46
Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont)

Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Chapter 3

Decision Analysis(cont)

Page 2: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Decision Trees Any problem that can be presented in a decision

table can also be graphically represented in a decision treedecision tree

Decision trees are most beneficial when a sequence of decisions must be made

All decision trees contain decision pointsdecision points or nodesnodes and state-of-nature pointsstate-of-nature points or nodesnodes

Page 3: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Structure of Decision Trees

Trees start from left to right Represent decisions and outcomes in

sequential order Squares represent decision nodes Circles represent states of nature nodes Lines or branches connect the decisions

nodes and the states of nature

Page 4: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Five Steps toDecision Tree Analysis

1. Define the problem2. Structure or draw the decision tree3. Assign probabilities to the states of

nature4. Estimate payoffs for each possible

combination of alternatives and states of nature

5. Solve the problem by computing expected monetary values (EMVs) for each state of nature node

Page 5: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Thompson Lumber Company

STATE OF NATURE

ALTERNATIVEFAVORABLE MARKET ($)

UNFAVORABLE MARKET ($)

Construct a large plant 200,000 –180,000

Construct a small plant 100,000 –20,000

Do nothing 0 0

Table 3.1

Page 6: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Thompson’s Decision Tree

Favorable Market

Unfavorable Market

Favorable Market

Unfavorable Market

Do Nothing

Construct

Large P

lant

1

Construct

Small Plant2

Figure 3.2

A Decision Node

A State-of-Nature Node

Page 7: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Identifying the best decision in the tree

Work from right to left

Calculate the expected payoff at each outcome node

Choose the best alternative at each decision node (based on expected payoff)

Page 8: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Thompson’s Decision Tree

Favorable Market

Unfavorable Market

Favorable Market

Unfavorable Market

Do Nothing

Construct

Large P

lant

1

Construct

Small Plant2

Alternative with best EMV is selected

Figure 3.3

EMV for Node 1 = $10,000

= (0.5)($200,000) + (0.5)(–$180,000)

EMV for Node 2 = $40,000

= (0.5)($100,000) + (0.5)(–$20,000)

Payoffs

$200,000

–$180,000

$100,000

–$20,000

$0

(0.5)

(0.5)

(0.5)

(0.5)

Page 9: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Thompson’s Complex Decision Tree

Thompson Lumber Co. consider the decision to make a survey about the market before making the decision to build the new plant.With their experience, they know that the result of this survey can be positive with 45% or negative with 55%.

The cost of this survey is $10,000

First Decision Point

Conduct Market Survey

Do Not Conduct Survey

1 Results

Favorable

ResultsNegative

Survey (0.45)

Survey (0.55)

Second Decision Point

Page 10: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Thompson’s Complex Decision Tree

If the survey leads to positive result (45%), the conditional probability for occurrence of each state of nature is:

Favorable market: 78%

Unfavorable market: 22%

If the survey leads to negative result (55%), the conditional probability for occurrence of each state of nature is:

Favorable market: 27%

Unfavorable market: 73%

If Thompson Lumber Co. decides not to conduct the survey, the probability for each state of nature is same, 50% for favorable market and 50% for unfavorable market

Page 11: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Thompson’s Complex Decision Tree

First Decision Point

Second Decision Point

Favorable Market (0.78)

Unfavorable Market (0.22)

Favorable Market (0.78)

Unfavorable Market (0.22)

Favorable Market (0.27)

Unfavorable Market (0.73)

Favorable Market (0.27)

Unfavorable Market (0.73)

Favorable Market (0.50)

Unfavorable Market (0.50)

Favorable Market (0.50)

Unfavorable Market (0.50)Large Plant

Small Plant

No Plant

6

7

Condu

ct M

arke

t Sur

vey

Do Not Conduct Survey

Large Plant

Small Plant

No Plant

2

3

Large Plant

Small Plant

No Plant

4

5

1Results

Favorable

ResultsNegative

Survey (0

.45)

Survey (0.55)

Payoffs

–$190,000

$190,000

$90,000

–$30,000

–$10,000

–$180,000

$200,000

$100,000

–$20,000

$0

–$190,000

$190,000

$90,000

–$30,000

–$10,000

Figure 3.4

Page 12: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Thompson’s Complex Decision Tree

1.1. Given favorable survey results,EMV(node 2) = EMV(large plant | positive survey)

= (0.78)($190,000) + (0.22)(–$190,000) = $106,400EMV(node 3) = EMV(small plant | positive survey)

= (0.78)($90,000) + (0.22)(–$30,000) = $63,600EMV for no plant = –$10,000

2.2. Given negative survey results,EMV(node 4) = EMV(large plant | negative survey)

= (0.27)($190,000) + (0.73)(–$190,000) = –$87,400EMV(node 5) = EMV(small plant | negative survey)

