40
Banerji, Sanjay and Basu, Parantap (2017) Universal banking, asymmetric information and the stock market. Economic Modelling, 60 . pp. 180-193. ISSN 0264-9993 Access from the University of Nottingham repository: http://eprints.nottingham.ac.uk/41163/1/Universal%20Banking%20asymmectric %20informaiton%20and%20the%20stock%20market.pdf Copyright and reuse: The Nottingham ePrints service makes this work by researchers of the University of Nottingham available open access under the following conditions. This article is made available under the Creative Commons Attribution Non-commercial No Derivatives licence and may be reused according to the conditions of the licence. For more details see: http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/2.5/ A note on versions: The version presented here may differ from the published version or from the version of record. If you wish to cite this item you are advised to consult the publisher’s version. Please see the repository url above for details on accessing the published version and note that access may require a subscription. For more information, please contact [email protected]

Banerji, Sanjay and Basu, Parantap (2017) Universal …eprints.nottingham.ac.uk/41163/1/Universal Banking...I. Introduction Following the financial crisis of 2008-9, a wave of papers

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Banerji, Sanjay and Basu, Parantap (2017) Universal banking, asymmetric information and the stock market. Economic Modelling, 60 . pp. 180-193. ISSN 0264-9993

Access from the University of Nottingham repository: http://eprints.nottingham.ac.uk/41163/1/Universal%20Banking%20asymmectric%20informaiton%20and%20the%20stock%20market.pdf

Copyright and reuse:

The Nottingham ePrints service makes this work by researchers of the University of Nottingham available open access under the following conditions.

This article is made available under the Creative Commons Attribution Non-commercial No Derivatives licence and may be reused according to the conditions of the licence. For more details see: http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/2.5/

A note on versions:

The version presented here may differ from the published version or from the version of record. If you wish to cite this item you are advised to consult the publisher’s version. Please see the repository url above for details on accessing the published version and note that access may require a subscription.

For more information, please contact [email protected]

Universal Banking, Asymmetric Information and the

Stock Market*

SANJAY BANERJI AND PARANTAP BASUy

August 2016

ABSTRACT

This paper aims to explore the role of the universal banking system in contributing to the

stock market bust in the wake of the financial crisis 2008-9 when bankers might have

incentive to hide information from shareholders. We set up a stylized model of consumption

smoothing involving universal banks that undertake both investment and commercial banking

activities. Banks have private information about the outcome of a project that it funds. In the

wake of bad news about the project, the banker has an incentive to sell lemon shares in a

secondary market with the pretence of a liquidity crunch. Our model shows that such an

incentive results in: (i) a sharp discounting of stock prices, (ii) greater loan demand (iii) higher

fraction of bank ownership of the borrowing firms, and (iv) heightened consumption risk

resulting in precautionary savings by households. The magnitude of these effects depends on

the market's perception about the preponderance of lemons in the stock market. A credible

punishment scheme implemented by the government in the form of fines may moderate the

stock market decline and consumption volatility due to information friction. However, it

imposes a deadweight loss on private citizens because of a fall in all banks'expected profit. On

the other hand, a "ring-fenced" banking arrangement along the way suggested by the Vickers

Commission may entail a first order welfare loss due to the lack of diversification

opportunities.

*We would like to acknowledge four referees for their very thoughtful comments which considerably enriched

the paper. The usual disclaimer applies. yBanerji: Finance Group, Nottingham University Business School, Nottingham University, Nottingham, NG8

1BB, [email protected]. Basu: Department of Economics and Finance, Durham Business School, Durham University, 23/26 Old Elvet, Durham DH1 3HY, UK (e-mail: [email protected]). Without implicating, we acknowledge the constructive comments of Angus Chu, Daniel Li, Patrick Minford, the participants of Durham brown bag workshop, the participants at the European Monetary Forum at the Bank of Greece, Loughborough Macroprudential Conference and Glasgow University workshop. The timely research assistance of Congmin Peng, Zilong Wang, Sigit Wibowo and Shesadri Banerjee are gratefully acknowledged. The first author gratefully acknowledges a seedcorn funding support from Durham Business School.

1

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2016.09.009

I. Introduction

Following the financial crisis of 2008-9, a wave of papers appeared in the finance and eco-

nomics literature exploring the diagnostics of the stock market crash. The aim of this paper is to

explore the role of universal banking arrangement in contributing to the collapse of the stock

market and related economic activities. A universal bank combines investment and commercial

banking by holding and underwriting securities of non financial firms while performing its usual

commercial banking operations. In recent times, functioning of all such activities under the um-

brella of a single financial institution has been a subject of much heated debates. A prevailing

notion is that such financial integration gave rise to a conflict of interest between retail and

investment banking activities which manifested in terms of banks hiding information from its

clients and selling lemon securities to ordinary citizens. In a recent book, Akerlof and Shiller

(2015) argue that investment banks sold complex financial instruments that contained lemons.

Since the public failed to perceive the quality of the mutual funds they were buying, it gave rise to

a typical lemon problem in the stock market triggering a crash. Thus, a stock market bust could

be the end result of a potential conflict of interest between bankers and ordinary

shareholders endemic to the universal banking system.

In this paper, we set up a stylized model of consumption smoothing and banking to demon-

strate how such a lemon problem could contribute to a stock market bust. We first show that the

institution of universal banking works best in the absence of any such information friction as it

provides a perfect consumption risk sharing opportunity to the households. However, due to the

universal bank's multifarious financial activities, the system potentially generates an agency

problem in terms of bankers using private information to their own advantage. This happens

because the banker/underwriter who has funded risky projects has private information about the

potential success or failure of the projects. If hit by a bad shock, bankers sell off both these good

and bad securities by bundling them together as mutual funds with a pretence of a liquidity

crunch. On the receiving end, household/shareholder cannot distinguish whether such a sale is

triggered by the wake of bad news about the project outcomes or due to liquidity shortage

suffered by the banks. Our paper shows that the perfect consumption risk sharing in the universal

banking system breaks down due to this conflict of interests stemming from private information.

This leads to: (i) a sharp discount in the price of stocks underwritten by banks, (ii) greater

precautionary motive by households for holding more deposit, (iii) loan pushing by

2

the banks.1

A novelty of our paper is that we investigate the impact of such information friction not

only on the pricing of securities but also on commercial banking activities of the universal banks

which comprise the volume of lending and the magnitude of depository activities. In addition, we

also analyze the real output and welfare effects of such a conflict of interest. We show that the

conflict of interest that manifests in terms of information friction has potentially harmful

real effects on the aggregate economy.

Our stylized model provides insights about the chain reaction caused by the information

friction in the universal banking system. First, as rational investors solve a signal extraction

problem by assigning a probability that banks might be selling lemons, such securities sell at a

discount. The model simulation suggests that this discount is quantitatively substantial and it

depends on the probability of a sale of lemon imputed by investors. Second, the immediate

effect of this sale of lemon securities disrupts the perfect risk sharing arrangements obtained

under full information. This happens because losses incurred by the investors from buying a

probable lemon security even at a discount are not fully compensated at the margin when

securities turn out to be good. The unevenness in investor's income causes increased volatility

in consumption across states of nature which inflicts a welfare loss on households. Third, to

mitigate this consumption risk, households undertake more savings resulting in an increased

volume of bank deposits. Fourth, banks make extra profit from selling lemon stocks which is

channelled (via their balance sheet) towards greater loan pushing to households. Finally, the

effect of holding and trading financial claims upon information spills over to both investment

and commercial banking activities. This contributes to a decline in the aggregate investment

and output because of a higher market interest rate.

The US experiences in the wake of the financial crisis and its aftermath are broadly in line

with the predictions of our model. Commercial banking activities showed a spurt after 2004.

During 2004Q1-2008Q4, the quarterly savings deposit:GDP ratio rose from 20.6% to 30% while

the quarterly commercial and industrial loans also showed an increase from about 7.6% of GDP

in 2004 to 11.3% until the onset of the credit crunch. This increase in commercial banking

activity was accompanied by a sharp drop in the quarterly GDP growth rate from 1.5% to

1In this paper, the sole focus is on the effect of lender's moral hazard problem on the stock market in the

presence of information friction. In a separate paper, Banerji and Basu (2015) deal with the borrower's moral

hazard problem.

3

-0.2% and about a 30% decline in the real S&P index.2

Our paper does not aim to provide an explanation of the financial crisis because we do

not model the banker's bankruptcy due to liquidity shock which is an important feature of the

financial crisis. Nevertheless, our model provides useful insights about the tremendous risk taking

incentive of the universal banks. An implication of our model is that the universal banking system

could have possibly contributed to the crisis only to the extent that bankers had hidden

information about the borrowing firms. This might have led to the lemon problem in the stock

market that Akerlof and Shiller (12015) call a "phishing equilibrium". How much information

was actually hidden in the banking system is an empirical question which is beyond the scope

of this paper.

The policy implication of our model is that a universal banking system could work efficiently

if there is full disclosure of negative information. A punitive tax on banks could moderate the

lemon problem due to information friction and lower the consumption risk of the households.

However, such a tax entails some efficiency loss because the enforcement authority suffers from

the same information friction as private citizens. Thus, it poses a burden on all banks regardless

of their deviant status. In addition, our model also implies that in the presence of informational

friction, even scrupulous rating agencies could make mistakes in rating securities because they

face the same signal extraction problem as the household.

