ce39ecd4-587b-41d5-a4ad-9782c00a22fc

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/29/2019 ce39ecd4-587b-41d5-a4ad-9782c00a22fc

    1/8

    Consumer Perception of Mobile Telephony Tariffs

    with Cost Caps

    Jan KramerKarlsruhe Institute of Technology

    Karlsruhe, Germany

    Email: [email protected]

    Lukas WiewiorraKarlsruhe Institute of Technology

    Karlsruhe, Germany

    Email: [email protected]

    AbstractIn this article we provide a seminal academic investi-gation of mobile telephony consumers perception of the recentlyintroduced cost cap tariff in comparison to corresponding pay-per-use and flatrate calling plans. Previous studies have identifiedseveral psychological effects through which consumers are be-lieved to be biased towards flatrate plans. However, flatrate plansalso limit customers tariff flexibility in months of low usage.Cost cap tariffs are a hybrid between pay-per-use and flatrateplans and can offer cost insurance while maintaining flexibility.

    In particular, we provide evidence from a survey among 214German university students that flexibility, cost insurance andthe so-called taximeter effect are the main drivers behind costcap tariff choice. Furthermore, we show that the insurance andtaximeter effects are distinct if evaluated within a flatrate orcost cap tariff framework. Finally, based on our results we alsocomment on the profitability of cost cap plans from a strategicmanagement perspective.

    I. INTRODUCTION

    Competition in the mobile telephony market is fierce and

    the scope for product differentiation is limited - a combination

    that leads mobile telephony providers to engage in price

    differentiation instead. Indeed, the actual extend of price

    differentiation in the market is striking and customers are facedwith a multitude of different tariff types [1][3].

    Traditionally, mobile telephony providers have only offered

    two-part tariffs, which consist of fixed monthly fee and a

    usage-based component [4]. Two-part tariffs have a long

    tradition in telephony [5]. Their popularity stems from the fact

    a large portion of the providers costs are fixed costs related

    to the build up, maintenance and operation of the network

    infrastructure, which can be recovered by the fixed component

    of the two-part tariff [6]. On the contrary, the marginal

    costs of calling, which are constituted through switching or

    interconnection fees, for example, are relatively small and

    can be recovered by the variable component of the two-part

    tariff. In fact, if the telephony provider holds a monopoly,which has been the case for the fixed-line providers for most

    of the twentieth century, two-part tariffs can even achieve to

    extract customer rent completely, comparably to perfect price

    discrimination [7].

    However, in the mobile telephony market, which has been

    liberalized much earlier than the fixed telephony market,

    actual infrastructure-based competition has created a very

    competitive market environment. In an effort to differentiate

    their service offering, providers have experimented with new

    and innovative tariff structures to the extend that the mobile

    telephony market is flooded with a seemingly endless variety

    of voice telephony tariffs today. Besides the classical two-part

    tariff, the tariff portfolio ranges from three-part tariffs that

    include a usage allowance or minimum turnover requirements

    to one-part tariffs, i.e. pure pay-per-use or flatrates tariffs.

    In this paper we highlight the innovative cost cap tariff

    which has been introduced to the German mobile market in2009 by o2 (Telefonica).1 The cost cap tariff is a new type of

    two-part tariff that constitutes a hybrid between a pay-per-use

    and a flatrate tariff. It is a pure pay-per-use tariff until the

    total costs exceed a predefined cost cap, at which the tariff

    effectively becomes a flatrate. o2 claims that the cost cap tariff

    is a great success and has significantly contributed to attracting

    new customers [8].

    In this article we provide a seminal academic investigation

    of mobile telephony consumers perception of cost cap tariffs

    based on a survey among 214 German university students. In

    particular, it seems obvious that consumers will perceive the

    cost cap tariff as weakly dominant over both the pay-per-use

    tariff (because it offers a cost insurance in months of highusage) as well as the flatrate plan (because it offers flexibility

    in months of low usage) if the cost cap tariff offers the same

    per-minute prices as a pay-per-use tariff and if the cost cap is

    set at the price of a corresponding flatrate plan. On the other

    hand, it is questionable to which degree customers of pay-

    per-use plans would in fact accept a higher per-minute price

    under a cost cap tariff in order to be insured against high

    monthly invoices.2 Likewise, previous studies (e.g. [9][14])

    have provided strong empirical evidence that customers have a

    bias towards flatrate plans due to psychological reasons. In the

    following we will also investigate to what extend the cost cap

    tariff is also capable to benefit from these psychological effects

    compared to pure flatrate tariffs while additionally capturingthose customers that have a strong desire for flexible pay-per-

    use tariffs.

    The remainder of this article is structured as follows: In

    Section II we introduce the psychological effects that have

    1The tariff, which is called o2o, has officially been released on May 5,2009.

    2In the o2o cost cap tariff customers pay 15 Euro cents per minute, whilecomparable pay-per-use plans are currently available from as low as 7.5 centsper minute.

    978-1-4244-7986-3/10/$26.00 2010 IEEE

  • 7/29/2019 ce39ecd4-587b-41d5-a4ad-9782c00a22fc

    2/8

    been identified as cognitive causes of a flatrate bias and discuss

    them in the context of cost cap tariffs. Section III derives our

    research questions and IV presents the set up and content of

    the survey. In Section V, finally, we will present and discuss

    the results of our statistical analysis and conclude in Section

    VI by commenting on the results with respect to customers

    perception of cost cap tariffs.

