cir. 1934) (Learned Hand, C.J.) (“There is indeed a limit; the goods on which the supposed infringer puts the mark may be too remote from any that the owner would be likely to sell. It would be hard, for example, for the seller of a steam shovel to find ground for complaint in the use of his trade-mark on a lipstick.”); but cf., Trade Marks Directive art. 5, § 2 (extending protection against signs which take unfair advantage of, or are detrimental to, the distinctive character or repute of the trademark); CTM Regulation art. 9, § 1(c) (same); Case C-292/00, Davidoff & Cie SA v. Gofkid Ltd., [2003] E.C.R. I-389, [2003] 1 C.M.L.R. 35, ¶¶ 26 & 30.

85. See Case C-39/97, Canon KK v. Metro-Goldwyn-Mayer Inc., [1998] E.C.R. I-5507, [1999] 1 C.M.L.R. 77, ¶¶ 15-19.

86. Pattishall, supra n.39, at 979.

87. Robert Burrell, et al., Three-Dimensional Trade Marks: Should the Directive be Reshaped?, in Trade Marks Retrospective 139, 139 & 156-58 (Norma Dawson & Alison Firth ed., I.P. Unit, Queen Mary, U. London, Persp. on Intell. Prop. vol. 7, 2000).

Page 14: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1327

those of another and, generally, may be accorded trademark protection.88 Trademark protection, however, explicitly is denied symbols which “consist exclusively” of: “the shape resulting from the nature of the goods themselves”; “the shape of the goods which is necessary to obtain a technical result”; or “the shape which gives substantial value to the goods.”89 These provisions are to be interpreted to protect the “public interest” against the creation under trademark law of a monopoly “on technical solutions or functional characteristics of a product which a user is likely to seek in the products of competitors.”90 With regard to technical solutions, it is of no consequence that alternatives are available.91 These prohibitions are absolute; no degree of acquired distinctiveness will confer protectable rights.92 Consequently, as a matter of law, trademark protection is withheld from functional and technical product features and, absent some other intellectual property right in such features, they are freely available for use by all.

For the reasons previously discussed, trademark “monopoly,” such as it is, is quite thin.93

D. Trademarks in the Community Context

Intellectual property rights, including trademarks, historically have been viewed with suspicion within European Community jurisprudence.94 This, in part, is another Freiburg School legacy;95 the ordoliberals viewed such rights as sources of undesirable, undemocratic “monopoly” power.96 Such hostility also is attributable to an unrelenting pursuit of the single market imperative. Because intellectual property rights largely are creatures of the national laws of each Member State and are territorial in scope (and, therefore, largely geographically coterminous with national borders), such rights were perceived as impediments to the creation of the single European market.97 A direct assault upon intellectual property rights, however, seemed to be precluded by the E.C. Treaty itself, which provides that the

88. Case C-299/99, Koninkijke Philips Elecs. NV v. Remington Consumer Prods. Ltd., [2002] E.C.R. I-5475, [2002] 2 C.M.L.R. 52, ¶¶ 47-50.

89. Trade Marks Directive art. 3, § 1.(e); CTM Regulation art. 7, § 1.(e).

90. Case C-299/99, Koninkijke Philips Elecs. NV, at ¶¶ 77-78.

91. See id. at ¶ 81.

92. See id. at ¶ 76.

93. See Rogers, supra n.40, at 249 (“monopoly” interest in trademarks is no greater than the “monopoly” enjoyed by the owners of realty or tangible personalty).

94. See Korah, supra n.27, at 803.

95. See supra Section II.

96. See Korah, supra n.27, at 803-04 & n.9; Gerber, supra n.27, at 52

97. See Korah, supra n.27, at 803.

Page 15: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1328 Vol. 93 TMR

Treaty does not “prejudice the rules in Member States governing the system of property ownership.”98

To combat the perceived threat posed by intellectual property rights to European integration, the ECJ adopted a view under which it “drew a distinction between the grant or existence of a national intellectual property right, which was not subject to the [E.C.] Treaty, and its exercise, which was.”99 Of course, “[t]he lawyer’s definition of a right that exists is the sum of the ways it can be exercised.”100 This existence/exercise dichotomy seemingly defies meaningful legal analysis and has been described by Professor Valentine Korah of the University of London in terms of being essentially an ex post facto rationalization for upholding or striking down intellectual property rights as best fits the ECJ’s market integration objectives.101

Through the application of the existence/exercise dichotomy, the Court imposed an aggressive regime of exhaustion of rights within the Common Market.102 Accordingly,

once a protected product had been put on the market by the holder of an intellectual property right or with its consent in one member state, the right was exhausted and a parallel intellectual property right could not be used to restrain the commercial importation of the product to another member state. The integration of the market trumped the rationale for intellectual property rights. . . .103 Even within this generally hostile environment for intellectual

property rights, trademarks were singled out for special enmity.104 The ECJ explicitly stated that trademarks are “distinguishable . . . from other forms of industrial and commercial property, inasmuch as the interests protected by the latter are usually more important, and merit a higher degree of protection, than the interests protected by an ordinary trade-mark.”105 Further, “[t]he exercise of a trade-mark right is particularly apt to lead to partitioning of markets, and thus to impair the free movement of goods between

98. See E.C. Treaty art. 295.

99. See Korah, supra n.27, at 805, citing Case 56/64, Etablishment Costen SA v. Commission, [1966] E.C.R. 299, [1966] C.M.L.R. 418.

100. Korah, supra n.27, at 805 & n.17.

101. See id. at 805.

102. See id. at 805-06.

103. Id. at 805 (footnote omitted); see generally Whish, supra n.11, at 704-11.

104. See James M. Naftel, Exclusive Trade Mark Licensing, Article 85 and Market Definition, 18 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 406, 407 (1996) (noting historical ECJ animosity to trademarks); Korah, supra n.27, at 806-07 (noting “earlier customary” dismissal of the significance of trademarks by ECJ).

105. See Case 40/70, Sirena S.r.l. v. Eda S.r.l., [1971] E.C.R. 69, [1971] C.M.L.R. 260, ¶ 7.

Page 16: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1329

states which is essential to the Common Market.”106 Although the source indicating functions of trademarks were deemed “useful” to consumers, the Court dismissively concluded that this function could be served by means (tellingly not specified by the Court) other than disruptive trademarks.107 Trademarks also were deemed to be suspect because, unlike other forms of intellectual property, they existed for an indefinite term.108 Not until the early 1980’s did this general antipathy to intellectual property rights begin to abate within the Community.109

It is not surprising, therefore, that the ECJ “has long maintained that the prohibitions in Articles [81] and [82] are unyielding restrictions upon the exercise of intellectual property rights,” and “has regularly held that the exercise of [intellectual property rights] must defer to the competition rules in cases where the two are in conflict.”110

IV. ARTICLE 82 VIOLATION

Article 82 provides in pertinent part, “Any abuse by one or more undertaking of a dominant position within the common market or in a substantial part of it shall be prohibited as incompatible with the common market insofar as it may affect trade between Member States.” Consequently, the elements of an Article 82 violation may be said to be: (1) the action taken by the undertaking that is the subject of complaint must affect trade between the Member States; (2) the undertaking (or undertakings) must have a dominant position; (3) the dominance must extend to the whole or a substantial part of the Common Market; and (4) the undertaking’s conduct must be deemed to be an abuse within the meaning of Article 82. We examine each element in turn.

A. Inter-State Trade Effect

To fall within Article 82’s parameters, an undertaking’s conduct must have an effect upon trade between Member States. “The inter-Member State trade clause is . . . of central importance in E.C. Competition law, since it defines ‘the boundary between the areas respectively covered by Community Law and the law of

106. Id.; see also Case 192/73, Van Zuylen Frères v. Hag A.G., [1974] E.C.R. 731, [1974] 2 C.M.L.R. 127, ¶¶ 11-15 (“Hag I”).

107. Case 192/73, Hag I, ¶ 14.

108. Id. ¶ 11.

109. See Korah, supra n.27, at 807; see also Case C-10/89, CNL Sucal v. Hag A.G., [1990] E.C.R. I-3711, [1990] 3 C.M.L.R. 571, ¶ 14 (“Hag II”).