The issue still remains whether an effective "ring fencing" as suggested by the Independent

Banking Commission in 2011 could perform better than the universal banking system. We show

that an artificial separation between retail and investment banking in a

gives rise to a first order welfare loss due to lack of diversification opportunities. As a result,

efficient consumption risk sharing breaks down when such "ring fencing" is implemented. The

"ring-fenced" system

result is robust even when we allow for hidden information in the universal banking arrangement.

The paper is organized as follows. The following section is devoted to review the related

literature on universal banking. Section 3 lays out the model and the environment. Section 4

solves a baseline model of universal banking with full information about states of nature. Section

5 introduces asymmetric information about the states and the consequent conflict of interest

between banks and the stockholders. Section 6 reports results from a simulation experiment

based on our model to test robustness of the key results when interest rate is endogenized. In

2These data are reported from the quarterly database of the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis. The S&P indiex is deflated by the CPI (all items) to arrive at the real stock price index comparable to our model.

4

section 7, we report the results of a policy experiment when the government imposes a punitive

tax on banks to ameliorate the lemon problem. Section 8 reports results of the comparison

between universal banking and stand-alone banking systems. Section 9 concludes.

II. Background and Literature Review

Our paper contributes to the debate on the efficacy of the universal banking system vis-a-vis

retail or stand-alone banking system. Investment banking activity primarily deals with the activity

of underwriting of securities while retail banking engages in the business of taking deposits and

making loans. Following the great depression in the US, the Glass-Steagall Act of 1933 separated

these two activities. Consequently, financial intermediaries could not participate in both equity

and bond markets. A series of financial reforms, starting in the late 80s and culminating in the

Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act of 1999 finally ended this separation between commercial and

investment banking. This banking integration was envisaged to carry out efficient risk sharing in

the financial services markets. Benston (1990,1994), Barth et al. (2000), Krozner and Rajan (1994,

1997), Puri (1996), Gande et. al (1997), Stiglitz (2009) among many others contributed

to this lively debate in the 90s.

In the aftermath of the financial crisis, universal banking arrangement started losing its

virtues. There was widespread speculation that the integrated system posed greater risks for

households because too much private information was held by a unified financial system to the

detriment of the households. The regulators in the UK and the USA started contemplating to

curb multifarious activities of these institutions, especially in areas where commercial banks

entered the business of underwriting equities. In 2011, an independent commission on banking

chaired by Sir John Vickers made a comprehensive assessment of the extant universal banks and

suggested protective a 'ring-fence'around their high street banking activities. The UK banks

are expected to implement these reforms no later than 2019.3

The extant literature on universal banking covers different features of the universal banking

system which includes certification effects or economies of scope or transmission of information

to outsiders. For example, Kanatas and Qi (1998, 2003) discuss the trade-off between economies

of scope embedded within universal banking versus deteriorations of quality of projects and

innovations. Puri (1996, 1999) focuses on the added role of certification of banks while under-

3See Financial Times (21 December, 2012 and April 21, 2011). See also Guardian (12 September, 2011).

5

writing debt securities versus conflicts of interests in equity holding. Rajan (2002) analyzes the

efficiency of universal banking related to competitiveness of the institutions.

Our model has direct or indirect relevance to this large volume of literature on universal

banking. However, our stylized model focuses primarily on the information friction endemic to

the universal banking system. The building block of our framework is the traditional model of

banking in which financial intermediaries transform riskier loans made to individuals to relatively

safer deposits by holding a diversified portfolio of loans to many projects with uncorrelated risks.

The model in this sense builds on Azariadis (1993, page 238-244), Bhattacharya and Thakor

(1993) and Diamond (1984) and Gurley and Shaw (1960). We embed optimal financial contracts

into this traditional model of banking where banks hold both deposits and tradable financial

securities of their client firms. We follow this approach to grasp the additional mileage of the

universal banking over standard framework of intermediation that focuses on economies of scale

or scope associated with such banking system. Our paper is closer in spirit to the recent analysis

of conflict of interest in other areas of financial services industry rooted in the informational

problems.4

Our paper also connects to a thread of literature that evaluates whether bank regulations and

supervisions could be welfare improving. Kilinc and Neyapati (2012) set up a general equilibrium

model and argue that regulation has positive output and welfare effects if it reduces adverse

selection and moral hazard problem. However, they focus mostly on borrower's moral hazard

problem while in this paper our centre of attention is the adverse selection due to lender's

superior information. Tchana (2012) brings banking regulations in an overlapping generations

model and demonstrates the trade-off between banking stability and economic growth. In our

model, the loss of output and welfare primarily results from the conflict of interest between

universal bankers and the shareholders due to hidden information. We argue that an attempt to

eliminate this information friction by punitive tax could have mixed effects. While investment and

output could rise due to contrived decline in interest rate, aggregate welfare could fall because of

a blanket tax on profits of each bank regardless of its deviant status. On the other hand, if the

bank regulation takes the form of "ring-fencing" the banking sector, it could have a first order

welfare loss due to the loss of diversification opportunities of the households.

Our paper has indirect implications for an emerging debate about the role of rating agencies

4See Mehran and Stultz (2007) (and other papers in the volume) for a comprehensive analysis of such conflicts pertinent to financial services industry originating from asymmetry of information.

6

in accentuating the financial crisis. Akerlof and Shiller (2015) argue that well known rating

agencies did not justifiably rate the new security issuance because of conflict of interest with the

investment banks. Hill (2010), however, does not entirely subscribe to this conventional view. He

argues that these rating agencies were overwhelmed by the increasing complexity of

securitization. In terms of our model, we subscribe to Hill's view. The rating agencies also

succumbed to the same informational asymmetry problems as the ordinary shareholders.

III. The Model

A. Households

We consider a simple intertemporal general equilibrium model in which there is a continuum of

identical agents in the unit interval who live only for two periods. At t = 1, a stand-in agent is

endowed with y units of consumption goods, and she also undertakes a physical investment of k

units of capital in the current period which produces a random cash flow/output in the next

period. Since the household's initial endowment is insufficient to finance such an investment,

the household approaches a bank for financing its project. The financing bank basically owns

equity claims to the project which means that the household is contractually bound to pay a

state contingent cash flow net of dividend to the bank. The exact design of the contract will be

specified later.

The bank manages the production of final goods by delegating it to a nonfinancial firm who

has no relations to the household. The production of output is subject to two types of binary

shocks: (i) an aggregate shock, (ii) an idiosyncratic shock. The aggregate shock is transmitted to

intermediaries/agents via a probabilistic signal. A signal conveys news about the state which

could be high (h) and low (l) with probabilities oh and 1 - o respectively. A low signal (a

recessionary state) triggers widespread liquidation of the current projects and the project is

liquidated at a near zero continuation value (m).5 If the signal is h, agents are still subject to

idiosyncratic shock which manifests in terms of a project success which means that output is

Ogg(k) with probability p and failure meaning output equal to Obg(k) with probability 1 - p

where Og > Ob.6

5This assumption is made in order to preserve a simple structure for analysis. Instead of assuming a fixed

salvage value, we could have alternatively proceeded with a lower probability of success in individual projects in

the event of a low aggregative signal and this would not change our results. 6Since this type of risk is distributed independently across infinite number of projects, the law of large number

holds in an economy populated by continuum of agents so that p fraction of individuals is more successful than

7

To sum up, the random output in next period has the following representation:

m with probability 1 - ah

Ogg(k) with probability ahp

Obg(k) with probability ah(1 - p)

B. Banks

In the same spirit as in Azariadis and Smith (1993) and Hart (1995), competitive banks offer a

menu contracts to the households as follows. At date 1, competitive universal banks offer an ex

ante contract that stipulates: (i) deposits (s), (ii) loans (f), and (iii) contingent payments (di, i = g,

b). After writing such a contract and before the realization of the random shock, banks may

experience a liquidity shock (C) which necessitates banks to sell their ownerships claims (Oig(k)

- di) to the public in a secondary market at a price q.7 Let N be the number of such securities. Let

x and nx denote the states of liquidity shock and no such shock with probabilities

1 - 'y and 'y. This interim period when the secondary market opens is dated as 1.5.8

At this interim date 1.5, the bank may also acquire an early signal about the aggregate shock.

If the signal is high (h) with probability ah, the project's value upon continuation is greater than

the same under liquidation. If the signal is low, it means that banks get early information

that most of the projects will turn out to be a lemon with a negligible value m (close to zero).9

At t = 2, uncertainties get resolved and all agents receive pay-off according to the contracts

written at date t = 1, which, in turn, depends on (a) resolution of individual uncertainty and

the rest. On the other hand, no such law holds for a low aggregate state. 7We only allow the banks to have a liquidity shock and exclude individuals to have similar problem because it

makes the exposition simpler and also owing to the fact that the primary purpose of the paper is to investigate the

consequence of banks'holding of tradable financial assets on the rest of the economy under both full information and

asymmetric information. In particular, we show later how the private information gathered by banks regarding

the aggregate state has both financial and real effects. 8Under universal banking, banks or intermediaries can hold securities which are otherwise unrestricted and tradable

compared with the system where banks can only hold debt securities which cannot easily be traded in

the financial/debt market. 9The rationale behind such assumption is that since banks lend and monitor a large number of projects across

the economy, they gather expertise to collect information relevant not only to a single project but can extract

information about the overall economy better than the households. This is a standard function of banks who are

also known as "informed lenders" (see Freixas and Rochet, 2008). However, the main difference between the

universal and non universal banking is that the former can take its informational advantage by selling stocks to

others before the bad event realizes while the latter cannot do such things because they are not allowed to hold

equity in the borrowing firms.