    I I . REASONS FOR BIASED TARIFF CHOICE

    Economic theory assumes that consumers maximize their

    utility when selecting a mobile tariff, such that the chosen

    calling plan should (on average) lead to the lowest possi-

    ble telephone bill, given correct anticipation of the average

    usage. However, several studies (e.g. [12], [14][16]) have

    provided strong evidence that customers actual tariff choice

    may deviate from the economic prediction due to motivational,

    psychological or cognitive causes that lie outside of the stan-

    dard economic framework of fully rational market participants

    with perfect foresight. The most prominent example of suchsystematic deviations is the the so-called flatrate bias, which

    has been shown in context with all-you-can-eat buffets [17],

    gym subscriptions [9], Internet access plans [10][12] and

    mobile calling plans [13], [14]. The flatrate bias asserts that

    consumers often favor flatrate tariffs, although a pay-per-use

    tariff would be cheaper with regard to their actual usage

    volume. From psychological perspective, the main difference

    between a pay-per-use (or cost cap tariff for that matter) and a

    flatrate tariff is that telephone costs are sunk in a flatrate plan

    and consequently customers need not worry about the costs

    of current or future usage.3 More specifically, with respect

    to information and communication services, the literature has

    identified four distinctive effects that are supposed to drive theflatrate bias:

    a) Insurance: The insurance effect aims at customers

    that want to insure themselves against exceptionally (and

    unexpectedly) high telephony bills. Customers may be risk

    averse towards the correctness of their estimation of current

    service usage or with respect to future changes in demand.

    Therefore these customers are willing to pay (on average) more

    for a flatrate plan than what the costs of a corresponding pay-

    per-use tariff would be, because they are insured against these

    risks. In this vein the difference between the costs for a flatrate

    and the average costs for a pay-per-use tariff can be interpreted

    as an insurance premium. Indeed, [11] show that the optionvalue attached to flatrate plans is independent of the actual

    usage.

    b) Convenience: As outlined before, consumers face a

    tremendous variety of alternative tariffs in the mobile tele-

    phony markets. The convenience effect is driven by those

    consumers who want to avoid the effort of finding a cheaper

    3This corresponding psychological concept is known as mental account-ing and has been investigated in a number of different domains ( [18][20]).

    and perhaps more complex tariff.4 The costs associated with

    a flatrate, however, are easily accessible and independent of

    ones own (possibly unknown) calling volume.

    c) Overestimation: Consumers often fail to anticipate

    their own usage of telecommunication services correctly [16];

    either because of limited foresight and uncertainty in demand,

    or because of bounded rationality. In anticipating their current

    or future service usage, consumers have a tendency to overes-timate their actual demand, which, in turn, will induce them to

    select a flatrate plan more often. At the same time, users are

    often overly confident that their usage estimation is correct

    [16]. This makes the overestimation effect distinct from the

    insurance effect and leads consumers to repeatedly choose the

    wrong calling plan.

    d) Taximeter: The so-called taximeter effect is derived

    from the experience of using a taxi in a foreign city: The

    taxi ride can be perceived as unpleasant, because the run-

    ning taximeter constantly visualizes the currently accumulated

    costs. In the telecommunications domain, the analogous effect

    can for example be experienced while waiting in the queue ofa very costly hotline. Under a flatrate plan, on the contrary, all

    costs are sunk ex ante and the marginal costs of consumption

    are zero. This prevents consumers from experiencing the

    taximeter effect, who may thus favor flatrate plans.

    However, there is also a distinctive reason for customers not

    to choose a flatrate plan.

    e) Flexibility: By choosing a flatrate, consumers commit

    themselves to pay a fixed amount for telephone usage in each

    billing period, independent of their actual usage. This potential

    discrepancy between actual usage and committed costs can

    result in two adverse effects, which we have summarized

    under the roof of flexibility. First, subscribers may ex postregret their cost commitment under a flatrate plan after having

    realized that a usage-based tariff would have generated lower

    costs after all. Pay-per-use tariffs, on the contrary, avoid such

    commitments and react flexibly to (exceptionally low) usage.

    Secondly, the cost commitment may tempt flatrate subscribers

    to excess telephone usage. In other words, consumers may

    seek to avoid the ex post regret that they have not chosen a less

    expensive pay-per-use plan and therefore exploit the flatrate by

    telephoning more than reasonable. This effect is comparable

    to the so-called buffet effect by which customers of all-you-

    can-eat buffets eat more than they desire in an effort to justify

    the break even costs of an all you can eat buffet in comparison

    to the la carte menu [17]. Consequently, consumers with astrong aversion against ex post regret or the buffet effect are

    more likely to opt for a flexible pay-per-use tariff and seek to

    4Network providers sometimes even try to leverage the potential of conve-nient consumers and engage in so called foggy pricing. In its most extremeform, service providers deliberately offer dominated calling plans, because theadditional costs of doing so are very low and there is a positive probabilitythat convenient or uninformed consumers will actually choose this tariff. Fora critical analysis of foggy pricing see [3].

  • 7/29/2019 ce39ecd4-587b-41d5-a4ad-9782c00a22fc

    3/8

    avoid the cost commitment associated with a flatrate plan.5

    III. RESEARCH QUESTIONS

    The main research question we seek to investigate in this

    article is whether a cost cap tariff can also tap on one or some

    of these effects and if so, how strong the impact on customer

    choice will be. Due to its hybrid nature, we can presume

    that the cost cap tariff can capture some of the flatrate bias

    components, namely the insurance and overestimation effects,

    as well as the pay-per-use component, namely the flexibility

    effect. At this point, it remains open, however, how consumers

    will evaluate the cost cap tariff compared to a flatrate plan

    with respect to the convenience and taximeter effect. Table I

    summarizes the potential impact of the identified effects on

    the three fundamental tariff schemes.