110. Anderman, supra n.8, at 9 (footnote omitted).

Page 17: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1330 Vol. 93 TMR

the Member States.’”111 The inter-Member State trade clause has been liberally construed to provide an expansive application of Article 82.112 The requirement is satisfied if the alleged conduct could affect the structure of competition within the specified market, for example, through the elimination of a competitor.113 “In view of the territorial nature of intellectual property rights, it is extremely unlikely that a situation could be envisaged often where an argument could be sustained that the behaviour of the owner of the right did not affect trade between Member States.”114

B. Dominance

The ECJ has defined “dominance” as “a position of economic strength enjoyed by an undertaking which enables it to prevent effective competition being maintained on the relevant market by affording it the power to behave to an appreciable extent independently of its competitors, customers and ultimately of its consumers.”115 The ability of an undertaking to act independently on the market is the essential condition for finding dominance.116 The determination of whether an undertaking holds a dominant position is a two-step process requiring: (1) the identification of the pertinent market; and, (2) the determination of whether the subject undertaking enjoys market power within that market.117

1. Market Definition

According to the European Commission, relevant market definition “is a tool to identify and define the boundaries of competition between firms.” 118 The defined market establishes

111. Whish, supra n.11, at 111, quoting Case 22/78, Hugin Kassaregister AB v. Commission, [1979] E.C.R. 1869, 1899, [1979] 3 C.M.L.R. 245, 373. The inter-Member State trade clause is similar to the Commerce Clause of the United States Constitution, U.S. Const. art. I, § 8, the fault line between the federal and state regulations of commercial activities. See United States v. Lopez, 514 U.S. 549, 552-61 (1995).

112. See Whish, supra n.11, at 111, 151.

113. See id. at 113, 118, 151.

114. Greaves, supra n.6, at 380; see also Hedvig K.S. Schmidt, Article 82’s “Exceptional Circumstances” That Restrict Intellectual Property Rights, 23 Eur. Competition L. Rev. 210, 211 (2002). At least in connection with Article 81 cases, however, there does seem to be some trend in the direction of deferring to Member State regulation in this field by declining to find the requisite effect. See Whish, supra n.11, at 111.

115. Case 27/76, United Brands Co. v. Commission, [1978] E.C.R. 207, [1978] 1 C.M.L.R. 429, ¶ 65.

116. See Whish, supra n.11, at 153.

117. See id. at 152; see also Greaves, supra n.6, at 380.

118. European Commission Notice on the Definition of the Relevant Market for Purposes of Community Competition Law, 1997 O.J. (C 372), [1998] 4 C.M.L.R. 177, ¶ 2 (hereinafter “Commission Notice”). The Commission Notice is merely a policy statement; it is not legally binding. See Whish, supra n.11, at 31-32.

Page 18: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1331

“the framework within which competition policy is applied. . . .”119 “The main purpose of market definition is to identify in a systematic way the competitive constraints that the undertaking involved face.”120 Accordingly, a relevant market is defined in terms of both products and geographic area in order to determine both existing and potential competitors of the subject undertaking that are capable of constraining the undertaking’s behavior and of preventing it from behaving independently of effective competitive pressure.121 Market definition, therefore, is more an economic judgment than a legal determination.

The product market component is not limited to the particular product being offered by the subject undertaking. Rather, the relevant product market “comprises all those products . . . which are regarded as interchangeable or substitutable by the consumer, by reason of the products’ characteristics, their prices and their intended use.”122 The geographic market component “comprises the area in which the undertakings concerned are involved in the supply and demand of products . . ., in which the conditions of competition are sufficiently homogeneous and which can be distinguished from neighbouring areas because conditions of competition are appreciably different in those areas.”123 Thus, the geographic component essentially frames the relevant product market, and has been said to be “obvious” in most cases.124

There are two principal sources of competitive restraint defining the relevant market: demand substitutability; and supply substitutability.125 Demand substitutability generally is considered to be the more important of these sources.126 Demand substitutability analyzes the range of products viewed as substitutes by consumers.127

Supply substitutability analyzes whether suppliers are able to switch production to the relevant products. Supply substitutability should be considered only where suppliers are “able to switch productions to the relevant products and market them in the short term [(i.e., the period which does not imply a significant adjustment of existing tangible and intangible assets . . .)] without incurring significant additional costs or risk. . . .”128

119. Commission Notice, supra n.118, ¶ 2.

120. Id. ¶ 2 (footnote omitted).

121. See id. ¶¶ 2 & 13.

122. Id. ¶ 7.

123. Id. ¶ 8.

124. See Greaves, supra n.6, at 380.

125. Commission Notice, supra n.118, ¶ 13; see generally Whish, supra n.11, at 26-30.

126. Commission Notice, supra n.118, ¶ 13.

127. Id. ¶ 15.

128. Id. ¶ 20.

Page 19: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1332 Vol. 93 TMR

A third source of competitive restraint, albeit one which is not used to define the relevant market, is potential competition. Potential competition analyzes whether new suppliers will enter the pertinent market to produce and distribute relevant products. If deemed relevant, the effect of potential competition is considered only once other competitors are identified and the analysis suggests the existence of a competitive problem in the relevant market.129

Conceptually, defining the relevant market in terms of substitutable products appears quite straight forward. The practical application of the principle, however, may be more complex.130 In order to make the determination of substitutability, the Commission has adopted the so-called SSNIP test (i.e., Small but Significant Non-transitory Increase in Price).131 The SSNIP test assumes the subject undertaking has made a “hypothetically small (in the range 5% to 10%), but permanent relative price increase in the products and areas being considered.”132 The effect of this hypothetical price rise is then analyzed in terms of demand substitution and, if appropriate, supply substitution. If in reaction to this price increase customers of the subject undertaking “would switch to readily available substitutes or to suppliers located elsewhere . . . [so as] to make the price increase unprofitable because of the resulting lost sales, . . . [these] substitutes and areas are included in the relevant market.”133

Both the Commission134 and the ECJ135 have recognized that the definition of the relevant market often has a decisive influence on the determination of the existence of dominance in an Article 82 investigation.136 “‘If the market is wrongly defined, then all 129. Id. ¶ 24.

130. See David Harbord & Georg von Graevenitz, Market Definition in Oligopolistic & Vertically Related Markets: Some Anomalies, 21 Eur. Competition L. Rev. 151 (2000).

131. See Commission Notice, supra n.118, ¶ 15; see also Whish, supra n.11, at 27. Interestingly, although SSNIP was developed by the United States Department of Justice, the test is not used by it to define markets in cartel and monopolization cases, but rather only in merger cases. Whish, supra n.11, at 27-28 & n.9; see also Harbord & von Graevenitz, supra n.130, at 151-52.

132. Commission Notice, supra n.118, ¶ 17.

133. Id. In applying the SSNIP test, care must be exercised to avoid the so-called “Cellophane fallacy.” Accordingly, if a product is being supplied by an undertaking already holding a monopoly position, and a “monopolist price” is being charged for the product, then it follows that further price increase will be unprofitable. “Implementing the SSNIP test from the current monopoly price will lead us to define the relevant . . . market too widely, and we will incorrectly conclude that a monopolist has no market power.” See Harbord & von Graevenitz, supra n.130, at 151-52; see also Whish, supra n.11, at 28-29.

134. See Commission Notice, supra n.118, ¶ 4.

135. See, e.g., Case 6/72, Europemballage Corp. & Continental Can Co. Inc. v. Commission, [1973] E.C.R. 215, [1973] C.M.L.R. 199, ¶ 32.

136. See Whish, supra n.11, at 25; Schmidt, supra n.114, at 211; Tritton, supra n.12, at ¶ 11-005.

Page 20: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1333

subsequent analysis based on market shares or market structure is flawed.’”137

In general, a broadly defined market, with an expected corresponding increase in potential substitute goods, makes a finding of dominance by an undertaking under Article 82 less likely.138 Inevitably in an Article 82 investigation, the Commission will define the market narrowly in both product and geographic terms to facilitate a finding of dominance.139 For example, in United Brands Co., a case “often referred to as a paradigm” for narrow market definitions,140 the ECJ affirmed the Commission’s determination that bananas, not fresh fruit generally, constituted the relevant product market. The Court justified this extremely narrow market definition on the grounds that bananas are interchangeable with other fresh fruit to “only a limited extent” because bananas are a year-round fruit, thus not subject to “unavoidable seasonal substitutions.” Further, as compared to other fruits, and in particular other year-round fruits such as apples, grapes and oranges, bananas were characterized by an “appearance, taste, seedlessness, easy handling, [and] constant level of production which enabled it to satisfy the constant needs of an important section of the population consisting of the very young, the old and the sick.”141

The limitation of the United Brands’ market to bananas seems unduly restrictive. Thus:

When assessing demand-side substitution it is not necessary for all consumers to switch away from bananas for the wider market to be relevant. It would have been sufficient for the parties to show that a sufficient number of consumers would consider other fruits substitutes to render the hypothetical price increase unprofitable. However, . . . the [ECJ] appears to have required virtually complete substitutability, ignoring the existence of many marginal customers who could have switched away from bananas and whose existence could very well have constrained pricing to competitive levels. 142

137. Harbord & von Graevenitz, supra n.130, at 153, quoting National Economic Research Assocs., Market Definition in U.K. Competition Policy (U.K. Office of Fair Trading, Research Rep. No. 1, 1992).