= (0.27)($90,000) + (0.73)(–$30,000) = $2,400EMV for no plant = –$10,000

Page 13: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Thompson’s Complex Decision Tree

Figure 3.4

First Decision Point

Second Decision Point

Favorable Market (0.78)

Unfavorable Market (0.22)

Favorable Market (0.78)

Unfavorable Market (0.22)

Favorable Market (0.27)

Unfavorable Market (0.73)

Favorable Market (0.27)

Unfavorable Market (0.73)

Favorable Market (0.50)

Unfavorable Market (0.50)

Favorable Market (0.50)

Unfavorable Market (0.50)Large Plant

Small Plant

No Plant

Condu

ct M

arke

t Sur

vey

Do Not Conduct Survey

Large Plant

Small Plant

No Plant

Large Plant

Small Plant

No Plant

Results

Favorable

ResultsNegative

Survey (0

.45)

Survey (0.55)

Payoffs

–$190,000

$190,000

$90,000

–$30,000

–$10,000

–$180,000

$200,000

$100,000

–$20,000

$0

–$190,000

$190,000

$90,000

–$30,000

–$10,000

$2,4

00$1

06,4

00

$106,400

$63,600

–$87,400

$2,400

Page 14: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Thompson’s Complex Decision Tree

3.3. Compute the expected value of the market survey,EMV(node 1) = EMV(conduct survey)

= (0.45)($106,400) + (0.55)($2,400)= $47,880 + $1,320 = $49,200

4.4. If the market survey is not conducted,EMV(node 6) = EMV(large plant)

= (0.50)($200,000) + (0.50)(–$180,000) = $10,000EMV(node 7) = EMV(small plant)

= (0.50)($100,000) + (0.50)(–$20,000) = $40,000EMV for no plant = $0

5.5. Best choice is to seek marketing information

Page 15: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Thompson’s Complex Decision Tree

Figure 3.4

First Decision Point

Second Decision Point

Favorable Market (0.78)

Unfavorable Market (0.22)

Favorable Market (0.78)

Unfavorable Market (0.22)

Favorable Market (0.27)

Unfavorable Market (0.73)

Favorable Market (0.27)

Unfavorable Market (0.73)

Favorable Market (0.50)

Unfavorable Market (0.50)

Favorable Market (0.50)

Unfavorable Market (0.50)Large Plant

Small Plant

No Plant

Condu

ct M

arke

t Sur

vey

Do Not Conduct Survey

Large Plant

Small Plant

No Plant

Large Plant

Small Plant

No Plant

Results

Favorable

ResultsNegative

Survey (0

.45)

Survey (0.55)

Payoffs

–$190,000

$190,000

$90,000

–$30,000

–$10,000

–$180,000

$200,000

$100,000

–$20,000

$0

–$190,000

$190,000

$90,000

–$30,000

–$10,000

$40,

000

$2,4

00$1

06,4

00

$49,

200

$106,400

$63,600

–$87,400

$2,400

$10,000

$40,000

$49,200

Page 16: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Expected Value of Sample Information

Thompson wants to know the actual value of doing the survey

EVSI = –

Expected valuewithwith sample

information, assumingno cost to gather it

Expected valueof best decisionwithoutwithout sample

information

= (EV with sample information + cost)– (EV without sample information)

EVSI = ($49,200 + $10,000) – $40,000 = $19,200

Page 17: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Sensitivity Analysis

How sensitive are the decisions to changes in the probabilities? How sensitive is our decision to the

probability of a favorable survey result?

That is, if the probability of a favorable result (p = .45) where to change, would we make the same decision?

How much could it change before we would make a different decision?

Page 18: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Sensitivity Analysis

p =probability of a favorable survey result(1 – p) =probability of a negative survey result

EMV(node 1) = ($106,400)p +($2,400)(1 – p)= $104,000p + $2,400

We are indifferent when the EMV of node 1 is the same as the EMV of not conducting the survey, $40,000

$104,000p + $2,400 = $40,000$104,000p= $37,600p= $37,600/$104,000 = 0.36

Page 19: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Not Conducting Survey

EMV= $40,000

Conducting survey

EMV= $104,000p + $2,400

P=0.36

Sensitivity Analysis (cont.)