    TABLE IPOTENTIAL EFFECTS ON THE CHOICE OF DIFFERENT TARIFF SCHEMES

    Pay-per-use Cost Cap Flatrate(PPU) (CC) (FR)

    Insurance - + +

    Convenience - ? +Overestimation - + +Taximeter - ? +Flexibility + + -

    In the seminal analysis, it is important to isolate the psycho-

    logical effects that are exhibited by a certain tariff scheme from

    the underlying economic effects. Therefore, in the following

    the cost cap plan is compared to a pay-per-use plan with the

    same per-minute price and with a flatrate plan that is priced at

    the level of the cost cap. In this way, the cost cap plan weakly

    dominates both the pay-per-use and the flatrate plan and hence

    tariff biases can be easily identified.6

    Furthermore, recall that the pay-per-use and the flatratecalling plan are both a one-part tariff, which put together,

    constitute the two-part cost cap tariff. These tariffs are not

    directly comparable to three-part tariffs (that consist of a fixed

    fee, an included allowance of minutes for which the marginal

    prize is zero, and a positive marginal price for additional

    minutes beyond the allowance), and will therefore not be

    considered here.7

    In the following section we present the design of a survey

    that is thought to quantify tariff bias effects and their impact on

    consumers choice of pay-per-use, cost cap or flatrate calling

    plans. In addition, in contrast to previous studies on the flatrate

    bias, our analysis of the cost cap pricing scheme also offers

    5It shall be annotated that in different domains, where excessive usageis a desired outcome to the consumer, the lack of flexibility may evenconstitute a flatrate bias. With a flatrate plan, customers can strategicallycommit themselves to more service usage for the same reasons as above. Forexample, people often subscribe to a long term flatrate contract for health clubsin order to commit themselves to use the gym more often. In the literature thisreverse interpretation of the flexibility effect is called self-discipline effect(cp. e.g. [9]).

    6See Section VI for ideas on possible alternative choice scenarios thatshould be subject to future research.

    7Three-part tariffs are for example very popular in the US cellular phoneservices market.

    a new way to test the taximeter effect independent of the

    insurance effect.

    IV. SURVEY DESIGN

    The survey is structured in four distinctive parts.

    In the first part, participants are asked to decide betweenalternative tariffs in two series of hypothetical usage scenarios.

    More precisely, participants are presented with several ficti-

    tious usage scenarios in which they have to indicate which of

    two alternative calling plans they would choose. This method-

    ological approach is sometimes called quasi-experimental [12].

    The first part of the survey is subdivided into two series of

    choice scenarios.

    In the first series of four usage scenarios participants had to

    decide between a flatrate plan and a pure pay-per-use tariff.

    Usage scenarios differed only by the induced minimum and

    maximum usage (in minutes), whereas the average usage was

    identical in all scenarios.8 Hence, the setup measures if differ-

    ent perceived extrema of usage impact tariff choice.9

    Moreover,it is emphasized that we have chosen realistic choice scenarios,

    which are in line with average usage volumes of mobile

    telephony and actual market prices in Germany at the time

    of the survey.

    For the first series of usage scenarios, respondents are ran-

    domly assigned to one of two settings. In the first setting,

    the usage scenarios are such that the costs of the flatrate plan

    are identical to the average monthly costs under the pay-per-

    use plan (45e). Thus, we would expect to observe an equal

    distribution of participants between the two alternative calling

    plans. In the second setting, the flatrate is priced slightly higher

    49e). With this modified version of the question it can be

    verified if a potential bias towards a flatrate is also presentunder a pricing scheme with higher than average monthly

    costs.

    In a second series of four similar usage scenarios, all respon-

    dents were asked to choose between a cost cap tariff and a

    flatrate tariff. The usage scenarios were designed such that it

    is possible to check for a flatrate bias over a cost cap plan.

    In the second part of the survey participants are presented

    with several verbal phrases, who are then asked to indicate

    their consent on a five point Likert scale. These phrases are so

    called indicators which are later aggregated to constructs

    that measure the effects in table I. Most of the indicators

    8Analogous to the survey design of [12], [21] minimum and maximumusage is varied in all possible combinations of 33.3% and 100% deviationof the average costs per month. The corresponding min/max usage levels are0/400, 200/400, 0/600 and 200/600 minutes.

    9The hypothetical questions were presented in the following manner: Pleaseimagine independently from your real usage behavior that you are using yourmobile phone on average 300 minutes per month to call into German networksand you have to pay the bill yourself. Your amount of usage fluctuates betweenthe months. Below you are presented with different values of minimum andmaximum usage per month. Average usage is always 300 minutes per month.Please indicate in all four cases your choice between tariff 1 where you pay15 Euro cents per minute and tariff 2 where you pay 45 Euros flat.

  • 7/29/2019 ce39ecd4-587b-41d5-a4ad-9782c00a22fc

    4/8

    have been adapted from [21] and [15].10 However, we derived

    our own indicators with respect to those constructs that were

    thought to measure the taximeter and insurance effect under

    a cost cap plan as well as the flexibility effect. Additionally,

    in this part of the survey respondents were asked for their

    appraisal of their own usage behavior and costs. To exclude

    unwanted effects stemming from the order of the items we

    presented them in random order to all participants.

    In the third part of the survey, data on the respondents

    actual mobile telephony tariff characteristics (such as con-

    tract duration, tariff model, average monthly bill is collected.

    Participants were notified that from this point on, they were

    asked about their real actual mobile phone usage. In the last

    and fourth part of the survey, participants were confronted

    with a standard risk aversion test based on [22] in which

    respondents must choose between a safe and a risky lottery in

    ten settings. Participants were incentivized to answer truthfully

    in the risk aversion test by offering the chance for a gift

    coupon of up to 38.5e value. The determination of the actual

    value of the coupon is perfectly aligned with the decisions

    in the risk aversion test and thus, the test was implementedas a non-hypothetical setting. More precisely, to determine

    the coupon value, one of the ten settings was chosen in

    which the respondents participated in the respective lottery

    of his choice. Lottery outcomes were also orientated on the

    average mobile phone bill of participants. Since our sample is

    very homogeneous we can on average neglect income effects

    influencing the results.

