Banking Free

  • Upload
    afzal

  • View
    217

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    1/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    2/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    3/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    4/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    5/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    6/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    7/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    8/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    9/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    10/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    11/232

    P REFACE TO N EW P RINTING

    After the first edition of this book appeared in 1993, I turned away from many of the banking issues explored herein. Anarchocapitalism, taxation, and publicgoods in maritime history occupied most of my professional attention, while atthe same time there was an ongoing personal project, a 1300-page manuscriptanalyzing merchant sailing ship performances, on which I have been working for some 20 years. I continued to think and write about business cycles, but largelyleft free banking behind. This was because I thought that the case for fractionalreserve free banking based on a commodity outside money had been persua-sively presented by myself and others such as Lawrence H. White, George Selgin,and Kevin Dowd. And I still do.

    However, one group of economists has continued to reject and attack laissez-faire banking, at least so long as such banks are based on the holding of less than100 percent (primary) reserves. This group is principally composed of certainRothbardians associated with the Ludwig von Mises Institute, some of whom, bythe way, I am pleased to think of as friends. It includes, among others, Walter

    Block, Jrg Guido Hlsmann, Hans-Hermann Hoppe, William Barnett II, andespecially Jess Huerta de Soto. In what follows I will explain why I think their various condemnations of fractional reserve free banking (FRFB), despite their energetic efforts, remain unconvincing.

    Allow me to begin with the last, Huerta de Soto. His massive 876-page trea-tise, Money, Bank Credit, and Economic Cycles (2006), is intended to be the finaland decisive proof that fractional reserves are incompatible with a) a proper defense of private property rights, b) morality, and c) a stable economy. With

    painstaking effort he investigates legal theory, banking history, business cycles,

    and even variations in medieval theological doctrine. There is much to interest thecurious reader, but a great deal is actually irrelevant to the authors professedintent. Further, one will repeatedly encounter, along with some careful scholar-ship, straw man arguments, nonsequiturs, and question-begging. Pervading the

    1

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    12/232

    early portions of the work is the assertion that ancient Roman law, and medievalEuropean law based upon it, correctly identified the true nature of demand

    deposits (monetary irregular deposits) as warehouse contracts involving fungi- ble goods (though he seems strangely unaware that commodity coins have oftennot been fungible due to debasement, or normal wear and tear). Any deviationfrom such contractual relations (e.g., fractional reserves) he thus castigates as anact of fraud or theft on the part of the banker. If that sounds as if the book adoptsa severely moralizing tone, it does. In fact, there is use of the term sin whenreviewing various episodes in banking history (pp. 88, 92, 97). And fractionalreserve depositaries are even described as legal aberrations possessing no legalstanding, much like human monsters with physical deformities (p. 143).Moreover, Huerta de Soto insists that banks indulging in fractional reservesinevitably open the Pandoras Box of monetary inflation, excessive credit cre-ation, malinvestment, and business cycles (pp. xxvi, 56 n32, 265395).

    He does recognize that loans ( mutuum contracts) are also legitimate, but atthe same time insists that all loans must be for a stated time period. Amazingly,Huerta de Soto declares that loans devoid of such a time stipulation cannotexist (pp. 34). And yet they do exist. Prepayment options are common today in

    both mortgage contracts and tuition loans to college students. At a number of points elsewhere in the book, he claims that throughout history the principal, if not the only, reason for bank failures and bank runs has been fractional reserves.Here he ignores two crucial facts: a) bank failures have often been the result of constraining regulations and/or errors in granting loans and b) during bank runs,consumers have often shifted their checkable deposits from an insolvent fraction-al reserve bank to some other, solvent fractional reserve bankinstead of simplyholding greater amounts of cash, either at home or in a safety deposit box. It is

    precisely this sort of faulty reasoning, born of a plausible premise but imperviousto the facts, which will justifiably fail to persuade many economists.

    In effect, Huerta de Soto defines demand deposits as a warehousing contractand then proceeds to provide many details on how that sort of contract has often been violated by banks. He never really comes to grips with the nature of FRFB,nor with its defenders arguments (though he attempts to do this in his Chapter 8).This book chronicles many episodes in banking history, but the conclusions thatare drawn are highly dependent upon the assumptions from which they com-mence. For example, a speech given by Demosthenes in 362 B.C. is discussed atsome length in order to glean an understanding of ancient Greek banking.However, when Demosthenes declares that the main reason for bank failures was

    the extension of credit to unworthy borrowers, Huerta de Soto suddenly partscompany with him, insisting that he is mistaken since the real reason for suchfailures was bankers failure to hold 100 percent reserves (pp. 4849). Similarly,after favorably citing works by scholars Ramon Carande, Abbott P. Usher, andRaymond De Roover, he asserts that they all have misinterpreted the historical

    2 Preface

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    13/232

    evidence insofar as they fail to dwell on what he would, no doubt, describe as theegregious fraud of fractional reserves (pp. 71 n56, 74, 81).