8

(b) occurrences of liquidity shocks of banks. The Figure 1 summarizes the timeline in terms

of a flow chart assuming that households and banks have symmetric information about the

timing of shocks.

<Figure 1: Timeline of Universal Banking under Symmetric Information>

The expected profit of the bank is thus:

bank = ahy:[p{Ogg(k) — dg} + (1 — p):{Obg(k) — db}]

+ah(1 — 7):(qN — C) (1)

+(1 — ah)m — f:(1+rah)

The bank's expected profit function is standard and it is borrowed from the optimal contract

literature (see for example, Frexias and Rochet, 2008). The expected profit takes into account that

the universal bank is an equity holder of the project that it finances. The first square bracket term

is the expected cash flow that the bank receives in a high signal (h) and no liquidity shock (nx)

state. The second term is the expected cash flow from selling shares in the secondary market net

of the liquidity shock when the bank experiences liquidity shock in a high state. The third term is

the expected payoff when the bank liquidates the project in a low aggregate state. Notice that the

last term involving the loan (f) plus its service cost (rah) is a negative payoff to the bank because it

is disbursed to the household. The loan servicing cost is roh because banks do not pay any

interest on savings in a low signal state which occurs with probability 1—0h. For analytical

simplicity we assume until section 6 that the loan interest rate is outside the realm of this

contract and is fixed exogenously. In section 6, we analyze the case when interest rate is

endogenous and determined by the loan market clearing condition. Hereafter, we also assume

that banks issue just enough shares to cover the liquidity crunch which means N = C=q:10

A few more comments are in order to justify the existence of multiple shocks in the model. The

presence of idiosyncratic shocks to individual projects induce banks and individuals to allocate

risk optimally among themselves. Banks divide ownership claims in the borrowing firms between

themselves and the household/shareholders which is a typical feature of universal banking. This

division of ownership serves as a mechanism for risk sharing with the households.

Second, the introduction of liquidity shock by banks directly provides rationale for banks selling

10In fact, when information friction is present (which we deal in the later section), it is not incentive

compatible for any bank to issue more shares such that qN > c. If a bank does so, it will be labelled as a

deviant bank by the investors.

9

stocks to investors in the secondary market at date 1.5 when the bank could receive bad news

about the project and sell such lemon stocks with a pretence of a liquidity shock. We deal with

such a scenario of asymmetric information in section 5. Finally, the aggregate shock also provides

a rationale for households to hold claims in the form of bank deposits (i.e., demand deposits in

addition to holding financial claims via optimal contracts). Household's saving also provides

liquidity to the stock market when it opens at the intermediate date 1.5. Saving thus performs

two roles: (i) consumption smoothing, and (ii) liquidity for speculative purchase of shares.

All banks are competitive and in equilibrium a zero profit condition holds. However, each

generic bank offers a menu of contacts which includes loan (f), investment (k), dividend payment

(dg, df) which maximize the expected utility of a stand-in household to which we now turn. Since

a bank delegates the production decision to a competitive firm who has no relationship to the

household, the latter does not see the firm specific shocks. This separation preserves the

information friction problem that we spell out later.11

C. Preferences

The utility function of each household/ borrower/depositor is additively separable in consump-

tion at each date and is of the form:

U = u(c1) + v(c2) (2)

where ct= consumption at date t, where t = 12 u(.) and v(.) are: (a) three times continuously ,,

differentiable, (b) concave, and (c) have a convex marginal utility function. Hence, agents are

risk-averse and in addition, they have a precautionary motive for savings.

Apart from the current period, in period 2 there are 5 possible states and the expected utility

of an agent from consumption that occur in all such contingencies is given by:

EU = [u(c1) + ahy{pv(cn2g ) + (1 x - p)v(c2b nx )}

+ah(1 - y){pv(c2xg) + (1 - p)v(cx2b}1 (3)

+(1 - ah)u(c2l)

11The issue remains why in a universal banking environment it is incentive compatible for the household to

get involved in such contingent payment contract with the banks. We do not explicitly model this. We

implicitly assume that the household needs to incur a fixed cost of running its own production

establishment which makes its expected payoff lower compared to a contingency payments arrangement.

10

The superscripts x and nx stand for liquidity or no liquidity shock for banks12 and the

subscript 2g and 2b stand for good and bad project outcomes (idiosyncratic shocks) at date 2

with the good news about aggregate shock (subscript h) and the subscript l refers to the low

aggregate state. The other notations are as follows:

c1 = consumption of the agent in the first period.

c2j nx = consumption of the agent in the period 2 when the banks with high aggregate signal

do not suffer liquidity shock (nx) and the individual state is j = g or b , which means that

the cash flow is 0jg(k).

In a similar vein, c2xj = consumption of the agent in the period 2 when the banks with a

high signal suffer liquidity shock (x) and the individual state is j.

c2l = consumption of the agent when the bank has received a low signal and face liquidation

of the project.

The first term, u(c1) in (3) is the utility from current consumption. The term ahy{pv(cn2g )+ x

p)v(c2b

do not suffer liquidity shock. Similarly, the term -oh(1 — y'){pv(c2xg) + (1 — p)v(cx2b)} is the

probability weighted utility in a good aggregate state when banks suffer liquidity shock. The

final term (1 — o-h)u(c2l), is the weighted utility in the bad aggregate state when banks do not

pay interest to depositors.

(1 — nx )} is the probability weighted utility when the aggregate news is good but banks

D. Budget Constraints

The budget constraint in period 1 and all five contingencies in period 2 are:

c1 = y + f — s — k (4)

c2g

nx = dg + s(1 + r) (5)

c2b nx = db + s(1 + r) (6)

cx2g = dg + (s — z)(1 + r) + zE X~ (7) q

c2xb = db + (s — z)(1 + r) + zE X~ (8) q

c2l = s — z (9)

12Although individuals do not suffer any liquidity shock, banks' state of liquidity matter to them because it determines the state whether they will participate in the stock market or not.

11

where 0 = pOg + (1 — p)Ob, d = pdg + (1 — p)db , E X = Og(K) — d and K = the average capital

stock in the economy.

The equation (4) is the first period budget constraint which states that consumption of

an agent is equal to endowment y plus the fund received from bank f less the money stored as

deposit s and expenditure on capital good k.13 The equations (5) and (6) capture agents'

consumption (equal to income) in the good and bad states of production respectively when banks

do not suffer any liquidity shocks. In these states of nature, individuals do not participate in the

stock market in the intermediate period. In such states, the agent's income consists of

two parts: (i) the contingent payments d depending on the state of production, (i = g, b), (ii)

the principal and the interest income on deposits s(1 + r)

Equations (7) and (8) are the state dependent budget constraints when banks encounter

liquidity shock and the project can be a success (g) or failure (b). When the household member

invests z in stocks at a unit price q, it entitles him a claim of E X units of goods because the q

bank sells a mutual fund to the household bundling good and bad shares.14 An atomistic bank while

stipulating an optimal contract for an atomistic household takes the average variables, K and d as

given. However, in equilibrium these two average variables are determined by aggregate

consistency conditions.

Equation (9) shows that when the bank receives a bad news (state l) about the economy,

the project is liquidated and the banks receive the liquidation value as it has the first priority

over claims. Recall that in such a low signal state (which is a state of macroeconomic shock),

banks are unable to make full payment and only return the deposits s to the households.15

IV. Universal Banking under Full Information

As a baseline case, we first lay out the equilibrium contract in a full information scenario.

For a given interest rate r and stock price q, each bank offers a package to the household which

includes (i) the loan size f, (ii) payments to the same household d contingent on realizations

of idiosyncratic states. In return, the household must put in a deposit s at the same bank and

13The endowment y is defined as net of the foreign interest paid or received from abroad. See the appendix

outlining the equilibrium section for details.

14A bank lends out to infinitely many people. Hence, an individual over a unit interval, when buys one such

bank's mutual fund receives a payment of (pOg+(1 — p)Ob)g(K)—d per share. 15Nothing fundamentally changes in our model if we assume instead that banks return only a fraction of savings

in a low aggregate state.

12

undertake a physical investment k in the project. Such a package is stipulated by the bank that

solves the expected utility of the household subject to the condition that these universal banks

offering such competitive contracts satisfy the participation constraint which means that they

must break even.

The optimal contract facing the household is to maximize the expected utility (3) subject

to the budget constraints given by (4) through (9) and zero profit constraint of the

intermediary, i.e.

7rbank = h-y [p{0gg(k) — dg} + (1 — p){0bg(k) — db}]+(1—~h)m+ah(1—-y)(qN—C)—f.(1+rah) ? 0

Since there is full information, the agent exactly knows the node at which the bank operates.

Thus at a low signal state agents know that a stock market will not open at date 1.5. This

immediately means that z = 0 at this low signal state.

As a baseline case, we assume that the real interest rate, r is fixed by a policy rule. Any

discrepancy between borrowing f and lending s is financed by a net inflow of foreign funds (call

it NFI) from abroad at this fixed interest rate.16The Appendix A provides the details of the

market clearing conditions.