    The survey was conducted in February 2010 through a

    web-based questionnaire among undergraduate students at the

    Karlsruhe Institute of Technology in Germany. Students were

    invited to the questionnaire via the mailing list of an introduc-

    tory economics course. We stimulated participation by offering

    a chance to take part in a lottery of four 25 e gift couponsfor a large online retail store after completing the survey.

    96.7% of the participants decided to participate in the lottery.

    Additionally one gift coupon was awarded in the risk aversion

    test. Certainly, we do not claim that students of economics

    are a representative panel for the German or European mobile

    telephony subscriber. However, we can presume that students

    are more rational and more aware of their mobile tariff

    and the associated costs than the average subscriber. Thus,

    if we find empirical evidence for systematic selection biases

    in our panel, it is likely that the actual effects are in fact

    even stronger. We will discuss this issue in more detail in the

    following sections.

    V. RESULTS

    A total of 214 respondents (23.5% female, 76.5% male)

    with an average age of 20.5 years (S=1.47; min=16; max=27;

    10In particular, [21] adapted and validated well known scales from market-ing science to measure these effects (latent variables in a statistical model)influencing the decision in favor for a flatrate tariff. Even though the originalscale was constructed to test for the effects in connection with Internet accessprices we modified the wording only if necessary.

    median=20) completed our survey successfully.11 All of the

    respondents are mobile telephony customers. The mean of

    the reported average monthly telephone bill in our sample is

    19.14e (S=17.53), with a noticeable discrepancy between the

    mean average monthly bill of the 46.73% with prepaid tariffs

    (M=10.15e; S=9.37) compared to those with postpaid tariffs

    (M=27.03e; S=19.19). Thus, our sample contains about an

    equal split of users with low and comparably high mobile

    telephone usage.

    At first, we investigate the degree to which the participants

    in our sample are biased towards choosing a flatrate plan

    over a pay-per-use plan. Table II summarizes the results.

    Participants were randomly assigned to one of two settings

    with different flatrate prices, in which they were asked to state

    their preference for the flatrate or a pay-per-use plan in four

    usage scenarios. In the first setting, which was assigned to

    52.3% of the participants, the flatrate was priced at 45 e the

    costs for the alternative pay-per-use plan under average usage.

    The remaining 47.7% of the respondents evaluated the second

    setting, in which the usage scenarios are identical, but the

    flatrate is priced slightly above the average costs for the pay-per-use plan.12

    TABLE IICHOICE OF FLATRATE OVER PAY-PE R-USE PLAN

    Usage (minutes) Flatrate choice atMin Avg. Max 45e 49e

    0 300 400 18.63% 4.46%200 300 400 46.08% 25.00%

    0 300 600 41.96% 37.50%200 300 600 83.33% 66.96%

    compared to a pay-per-use plan at 15 cents/minute

    In both settings, except for the scenario with high minimum

    and maximum usage, respondents favored a pay-per-use planover the flatrate. Previous studies have argued that in each

    scenario in which the flatrate is priced at average costs

    unbiased participants would be indifferent between choosing

    the flatrate and the pay-per-use tariff [12], [14]. Therefore,

    one would expected the flatrate to be chosen in 50% of the

    cases. In a qualitatively identical setting, [12] and [14] find that

    respondents chose the flatrate in three out of four scenarios at

    average cost pricing and in two out of four scenarios at slightly

    above average cost pricing. However, in our panel we find to

    the contrary, that participants prefer the pay-per-use tariff in

    three out of four scenarios in both settings. Thus, if there is a

    bias in our sample, it would rather run in favor of a pay-per-

    use tariff.

    11A total of 346 Students followed the link and 247 of them completedthe survey. In a final validity question 7 participants indicated to haveanswered incorrectly in the survey and were eliminated from the final dataset.Moreover, in order to increase the internal validity of the responses, another17 observations were omitted from the analysis due to obviously random andirrational choices in the risk aversion test. Since there are no categorical wronganswers in the remaining parts of the survey, we generalized the validity of theanswers in the risk aversion test to the other survey questions. However, ourreported results do not significantly vary if these observations are included.

    12We decided to present a price of 49 e to them.

  • 7/29/2019 ce39ecd4-587b-41d5-a4ad-9782c00a22fc

    5/8

    We offer two alternative explanations for this finding. First,

    as argued above, the respondents in our sample are students

    of economics and therefore (i) aware of rational choices and

    expected utility theory and (ii) sensitive to costs in general.

    Moreover, the participants in our survey are also very aware

    of the costs of using their mobile phone. In the items that

    capture cost control (cp. Table III) respondents agree to

    a high degree (M=4.21; S=0.72) on a 5-point Likert scale.

    Second, although the relation between the usage scenarios

    is identical to those in [12] and [14] we use actual market

    prices.13 In [14], for example, which also considers mobile

    telephony tariffs and builds on survey data from July 2006,

    the flatrate is priced unrealistically low at 30e and 33e while

    the pay-per-use tariff costs 30 cents per minute.