138. See Whish, supra n.11, at 27.

139. See, e.g., Greaves, supra n.6, at 379; Oliver Vrins, Intellectual Property Licensing and Competition Law: Some News From the Front—The Role of Market Power and Double Jeopardy in the E.C. Commission’s New Deal, 23 Eur. Intell. Prop. Rev. 576, 579 (2001).

140. See Vrins, supra n.139, at 579.

141. See Case 27/76, United Brands Co. v. Commission, [1978] E.C.R. 207, [1978] 1 C.M.L.R. 429, ¶¶ 12-35.

142. National Economic Research Assocs., The Role of Market Definition in Monopoly and Dominance Inquiries 26 (U.K. Office of Fair Trading, Econ. Discussion Paper 2, July 2001).

Page 21: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1334 Vol. 93 TMR

In addition, the emphasis placed by the Court upon unique

product characteristics such as softness and “seedlessness,” and the purported appeal that such features hold for consumers, particularly the elderly, does not seem grounded in empirical data.143 Such reasoning by Community competition authorities and the courts appears to be “malleable” and lacking of analytic “rigor,” which “suggests impressionistic reasoning in service of a predetermined (regulatory) outcome. . . .”144

2. Market Power

Having defined the relevant market, one must determine whether the subject undertaking is dominant within that market. As previously noted,145 a dominant undertaking is one that has the ability to act independently on the market. Such independence may manifest itself in various ways such as an “ability to act as a price leader, if it can dictate the conditions of sale for its products, if it is able to deter entry [into the market by other undertakings], or if it can make persistently super-normal profits.”146 A dominant firm is said to enjoy market power.147

The degree of market power enjoyed by a given undertaking will vary according to the particular conditions of competition prevailing within the relevant market. Under the conditions of “perfect competition,” it is presumed that no undertaking within the relevant market possesses market power, and they “have to take the going price, and cannot hope to alter it on their own.”148 When one or more undertakings possess market power, they can unilaterally change the market conditions as described above. The greater degree of independence from market constraints enjoyed by the undertaking, the greater degree of market power it is said to possess.149 Thus, there is a continuum of market power rising from none in a hypothetical perfect market150 to total market power where a relevant market is reduced to a single supplier (i.e., a monopoly).151 True monopolies are rare, however, and almost all

143. See id. at 26-27.

144. See Per Jebsen & Robert Stevens, Assumptions, Goals and Dominant Undertakings: The Regulation of Competition Under Article 86 of the European Union, 64 Antitrust L.J. 443, 471-72 (Spring 1996).

145. See supra Section IV.B.

146. See John Black, Oxford Dictionary of Economics 292 (2d ed. 2002).

147. Whish, supra n.11, at 153; Black, supra n.146, at 292.

148. Graham Bannock, et al., Penguin Dictionary of Economics 263 (6th ed. 1998).

149. Id.

150. See generally Pickering, supra n.47, at 72-73 (on perfect free markets).

151. See Bannock, supra n.148, at 263, 283.

Page 22: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1335

Article 82 cases will fall somewhere between these points of the continuum.152

Although not dispositive, an undertaking’s market share within a relevant market “may be regarded as a proxy, albeit an imperfect one, for determining dominance. . . .”153 In general terms, the greater the market share, the greater the likelihood of a finding of dominance under Article 82. It does appear, however, that a market share of approximately 40% will be required to establish the existence of a dominant position under Article 82.154 Moreover, market share may rise to a sufficiently high percentage that, absent a showing of “exceptional circumstances,” market share evidence alone will be deemed to establish dominance, particularly where a large share is maintained over time.155 Where an undertaking is shown to possess a market share of at least 50%, a rebuttable presumption of dominance is established.156

In most cases, however, an inquiry beyond determination of market share alone should be made.157 Additional factors which may be pertinent include: barriers to entry; conduct (e.g., discriminatory pricing offers, other anticompetitive conduct); economic performance (e.g., idle production capacity); and wrongful intent to monopolize. Of these, barriers to entry are the most important factor.

Barriers to entry are “[e]conomic and technical factors which prevent or make it difficult for firms to enter a market and compete with existing suppliers.”158 Under Community law, barriers to entry may include: legal provisions (e.g., intellectual property rights, government licensed activities, domestic content laws); superior technology; deep pockets (i.e., access to capital); economies of scale; vertical integration and distribution systems; product differentiation; and opportunity costs.159 It is further suggested that competition authorities and the courts are likely to interpret “‘technical and commercial advantages’ of any kind” as

152. Whish, supra n.11, at 153.

153. Id. at 153-54.

154. See id. at 43; but see European Commission, Xth Report on Competition Policy ¶ 150 n.4 (1981) (market share of merely 20% may be sufficient). A firm probably would not be deemed dominant under United States law without at least a 60% market share. See Jebsen & Stevens, supra n.144, at 479.

155. Whish, supra n.11, at 154, citing Case 85/76, Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v. Commission, [1979] E.C.R. 461, [1979] 3 C.M.L.R. 211, ¶ 41.

156. Whish, supra n.11, at 154-55, citing Case C-62/86, AKZO v. Commission, [1991] E.C.R. I-3359, [1993] 5 C.M.L.R. 215.

157. See Whish, supra n.11, at 41, 153-54.

158. Bannock, supra n.148, at 28.

159. See Whish, supra n.11, at 156-61; see also Bannock, supra n.148, at 28; Black, supra n.146, at 27.

Page 23: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1336 Vol. 93 TMR

suspect barriers to entry.160 It is remarkable that many of these “barriers” may “reflect nothing more than efficiency and success in enhancing consumer welfare,” and their treatment as indicia of dominance “suggests a certain predisposition with respect to outcome.”161

Under Community law, the consequences of a finding that an undertaking holds a dominant position are significant. The most obvious of these consequences is, of course, that Article 82 may only be invoked against a dominant undertaking. Moreover, the ECJ has held that a dominant undertaking “has a special responsibility not to allow its conduct to impair undistorted competition on the general market.”162 The special responsibilities imposed upon dominant undertakings create duties not merely within the relevant market in which the undertaking is deemed to be dominant, but also in ancillary markets.163

Where an undertaking is not merely dominant, but “‘enjoys a position of dominance approaching a monopoly’” (e.g., 90%), it may be said to be in a position of “super-dominance.”164 It has been suggested that undertakings enjoying a super-dominant position may be prohibited from engaging in activities that would otherwise not be deemed abusive under Article 82.165 In any event, it seems clear that a super-dominant undertaking is subject to a heightened version of the special duty imposed upon merely dominant undertakings and is therefore more likely to be found to be guilty of abuse under Article 82.166

C. Common Market

A finding of mere dominance is insufficient under Article 82; such dominance must be found to exist throughout the whole or a substantial portion of the Common Market. This requirement is not merely a reiteration of the determination of the pertinent 160. See Jebsen & Stevens, supra n.144, at 484, quoting Case 85/76, Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v. Commission, [1979] E.C.R. 461, [1979] 3 C.M.L.R. 211, ¶ 48.

161. See Jebsen & Stevens, supra n.144, at 483-84.

162. E.g., Case 322/81, Michelin v. Commission, [1983] E.C.R. 3461, [1985] 1 C.M.L.R. 282, ¶ 57; see also Whish, supra n.11, at 161-62.

163. See Jebsen & Stevens, supra n.144, at 476-78.

164. See Whish, supra n.11, at 162-63, quoting Joined Cases 395 & 396/96P, Compagnie Maritime Belge Transps. SA v. Commission, [2000] E.C.R. I-1365, [2000] 4 C.M.L.R. 1076, ¶ 136 (Opinion of Fennelly, A.G.). The concept of “super-dominance” has not been explicitly adopted by the ECJ. See Whish, supra n.11, at 163. Rather, the court has characterized cases involving the existence of near monopoly conditions as involving “‘special circumstances of the case.’” See id., quoting Case C-333/94 P, Tetra Pak v. Commission, [1996] E.C.R. I-5951, [1997] 4 C.M.L.R. 662, ¶ 24. Professor Whish’s “super-dominance” concept, however, does appear to be a useful tool in understanding the application of Article 82.