Proposition 1: The competitive equilibrium contract has the following properties:

(i) Contingent Payments: dg = db = d (say) such that 1+r~h ~u'(c1)

= v'(d + s(1 + r))

(ii) Share Price: q = +where E X~ 0g(K)— d

r N

(iii) Consumption: cn2g x = nx = = d + s(1 + r) = c2(say) > c2l = s c2b = c2g c2b

(iv) Saving: u'(c1) = [ 1— (1—ah)(1+rah)

7)] v(s) 7 o-h+rah(1—

(v) Investment: a-h-y 0 g'(k) = 1 + rah where 0 —

= p0g + (1 — p)0b and

(vi) Loan: f = o-

hy (0g(k)—d)+(1—o-h)m+o-

h(1—7)(qN—C) 1+rah

(vii) Consistency of Expectations: k = K

Proof: Appendix B.

Discussion: (i), (iv), (v) and (vi) together determine {d, s, K, f } and the equation (ii)

determines q, given an exogenous r. Stocks have fair market value as seen in (ii) and the

risk premium is thus zero. The risk neutral bank bears the whole idiosyncratic risks which

16This assumption is made for analytical simplicity because it rules out the second order effect of the financial operations of banks and households on the real interest rate. In section 6 where we undertake model simulation, we allow the interest rate to vary to equilibrate the loan market.

13

explains why the market risk premium is zero. (i) and (ii) together state that conditional on the

realization of high signal, an agent receives a constant sum d across all states of nature.

Although idiosyncratic risk is washed out in the high state h, in the low state individuals are still

exposed to negative aggregate shock which explains the last inequality of (iii). The holding of

deposit in the form of savings acts as an instrument to deal with this situation. If there is no

aggregate risk, h = 1, optimal saving is zero as seen from (iv) which highlights the precautionary

motive for savings. (v) states that the expected marginal productivity of investment equals the

risk adjusted interest rate, 1 + ohr. The physical investment k is lower if the probability of low

aggregate state is higher (lower ah) or the probability of liquidity shock is higher (lower y). In the

latter case, banks may cut back lending and hold less equity stake due to looming insolvency17.

(vi) states the equilibrium loan size obtained from bank's zero profit condition. Finally, (vii) states

the aggregate consistency condition that sum of all individual capital stocks

equals the aggregate capital and over a unit interval.

The results in the proposition 1 serve to capture the basic functioning of the universal

banking in the simplest possible full information framework. The universal banks optimally

share project risks by offering a riskfree payment d and the residual 03g(k) - d is kept by the

bank.18 Without any conflicts of interest (asymmetric information), this is a Pareto optimal

contract. It eliminates idiosyncratic uncertainties in household consumption and makes

stock price trade at a fair market value.

V. Universal Banking under Asymmetric Information

Using the baseline model of full information described in the preceding section, we now turn

to the case of asymmetric information. The basic tenet of such informational asymmetry is that

banks hold private information about the realization of the aggregate business cycle as well

the liquidity shocks.19 In other words, banks observe true realizations of both liquidity shocks

17In the simulation experiment reported in Table 3 later this conjecture is confirmed.

18This contract is equivalent to: (i) agents holding a preferred stock (or any other instrument that ensures a

constant sum in all contingencies within good aggregate state), and (ii) banks owning ordinary stocks and thus bear

all the residual risks. Thus, banks holding of equity, a hallmark of universal banking, emerges as a mechanism

of an optimum allocation of risk. 19The banks can observe the aggregate shock at least in a partial manner because they lend it to agents

economy-wide and collect/collate information from each borrower. Hence, they tend to have economy-wide

information while each agent is too small to acquire aggregate signal. However, bank's signal about aggregate

and idiosyncratic shocks need not be perfect and could be even noisy. For the sake of parsimony, simplicity,

and without compromising our results below, we ignore the noisiness of bank's signal about aggregate shock

and their private information about individual projects.

14

and the realization of the signal regarding the macro business cycle state but agents know only

the distribution of liquidity shocks and the signals. Since interest payment on deposits and

liquidation of projects in a bad aggregate state take place at t = 2 after the transaction in

intermediate stock market, if the stock market opens at date 1.5, agents cannot ascertain

whether banks have received a low signal or simply suffered a liquidity shock. The information

friction is further aggravated by the fact that household is separated from the firm undertaking

production decisions. This gives rise to a typical lemon problem because universal banks with a

low realization of the signal may sell off the equity held by them in the borrowing firm with a

pretence of the liquidity shock. This problem of selling lemon stocks can emerge only in the

universal banking system as opposed to the non universal system where banks are barred from

holding equities in the borrowing firms.

Figure 2 summarizes the timeline of universal banking in the presence of asymmetric infor-

mation. The only difference from Figure 1 is the dotted line at the node t = 1.5 which represents

the fact that the agent cannot ascertain at this node whether the bank has suffered a liquidity

shock or has received a low aggregate signal or both. At this node, she only observes whether the

stock market has opened or not. If the stock market does not open then she knows for sure (a)

high signal has occurred and (b) no bank has suffered a liquidity shock. Of course, she could

still either succeed or fail. Given that (a) and (b) happen with probability 'yah, the expected

utility (up to this node) is:

ahy[pv(dg + s(1 + r)) + (1 - p)v(db + s(1 + r))].

If the equity market opens at the intermediate date 1.5 where a financial intermediary sells

stocks, an agent concludes that either the bank has received a low signal (with a probability of

1 - ah) or the bank has received good news about the aggregate shock but it is still selling the

stock because it has suffered a liquidity shock. The probability of the latter event is ah(1 - 'y).

Hence, an individual at the node at date 1.5 when she is observing someone selling the stocks

will impute the probability ~ah(1— h(1— ) ~h(1—~) that the stock is not a lemon. The model

(1—yah) y)+(1—ah)

thus portrays a situation where banks lend money to its borrowers and also hold other tradable

financial claims on them. Hence, our model is rich to capture a scenario whereby a bank can

sell off lemon securities to investors when it has private information about bad project state

15

underlying these securities, enabling it to recover some of its lending losses.

<Figure 2: Timeline of Universal Banking under Asymmetric Information>

Define EUa as the expected utility in the presence of information friction. The optimal

contract problem can be thus written as:

fdg;db;s;z;l;kg max EUa = [u(y + f - s - k)] + o-h-y[pv(dg + s(1 + r)) + (1 - p)v(db + s(1 + r))]

+(1 - a h ( 1 ) -Yah) • ((1-7 an)))[pv(dg + (s - z)(1 + r) + zEX~)

q

+(1 - p)v(db + (s - z)(1 + r) + zEX~)] q

+(1 - -yo-h) ((1lyah)) v(s 1 )

- z)

(10)

subject to

bank a = o-h-y [p{0gg(k) - dg} + (1 - p){0bg(k) - db}]+o-h(1--y)(qN-C)+(1-o-h)(qN+m)-f(1+ro-h) ? 0

(11)

There are two important features of this optimal contract problem which require clarification.

First, while writing a contract with the bank, household/shareholder takes into account that

banks can sell off stocks in the midway (at date 1.5) in the wake of bad news and thus they may

incur capital losses. Second, the zero profit constraint (11) now contains an additional term (1 -

o-h)qN which is the extra expected income of the banks from selling securities upon bad

news.

Proposition 2: The equilibrium contract under asymmetric information has the following

properties:

(ia) Contingent Payments: dga = dba =

0@-

da (say) and 1+r~h ~u'(c1) =

1

x

~v0(cn2a ) + (1 - 7)v0(cx2a)

(iia) Share Price: E X~a - (1 + r) = v'{(8a - i l 1-0-h > 0 where E ica

z{ da±(8a—z)(1+r)+zq EX}

ah(1-7\i q

=0g(K) ~

da -

(iiia) Consumption: cx2g = cx2b c2a = da + sa(1 + r) + E Xa n q - (1 + r)oz > cn2g x =

nx c2b =

c2a nx (say) = da + sa(1 + r) > cla = sa - z

(iva) Saving: u0(c1a) = 1(1Ta:41+7h) - a 0 - -r) a - z)

~

(va) Investment: o-h-y 0 g0(k) = 1 + ro-h where 0 = pOh + (1 - p)0l and

(via) Loan: fa = ~h~(~g(k)~da)+(1~~h)(qN+m)+~h(1~~)(qN~C)

1+r~h

(viia) Consistency of Expectations: k = K

16

Proof: Appendix B.

Discussions: We denote the subscript a as the solution of the variables under asymmetric

information. (ia) shares the same feature as (i). Idiosyncratic risks are again borne by the risk

neutral bank and household receives a riskfree payment da for its ownership claim to the project.

The major difference from the baseline full information setting appears in (iia). Since banks can

potentially sell lemon securities in the midway at date 1.5, the optimal contract embeds this

possibility. (iia) shows that stocks sell at a discount in the sense that the price is less than the

discounted value of the cash flow. To put it alternatively, a positive market risk premium

emerges in equilibrium to reflect this lemon problem.

The intuition for (iia) goes as follows. If a household spends one unit to buy stock from a

bank, the marginal utility gain is:

zq EX~(

E X

) v'

1da + (s - z)(1 + r) + - (1 + r) q

which happens with the probability, ah(1 - 'y) that he buys stocks from a good bank suffering

from a liquidity shock. On the other hand, the marginal cost is that if the purchased stock is a

lemon, then he loses out on his savings and consequent marginal utility loss is v'{(s - z)}

which happens with probability (1 - ah). The equivalence between the marginal gain and loss

in investing in stocks explains that the stocks are selling at a discount (or equivalently the

emergence of risk premium) as shown in the equation (iia). Everything else equal, the greater

1h (relative proportion of lemon) the lower the price of the stock. the ratio of ah(1~~)

The immediate implication of stocks selling at a discount is captured in proposition (iiia)

which shows that the consumption flows of households are smoothed out only partially when

banks sell their ownership claims upon bad news. The consumption in the states where house-

holds participate in the stock market exceeds the consumption in states where they do not. (iva)

and (va) are the usual first order conditions for saving and investment. (via) shows the

equilibrium loan size based on the zero profit constraint that binds at the optimum.20

Comparison with the full information baseline reveals that the stock market risk premium

arises purely due to information friction. Since shareholders are unable to ascertain whether

banks sell off shares due to liquidity shock or arrival of bad news, additional premium is required

20The description of overall equilibrium is omitted as they mirror conditions laid out in the appendix, except that

the variables now refer to the asymmetric information case.