    TABLE IIISELF REPORTED COST AWARENESS

    Cost Control(Cronbachss = 0.71, M=4.21, S=0.72)

    I can accurately assess my own mobile telephony usagebehavior

    (M=4.12; S=0.88; median=4)I know my calling plan and all costs involved very well.(M=4.43; S=0.90; median=5)I can accurately assess my own mobile telephony costs(M=4.07; S=0.92; median=4)

    Next, we consider the respondents flatrate choice in com-

    parison to cost cap tariffs in different usage scenarios (Table

    IV). In this setting, the cost cap tariff offers a cap at the amount

    of the flatrate price. Therefore, the cost cap tariff weakly

    dominates the flatrate tariff for those usage scenarios where

    the minimum usage may be below 300 minutes, i.e. the point

    at where the cost cap becomes binding. Thus, in the absence

    of tariff biases, one would expect that the flatrate plan is not

    chosen in the first two scenarios. In the remaining two usagescenarios, the flatrate and the cost cap are factually identical

    because the cost cap is reached even under minimum usage.

    Thus, there is no advantage in selecting the cost cap tariff

    anymore. To the contrary, if respondents are averse towards

    the taximeter effect, they may even prefer the flatrate under

    these conditions. Thus, ex ante one could presume that the

    flatrate is chosen in at least 50% of the cases in the latter two

    scenarios.

    TABLE IVCHOICE OF FLATRATE OVER COST CAP PLAN

    Usage (minutes) Flatrate choice at

    Min Avg. Max 45e200 400 600 10.28%250 400 550 11.21%300 400 500 16.82%350 400 450 17.29%

    compared to a cost cap plan at 15 cents/minute and 45 e cost cap

    The actual choices of respondents differ substantially from

    the ex ante presumptions and are strongly in favor of the cost

    13At the time of the survey the o2o tariff offers per-minute prices of 15cents and a cost cap at 40e.

    cap tariff. Even in those scenarios in which the cost cap tariff

    has no advantage, more than 80% of the participants would

    still opt for this tariff. This result reveals the great attrac-

    tiveness cost cap tariffs seem to have on mobile telephony

    customers, even in those settings where the cost cap tariff is

    factually identical to the flatrate plan.

    TABLE V

    CONSTRUCTS CAPTURING FLATRATE EFFECTS

    Taximeter (FR)(Cronbachss = 0.81, M=3.67, S=1.00)

    A flatrate is good because I dont have to think about the costs.(M=3.73; S=1.29; median=4)I enjoy using the phone less if costs increase every minute ofuse(M=3.79; S=1.24; median=4)Only if I have a flatrate I enjoy using the mobile phone(M=3.00; S=1.39; median=3)If I have a flatrate I use my mobile phone in a more relaxedand unselfconscious manner.(M=4.16; S=1.11; median=5)

    Insurance (FR)(Cronbachss = 0.76, M=2.63, S=1.05)

    To be sure my costs of mobile telecommunication will neverbe higher than a certain predefined amount Im willing to paya little bit more than average(M=2.52; S=1.13; median=2)Even if a flat rate is somewhat more expensive than a pay-per-use rate Im happy because my costs wont exceed the fixedamount.(M=2.75; S=1.21; median=3)

    Flexibility (FR)(Cronbachss = 0.63, M=3.66, S=0.76)

    It bugs me when the flatrate wasnt profitable in a billingperiod.(M=3.66; S=1.11; median=4)It feels like a deficit when another tariff would have beencheaper than the flatrate in a billing period.(M=3.58; S=1.11; median=4)It matters to me to max out the flatrate.

    (M=3.49; S=1.19; median=4)It feels like a gain when the flatrate was cheaper than the nextbest tariff in a billing period.(M=3.92; S=1.00; median=4)

    Convenience(Cronbachss = 0.79, M=2.11, S=0.84)

    Figuring out which rate is better takes so long that it isntworth the effort.(M=2.01; S=1.04; median=2)It is too much trouble to find out the prices for mobiletelecommunications(M=2.08; S=1.20; media=2)The money you can save by finding a better calling planthan your current one doesnt make up for the time and effortinvolved(M=2.22; S=1.02; mean=2)The time it takes to switch to a cheaper calling plan isnt worth

    the effort.(M=2.11; S=1.01; median=2)

    Further insight on the reasons by which mobile customers

    perceive the relative attractiveness of pay-per-use, flatrate

    or cost cap tariffs can be gained by evaluating the con-

    structs which capture the taximeter, insurance, flexibility and

    convenience effects. Furthermore, recall that cost cap tariff

    framework allows us to present customers with constructs that

    can capture their perception of the taximeter and insurance

  • 7/29/2019 ce39ecd4-587b-41d5-a4ad-9782c00a22fc

    6/8

    effect independently. In contrast to a flatrate framework, the

    cost cap tariff allows for cost insurance, while maintaining

    the taximeter property as long as the cost cap is not reached.

    Therefore, we present our results separately for those con-

    structs that are evaluated within the flatrate framework (Table

    V) and those that are evaluated within the cost cap framework

    (Table VI).14

    TABLE VICONSTRUCTS CAPTURING COST CAP EFFECTS

    Taximeter (CC)(Cronbachss = 0.60, M=3.11, S=1.06)

    Under a cost cap tariff I enjoy the minutes before the cost capbecomes binding less.(M=2.88, S=1.29, median=3)Until the cost cap becomes binding I pay more attention to myusage behavior.(M=3.33; S=1.22; median=4)

    Insurance (CC)(Cronbachss = 0.72, M=3.47, S=0.97)

    With a cost cap I can use the mobile phone more jauntily.(M=3.54; S=1.06; median=4)I think less about my usage behavior in a tariff with cost cap,

    because my bill can never exceed a fixed amount.(M=3.39; S=1.13; median=4)