    While discussing theorists of the famed School of Salamanca, he concedesthat some actually favored fractional reserves, but these he dismisses as beingJesuit deviationists (p. 95, n97). He does of course praise those Dominicans of Salamanca who, he believes, were advocates of 100 percent reserves. However,it is not entirely clear from the citations provided whether these Dominicanscriticisms were actually aimed at fractional reserves per se or at usurious loancontracts between bankers and their customers (pp. 8588). In fact, he comesrather close, though unintentionally, to conceding the latter (p. 89).

    There are also some rather far fetched connections that Huerta de Soto is will-

    ing to use as evidence in his favor. One particularly notable example has to dowith his judgment of the operations of Spanish banks during the sixteenth centu-ry. Here he depends largely on the work of Carlo M. Cipolla regarding Italianbanks of that same time period. Amazingly, Huerta de Soto reassures the reader that the details on Italian banks are directly applicable to Spanish banks

    because of the close economic ties between the two nations (p. 81). I would grantthat banking practices in one nation might mirror those in another nation, but Iwould need more of an explanation than the mere assertion that the twoeconomies were, in certain ways, interdependent. Great Britain and the United

    States have been linked economically for a long time, but does that justify theconclusion that any analysis of American banking practices would be equallyapplicable to Britain?

    The foregoing indirectly brings to mind a further possible problem for thereader, though not necessarily a flaw in the presentation. Huerta de Soto is obvi-ously multilingual, which is entirely to his credit of course. His sources includeones which are in English, Latin, Spanish, Italian, and French. However, anyreader fluent in only one of those languagesand who might have reservationsabout Huerta de Sotos evidencemust be left with the nagging question of whether certain of the cited sources actually do support the books arguments.

    Above all, Huerta de Soto refuses to even consider the possibility that bankscustomers may have been quite willing to face some risk exposure in exchangefor the benefits of a) the receipt of interest on their deposits and b) having circu-lating inside money in the form of payable to the bearer banknotes (something100 percent reserve banks are unable to provide, since they must charge securityfees on all demand deposits). Instead, he is driven to a heavily conspiratorialinterpretation of banking history. In his hands any departure from 100 percentreserve banking is automatically taken to be evidence of malfeasance by bankers,even when there is no clear data on the details of the contractual relations nego-tiated by depositors. [T]he traditional principles of safekeeping on which themonetary irregular-deposit contract is based were violated from the very begin-ning [of banking] in a concealed manner. . . . [Governments] supported bankersimproper activity almost from the beginning (pp. 3738). This may accord with

    Preface 3

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    14/232

    Murray Rothbards view of the political class as some sort of unrepentant cabal, but it sheds rather little light on the essence of banking.

    A clever variation on this same theme of fractional reserve banking as fraudcan be found in Jrg Guido Hlsmanns article Has Fractional-Reserve BankingReally Passed the Market Test? ( The Independent Review , Winter 2003). Thenovelty here is the argument that the IOUs of fractional reserve banks (their issues of banknotes and deposit credits) are naturally differentiable due to thevarying risk characteristics of each bank, and thus such fiduciary instruments willvary in price, with all being traded at a discount relative to real money (specie)and money titles (notes issued by 100 percent reserve banks). To overcome this

    problem, Hlsmann claims that FRFB will unavoidably gravitate toward forming

    a cartel in which all individual banks agree to homogenize inside money byaccepting one anothers IOUs at par. Their goal is to accomplish the semantictrickery (p. 411) of deceiving the public into thinking that the banknotes or deposit credits issued by fractional reserve banks are no different from money or money titles.

    There are two flaws in this argument. First, if the cartel is voluntary, it willhave little chance of surviving. As Murray Rothbard pointed out in Man,

    Economy, and State (pp. 57986), such cartels are inherently unstable. Theyeither revert to a multiplicity of competitors or merge into one large firm. If we

    are to take Hlsmanns hypothesis seriously, then it is incumbent upon him toexplain why cartels are generically unstable, but somehow stable in the contextof fractional reserve banking. On the other hand, if compulsion is involved, whatone has is the imposition of a central bank on the economy. The former case isineffective, and the latter has no relevance to the case for FRFB.

    Second, Hlsmann apparently wants the reader to believe that consumers aresomehow steadfastly incapable of differentiating a) money warehouses whichissue money titles and charge their customers fees for the provision of security(and perhaps transaction services such as accounting entries which transfer fundsfrom one customer to another) from b) financial intermediaries which issue their own distinctive inside money (IOUs), offer transaction services, and pay inter-est on their customers account balances. In fact, he even claims that GreshamsLaw becomes operative in this environment (p. 408). That is, he insists that theoverpriced IOUs tend to drive the underpriced money titles out of circula-tion.