17

to lure households to buy shares. The emergence of a risk premium (or stocks selling at a

discount) prevents the agents from smoothing out consumption across nx and x states. In sharp

contrast, a full insurance across nx and x is possible under full information setting because

agents are perfectly informed about the nodes at which banks sell stocks.

The sale of stocks at a discount ex post, certainly changes the structure of contracts between

banks and the borrowing households and it affects investment and commercial banking directly.

The following proposition makes it evident.

Proposition 3: (i) d > da, (ii) s < sa, (iii) f < fa.

Proof: Appendix C.

Since s < sa and f < fa, the immediate implication is that the equilibrium loan size is higher under

asymmetric information. From (iii) and (iiia), it follows that the spread between the expected

consumption in the high and low aggregate signals under adverse selection is greater

than under full information.

The intuitive reasonings of the above results are as follows. Since risk averse households take

greater risks in the equity market than before due to possibilities of buying lemons, they are

compensated by lower equity stake in production, implying d > da. The additional risks of losing

their investment in the bad aggregate state makes marginal utility of households in that state even

higher. This prompts households to make more deposits at the bank for precautionary purposes.

Finally, the loan size increases because banks make more profit from both equity holding (Og(k)

- da) and trading shares ((1 - ah)qN), which lure more competitive banks to enter the commercial

banking industry. The end result is that the size of the commercial banking activity in the form of

loans and deposits expands under asymmetric information. On the other hand, this spurt in

commercial banking activity also leads to an increased volatility of

household's consumption.

Since households bear greater consumption risk in the asymmetric information environment, it

entails welfare loss compared to the full information baseline scenario. In the following proposition,

we establish that for a range of interest rates, the expected utility under asymmetric

information (EUa) is less than the baseline full formation expected utility (EU).

Proposition 4: EU > EUa

Proof: Appendix E.

A few comments are in order before concluding this section. When banks sell stocks upon

18

news, there is a redistributive element where banks receive (1 - ah)C from households (because

in equilibrium, qN = z = C). The inefficiency is thus rooted in two elements: q is traded at a

discount ( proposition 2) and an increase in precautionary savings (s) (proposition 3). Both lead

to a loss of welfare manifested in greater consumption risk (proposition 2). Here, a tax on

trading could partially ameliorate this welfare loss which we deal in section 7.21

VI. Endogenous Interest Rate

The analytical results in propositions 2 and 3 are established in the neighborhood of a full

information equilibrium and also with an assumption of a small open economy which means that

the real interest rate is exogenous. In this section, we perform a simulation experiment to check

the robustness of these results. Assume logarithmic utility functions which means: u(c1) = ln c1

and v(c2) = lnc2: The production function is assumed to be Cobb-Douglas, meaning g(k) = k

with 0 < c < 1. The interest rate (r) is now determined by the loan market equilibrium condition,

s = f: There are nine parameters in this stylized model, namely y;o-h;'y;p;c; °g, Ob; C and m: The

first period output y is normalized at unity with a view to express relevant macroeconomic

aggregates as a fraction of the first period output (GDP). The average growth rate of the

economy is then ahOka + (1 - ah)m.22 After fixing the capital share parameter c at its

conventional value 0.36, the remaining parameters are fixed to target the average quarterly

growth rate of GDP in the US and a real interest rate of 4.62% (computed by subtracting the

bank prime rate from the CPI rate of inflation) during the crisis period 2004Q1-2008Q4.23 The

Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis database is used to arrive at these summary measures for

output growth and real interest rate. Table 1 summarizes the baseline parameter values.

Table 1: Baseline Parameters ~ y Ob °g ~h 'y p m C

0.36 1.00 1.00 2.25 0.92 0.766 0.6 0.05 0.1

Table 2 compares two economies: (i) with symmetric information (Symm Info), (ii) with

21One has to take into account that such a tax also penalizes the honest banks who sell due to adverse liquidity.

An optimal tax can be designed which is beyond the scope of this paper. 22In the context of our two period model, the ratio of the second period to first period outputs approximates

the long run average GDP growth rate. 2 3Given the stylized nature of this two period model, we do not aim to fully calibrate our model economy.

The goal of this simulation is rather to illustrate the comparative statics effects on relevant aggregates setting

parameters at reasonable values. These comparative statics results are reasonably robust to alternative choice of

parameter values.

19

asymmetric information (Asymm Info) for different probabilities of low signal states (1- a-h). The

appendix describes the key equation system and the methodology for this model simulation. The

lemon effect on the stock market is reflected by a sharply lower stock price (q) in the economy

with information friction and a higher consumption volatility (c-vol) measured by the standard

deviation of consumption levels for two dates and states together. In conformity with proposition

3, when information friction is present, banks hold a higher equity stake ( thus lower d/y ) in the

borrowing firms 24 and issue more loans (higher f/y ). While the households also save more as a

precautionary motive, the loan demand far outpaces the supply (f > s) which explains why the

real interest rate rises. A higher interest rate raises the opportunity cost of investment (see

equations v and va in propositions 1 and 2) and has an adverse output effect.25 Consumption

volatility is higher when information friction is present. Notice also that a greater probability of a

low aggregate state (higher 1 - a-h) simply magnifies all these effects. All these results are in

conformity with propositions 2 and 3.

Table 2: Effect of a change in the probability of low signal state

a-h q d/y f/y r(%) output effect c volatility Symm Info

0.92 Asymm Info

0.27

0.13

0.79

0.64

0.20

0.30

4.56%

5.12% -0.27%

0.41

0.46 Symm Info

0.91 Asymm Info

0.30

0.13

0.76

0.62

0.22

0.32

3.4%

4.04% -0.31%

0.39

0.45 Symm Info

0.90 Asymm Info

0.34

0.12

0.74

0.59

0.24

0.34

2.22%

2.93% -0.35%

0.38

0.44

In Table 3, we perform similar sensitivity analysis by varying the probability (1 - 'y) of the

liquidity crisis state. The effect of information friction is again the same as in propositions 2

and 3. A greater probability of a liquidity crisis (lower 'y) heightens the speculative motive of

households for saving which lowers the interest rate in both economies with or without in-

formation friction. Banks keep a lower equity stake and also push less loans in response to a

greater anticipation of a liquidity crisis because of the looming insolvency. The output effects

of information friction is insensitive to change in 'y and so is the consumption volatility. 26

24Note that bank's equity share is simply {1 - (d/y)}100%.

25The adverse output effect of information friction, however, depends on the risk aversion parameter. We have

specialized to a log utility function which means the relative risk aversion parameter is unity. For a more general

power utility function, a higher relative risk aversion parameter entails greater precautionary savings which might

reverse the direction of the output effect because the supply of loans could then outpace the demand.

26The effect of a change in p is not reported here for brevity. Such a change in project risk has very little effects

on the economy except the loan size and contingent payments. In response to a higher project downside risk

(lower p), banks cut back loans (f) and contingent payments (d) to the borrowers significantly.

20

Table 3: Effect of a change in the probability of liquidity crisis ~ q dly fly r (%) output effect c volatility

Symm Info 0.766

Asymm Info

0.27 0.13

0.79 0.64

0.20 0.30

4.56% 5.12%

-0.27% 0.41 0.46

Symm Info 0.75

Asymm Info

0.27 0.13

0.80 0.66

0.19 0.29

2.22% 2.76%

-0.28% 0.41 0.47

Symm Info 0.74

Asymm Info

0.27 0.13

0.81 0.67

0.18 0.28

0.72% 0.12%

-0.28% 0.41 0.47

Table 4 reports the sensitivity analysis of a change in the size of the liquidity shock, C. While

the size of the liquidity shock has negligible consequences for the symmetric information

economy, it has significant effects on the economy with information frictions. This difference in

effects arises particularly due to the fact that C appears in the bank's equilibrium profit equation

(see equation (11)). Banks issue lemon shares with a pretence of a liquidity crunch and in

equilibrium banks can issue shares worth the size of the liquidity shock, C. Thus a greater size of

the liquidity shock provides an incentive to the banks to hold a greater equity stake in borrowing

firms (lower dly) and push more loans (fly) because banks make more profit by selling lemon

shares. The equilibrium interest rate in economies with asymmetric information is higher which

reflects bank's propensity to create more loan demand that far outpaces the household savings.

A higher interest rate has an adverse output effect because investment responds negatively to

interest rate via proposition 2v(a). Consumption volatility in economies with information friction

is significantly higher when the size of the liquidity shock

is higher. This happens because in the presence of information friction, household's equilibrium

consumption in the low signal state (c2l) is s - C which responds negative to a rise in C.