    Notice that the internal consistency of the constructs, as

    evaluated by Cronbachs scale reliability coefficient , is high

    throughout (M=0.72; S=0.086). This is particularly noticeable

    for the flexibility and cost cap constructs, which have been

    used in this study for the first time.15

    Finally, we estimate the influence of the above constructs on

    tariff choice in a nonlinear logit model. In the regression we

    also include the available variables on the usage scenario (min

    usage, max usage, flatrate price), the individual telephony be-

    havior (prepaid, bill, cost control), socio-demographics (male,age) and the individual risk attitude as explanatory variables

    in the regression model.16

    Table VII shows the results of the logit regressions. In the

    first model, which estimates the impact of the explanatory

    variables on the probability to choose a flatrate plan over a

    pay-per-use plan, only two of the four significant variables

    have a non-negligible effect. More precisely, the choice of a

    flatrate plan over a pay-per-use plan is mainly driven by the

    insurance effect and the price of the flatrate. An increase of the

    insurance effect by one unit will c.p increase the probability

    of flatrate choice by 38.7%, whereas an increase of the price

    by 1e will decrease the probability of choosing the flatrate

    by 23.7%.The second model estimates the participants choice of the

    flatrate over the cost cap plan with the flatrate-equivalent cost

    14The convenience construct is in fact independent of the particular tariffframework, but listed under the flatrate effects for conciseness and compara-bility to previous studies.

    15We followed the factor analysis methodology in order to eliminate andgroup the questions items according to the scale reliability coefficient.

    16Pairwise correlations (Pearson) of all explanatory variables used in thelogit regressions were all below the threshold of 50%.

    TABLE VIILOGIT REGRESSIONS ON FLATRATE CHOICE

    Flatrate (1) vs. Flatrate (1) vs.Pay-per-use (0) Cost Cap (0)

    Taximeter (FR) 0.109 -0.366

    (0.105) (0.129)Insurance (FR) 0.327 0.310

    (0.0983) (0.122)Flexibility (FR) -0.130 -0.210

    (0.120) (0.147)Taximeter (CC) -0.0243 0.268

    (0.0863) (0.109)Insurance (CC) -0.0747 -0.234

    (0.0941) (0.119)Convenience -0.0519 -0.0461

    (0.105) (0.136)Risk Aversion 0.0595 -0.212

    (0.0480) (0.0587)Male 0.0909 -0.254

    (0.199) (0.246)Age 0.0780 -0.0347

    (0.0576) (0.0733)Prepaid -0.190 -0.167

    (0.195) (0.247)Bill -0.00753 0.00451

    (0.00585) (0.00620)

    Cost Control -0.116 -0.0812(0.119) (0.146)Max Usage 0.00951 -0.00444

    (0.000868) (0.00185)Min Usage 0.00735

    (0.000855)Flatrate Price -0.213

    (0.0422)Constant 2.382 4.337

    (2.482) (2.130)

    Observations 852 852Log likelihood -449.97 -320.28

    Pseudo R2 22.15 % 6.04 %Correctly Classified 72.30 % 86.38%

    Standard errors in parentheses p < 0.05, p < 0.01, p < 0.001

    cap.17 In general, the explanatory power of this model, as

    evaluated by Log likelihood and Pseudo R2, is lower compared

    to the first model, because the flatrate is seldomly chosen in

    our sample. Whether the respondents prefer the flatrate or the

    cost cap plan depends foremost on the taximeter and insurance

    effects as well as on the degree of risk aversion.

    An increase of a participants evaluation of the taximeter

    effect under a cost cap plan by one unit makes him 30.6% more

    likely to choose the flatrate. Interestingly, with respect to the

    flatrate taximeter effect, the impact is opposite: Respondents

    who enjoy mobile telephony more under a flatrate plan (as

    opposed to a pay-per-use plan) are in fact more likely to chosea cost cap plan over the flatrate, if given the option. Moreover,

    this effect is strong, since an increase in the flatrate taximeter

    effect by one unit increases the probability of chosing a cost

    cap plan by 44.1%. This analysis also reveals that the context

    is important for the evaluation of the taximeter effect. We

    will return to this point during the discussion of the results in

    Section VI.

    17The variables min usage and flatrate price were omitted from theregression due to collinearity or invariance, respectively.

  • 7/29/2019 ce39ecd4-587b-41d5-a4ad-9782c00a22fc

    7/8

    Likewise, also the two insurance effects have opposite

    impact on the respondents choice of the flatrate plan. First,

    recall that the cost cap is set at the price of the flatrate in all

    choice scenarios. Therefore, respondents are equally insured

    against high usage under both plans. Nevertheless, participants

    are 36% more likely to chose a flatrate over a cost cap tariff if

    their assessment of the insurance effect of flatrates (compared

    to pay-per-use plans) increases by one unit. In reverse, if asked

    for the insurance effect with explicit reference to the cost cap

    tariff, a unit increase will result in an increased probability of

    26.3% towards choosing the cost cap plan over the flatrate.

    Again, this highlights that consumers perceive the taximeter

    and insurance effect differently in the context of a flatrate or

    a cost cap plan.

    Interestingly, also the risk preference has a strong effect

    on the choice of the two equally capped tariffs. An increase

    of respondents risk aversion by one unit18 increases the

    chances to choose the cost cap plan by 23.7%. This result is

    comprehensible, since the cost cap plan does not only insure

    against high usage volumes, but also against low usage.

    VI . DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

    In this article we have investigated mobile telephony cus-

    tomers perception of the recently introduced cost cap tariff

    in comparison to corresponding pay-per-use and flatrate plans.

    Previous studies have identified several psychological effects

    which are believed to bias consumers choice towards flatrate

    plans. However, flatrate plans also limit customers tariff

    flexibility in months of low usage. Cost cap tariffs are a

    hybrid between pay-per-use and flatrate plans and can offer

    cost insurance while maintaining flexibility. Our investigation

    of cost cap plans reveals three main insights.