    One immediate problem with this is that, as Murray Rothbard stated emphat-ically ( Man, Economy, and State , p. 783), Greshams Law only applies to the casewhere one form of money is officially overpriced and the other officially under-

    priced, that is, by an act of government. It does not apply to free market relation-ships. A further, obvious inconsistency is revealed as soon as the reader recallsthat these selfsame bank customers are allegedly able to differentiate among theIOUs issued by various fractional reserve banks (based on the variation in risk)and simultaneously unable to tell the difference between a fractional reserve IOU

    4 Preface

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    15/232

    and a real money title issued by a 100 percent reserve bank warehouse. This isnonsensical. It seems comparable to claiming that a person can differentiate

    among the numerous breeds of dogs, but cannot tell that a cat is not a dog.Allow me now to leave aside further specific criticisms of particular works

    and instead to emphasize certain commonalities. Found in both of these above-mentioned essays, and most if not all, other defenses of 100 percent reserve bank-ing are three problematic assertions. The first is the assumption that any departurefrom 100 percent reserves cannot be agreeable to the banks customers and thusconstitutes an act of fraud on the part of the banker. As a result, all the historicalepisodes in which banks began as money warehouses but later acted as interme-diaries holding fractional reserves are immediately interpreted as being rooted incriminality. The obvious alternative possibility, that fractional reserve holdingmight have naturally evolved as an improvement on warehousing is rejected outof hand. This mode of thinking extends to court cases. Any judge who ruled thatinterest-bearing demand deposits were a form of loan to the banker becomes anaccomplice to fraud. The idea that such a ruling might have accurately reflecteda common practice, one generated by the fully-informed and voluntary actions of

    both banker and depositor, is never investigated seriously.The second troubling premise is the notion that, once there exists an accepted

    medium of exchange used by all in a given society, no changes in the moneystock are ever welfare-enhancing. In other words, at that moment the existingsupply is already optimal. Neither subsequent increases nor subsequent decreas-es serve any valid economic purpose (other than those deflationary decreaseswhich are the corrective for prior inflationary increases). That having been said,they do not quite mean literally all changes in the money supply. Increases in ban-knotes or deposit credits which stem from an increase in the monetary gold heldin the vaults of the 100 percent reserve banks are seen as natural and harmless.And they often note that such increases in the specie base have occurred histori-

    cally at modest annual rates of 1 percent5 percent.This proposition faces a serious difficulty. It can only be correct if it is truethat the purchasing power of a given money stock adjusts immediately to reflectchanging conditions, i.e., all prices must be perfectly flexible in the short run.And I have long found that latter condition to be highly questionable. Indeed, itflies in the face of certain crucial aspects of Austrian thought. For instance, allAustrians describe the market as comprising interactions between forward-look-ing (i.e., speculative) buyers and sellers whose state of knowledge is alwaysincomplete, even as they strive for completeness. Moreover, this state of knowl-

    edge is ever-evolving precisely because the market is a discovery process . But todiscover economic facts requires time. It cannot be anything close to instanta-neous. And it cannot be devoid of error. Therefore, to conceive of the market asa discovery process is to cast doubt upon the idea that all prices are fully and rap-idly flexible. Those who maintain that any supply of money is optimal seem, in

    Preface 5

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    16/232

    effect, to live in the long run world of full equilibrium, not the real world of con-stant adjustments and corrections.

    Further doubt is raised as soon as one tries to integrate full and rapid priceflexibility with the Austrian theory of business cycles (ABCT). This probablycannot be done in any plausible way. ABCT is a theory of unsustainable booms

    followed at some point by inescapable contractionswhich are fueled byexcessive credit expansion undertaken by the central bank. Relative prices and themarket rate of interest are modified in a way that is inconsistent with consumerstime preferences. These monetary effects are far from trivial because they elicitchanges in real factors, in particular, changes in the capital structure. In strikingcontrast to mainstream macroeconomists, who usually ignore all issues of the

    capital structure (and thus focus on either short run disequilibria or on full, longrun equilibrium), Austrians wisely emphasize the medium run. This is a time peri-od long enough for a restructuring of capital to take place, but too short for theresulting malinvestment to be both recognized and corrected.

    Money and credit precipitate the problem; while time-consuming alterationsin capital are its manifestation. Furthermore, if the array of relative prices wereto be disrupted only briefly, then the capital budgeting errors that are later iden-tified as malinvestment would be much less likely to occur in the first place. If longer-term projects were planned, but then relative prices quickly changed back

    so as to reveal them to be errors, many projects would never be undertaken at all,and others soon thereafter would be liquidated. The unsustainable boom wouldnever really get underway at all. Once again, some passage of time is needed.There must be time to plan capital projects, time to put those plans in action, timeduring which the deceptive market signals continue to reassure entrepreneurs thattheir projects are justified, time for the temporal malinvestment eventually toreveal itself. ABCT deals not with the artificial world of perfect competition, per-fect knowledge, and an infallible auctioneer, but with the real world of strategicaction, imperfect knowledge, and fallible entrepreneurs. ABCT would appear torequire that money has powerful, but sometimes sluggish, effects on prices.