Table 4: Effect of a change in the size of the liquidity shock

C q dly fly r (%) output effect(%) c volatility

0.1 Symm Info

Asymm Info

0.27 0.13

0.79 0.64

0.20 0.30

4.56% 5.12%

-0.27% 0.41 0.46

Symm Info 0.15

Asymm Info

0.28 0.14

0.79 0.57

0.20 0.35

4.56% 5.4%

-0.41% 0.40 0.53

0.2 Symm Info

Asymm Info 0.28 0.14

0.81 0.50

0.20 0.40

4.56% 5.68%

-0.54% 0.41 0.60

Figures 3 through and 5 summarize the salient features of this sensitivity analysis for a longer

ranges of probabilities and size of the liquidity shocks. In response to a higher probability of low

signal state (1-a-h), the ratio of stock prices in an asymmetric to symmetric information scenarios

21

(denoted as qa/q) declines by nearly 60% while the corresponding consumption volatility ratio

(denoted as cvo/a/cvo/) increases by nearly 48%. A higher probability of liquidity crunch (1—'y)

has a mixed effect on the same stock price ratio (qa/q) which declines when the probability of

liquidity crunch exceeds 0.35 while a greater size of the liquidity shock (C), however, keeps the

stock price ratio nearly the same but it raises the consumption volatility quite sharply.

<Figure 3: Effect of a higher probability of a low signal state>

<Figure 4: Effect of a higher probability of a liquidity crunch>

<Figure 5: Effect of a higher liquidity shock, C>

A. What drives the stock market discount?

The upshot of this paper is that the information friction due to bank's conflict of interest could

give rise to a lemon problem which could translate into a stock market discount. The model

predicts that such a discount (measured by the percent change in q from the symmetric

information scenario) could be quite deep. For example, at the baseline parameter values, the

stock market discount is about 52%. The size of the discount is crucially determined by the

relative proportion of lemon in the stock market. Recall that the relative proportion of lemon is

(1—Uh)/(1—-y)Uh which is decreasing in Uh and increasing in -y. Thus a higher probability of a low

aggregate state (lower Uh) and/or a lower probability of liquidity crisis (higher 'y) heightens this

stock market discount. This results in a higher consumption volatility because investors demand a

larger risk premium on shares. This basically summarizes the rational market's reaction to the

potential lemon problem

VII. Punishment

Suppose the government enforces a punishment in the form of a fine 4) if banks misbehave. Let

the probability of being caught for such a misbehavior be A. The expected profit of the bank then

changes to:

7 bank a = Uh~ [p{~gg(k) — dg} + (1 — p){~bg(k) — db}]

+Uh(1 — -y)(qN — C) + (1 — Uh)[(1 — A)(qN + m) —

—f(1 + rUh)

22

Table 3 reports the effects of an increase in the fine amount setting the probability of

detection ('X) at 0.5. An increase in the size of penalty has little effect on share prices and bank's

capital structure d/f. However, the interest rate sharply falls due to such policy intervention. This

happens because for a given interest rate, a higher penalty lowers the loan size at which the zero

profit condition holds. 27. Since the fine amount does not directly appear in the first order

conditions of the household, it has little effect on savings at a given interest rate. The interest rate,

therefore, adjusts downward to equilibrate in response to such a decline in loan demand. This

raises investment and output. This effect is magnified if the fine amount is larger. The stock

market discount due to information friction is also considerably less (40% for a hefty fine of = 2

as opposed to 52% when = 0). Consumption volatility is also lower when the fine amount is

larger. For a sufficiently large fine amount (around = 3), it is possible to replicate the same

consumption volatility as in a symmetric information economy.

Table 5: Effect of a change in the size of the fine for bank misbehavious

q d/y fly r (%) output effect(%) c volatility EU

0.0 Symm Info Asymm Info

0.27

0.13

0.79

0.64

0.20

0.30

4.56%

5.12% -0.27%

0.41

0.46

-0.43 -0.42

0.5 Symm Info Asymm Info

0.27

0.14

0.79

0.63

0.20

0.29

4.56%

3.31% 0.62%

0.40

0.45

-0.43 -0.45

1.0 Symm Info Asymm Info

0.27

0.15

0.79

0.61

0.20

0.30

4.56%

1.93% 1.32%

0.40

0.44

-0.43 -0.47

2.0 Symm Info Asymm Info

0.27

0.16

0.79

0.59

0.20

0.29

4.56%

0.00% 2.75%

0.40

0.42

-0.43 -0.53

Since the policy authority does not know precisely the node at which the bank operates at

date 1.5, it suffers from exactly the same information friction as private citizens. The expected

fine amount thus appears as a tax on all banks' expected profit regardless of their deviant

behaviour. As a result, the punishment is not costless to the society because it is a deadweight

loss. This decreases welfare of private citizens which appears in the last column of Table 5.

VIII. A comparison with a stand alone banking system

Will private citizens be better off if retails banks are "ring-fenced" and legally mandated not

to underwrite securities? The question is relevant in the present context of banking commission's

27To see this note that in the presence of fine fa fa

as shown in proposition 2 for a given r.

= ~h~( ~ g(k)~da)+(1~~h ~(qN+m)~(1~~)~ which is lower than 1+r~h

23

legislation. Using our model, we now demonstrate that in such a restricted environment when

banks cannot diversify away the liquidity shocks by trading securities, full consumption risk

sharing fails even under full information.

Consider an environment where retail banks and investment banks are separated. Retail

banks only perform loan and depository activities while households mimic the operation of

investment bankers by issuing securities to each other. Banks issue loans (F) to the house-

hold/entrepreneur and incur the same loan servicing cost as before. As in the previous scenario,

there is a state of a global liquidity shock where all banks suffer a liquidity shock C. However,

unlike the universal banking regime, in a low aggregate state banks instead of issuing securities

in a secondary share market, call off the loan and sell the capital at a salvage value m. Thus we

merge the two states x and l in a single state where banks liquidate the project early and pay

zero interest on saving deposits.

Bank's zero expected profit condition thus changes to:

E7r = 'Rah(pRg + (1 - p)Rb) - (1 - ah)m - ah(1 - y)C - F(1 + rah) ~ 0

where Rg and Rb are the payments stipulated by the banks in good and bad states, g and b The

expected profit of the bank reflects the following facts. First, the bank receives pay-off from the

project only in the high state with no liquidity shock which explains the first term. Second,

banks sell off the capital at the salvage value m and do not pay interest in states l and x, which

explains the second term. Third, the liquidity shock C hits the bank with the probability ah(1 -

-y) that explains the third term. Finally, the last term captures the fact that banks pay

interest with probability ah.

For the household, we assume that a stand-in household holds a fractional claim (x) to

the value of the stock (Q) at date 1 and issues out (1 - x)Q to others. In equilibrium only a

single share is traded (which means x = 1). The rest of the institutional arrangement is the

same as in the earlier banking scenario.

24

Household's flow budget constraints are now:

c1 + s + k + 3,‘Q = Y + Q + F (12)

c2g nx = s(1 + r) + xf(k)Og — Rg (13)

nx c2b = s(1 + r) + xf(k)Ob — Rb (14)

cx2 = cl = s (15)

The optimal control problem is:

Max u(c1) + ah7[Pv(cn2g ) + (1

x

— P)v(cn2b ) + (1 x — 70" h)v(s)1 (16) {F;Rg;Rb;k;s;x}

subject to (12) through (15).

It is straightforward to check now that derivative of the maximand (16) with respect to the

debt instruments Rg and Rb yields the following first order conditions:

u'( c 1) = v'(c2g nx ) = v(cn

2b x ) (17) 1 +rah

which means that cn2g x = nx c2b = c2

nx (say). Thus debt instruments can eliminate the idiosyncratic

risks in a state of no liquidity shock.28 However, full consumption insurance is not possible

because cn2g = cn2b x x =6 c2

x = cl. In addition, a positive risk premium (RP) arises that is given by

the following expression:

RP = (1 — 7a-h)v'(s)

> 0 (18) 70.hv'(cn

2x)

The failure of full consumption risk sharing and the emergence of a positive risk premium

stands in sharp contrast with universal banking. In the latter case, the presence a secondary stock

market mimics a complete market scenario and enables the household to strike full consumption

insurance through the efficient operation of the equity market. On the other hand, in a stand

alone banking system, the financial markets are fundamentally incomplete due to insufficient

number of financial instruments. This makes full consumption insurance impossible.29

The issue still arises whether private citizens could be better off in a stand alone banking

28Note that unlike universal banking optimal Rg is not equal to Rb. Rather Rg — Rb =(Eig — Bb)f(k) to ensure

consumption equalization between good and bad states. 29In a companion paper with borrower's moral hazard (Banerji and Basu, 2015), we arrive at a similar conclusion.

25

system as opposed to a universal banking environment where information friction is endemic.

Table 6 makes an expected utility comparison of the stand alone banking system with the same

as in the universal banking system with information friction for differ ent values of

probabilities, o-h and 'y around the baseline levels. The expected utility is uniformly higher in

the latter banking arrangement. One needs to be careful about this kind of expected utility

comparison because such a comparison is very model specific and it does not capture numerous

features of both banking systems. Nevertheless, one can at best conclude that everything else

equal, private welfare is higher in a scenario of universal banking where risk diversification

opportunities exist even though conflict of interest between bankers and share holders is

present as opposed to a stand alone banking regime where all these risk sharing opportunities

are shut down by legislation.