165. See Whish, supra n.11, at 162-63.

166. See id. at 162-63, 167; see also Anderman, supra n.8, at 150.

Page 24: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1337

geographic market, but rather is a requirement to avoid de minimis violations.167 Dominance throughout the Common Market would appear to satisfy this requirement per se.168

Where less than the entire Common Market is involved, the issue of “substantiality” does not turn merely upon the physical size of the territory in which dominance exists and the determination must be made with reference to a variety of market factors.169 There is no magic threshold share of the overall product market set by Community law for “substantiality.”170 However, “it is likely that each Member State would be considered to be a substantial portion of the common market, in particular where an undertaking enjoys a statutory monopoly. . . .”171

D. Abuse

The next element is whether the subject dominant undertaking has abused its dominant position. “The concept of abuse is an objective concept. . . .”172 Consequently, “behaviour can be abusive even where the dominant undertaking had no intention of infringing Article 82.”173 In interpreting the meaning of abuse under Article 82, the ECJ has given great weight to the need to promote the policy objectives embodied in Articles 2 and 3(g) of the E.C. Treaty.174

The reach of Article 82 is not restricted to large firms or major economic activities; Article 82 may be used to regulate even the most obscure economic sectors.175 Thus, a firm with worldwide sales of approximately £38,000,000 was deemed dominant in the market for British-style brass band instruments.176 Discriminatory sales of 574,300 tickets to the 1998 World Cup was deemed an Article 82 abuse.177

167. See Whish, supra n.11, at 164; see also Greaves, supra n.6, at 380.

168. See Whish, supra n.11, at 164.

169. See id., citing Case 40/73, Coöperative Vereinigung “Suiker Unie” v. Commission, [1975] E.C.R. 1663, [1976] 1 C.M.L.R. 295, ¶ 371.

170. See Whish, supra n.11, at 164-65.

171. See id. at 164; see also Greaves, supra n.6, at 380.

172. Case 85/76, Hoffmann-La Roche & Co. AG v. Commission, [1979] E.C.R. 461, [1979] 3 C.M.L.R. 211, ¶ 91.

173. See Whish, supra n.11, at 167.

174. See id.; see also Jebsen & Stevens, supra n.144, at 458-61; see generally supra Section II.

175. Whish, supra n.11, at 165-66.

176. BBI/Boosey & Hawkes: Interim Measures, [1987] O.J. L-286/36, [1988] 4 C.M.L.R. 67 (Eur. Comm.).

177. Football World Cup 1998, 2000 O.J. (L-5/55), [2000] 4 C.M.L.R. 67 (Eur. Comm.).

Page 25: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1338 Vol. 93 TMR

Article 82 does not provide a comprehensive definition of what conduct constitutes an abuse. Rather, Article 82 contains a non-exclusive list of conduct constituting “abuse,” namely:

(a) directly or indirectly imposing unfair purchase or selling prices or other unfair trading conditions;

(b) limiting production, markets or technical development to the prejudice of consumers;

(c) applying dissimilar conditions to equivalent transactions with other trading parties, thereby placing them at a competitive disadvantage;

(d) making the conclusion of contracts subject to acceptance by the other parties of supplementary obligations which, by their nature or according to commercial usage, have no connection with the subject of such contracts.178

Article 82 can be said to embrace three different concepts of abuse—exploitative conduct, anticompetitive practices, and abuses harmful to the single market.179 Exploitative conduct “is the narrower economic concept of ‘exploitive abuse’, i.e. conduct which consists of using market power to extract supracompetitive gains from customers by unfairly high prices . . . and limiting supply to markets. . . .”180 Exploitive conduct is explicitly prohibited by sub-sections (a) and (b) of Article 82.

Anticompetitive practices are “predatory or ‘anticompetitive abuse,’ i.e. conduct attempting to evict or exclude competitors from the market.” 181 Although said to be “hinted at” in the sub-section (c) discriminatory treatment prohibition and in the subsection (d) tie-in prohibition, the prohibition against anticompetitive practices is not explicit in Article 82.182 Rather, Article 82’s sweeping anticompetitive conduct prohibition was inferred by the ECJ from Article 82, together with Articles 2 (e.g., promoting continuous and balanced economic expansion) and 3(g) (i.e., prohibiting market distortions), so as not merely to prevent market distortions, but also to preserve competition within markets.183 Anticompetitive conduct includes, inter alia, prohibitions against tie-ins, discriminatory pricing and mergers harming market structure, as well as refusals to supply.184

178. E.C. Treaty art. 82.

179. See Whish, supra n.11, at 168, 169, 179

180. Anderman, supra n.8, at 148.

181. See id.

182. See id.; see also Whish, supra n.11, at 170-71.

183. See Whish, supra n.11, at 170, citing Case 6/72, Europemballage Corp. & Continental Can Co. Inc. v. Commission, [1973] E.C.R. 215, [1973] C.M.L.R. 199; see also Whish, supra n.11, at 170-73.

184. See Whish, supra n.11, at 175-79.

Page 26: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1339

The third abuse concept under Article 82 is conduct harmful to the single market. Accordingly, Article 82 has been interpreted to prohibit both contractual and unilateral conduct by a dominant undertaking having the effect of disrupting the free flow of goods among member states.185

Of these three abuse concepts, Community competition authorities have had most frequent recourse to the prohibition against competitive abuses.186

As previously discussed,187 unlike Article 81, conduct violating Article 82 prohibitions may not be exempted. Nevertheless, “abuse” is interpreted to exclude conduct which is found to be “objectively justified” or “proportional.”188 The line between abusive conduct on the one hand, and objectively justified or proportional conduct on the other, “is very fine—sometimes invisible. . . .”189

As previously discussed,190 Community competition authorities use competition law to maintain the existence of smaller competitors. A particularly controversial application of competition law is found in the refusal to supply and essential facilities cases.191

Under some circumstances, a dominant undertaking’s unilateral refusal to deal will be abusive.192 In Commercial Solvents,193 the ECJ held that a dominant undertaking’s unilateral decision to discontinue supplying an essential raw material to a producer that was dependent upon that dominant undertaking, thereby effectively putting the producer out-of-business, was abusive, and not justified by the fact that the undertaking’s subsidiary was entering the same downstream manufacturing market as the producer.

The Commercial Solvents doctrine has been extended well beyond a mere refusal to supply raw materials or finished goods.194 Relying upon Commercial Solvents, the European Commission has held that an Article 82 abuse may occur where a dominant undertaking denies another the use of an “essential facility.”195 An essential facility is “a facility or infrastructure without access to

185. See id. at 179-80.

186. See id. at 169.

187. Supra at Section II.

188. Whish, supra n.11, at 180-81.

189. Id. at 170.

190. Supra at Section II.

191. Whish, supra n.11, at 611.

192. See id.

193. See Joined Cases 6 & 7/73, Istituto Chemioterapico Italiano SpA v. Commission, [1974] E.C.R. 223, [1974] 1 C.M.L.R. 309, ¶¶ 23-29 (“Commercial Solvents”).

194. See Whish, supra n.11, at 612-16.

195. See id. at 616.

Page 27: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1340 Vol. 93 TMR

which competitors cannot provide services to their customers.”196 According to the Commission:

A dominant undertaking which both owns or controls and itself uses an essential facility . . . and which refuses its competitors access to that facility or grants access to competitors only on terms less favourable than those which it gives its own services, thereby placing the competitors at a competitive disadvantage, infringes Article [82]. . . . The owner of an essential facility which uses its power in one market in order to strengthen its position in another related market, in particular, by granting its competitors access to that related market on less favourable terms than those of its own services, infringe Article [82] where a competitive disadvantage is imposed upon its competitor without objective justification.197

Owning an essential facility may be equated with holding a de facto monopoly, thereby imposing upon the dominant undertaking a materially heightened duty to competitors.198

Essential facilities are not limited to tangible goods or infrastructure. In the now infamous Magill decision,199 the ECJ held that three television broadcasters collectively had abused their dominant position by refusing to grant copyright licenses to a publisher that desired to publish a weekly television programming guide. Each of the broadcasters published its own weekly guide to its own programming, but there was no single weekly guide available to consumers that collectively disclosed the programming of the three broadcasters. While expressly disclaiming that the broadcasters’ copyrights in their respective programming guides conferred a dominant position, the court found that each had a de facto monopoly over the information and that such a monopoly was not shielded from Article 82 simply because it was subject to valid national copyright protection. In “exceptional circumstances,” the exercise of valid national intellectual property rights may be an Article 82 abuse.200 Exceptional circumstances were found here because, without justification, the broadcasters’ refusal to license the publisher denied the public a product not heretofore available

196. See Sea Containers v. Stena Sealink—Interim Measures, 1994 O.J. (L 15/8), [1995] 4 C.M.L.R. 84, ¶ 41 (Eur. Comm.).

197. See id.

198. See Whish, supra n.11, at 163; Anderman, supra n.8, at 150; see also supra Section IV.B.2.

199. See Joined Cases C-241 & 242/91 P, Radio Telefis Eireann v. Commission, [1995] E.C.R. I-743, [1995] 4 C.M.L.R. 718 (“Magill”).