    First, customers favor cost caps tariffs over flatrates that

    are priced at the cost cap level, even in those usage scenarioswhere the cost cap is reached with certainty. Obviously cost

    cap tariffs seem to draw consumers attention, especially

    when flexibility is important to them. In fact, in our sample

    respondents show a strong desire for flexibility. In contrast to

    previous quasi-experimental studies on tariff-choice, our study

    cannot confirm a flatrate bias. To the contrary, our results

    are in favor of a pay-per-use bias and in line with [1] and

    [23], who have derived their results empirically from the 1986

    Louisville, Kentucky local telephone tariff dataset. One could

    argue, that the pronounced desire for flexibilty in our sample

    is due to the fact that we have distributed the survey among

    students of economics, who are aware of costs in general but

    also primed to make rational choices. The sample is obviouslynot representative of the German population and also rather

    conservative in terms of biased choice. However, the same

    arguments hold true for the studies that have found a flatrate

    bias in a similar group [14], [21]. Furthermore, in contrast

    to [14], we have confronted respondents with realistic choice

    scenarios in terms of usage and prices. Nevertheless it cannot

    18Risk aversion is measured by the number of safe choices from the tennon-hypothetical choice scenarios of the risk aversion test. Thus, the riskaversion measure can take any integer value from 1 to 10.

    be excluded that our findings are extenuated with a larger

    representative set of participants. Furthermore, it is annotated

    that it is not surprising that flexibility is not a significant factor

    in our regression analysis: Because all respondents have in our

    sample have confirmed a high desire for flexibility (M=3.66/5)

    with small standard deviation (S=0.76), this construct is not a

    good discriminator in the regression.

    Secondly, we can confirm that the choice of cost caps

    tariffs is in fact also driven by the taximeter and insurance

    effects. The convenience effect, on the contrary, turns out to

    be insignificant in our dataset. However, this may again be due

    to a sample bias, since students do not tend to place emphasis

    on convenience (M=2.11/5) and are rather homogeneous in

    this perception (S=0.84).

    Our third insight is more subtle and concerns the way

    in which the taximeter and insurance effects influence tariff

    choice. In particular, we find an opposite impact of these

    effects if evaluated with respect to a flatrate or a cost cap tariff:

    When given the opportunity to choose between a flatrate and

    a comparable cost cap plan, those consumers tend to favor the

    cost cap who prefer a flatrate (in lieu of a pay-per-use plan)due to the taximeter effect. On the contrary, there also seems

    to be a distinct taximeter effect under a cost cap plan that

    induces customers to divert away from the cost cap tariff and

    towards the flatrate plan. Similarly, although participants are

    equally insured under the available flatrate and cost cap plan,

    those customers that have revealed the insurance effect as a

    driver for choosing the flatrate plan are indeed less likely to

    choose a cost cap plan instead. However, if those customers

    that feel insured under a cost cap tariff will also choose this

    tariff variant more likely.

    In summary, we find that cost cap tariffs have combined

    desirable properties of pay-per-use and flatrate plans and that

    customers are well aware of this. Our insights on cost captariffs have direct ramifications for the strategic management

    of mobile telephony providers that seek to offer this tariff. If

    people are, as other studies suggest (e.g. [9], [10], [15], [19],

    [24], [25]), presumably willing to pay a higher than average

    monthly fee for a flatrate, it is likely that this holds also true

    under a cost cap tariff. Thereby, cost cap tariffs are particularly

    interesting for those customers that have a strong desire to

    be insured against high telephony bills, but wish to maintain

    tariff flexibility. Thus, on the one hand, the cost cap tariff is

    attractive to those customers that are currently under a flatrate

    plan if their perception of the cost-cap-related taximeter effect

    is not too strong. Especially risk averse flatrate customers may

    even be willing to opt for a cost cap plan although the cost capis higher than the corresponding flatrate price, because then

    they are insured in months of low usage. On the other hand,

    those users that have currently a pay-per-use plan, because

    they have a strong desire for a flexible tariff or because they

    have a comparably low usage volume, could also be lurked

    into a cost cap tariff even if this means to accept higher per-

    minute prices. In other words, these customers are willing to

    pay an indirect risk premium via the per-minute price in order

    to be insured against high telephone bills. If the cost cap does

  • 7/29/2019 ce39ecd4-587b-41d5-a4ad-9782c00a22fc

    8/8

    not become binding, the mobile operator can especially profit

    from these customers.

    In fact, this latter reasoning seems to have been the main

    driver for o2 to introduce a cost cap tariff whose cost cap

    is set at the level of the cheapest available all-net flatrate

    in the market. On the contrary, the per-minute price under

    this cost cap tariff is twice as high as the cheapest standard

    pay-per-use rate in the market. However, from a strategic

    management perspective, it is also very risky to offer a cost

    cap tariff. In contrast to a flatrate, under a cost cap plan

    consumers with a comparably low usage cannot compensate

    for the costs of heavy users. But, the company may also

    speculate on the existence of a more subtle effect: Because

    customers are insured against high costs and because the cost

    cap tariff may effectively mitigate the taximeter effect with

    respect to a pay-per-use plan, a customer may in fact phone

    more than under a pay-per-use plan, but total costs yet remain

    below the cost cap. The marketing of o2 focuses on this

    aspect of the consumption behavior. Users should feel save

    with the so-called cost airbag and therefore do not have to

    think about their consumption behavior anymore. Therefore,the target group for this tariff scheme does not seem to be the

    typical heavy or actual flatrate user, but the average user who

    does not want to commit himself to high monthly costs.