Table 6: Expected utilties in universal and stand alone banking s ystems

0.766 0.78 0.79

0.92 EUu= —0:42

EUn= —2:49

EUu= —0:42

EUn= —2:14

EUu= —0:41

EUn= —1:96

0.93 EUu= —0:40

EUn= —2:26

EUu= —0:40

EUn= —1:99

EUu= —0:39

EUn= —1:84

0.94 EUu= —0:38

EUn= —2:09

EUu= —0:38

EUn= —1:87

EUu= —0:38

EUn= —1:75

IX. Conclusion

The universal banking system has been a subject of controversy especially in the wake of

current financial crisis. The critics argue that such a system could inflict excessive risks on the

financial system. In this paper, we evaluate the nature of such risks and the consequent impact

on overall banking activities. We find that discounting of stocks, volatilities in consumption,

pushing of loans and excessive savings could emerge if hidden information is pervasive and if

particularly the probability of bad aggregate shock is high.

The major policy question still remains open whether Glass -Steagall banking should be

brought back and ring fencing should be strengthened. The recommendation of the independent

banking commission in the UK and the recent trends in the US banking system point to this

26

Note: EUu = Expected utility in the universal banking and EUn = Expected utility in the stand alone banking

direction. While a full blown comparison of universal banking and a stand-alone banking

systems is beyond the scope of this paper, one can argue on the basis of our model that a

universal banking system could efficiently allocate risk and could replicate the first best

optimum under an ideal scenario of no information friction. In the presence of information

friction, the undesirable consequences have to be weighed against the inefficiency imposed by

the artificial separation between commercial and investment banking in a Glass-Steagall

banking regime. The universal banking could work well if the regulatory authorities are

committed to enforce strict disclosure of regimes to eliminate the information frictions. This

together with a small punitive tax on trading of stocks can reduce the lemon problem of the

universal banking and can improve the efficiency of the banking sector although it could still

entail some welfare loss due to a blanket tax in all banks'profits.

Appendix

A. Equilibrium Conditions

In equilibrium, three conditions hold:

1. Each bank stipulates an optimal contract laid out in proposition 1 with each household

taking the average capital stock, K and average contingent payments d as given.

2. Expectations are consistent which means k = K

3. All markets clear which means:

In the contingent claims market at date 1, each bank's state contingent shares are given

by Ogg(k)—dg

and Obg(k)—db

while household's shares are given by Ogg(k) d g and db .

Ogg(k) Obg(k) Obg(k)

In the secondary share market at date 1.5, the demand for shares equals the supply which

means qN = z = C.

Goods markets clear at each date which mean

- At date 1, c1 + k = y - rahNFI ~

= y

- At date 2,

0h[pOg + (1 - p)Ob]g(k) + (1 - ah)m - ah(1 - 'y)C(1 + r) = Ec2

27

x

~h~[pcn2g + (1 _ p)cn

2b ] + 0-h(1 x

— -y)[pcx2g + (1 — p)cx

2b] + (1 — a-h)c2l (19)

The following remarks about market clearing conditions are in order: First the contingent

claims di are not traded in a market. These are stipulated by optimal contracts and that is why

there is no price attached to each such contingent claim. Second, the secondary shares are

traded in a market that opens at date 1.5. The demand for such shares is z which is the amount

a household agent apportions from her savings. The supply is the amount that banks issue

consequent on a liquidity shock. We assume that given q, banks issue shares exactly worth

the amount of the exogenous liquidity crunch C: This means that qN = z = C

Third, about the date 1 goods market clearing conditions, the imbalance between saving

(s) and loan (f) is financed by net foreign investment (NFI f — s) at a fixed world interest rate

(r) after adjusting for the probability of aggregate high state (o-h). Although the payment from

such net foreign investment comes at date 2, we net out the interest payment from date

1 endowment (y) as a fixed transfer payment. This explains the presence of the term rahNFI

and why y = y — ra-hNFI. Finally, the date 2 goods market clearing condition basically

means that the right hand side term which is the consumption plus the foreign debt

retirement aggregated across all individuals must balance the corresponding left hand side

term which is the aggregate output net of the liquidity shock including the interest payment

on it. Since this shock is exogenous, it appears like a tax on date 2 output. This explains the

presence of the term o-h(1 — -y)C(1 + r) on the left hand side of (19).30

B. Proof of Proposition 1

Plugging consumption of individual agents in each contingency outlined above in the expected

utility function, we get:

Max EU = [u(y + f — s — k)] + a-h-y[pvfdg + s(1 + r)g + (1 — p)vfdb + s(1 + r)g]

+a-h(1 — 7)[pvfdg + (s — z)(1 + r) + —EXg + (1 — p)vfdb + (s — z)(1 + r) + —zEXg] q q

+(1 — a-h)v(s)

30It is easy to verify that the Walras law holds here so that if all but one market clears, then adding all the

budget constraints would ensure that the remainder market must clear as well. To see this, one can plug the

budget constraints (4) through (9) and the zero profit condition ((vi) in Proposition 1 into the date 2 aggregate

demand for good (Ec2) and by using the secondary market equilibrium condition (en = C = Z) in the resulting

expression will verify that the market for goods at date 2 automatically clears.

28

subject to:

~b = ah-y[pfOgg(k) — dgg + (1 — p)f0bg(k) — dbg] + (1 — a-h)m — f:(1 + rah) = 0

First order conditions with respect to dg,db,s,k and z respectively are

(c1) dg iJ +rah = ( c r y) + (1 — y))vv ((cc2xgg)) (A1)

db -yu'( c i)

= 'Yv'(cn2bx) + (1 — )v(cx2b) (A2)

,1+r ah

s u(c1)

= ~~h[pv(cn2gx) + (1 — p)v'(cn

2b x )] (A3) 1 + rah

+(1 — -y)ah[pv(cx2g) + (1 — p)v(cx

2b)](1 + r) + (1 — crh)v(c2l)

k : u'(c1)[ah-yOg'(k) — (1 + r)] = 0 (A4)

~ EX

z : [pv'(cx2g) + (1 ~ p)v(c2x b)]( — (1 + r))? 0

(A5) q

(i) We will show now that dg = db = d:

Let us suppose that dg > db. Let us make the adjustment such that dg is reduced and db is

increased so as to reduce the gap in such a way that the zero profit constraint is not affected,

i.e. [pdg + (1 — p)db] is constant. Hence, [p(dg — A1) + (1 — p)(db + A2)] is a constant so that

(1 — p)A2 = pA1:

Now, evaluate the expected utility with small increments that satisfy the above equality.

AEU = ~h[~f~pv'(cn2g x )~1 + (1 — p)v'(cn

2 T)A2g + (1 — -y)f—pv'(cx2g)A1 + (1 — p) v(cx

2b)A2g]

)

AEU = ~h[~fv(c2b nx ) — v(cn2g x )g + (1 — -y)fv'(cx

2b) — v'(cx2g)g](1 — p)A2 > 0 (A6)

s Since, cn2b < cn2g s it implies that v'(cn 2bx ) — v'(cn

2gx) > 0 (due to concave utility function) and

since cx2b < c2g, v(cx

2b) — v'(cx2g) > 0 and A2 > 0 because db was increased.

x '

Hence, adjustment can be made until v'(cn2bx) — v'(cn

2g

nx and cx2b = cx

2 which implies dg = db

x ) = 0 and v'(cx2b) — v'(cx

2g) = 0. Hence,

nx c2b = c2g

One can start with the reverse inequality dg < db and make the opposite adjustments to

29

reach this equality. This proves (i).

(ii) and (iii): From (A5), it follows that (EX q (1 + r)) = 0 and plugging the result in

cx2g = dg + (s — z)(1 + r) + zE X and cx2b q = db + (s — z)(1 + r) + zE X and using the result from q

(i) that dg = db = d yields cn2g = cn2b = cx2g x x = cx2b = c2(say). This proves (ii) and (iii).

(iv): The equation (A3) can be written as

u'(c1) = ah[pf'Yv' (c27 7)++ ((11 ——7~y))'1v1 ((cc772, 27)1+ (1 —P) {111 (c- Y ) + (1-7)v' (cx2b)g](1+r)+(1—o-h)v'(c2l)

1 + rah

Plugging (A1) and (A2), 1+rah u(c1) = u()(r) + (1 ah1+ah

— ah)v0(c2l) and by rearrangement, we

get:

u ,(c1) =

[-1 (1

-yah + -yo-h(1 —'y)

— o-h)(1 + rah) ]v(s)

which proves (iv).

The part (v) follows from the straightforward differentiation with respect to k and the binding

zero profit constraint of the intermediary together with (i) yields the last proposition. //

C. Proof of Proposition 2

Using the same line of reasoning as in Proposition 1, one can establish that

v(c2b nx ) — v(c2g nx ) = (B1)

and

v(c2b) — v(c2g) = 0 (B2)

On the other hand, the first order condition for z is:

v,(da + (sa

z ~

{

E X r) — z)(1 + r) + EX a ) : — (1 + crh(1 — r) = v(sa — z)(1 — o-h)

qa qa

Since v'(:) > 0 ) E Xa ~ (1 + r) > 0 ) c2xg > cn2bx Hence, (B1) and (B2) can hold if

qa

c2g = c2b > c2g nx = c2b

nx

(B3)

The part (ia) follows from the above result and the two first order conditions with respect

30

to fdg; dbg

"d'g' ru'(c1) 1+rah =

,' v'k( cn2g) + (1 x

— ,y)v'(cx2g )

db : 1+~~h ~u'(c1)

= 7v'(cn2bx) + (1 — 7)v'(cx2b)

The part (iia) follows directly from the first order with respect for z, which is,

v'fda + (sa z)(1 + r) + z

EXagf

~ E Xa

(1 + r)gfah(1 ~)g v'f(sa z)g(1 ah) — — — = — — qa qa

The part (iiia) follows from (B3) and (ia).