200. See id. ¶¶ 46-50.

Page 28: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1341

for which there was clear public demand.201 The court affirmed the remedial imposition of compulsory copyright licenses.202

V. TRADEMARKS AND ARTICLE 82

As previously discussed,203 given the liberality of their construction, the inter-state trade effect and Common Market elements of an Article 82 violation are almost always deemed to be satisfied. Consequently, in looking at the specific role of trademarks in Article 82 jurisprudence, we shall focus on the remaining two elements—the existence of dominance and abuse.

A. Dominance

The ECJ “has made it absolutely clear that an undertaking is not dominant merely because it is the owner of an intellectual property right.”204 Professor Rosa Greaves of the University of Durham has observed that this places intellectual property rights in “a privileged position because [they] do confer market power, but are not automatically dominant within the meaning of Article [82].”205 Accordingly, in evaluating dominance in relationship to goods protected by intellectual property rights, regard must be had to potential substitutes. Greaves notes, however:

Although it is highly unlikely that a patented product will have no substitutes, the same cannot be said for products protected by trademarks, copyright and design rights if the test of substitutability is dependent on the characteristics of the user. It was commented at the time that the product market in United Brands could have been narrowed even further, to “Chiquita” bananas themselves (the branded product).206

Although she does not elaborate upon her views, it appears that Greaves believes that trademarks differentiate products in a

201. See id. ¶¶ 53-56; accord Case C-7/97, Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co. KG v. Mediaprint Zeitungs und Zeitschriftenverlag GmbH & Co. KG, [1998] E.C.R. I-7791, [1999] 4 C.M.L.R. 112, ¶¶ 40-47; see also Schmidt, supra n.114, at 213-15, 216.

202. See Joined Cases C-241 & 242/91 P, Magill, at ¶ 91. The effects of the grant of a compulsory license, with its implications for the erosion of Community intellectual property rights, has been described as “explosive.” See Christopher Strothers, Refusal to Supply as Abuse of a Dominant Position: Essential Facilities in the European Union, 22 Eur. Competition L. Rev. 256, 261-62 (2001).

203. Supra Sections IV.A. & C.

204. Greaves, supra n.6, at 381 (footnote omitted); see also Case 40/70, Sirena S.r.l. v. Eda S.r.l., [1971] E.C.R. 69, [1971] C.M.L.R. 260, ¶ 16 (“the proprietor of a trade-mark does not enjoy a ‘dominant position’ within the meaning of Article [82] merely because he is in a position to prevent third parties from putting into circulation, on the territory of a Member State, products bearing the same trade-mark.”).

205. Greaves, supra n.6, at 381.

206. Id. (emphasis added).

Page 29: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1342 Vol. 93 TMR

manner which precludes the acceptability of substitute goods by consumers. Such a view, of course, would not be unique.

The most influential proponent of the view that trademarks confer market power by differentiating products is the late Professor Edward H. Chamberlin of Harvard University.207 Chamberlin, a member of the so-called Harvard School of Economics,208 argued that there is a synthesis of competitive and monopolistic elements at work in the modern free economy; a condition he designated “monopolistic competition.”209 To eliminate the operation of market power, Chamberlin observed that it was necessary that all producers produce “identical goods” sold in “identical markets.”210 Where producers produced even “slightly different” products, or such goods were sold under conditions where consumers were otherwise influenced to favor one seller over another for any reason (e.g., “personality, reputation, . . . or the tone of his shop”) and regardless of whether the differences are “real or fancied,” the products are no longer identical because these differentiated attributes, together with the underlying good, constitute a unitary “bundle of utilities.”211

Chamberlin specifically studied the role of trademarks in the economy of monopolistic competition.212 According to Chamberlin, by differentiating products, trademarks moved the economy further away from a state of perfect competition. Individual monopolies were created in each different branded (i.e., differentiated) product.213 Trademark law, by protecting the exclusive rights of one producer to use a trademark, “preserv[es] not competition, but monopoly.”214 Consequently, “[t]o permit . . . [trade-mark] infringements . . . would be to purify competition by eliminating monopoly elements.”215

This is not to say there is no competition in the monopolistic competition world. As Chamberlin acknowledged, “[a] monopoly of

207. See, e.g., Brainerd Currie, Forward “Trade-Marks in Transition” Symposium, 14 Law & Contemp. Probs. 171, 171 (Spring 1949); Daniel M. McClure, Trademarks and Unfair Competition: A Critical History of Legal Thought, 69 TMR 305, 329-30 (1979).

208. See Pickering, supra n.47, at 76 n.33; see generally id. at 76-83 (Harvard School and trademarks).

209. See Edward H. Chamberlin, The Theory of Monopolistic Competition 68-70 (Harv. U., Harv. Econ. Stud., vol. 38, 1st ed. 1933).

210. See id. at 7-8.

211. See id. at 7-8, 56.

212. See id. at 57-64, 204-08.

213. See id.

214. Id. at 205.

215. Id. at 204. According to Chamberlin, however, the public interest in preventing public deception would be served by requiring the copyist to produce goods of the same quality as the goods of the trademark owner. Quite how this was to be accomplished is unclear. See id. at 207.

Page 30: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1343

LUCKY STRIKES does not constitute a monopoly of cigarettes.”216 “[Al]though a monopoly in a narrow, technical sense is present, it is difficult to envisage how the responsible trademark could be economically damaging on its own when it distinguishes the product from competitive substitutes.”217 Chamberlin’s trademark “monopoly” is not a “monopoly” that would be recognized by many.218

Moreover, few would posit as a “welfare ideal” the world of Chamberlin’s “perfect competition” since it would require wholly “homogenous” products and consumer taste.219 As Chamberlin observed, “wherever there is a demand for diversity of product, pure competition turns out to be not the ideal but a departure from it.”220 Consequently, regardless of the astuteness of his descriptive insight into the workings of the contemporary market, Chamberlin’s monopolistic competition theory appears to have little, if any, value as a basis for the application of competition policy.221

At a simplistic level, there is some appeal to Chamberlin’s position that trademark owners enjoy monopoly rights by reason of the branding of their products. Clearly, to at least some consumers, a handbag bearing the GUCCI mark will be deemed more desirable than an identical handbag bearing the J.C. PENNY mark, and, as a consequence, the former commands a higher price for its handbag than the latter. Only the owner of the GUCCI mark may lawfully affix that mark to its goods; other competitors are precluded by law from introducing their own GUCCI branded bags to compete with the lawful trademark owner.

Notwithstanding this “limitation” on competition, however, it is clear that for many consumers the J.C. PENNY branded bag, although perhaps not a completely identical product to the GUCCI branded bag, nevertheless is a substitutable product. When viewed in a marketplace offering not merely J.C. PENNY and GUCCI branded bags, but also SEARS and WAL-MART branded bags, COACH and EVAN-PICONE branded bags, and PRADA and LOUIS VUITTON branded bags, it would be the odd consumer who would not find a substitutable product for the GUCCI branded bag, regardless of the degree of his or her brand loyalty. The “monopoly” in GUCCI bags enjoyed by the trademark owner is ephemeral. 216. Id. at 65; see also Edward H. Chamberlin, Product Heterogeneity and Public Policy, 40 Am. Econ. Rev. 85, 86-87 (May 1950).

217. Pickering, supra n.47, at 80.

218. See Harbord & von Graevenitz, supra n.130, at 153-54.

219. See Edward H. Chamberlin, Mrs. Robinson’s Recent Visit to Monopolistic Competition, in A More General Theory of Value 307, 309 (1957).