    The third problem area is a derivative of the issue of price flexibility dis-cussed above. It is the implicit assumption that the demand for money is, ineffect, irrelevant to a proper analysis of banking. Led by Murray Rothbard, vari-ous Austrians have addressed a question which will inevitably be asked of anyadvocate of 100 percent reserves: What happens if the demand for money rises or falls? According to these Austrians, a change in the demand for money does not

    justify a commensurate change in the supply of money. With a given nominalsupply of money, if the demand rises (falls) all that will occur is that the purchas-ing power of money (the inverse of the array of goods prices) will rise (fall). Noadjustment to the nominal stock of money is needed, so 100 percent reserve hold-ing by banks creates no difficulty. Perfect price flexibility allegedly ensures thatthe real money stock adjusts in the appropriate direction. If that line of reason-ing is correct, then why does this not work equally easily on the other side of the

    6 Preface

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    17/232

    market? That is, with a given nominal demand for money, if the nominal supplyof money rises (falls) why is the corrective not simply a fall (rise) in the pur-

    chasing power of money?As questionable as the foregoing perspective is, no short-run alternative solu-

    tion would seem to exist for the proponent of 100 percent reserves. Thus, in theabsence of perfect price flexibility for all goods and services, both inputs and out-

    puts, only fractional reserve free banks are capable of responding properly tochanges in the demand for money. Chapters 2 and 3, plus portions of Chapters 4and 8, of the present work will examine that adjustment process in considerabledetail.

    I would like earnestly to thank Jeffrey Tucker and the Ludwig von Mises

    Institute for their willingness to publish this new edition. Whether or not oneagrees with the conclusions found herein, I believe that it offers a valuable sur-vey of many of the historical and theoretical issues surrounding laissez-faire

    banking. Therefore, I hope that one of its uses may be as a supplemental text in banking or monetary theory courses.

    I greatly appreciate the helpful comments I have received from John P.Cochran, Steven Horwitz, Lawrence H. White, George Selgin, and Kevin Dowd,as well as the gracious responses from Jess Huerta de Soto to certain questionsof mine.

    Finally, I wish to thank my wife Mary Ann and my son Kyle for their invalu-able love and support.

    Larry J. SechrestJune 2008

    Preface 7

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    18/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    19/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    20/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    21/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    22/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    23/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    24/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    25/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    26/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    27/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    28/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    29/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    30/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    31/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    32/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    33/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    34/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    35/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    36/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    37/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    38/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    39/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    40/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    41/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    42/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    43/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    44/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    45/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    46/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    47/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    48/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    49/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    50/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    51/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    52/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    53/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    54/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    55/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    56/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    57/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    58/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    59/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    60/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    61/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    62/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    63/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    64/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    65/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    66/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    67/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    68/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    69/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    70/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    71/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    72/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    73/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    74/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    75/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    76/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    77/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    78/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    79/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    80/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    81/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    82/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    83/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    84/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    85/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    86/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    87/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    88/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    89/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    90/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    91/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    92/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    93/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    94/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    95/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    96/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    97/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    98/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    99/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    100/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    101/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    102/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    103/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    104/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    105/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    106/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    107/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    108/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    109/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    110/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    111/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    112/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    113/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    114/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    115/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    116/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    117/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    118/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    119/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    120/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    121/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    122/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    123/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    124/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    125/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    126/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    127/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    128/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    129/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    130/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    131/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    132/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    133/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    134/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    135/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    136/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    137/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    138/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    139/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    140/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    141/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    142/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    143/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    144/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    145/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    146/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    147/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    148/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    149/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    150/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    151/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    152/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    153/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    154/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    155/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    156/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    157/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    158/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    159/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    160/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    161/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    162/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    163/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    164/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    165/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    166/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    167/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    168/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    169/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    170/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    171/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    172/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    173/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    174/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    175/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    176/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    177/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    178/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    179/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    180/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    181/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    182/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    183/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    184/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    185/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    186/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    187/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    188/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    189/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    190/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    191/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    192/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    193/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    194/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    195/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    196/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    197/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    198/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    199/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    200/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    201/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    202/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    203/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    204/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    205/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    206/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    207/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    208/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    209/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    210/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    211/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    212/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    213/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    214/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    215/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    216/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    217/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    218/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    219/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    220/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    221/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    222/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    223/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    224/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    225/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    226/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    227/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    228/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    229/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    230/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    231/232

  • 8/14/2019 Banking Free

    232/232