    We have merely presented a first step into the investigation

    of cost cap tariffs, which have, to the best of our knowledge,

    previously not been assessed academically. While our study

    has focused more on the choice between cost cap and flatrate

    plans, future work should especially consider the choice be-

    tween cost cap and pay-per-use tariffs in more detail. Recall

    that a cost cap tariff dominates the pay-per-use and the flatrate

    plan at equal per-minute prices and at a cost cap level equal to

    the flatrate price. Thus, future research should systematically

    investigate the cost cap tariff bias in those scenarios where(i) the per-minute price is higher in the cost cap tariff than

    in an equivalent pay-per-use plan and (ii) the cost cap is

    higher than the corresponding flatrate price. Furthermore, it

    seems interesting to further investigate the reasons why the

    insurance and taximeter effects are perceived differently under

    a cost cap and flatrate tariff framework. Within the flatrate

    framework, the insurance and taximeter effect are always

    coincidental, whereas the effects can be separated under a cost

    cap framework. The question remains if consumers experience

    the taximeter effect even if they are insured and how this

    affects their perception during telephony consumption as well

    as their potential tariff switching behavior.

    REFERENCES

    [1] E. J. Miravete, Choosing the Wrong Calling Plan? Ignorance andLearning, American Economic Review, vol. 93, pp. 297310, 2003.

    [2] , Are All Those Calling Plans Really Necessary? The LimitedGains From Complex Tariffs, 2007, cEPR Discussion Paper No. 4237.

    [3] , The Doubtful Profitability of Foggy Pricing, 2009, cEPR Dis-cussion Paper No. DP6295.

    [4] J. Hodge, Tariff structures and access substitution of mobile cellular forfixed line in South Africa, Telecommunications Policy, vol. 29, no. 7,pp. 493505, 2005.

    [5] S. Littlechild, Two-part tariffs and consumption externalities, The BellJournal of Economics, vol. 6, no. 2, pp. 661670, 1975.

    [6] T. Valletti, The theory of access pricing and its linkage with investmentincentives, Telecommunications Policy, vol. 27, no. 10-11, pp. 659675,2003.

    [7] W. Oi, A Disneyland dilemma: Two-part tariffs for a Mickey Mousemonopoly, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 85, no. 1, pp.7796, 1971.

    [8] V. Briegleb. (2009, 11) O2 mit mehr kunden und gewinn. Heise News-meldung. [Online]. Available: http://www.heise.de/mobil/meldung/O2-mit-mehr-Kunden-und-Gewinn-857876.html

    [9] S. Della Vigna and U. Malmendier, Paying not to go to the gym,

    American Economic Review, vol. 96, no. 3, pp. 694719, 2006.[10] K. E. Train, M. Ben-akiva, and T. Atherton, Consumption Patterns and

    Self-Selecting Tariffs, Review of Economic and Statistics, vol. 1, pp.6273, 1989.

    [11] D. J. Kridel, D. E. Lehman, and D. L. Weisman, Option Value,Telecommunication Demand, and Policy, Information Economics andPolicy, vol. 5, pp. 12544, 1993.

    [12] A. Lambrecht and B. Skiera, Paying too much and being happy aboutit: Existence, causes and consequences of tariff-choice biases, Journalof Marketing Research, no. May, 2006.

    [13] H. Mitomo, T. Otsuka, and K. Nakaba, A Behavioral EconomicInterpretation of the Preference for Flat Rates: A Case of Post-PaidMobile Phone Services, in 18th European Regional ITS Conference,

    International Telecommunications Society, Istanbul. Springer, 2007.[14] T. J. Gerpott, Biased choice of a mobile telephony tari type: Exploring

    usage boundary perceptions as a cognitive cause in choosing betweena use-based or a at rate plan, Telematics and Informatics, vol. 26, pp.

    167179, 2009.[15] J. Nunes, A Cognitive Model of Peoples Usage Estimations, Journal

    of Marketing Research, vol. 37, pp. 397409, 2000.[16] M. D. Grubb, Selling to overconfident consumers, American Economic

    Review, vol. 99, no. 5, pp. 17701807, December 2009.[17] D. Just and B. Wansink, The Fixed Price Paradox: Conflicting Effects

    of All-You-Can-Eat Pricing.[18] R. H. Thaler, Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice, Marketing

    Science, vol. 4, no. 3, pp. 199214, 1985.[19] D. Prelec and G. Loewenstein, The Red and the Black: Mental

    Accouting of Savings and Debt, Marketing Science, vol. 17, no. 1,pp. 428, 1998.

    [20] R. H. Thaler, Mental accounting matters, Journal of BehavioralDecision Making, vol. 12, no. 3, pp. 183206, September 1999.

    [21] A. Lambrecht and B. Skiera, Ursachen eines flatrate-bias, systema-tisierung und messung der einflussfaktoren, Schmalenbachs Zeitschrift

    fr betriebswirtschaftliche Forschung, vol. 58, pp. 588617, 2006.

    [22] C. Holt and S. Laury, Risk aversion and incentive effects, TheAmerican Economic Review, vol. 92, no. 5, pp. 16441655, 2002.

    [23] S. Narayanan, P. Chintagunta, and E. Miravete, The role of self selec-tion, usage uncertainty and learning in the demand for local telephoneservice, Quantitative Marketing and Economics, vol. 5, no. 1, pp. 134,2007.

    [24] K. E. Train, D. L. Mcfadden, and M. Ben-akiva, The Demand forLocal Telephone Service: A Fully Discrete Model of Residential CallingPatterns and Service Choices, Rand Journal of Economics, vol. 18,no. 1, pp. 10923, 1987.

    [25] B. M. Mitchell and I. Vogelsang, Telecommunication Pricing: Theoryand Practice. Cambridge University Press, 1991.