220. Chamberlin, n.216, at 92.

221. See Handler, supra n.47, at 441 n.3.

Page 31: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1344 Vol. 93 TMR

Moreover, even ownership of a widely recognized trademark assures the trademark owner of neither high consumer brand loyalty nor a material market share. Consequently, well-known trademarks per se do not confer significant market power.222

For the reasons previously discussed,223 a trademark confers the thinnest of “monopolies.” It neither confers exclusive rights in non-origin information nor in functional product attributes. It does not confer monopoly rights in a symbol per se nor even in the use of that symbol to identify the trademark owner’s products. At least under traditional theories, the trademark “monopoly” extends only as far as is necessary to prevent potential consumer confusion as to the source of the goods bearing the mark. Although the determination of the existence of a monopoly ultimately must be one of fact, it seems remarkably unlikely that a monopoly will be accorded by reason of the protection of trademark rights alone.224 Consequently, trademarks should not be deemed to confer market power for purposes of determining the existence of a dominant position under Article 82.

Even if we accept arguendo that a trademark properly may be used to define a product market for purposes of analyzing dominance for competition law purposes, basic trademark principles suggest that there is little risk of monopolization posed by the subject trademark. It is likely that in a “single-brand market[],” consumers would come to understand the brand name as the generic or common descriptive term for the single-brand product. Consequently, “the likelihood of genericide [i.e., the loss of rights in a mark resulting from its perception as the apt or common name for the goods] would abate the danger of monopoly.”225

B. Abuse

1. Refusal to Deal, Essential Facilities and Compulsory Licenses

For the reasons discussed immediately above, trademarks should not be deemed to confer market power. If, however, trademarks are deemed to differentiate goods in a manner conferring market power upon trademark owners, trademark rights may be put at risk. The owner of any particularly “well-known trade mark” might be deemed to hold a dominant position

222. Nigel Parr & Mathew Hughes, The Relevance of Consumer Brands and Advertising in Competition Inquiries, 14 Eur. Competition L. Rev. 157, 160 (1993).

223. See supra at Section III.C.

224. See Edmund W. Kitch, Elementary and Persistent Errors in the Economic Analysis of Intellectual Property, 53 Vand. L. Rev. 1727, 1730, 1734 (Nov. 2000).

225. Blakeney, supra n.35, at 420.

Page 32: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1345

within a single product market.226 As Professor Greaves noted, trademark owners should be “worr[ied]” because the ownership of such rights “becomes a particularly significant factor in assessing dominance in the defined relevant market.”227 Such a trademark owner, as a de facto monopolist,228 would be bound by the ill-defined special duty to avoid the impairment of undistorted competition.229 As we saw in Magill, the ECJ has ruled that under certain circumstances, a dominant undertaking may be required to license its intellectual property rights to avoid abuse of a dominant position.230

To date, Magill, a copyright case, is the only decision where a compulsory intellectual property license has been granted as a remedy under Article 82. Given the absence of additional compulsory licensing grants, some commentators dismiss the natural concerns of intellectual property owners regarding the application of the essential facilities doctrine to such rights.231 Such sanguinity may be misplaced.

Some commentators have noted that an important factor in the compulsory licensing grant in Magill was the implicit assumption that the copyrighted materials—television program-ming information—was less worthy of protection than other materials protected by intellectual property laws.232 As we have seen, at least historically, the ECJ has viewed trademarks as less worthy of protection than other intellectual property rights.233

Moreover, to the extent that trademarks are perceived as monopoly rights, the more likely competition law authorities are to perceive such rights as essential facilities necessary for use by third parties to sell competitive, or even non-competitive, goods.234 As we have seen, the misperception of trademarks as monopoly

226. See David Kittchin, et al., Kerly’s Law of Trade Marks and Trade Names ¶ 15-107 (13th ed. 2001) (“Kerly’s”).

227. Greaves, supra n.6, at 381.

228. See Vrins, supra n.139, at 579-80, 581 (Greaves’ “assertion that, in United Brands, the market could have been restricted to Chiquita [branded] bananas alone—in which case Chiquita would have had 100 per cent market share in its (own!) market—is not unfounded: . . . Is not it, after all, the . . . purpose of all trade mark owners to create a brand which destroys any substitutability with others?”).

229. See supra Section IV.B.2.

230. See supra Section IV.C.

231. See, e.g., Frank Fine, NDS/IMS: A Logical Application of Essential Facilities Doctrine, 23 Eur. Competition L. Rev. 457, 467-68 (2002).

232. See, e.g., Tritton, supra n.12, at 11-065; Sergio B. Opi, The Application of the Essential Facilities Doctrine to Intellectual Property Licensing in the European Union and the United States: Are Intellectual Property Rights Still Sacrosanct?, 11 Fordham Intell. Prop., Media & Ent. L.J. 409, 460-61 (Winter 2001); but see Anderman, supra n.8, at 211; see generally Section III.A. (on differing European copyright standards).

233. Supra Section III.D.

234. See Opi, supra n. 232, at 423-24.

Page 33: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1346 Vol. 93 TMR

rights remains strong, particularly in academic circles.235 Unfortunately, such misperceptions spread far beyond the academy. Thus, as recently as this year, the ECJ cited Community Trade Mark Office officials as characterizing a trademark as conferring a “legal monopoly” in the subject sign.236 Although we may take some comfort from the ECJ’s explicit reaffirmation of the value and importance of trademark rights within the Community’s single market,237 it also should be remembered that this reaffirmation was made in the face of English litigation which previously had sought to allow a competitor to sell football team merchandise, complete with registered trademarks, on the ground that such use was not trademark use, but rather merely emblems of team loyalty, unlikely to deceive consumers.238

Furthermore, if a trademark is treated as a product attribute rather than simply an indicia of origin, it is not difficult to envision cases arising where a trademark owner’s refusal to license his or trademark could preclude the introduction of a new product for which there was at least some public demand (e.g., GUCCI branded dog collars or PORSCHE branded baby strollers). Under Magill, it is at least possible that the frustrated licensee could seek a compulsory license under Article 82 against the de facto monopolist (i.e., the trademark owner) to permit the introduction of a product that probably could not be made available without a trademark license.239

The chronic misperception of trademark rights within the European Community, coupled with the continuing viability of the idea that competition law should protect (particularly smaller) competitors, is a source of continuing uncertainty and concern regarding the role and regulation of trademark rights.240 Although compulsory trademark licenses are not yet operating within the Community, such licenses still yet could be granted as Article 82 remedies.

235. See, e.g., Lunney, supra n.10, at 367-465; Sanders & Maniatis, supra n.45, at 406, 411.

236. See Case C-191/01 P, O.H.I.M. v. Wm. Wrigley Jr. Co., [2003] E.C.R. ___, 2003 WL 101985, ¶ 19 (23 Oct. 2003) (“DOUBLEMINT”).

237. Case C-206/01, Arsenal Football Club plc v. Reed, [2002] E.C.R. I-10273, [2003] 1 C.M.L.R. 12, ¶ 48.

238. Arsenal Football Club plc, [2001] R.P.C. 46, [2001] 2 C.M.L.R. 23, ¶¶ 36-43 (Ch. D.), further proceedings at [2003] 1 All E.R. 137, [2003] 1 C.M.L.R. 13 (Ch. D.), rev’d [2003] 3 All E.R. 865, [2003] 2 C.M.L.R. 25 (C.A.).

239. Compare supra Section IV.D. with Alex Kozinski, Trademarks Unplugged, 68 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 960, 961-62 (Oct. 1993), and with Plasticolor Molded Prods. v. Ford Motor Co., 698 F. Supp. 199, 201-02 (C.D. Cal. 1988), and 713 F. Supp. 1329, 1335 (C.D. Cal. 1989), vacated by 767 F. Supp. 1036 (C.D. Cal. 1991).

240. Cf., Fox, supra n.26, at 404-05 (noting less rigorous economic analyses of Community competition authorities coupled with a continuing concern to protect competitors).

Page 34: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1347

As a matter of public policy, a compulsory remedial trademark license should not be granted. As we have seen,241 trademark utility depends upon use of the symbol to tie a product to single, albeit anonymous, source. The ECJ has held that a trademark cannot “fulfil its essential role in the system of undistorted competition” unless the branded goods “have been manufactured or supplied under the control of a single undertaking which is responsible for their quality.”242 Consequently, compulsory licensing of trademarks is antithetical to, and wholly incompatible with, Community trademark law.