Finally, (iva) and (va) can be shown exactly using similar line of reasoning as in the earlier

section. //

D. Proof of Proposition 3

All variables are evaluated at their full information values obtained in the proposition 1. This

means that we start from a full information equilibrium with zero information friction. Thus at

date 1, in the absence of information friction, c1 = c1a. Given the same r, it means that k = ka:

From the date 1 resource constraint (4), it follows that f — s = fa —sa:

Starting from this scenario of no information friction, with the onset of information friction,

z and the risk premium terms turn positive from 0. Given c1 = c1a; from proposition 1(iv) and

proposition 2(iva) it follows that v'(s) = v'(sa — z) which means that s < sa. Since f — s = fa

—sa; the immediate implication is that f < fa:

Next compare the expressions for f and fa in proposition 1(vi) and proposition 2vi(a)

evaluated at equilibrium qN = C and note that since f — fa < 0, the following inequality holds

-yo-h(d — da) + C(1 — o-h) > 0

For a sufficiently small C, the above inequality means that d > da //

E. Proof of Proposition 4

Using the risk sharing results from proposition 2, the expected utility (EUa) in (10) can be

written in a compact form as:

EUa = u(y + fa — sa — k) + ah[7v(cn2ax) + (1 — 7)v(cx2a)] + (1 — ah)v(c2a)

31

1-1 a

Next note that the expected utility under full information (with full risk sharing) is given

by:

EU = u(y + f — s — k) + ahv(c2) + (1 — ah)v(cl2)

Since our baseline of comparison is full information equilibrium, by construction f — s = fa

—sa and cl2 = cl

2a (see proposition 3).

The comparison of two expected utilities EU and EUa thus hinges on the relative magnitudes

of v(c2) and [~v(cn2ax) + (1 — 7)v(c2

xa)]: Note from proposition 1(iii) that c2 = s(1 + r) + d: On

the other hand, recall from proposition 2(iiia), c2 nx

= da + sa(1 + r) and cx2a = da + sa(1 + r) +

f

1

E Xa (1 + r)} • c:

q

Since the comparison is made in the neighbourhood of a full information equilibrium, we set

the interest rate r such that

c2 = 7cn2a + (1

x — 7)c2a

By strict concavity of the utility function (applying Jensen's inequality), it then follows that

v(c2) > ~v(cn2ax) + (1 — 7)v(cx

2a): This proves that EU > EUa: //

F. Methodology for Model Simulation

Case of symmetric Information

With a log utility function and Cobb-Douglas production function g(k) = ka the equation

system in Proposition 1 reduces to:

-y(d + s(1 + r)) = (1 + rah)c1 based on (i) (20)

s = (1 — ah)(1 + rah)

7) 1 c1 based on (iv) (21) -yo-h+ rah(1 1 — —

k = +

~ based on (v) (22)

70-h0a

32

f = ah-y(Oka — d) + (1 — ah)m

based on (vi) after plugging qN — C = 0 (23) 1 + ro-

h

Given the loan market clearing condition s = f, the first period resource constraint for the

economy reduces to c1 + k = y which after plugging into (21) and (22), one gets

-y(d + s(1 + r)) = (1 + rah)(y — k) (24)

s = (1 — 0-

h)(1 + rah) i

(y—) (25) [1 — -yo-h + ro-

h(1— 7)

Eqs (22), (23), (24) and (25) solve for d; f; k; r. The security price q can be obtained by

using the equation q = ~~k~~d

1-Fr

Case of Asymmetric Information

With the same log utility function and the Cobb-Douglas production function, the risk

sharing condition (ia) in Proposition 2 (together with the loan market clearing condition, sa = fa

and the share market clearing condition z = C) reduces to

7 7 +

1 — -y (26)

(y — ka)(1 + raah) da + sa(1 + ra) + RP • C da + sa(1 + ra)

where RP stands for risk premium equal to n E Xa

— (1 + ra)oand the subscript a stands qa

for the interest in the asymmetric information scenario.

Next use the expression for risk premium in Proposition 2(iia) and solve the equilibrium

RP (imposing the aggregate consistency condition k =

(da + fa(1 + r)) RP = A1: ( 27 )

fa — C(1 + A1)

where

1 — a- =

Q(1 — -y)

After plugging the goods market clearing condition c1 +k = y and the loan market and share

market clearing conditions fa = sa and z = C, Proposition 2(iva) reduces to

(fa — C) = (1 — ah)(1 + raah)

(y — ka) (28) 1 — -yo-

h+ rao-h(1— 7)

33

11 Q

241

The investment equation is the same as before and can be written as:

ka = +

(29) ~

Finally the zero profit condition reduces to

fa = ah'y( Og(ka) - da) + (1 - ah)(m + C)

(30) 1 + raah

Eq (26) through (30) can be solved for five unknowns, fa; da; ra; ka; RP: The resulting share

price qa is given by 1+ra+RP == ~kaQ ~da

References

[1] Akerloff, G.A., and R.J. Shiller, Phishing for Phools: The Economics of Manipulation and

Deception, Princeton University Press, 2015.

[2] Azariadis, C. (1993). Intertemporal Macroeconomics. Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.

[3] Azariadis, C and B.D. Smith. (1993). Adverse Selection in the Overlapping Generations

Model: The Case of Pure Exchange, Journal of Economic Theory 60, 277-305.

[4] Banerjee, S and P. Basu. Borrower's moral hazard, risk premium, and welfare a comparison

of universal and stand-alone banking systems. The Journal of Economic Asymmetries 12(1):

61-72, 2015.

[5] Barth, J. R., R.D. Brumbaugh, and J.A. Wilcox (2000). The repeal of Glass-Steagall and

the advent of broad banking. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(2), 191– 204.

[6] Benston, G.J. (1990). The Separation of Commercial and Investment Banking: The Glass-

Steagall Act Reconsidered. New York: Oxford University Press.

[7] Benston, G.J. (1994). Universal banking. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8(3), 121-143.

[8] Ber, H., Y. Yafeha, and O. Yosha (2001). Conflict of interest in universal banking: Bank

lending, stock underwriting, and fund management. Journal of Monetary Economics 47(1),

189-218. (Redunant)

34

[9] Bhattacharya, S., and A. V. Thakor (1993). Contemporary banking theory. Journal of

Financial Intermediation 3(1), 2-50.

[10] Diamond, D.W. (1984). Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Eco-

nomic Studies 51 (3),

393– 414.

[11] The Financial Times (11th April, 2011). Proposals bring UK industry closer to US rules.

Retrieved from http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/fe2134a4-6484-11e0-a69a-00144feab49a.html.

[12] Freixas, Xavier and J.C. Rochet (2008). Microeconomics of Banking, 2nd edition. Massa-

chusetts: MIT Press.

[13] Gande, A., M. Puri, A. Saunders, and I. Walter (1997). Bank underwriting of debt securities:

Modern evidence. Review of Financial Studies 10(4), 1175-1202.

[14] Hart, Or (1995), Firms, Contracts and Financial Structure, Oxford University Press.

[15] Gurley and Shaw (1960). Money in a Theory of Finance. Washington: Brookings.

[16] Hill, C.A (2010). Why did rating agencies do such a bad job rating subprime securities?"

University of Minnesota Kaw School, Reproduced.

[17] Kanatas, G. and J. Qi (1998). Underwriting by commercial banks: Incentive conflicts, scope

economies, and project quality. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 30(1), 119-133.

[18] Kanatas, G. and J. Qi (2003). Integration of lending and underwriting: Implications of

scope economies. Journal of Finance 58(3), 1167-1191.

[19] Kroszner, R.S. and R.G. Rajan (1994). Is the Glass Steagall Act justified? A study of

the U.S. experience with universal banking before 1933. American Economic Review 84(4),

810-832.

[20] Kroszner, R.S. and R.G. Rajan (1997). Organization structure and credibility: Evidence

from commercial bank securities activities before the Glass-Steagall Act. Journal of Mon-

etary Economics 39(4), 475-516.

[21] Mehra, R., and E.C. Prescott (1985). The equity premium: A puzzle. Journal of Monetary

Economics 15(2),

145– 161.

35

[22] Mehran, H. and R. Stulz (2007). The economics of conflicts of interest in financial institu-

tions. Journal of Financial Economics 85(2), 267-296.

[23] Mustafa, K. and B. Neyapti (2012). Bank regulation and supervision and its welfare impli-

cations, Economic Modelling, 29,

132– 141

[24] Puri, M. (1996). Universal banks in investment banking: Conflict of interest or certification

role?. Journal of Financial Economics 40(3), 373-401.

[25] Puri, M. (1999), Universal banks as underwriters: Implications for the going public process.

Journal of Financial Economics 54(2), 133-163.

[26] Rajan, R ( 2002). An investigation into extending bank powers. Journal of Emerging Market

Finance 1(2), 125-156.

[27] Stigltiz Joseph (2009). Capitalism Fools, News article in Vanity Fair.

[28] Tchana, F.T. (2012). The welfare cost of banking regulation, Economic Modelling, 29,

217-232.

36

Fig 1: Timeline of universal banking under full information

Fig 2:Timeline of universal banking under asymmetric information

37