Compulsory licensing invalidates a trademark by placing it in the hands of firms other than the trademark owner.243 By displacing the single source behind the mark, compulsory licensing is deceptive.244 Moreover, adopting compulsory licensing as a competition law remedy undermines the value not merely of the subject mark, but also of the entire trade identity system because a consumer would not know if a mark is being used in the customary fashion or under a compulsory license. “Either [the consumer] would be unable to rely on any trademarks, which would leave him without adequate means of selection, or he would have to assume the risk of relying on a term that does not indicate the source he would otherwise anticipate.”245

If the compulsory license is not made subject to quality controls, “even minimal standards cannot be anticipated.”246 Even if the license grant is subject to quality control, it is unlikely to protect consumers. Because licenses may be held by multiple independent firms, there is little incentive for them to maintain quality because the reputation symbolized by the licensed mark may be injured by the actions of any one of them over which the others have no control.247 The trademark owner has no real enforcement mechanism because the license cannot be terminated and it is questionable that a public authority would have the same concern for maintaining the goodwill represented by the licensed mark.248 Finally, the licensees may have the perverse incentive to

241. Supra Section III.B.

242. Case C-206/01, Arsenal Football Club plc v. Reed, [2002] E.C.R. I-10273, [2003] 1 C.M.L.R. 12, ¶ 48 (citations omitted).

243. See Vincent N. Palladino, Compulsory Licensing of a Trademark, 26 Buff. L. Rev. 457 (1977), reprinted in 68 TMR 522, 524, 549 (1978) (footnote omitted); J. Thomas McCarthy, Compulsory Licensing of a Trademark: Remedy or Penalty?, 67 TMR 197, 227 (1977).

244. See Palladino, supra n.243, at 535; Cornish & Phillips, supra n.55, at 62-63.

245. Palladino, supra n.243, at 536.

246. Compare id. at 538, with supra Section III.B.

247. See Palladino, supra n.243, at 538.

248. See id.; McCarthy, supra n.243, at 228-29.

Page 35: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1348 Vol. 93 TMR

damage the goodwill symbolized by the mark in order to put their own brands in a better market position.249

2. Excessive Pricing

As previously discussed,250 it is to be expected that goods bearing well-established brands command a premium price as an incentive for quality maintenance. In a world where, “[t]hrough ingenuous marketing, a simple designer label can turn a comfy $10 T-shirt into a $100 object of aspiration,”251 however, it is not surprising that trademarks often are seen as instruments of exploitive pricing. The ECJ long has suggested that prices charged for some branded goods may be so excessive that they are tantamount to a Rule 82 abuse.252

A price is excessive if “it has no reasonable relation to the economic value of the product. . . .”253 Whether the price is so excessive that it is abusive may be determined with reference to either the absolute price or the price of other competing products.254 This standard is highly subjective and may prove analytically difficult given the complexity of factors that may legitimately affect product pricing (e.g., advertising, marketing, product development costs across the entire product line, etc.).255 This standard is particularly unhelpful in evaluating luxury goods, the very exclusivity (i.e., costliness) of which makes them desirable to some consumers.256

The ECJ’s recent rejection of the doctrine of international exhaustion of rights257 seemingly has given new impetus to excessive pricing attacks.258 Some argue that where goods are sold for a lesser price outside the Common Market than within, such a price differential should be regarded as evidence of excessive pricing.259 At a basic level, such analysis fails to account for the

249. See McCarthy, supra n.243, at 227-28.

250. See supra Section III.B.

251. Special Report: Counterfeiting, 367 The Economist, May 17-23, 2003, 69, 70 (U.K. ed.).

252. See Case 40/70, Sirena S.r.l. v. Eda S.r.l., [1971] E.C.R. 69, [1971] C.M.L.R. 260, ¶¶ 14 & 16.

253. Case 27/76, United Brands Co. v. Commission, [1978] E.C.R. 207, [1978] 1 C.M.L.R. 429, ¶ 250.

254. See id. ¶ 252; see also Whish, supra n.11, at 635-36.

255. See Heide, supra n.3, at 165-66 & 167; Jebsen & Stevens, supra n.144, at 504-06; Tritton, supra n.12, at ¶ 11-079.

256. See Tritton, supra n.12, at ¶ 11-079.

257. Joined Cases C-414, 415 & 416/99, Zino Davidoff SA v. A&G Imports, [2001] E.C.R. I-8691, [2002] 1 C.M.L.R. 1.

258. Heide, supra n.3, at 163.

259. See id. at 165.

Page 36: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1349

fact that goods sold under a trademark in a territory outside the Common Market may be materially different from the product sold under that mark within the Common Market.260 Where there are such material product differences, any price comparison based upon such goods is at least suspect as a yardstick for determining excessive prices. Moreover, even if the products are identical, price comparisons involving markets beyond the Common Market may not be warranted. To assure a meaningful analysis, price comparisons should be made only between “markets having similar conditions of supply and demand;” a rarely met condition.261

Finally, in light of the fact that trademarks do not confer real monopoly power upon their owners and consumers are free to choose alternative products, indeed products identical in all but trade indicia, it would seem far wiser to avoid state intervention in the market and to allow consumers to purchase according to their own preferences.262

3. Other Abuses

(a) Pre-emptive Registrations The Commission has held that national registration of a

trademark by a dominant undertaking may constitute an abuse under Article 82. Such an abuse occurs when the undertaking knew or reasonably should have known that the mark was already in use by a competitor in another Member State because the registration restricts the competitor’s opportunities for entering the dominant undertaking’s market.263 Recourse to Article 82, however, should be unnecessary.

If a firm has acquired a reputation, symbolized by a particular trademark, in a Member State other than those in which it does business, then that firm should be able to prevent the dominant undertaking (or any other firm) from obtaining (or at least maintaining) a national registration for that mark in each state in which the senior user enjoys a reputation.264

If the senior user does not enjoy a reputation under its mark in a Member Country, a trademark law remedy still should be available. Community trademark law provides for revocation of a trademark registration where it is established that the applicant

260. See, e.g., Colgate-Palmolive v. Markwell Fin., [1989] R.P.C. 497, 529 (C.A.) (Lloyd, L.J.).

261. See Heide, supra n.3, at 166-67; Whish, supra n.11, at 636.

262. See Pickering, supra n.47, at 82-83.

263. Oy Airam A.B. v. Osram GmbH, [1982] 3 C.M.L.R. 614 (Eur. Comm. 1981).

264. See CTM Regulation, art. 8(2)(c) (implementing Paris Convention art. 6bis (1), well known marks); see generally Ruth Annand & Helen Norman, Blackstone’s Guide to the Community Trade Mark 49-51 (1998).

Page 37: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1350 Vol. 93 TMR

acted in bad faith in filing its trademark application.265 Although bad faith has been narrowly construed by the Office for the Harmonization of the Internal Market (OHIM), it does prohibit “unfair practices involving lack of any honest intention on the part of the applicant . . . at the time of filing.”266 OHIM has strongly suggested that bad faith may invalidate a Community Trade Mark registration “where the applicant was aware that someone else intends to use/or register the mark, . . ., or where the applicant copied a mark being used abroad with the intention of pre-empting the proprietor. . . .”267 Moreover, although the concept of bona fide intent to use is not explicitly incorporated into Community trademark law, it may readily be inferred from the requirement of use of a mark to maintain a registration.268 If an application was filed solely for pre-emptive purposes, the requisite bona fide intent to use would be absent.

Of course, given the territorial nature of trademark rights, if the dominant undertaking adopted the mark in good faith without knowledge (actual or constructive) of the senior user in a Member State where the senior user is neither trading nor to which its reputation has extended, then the dominant undertaking should enjoy the unfettered right to use that mark in such territory.269 Any apparent hardship to the senior user is easily ameliorated by ready access to the Community Trade Mark registration system.

(b) Agreement to Refrain from Using a Trademark In Chiquita/Fyffes plc, the Commission held that an

agreement to forego use of a trademark benefiting a dominant undertaking may, under certain circumstances, constitute an Article 82 abuse.270 Prior to 1986, Chiquita, through a subsidiary, exclusively sold its bananas in the United Kingdom under the FYFFES trademark. During this period, Chiquita, through another subsidiary, sold some of its bananas on the Continent under the FYFFES trademark. In 1986, Chiquita sold its United Kingdom and Irish businesses, including the FYFFES trademark, 265. See CTM Regulation, art. 51(1)(b).

266. Invalidity No. C0000479899/1, Surene Pty. Ltd. v. Multiple Mktg. Ltd., [2001] 2 O.H.I.M. O.J. 393, ¶ 10 (1st Cancel. Div. 2000) (“BE NATURAL”).

267. Invalidity No. C0000479899/1, BE NATURAL, ¶ 15, quoting Intellectual Property Policy Directorate, U.K. Patent Office, Notes on Trade Marks Act 1994 § 3, ¶ 10 (Sept. 1994) (emphasis deleted).

268. Kerly’s, supra n.226, ¶ 7-230; but see Invalidity No. C000053447/1, Harte-Hanks Data Techs., Inc. v. Trillium Digital Sys., Inc., [2001] 7-8 O.H.I.M. O.J. 1575, ¶¶ 8 & 9 (1st Cancel. Div. 2000) (“TRILLIUM”) (Community trademark law, unlike U.K. law, does not require bona fide intention to use for registration).

269. See, e.g., United Drug Co. v. Theodore Rectanus Co., 248 U.S. 90, 100-01 (1918).

270. Chiquita/Fyffes plc, European Commission, XXIInd Report on Competition Policy 104-06 ¶¶ 168-76 (1992). The Commission also found an Article 81 violation, seemingly obviating the need for application of Article 82. See id. ¶¶ 168 & 170-71.

Page 38: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1351

to Fyffes plc, while retaining the FYFFES mark in at least certain continental Member States. Fyffes plc agreed to refrain from selling fresh fruit in continental Europe under the FYFFES mark for a period of up to twenty years even though Chiquita discontinued its use of the mark by 1989.271

Although the twenty-year prohibition against use in Chiquita/Fyffes plc seems somewhat excessive, there can be objectively reasonable justifications for precluding the use of a previously well established mark by a junior user even where the mark no longer is in use by the senior user. It is widely recognized that goodwill may continue to exist in a mark long after the owner ceases using the mark.272 Consequently, at least during the period of residual goodwill, prohibiting a junior user’s use of the mark would appear justified by the senior user’s legitimate desire to preclude public deception which necessarily would result if the junior user stepped into the vacated shoes of the senior user.

(c) Dispenser Exclusivity The Commission has held that it is abusive for a dominant

undertaking to require retailers exclusively to stock the undertaking’s single-wrapped impulse ice cream products in freezer-cabinets supplied and maintained for free by the undertaking to such retailers.273

In Van den Bergh Foods Ltd., Unilever PLC. (“Unilever”), doing business as Van den Bergh Foods Ltd., provided freezer cabinets (presumably all prominently bearing one or more Unilever trademarks) to Irish ice cream retailers without direct charge but subject to the requirement that the retailer stock the cabinet exclusively with Unilever ice cream products. Unilever was a dominant undertaking, having an eighty-five percent (85%) share of the Irish ice cream market. In the face of objections by Mars, Inc., Unilever sought to avoid liability for a competition law offence by changing its practice to allow retailers to rent the freezers without requiring cabinet exclusivity. Market surveys, however, established that Unilever’s changed practices had not in fact changed market conditions (presumably, most Irish retailers

271. Id. ¶168.

272. See, e.g., Ad-Lib Club v. Granville, [1971] 2 All E.R. 300, 302-03 (Ch.) (protectable residual goodwill four years after business closed); Ferrari S.p.A. Esercizio Fabbriche Automobili e Corse v. McBurnie, 11 U.S.P.Q.2d 1843, 1848-49 (S.D. Cal. 1989) (residual goodwill in car design 12 years after production termination).

273. Case Nos. IV/34.073, 34.395 & 35.436, Van den Bergh Foods Ltd., [1998] O.J. L-246/1 (Comm.), aff’d sub nom. Case T-65/98, Van den Bergh Foods Ltd. v. Commission, [2003] E.C.R. ____, 2003 WL 101979, ¶¶ 149-62 (Ct. First Instance Oct. 23, 2003); see also Case C-344/98, Masterworks Ltd. v. HB Ice Cream Ltd., [2000] E.C.R. I-11369, [2001] 4 C.M.L.R. 14 (parallel proceedings in the Irish courts).

Page 39: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

1352 Vol. 93 TMR

preferred a “free” exclusive cabinet to a “rented” non-exclusive cabinet).274

In finding that Unilever’s inducement of retailers to enter into exclusive cabinet agreements constituted an abuse of its dominant position in violation of Article 82,275 the Commission found that, given the nature of the Irish ice cream market, ice cream retailers accepting a “free” Unilever freezer cabinet were unlikely to stock competing ice cream products because such retailers tended to be smaller stores without space for more than one ice cream freezer.276

Notwithstanding the foregoing, it appears that Unilever may have been able to defend its original cabinet exclusivity practice as a necessary means of protecting its trademark rights. There are various goods (e.g., gasoline and fountain soft drinks) where the dispenser (e.g., gasoline pump and soda fountain) is the primary, if not the only, means by which the mark may be affixed or applied to the goods, and the public relies upon the dispenser’s trademark display to identify the source of the dispensed goods. Sales of third party products through such dispensers are likely to deceive consumers as to the source of those goods.277 Even as to goods which may otherwise be individually branded (e.g., bottled soft drinks or candy bars), it is not too much of a leap to anticipate that consumers could reasonably associate the source of those goods with the owner of the trademark prominently displayed on the dispensing vending machine or display cabinet. Consequently, where there is objectively reasonable evidence that consumers probably would be confused by purchasing third party products through dispensers bearing another’s trademark, dispenser exclusivity may be justified and should not be deemed abusive.278 Of course, in Van den Bergh Foods Ltd., once Unilever changed its cabinet exclusivity practices to permit Irish retailers to stock non-Unilever brands in rented freezer cabinets, this trademark protection justification was forfeited.

274. Freezer Exclusivity in Ice Cream Retail Outlets Condemned—Fine Imposed, 19 Eur. Competition L. Rev. N93 (1998).

275. As an independent basis for its decision, the Commission also found that the cabinet exclusivity agreements violated Article 85. Id.

276. See id.

277. See, e.g., Edward J. Sweeney & Sons, Inc. v. Texaco, Inc., 478 F. Supp. 243, 277-82 (E.D. Pa. 1979), aff’d 637 F.2d 105 (3d Cir. 1980), cert. denied, 451 U.S. 911 (1981); 4 J. Thomas McCarthy, McCarthy on Trademarks and Unfair Competition § 25:3 n.6 (4th ed. 2003).

278. See 4 McCarthy, supra n.276, § 25:48; but cf., Case T-30/89, Hilti AG v. Commission, [1991] E.C.R. II-1439, [1992] 14 C.M.L.R. 16, ¶¶ 102-19 (rejecting as objective justification of product tying, inter alia, third party false advertising claims regarding the quality of the third party products).

Page 40: ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS 93/vol93_no6_a6.pdf · ARTICLE 82 OF THE E.C. TREATY AND TRADEMARK RIGHTS* By Charles R. Mandly, Jr.** I. INTRODUCTION In popular

Vol. 93 TMR 1353

VI. CONCLUSION

For the reasons noted in this essay, trademarks are not monopolies. Trademarks confer ownership over neither products nor more abstract symbols. Indeed, within the traditional bounds of protection, the “exclusive” trademark right excludes others only to the extent necessary to avoid consumer deception. Moreover, trademarks are essential to the meaningful product differentiation which is the foundation of rationally functioning consumer product markets. Consequently, trademark use should be excluded from the regulatory scope of Article 82.

As we have seen, there is a substantial body of literature condemning trademarks as monopolistic. As Edward S. Rogers observed, however, “[m]onopoly is merely an ugly word used by people to put a curse on any kind of property they do not like.”279

The attack upon trademark rights and the purported irrational consumer market they purportedly support suggests unhappiness not with trademarks per se, but rather with market economics. Certainly, there is much to criticize with the cult of alienating materialism accepted by many individuals.280 However, there is little new in mankind’s use of possessions, in particular obviously expensive possessions, as signals to our fellows of our social standing.281 That trademarks have been incorporated into these symbolic social communications is hardly surprising, and no more irrational than many other social activities.

Like others,282 without necessary endorsement, the author accepts the primacy of market economics and seeks to understand trademarks within the prevailing social milieu. The author endorses the view of the late Milton Handler, “[a]nti-trust and trade-marks are essentially complementary in their objectives. . . . Anti-trust seeks to keep competition free. . . . Trade-marks and unfair competition endeavour to keep competition fair.”283

279. Rogers, supra n.40, at 249.

280. See Herbert Marcuse, One Dimensional Man 4-5, 49-50 (2d ed. 1991) (social control through “false needs”).

281. Thorstein Veblen, The Theory of the Leisure Class 60-87 (1970 Unwin Books, London, Eng.) (1899).

282. See Maniatis, supra n.10, at 66.

283. Handler, supra n.47, at 441.