Page 20: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Bayesian Analysis

Many ways of getting probability data It can be based on

Management’s experience and intuition Historical data Computed from other data using Bayes’

theorem Bayes’ theorem incorporates initial

estimates and information about the accuracy of the sources

Allows the revision of initial estimates based on new information

Page 21: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Calculating Revised Probabilities

In the Thompson Lumber case we used these four conditional probabilities

P (favorable market(FM) | survey results positive) = 0.78P (unfavorable market(UM) | survey results positive) = 0.22

P (favorable market(FM) | survey results negative) = 0.27P (unfavorable market(UM) | survey results negative) = 0.73

The prior probabilities of these markets are

P (FM) = 0.50P (UM) = 0.50

Page 22: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Calculating Revised Probabilities

Through discussions with experts Thompson has learned the following

He can use this information and Bayes’ theorem to calculate posterior probabilities

STATE OF NATURE

RESULT OF SURVEY

FAVORABLE MARKET (FM)

UNFAVORABLE MARKET (UM)

Positive (predicts favorable market for product)

P (survey positive | FM) = 0.70

P (survey positive | UM) = 0.20

Negative (predicts unfavorable market for product)

P (survey negative | FM) = 0.30

P (survey negative | UM) = 0.80

Table 3.11

Page 23: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Calculating Revised Probabilities

Recall Bayes’ theorem is

)()|()()|()()|(

)|(APABPAPABP

APABPBAP

whereevents two anyBA,

AA of complement

For this example, A will represent a favorable market and B will represent a positive survey

Thus, A’ will represent an unfavorable market and B’ will represent a negative survey

Page 24: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Calculating Revised Probabilities

P (FM | survey positive)

P(UM)|UM)P(P(FM) |FM)P(FMPFMP

positive surveypositive survey

positive survey )()|(

780450350

500200500700500700

...

).)(.().)(.().)(.(

P(FM)|FM)P(P(UM) |UM)P(UMPUMP

positive surveypositive survey

positive survey )()|(

220450100

500700500200500200

...

).)(.().)(.().)(.(

P (UM | survey positive)

Page 25: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Calculating Revised Probabilities

POSTERIOR PROBABILITY

STATE OF NATURE

CONDITIONAL PROBABILITY

P(SURVEY POSITIVE | STATE

OF NATURE)PRIOR

PROBABILITYJOINT

PROBABILITY

P(STATE OF NATURE | SURVEY

POSITIVE)

FM 0.70 X 0.50 = 0.35 0.35/0.45 = 0.78

UM 0.20 X 0.50 = 0.10 0.10/0.45 = 0.22

P(survey results positive) = 0.45 1.00

Table 3.12

The probability that the state of nature shows “Favorable market” given that the survey is “positive”

The Probability that the survey is “positive” and the state of nature shows “Favorable market”.

Observe the revision in the prior probabilities

Page 26: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Calculating Revised Probabilities

P (FM | survey negative)

P(UM)|UM)P(P(FM) |FM)P(FMPFMP

negative surveynegative survey

negative survey )()|(

270550150

500800500300500300

...

).)(.().)(.().)(.(

P(FM)|FM)P(P(UM) |UM)P(UMPUMP

negative surveynegative survey

negative survey )()|(

730550400

500300500800500800

...

).)(.().)(.().)(.(

P (UM | survey negative)

Page 27: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Calculating Revised Probabilities

POSTERIOR PROBABILITY

STATE OF NATURE

CONDITIONAL PROBABILITY

P(SURVEY NEGATIVE | STATE

OF NATURE)PRIOR

PROBABILITYJOINT

PROBABILITY

P(STATE OF NATURE | SURVEY

NEGATIVE)

FM 0.30 X 0.50 = 0.15 0.15/0.55 = 0.27

UM 0.80 X 0.50 = 0.40 0.40/0.55 = 0.73

P(survey results positive) = 0.55 1.00

Table 3.13

Page 28: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Potential Problems Using Survey Results

We can not always get the necessary data for analysis

Survey results may be based on cases where an action was taken

Conditional probability information may not be as accurate as we would like

Page 29: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility Theory

Will you accept a 50/50 bet for $5? Probably YES

Will you accept a 50/50 bet for $5m? Probably NO

BUT BOTH HAVE AN EMV = 0!

In some way you ‘care’ more about losing $5m than winning $5m

Limitations of EMV

Page 30: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Heads (0.5)

Tails (0.5)

$5,000,000

$0

Utility Theory

Accept Offer

Reject Offer

$2,000,000

EMV = $2,500,000

Figure 3.6

Do you accept to sell your ticket for $2,000,000?

You have a lottery ticket with 50% chance to win $5,000,000. And someone offers $2,000,000 for your ticket.

Page 31: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility Theory

Monetary value is not always a true indicator of the overall value of the result of a decision

The concept is based on the decision maker’s preference to taking a sure payoff versus participating in a lottery (under risk environment).

The overall value of a decision is called utilityutility

Rational people make decisions to maximize their utility

Page 32: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility Theory

Utility assessmentUtility assessment assigns the worst outcome a utility of 0, and the best outcome, a utility of 1

A standard gamblestandard gamble is used to determine utility values

When you are indifferent, the utility values are equal

Page 33: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Standard Gamble Best OutcomeUtility = 1

Worst OutcomeUtility = 0

Other OutcomeUtility = ?

(p)

(1 – p)Alternative 1

Alternative 2

Figure 3.7

Expected utility of alternative 2 =Expected utility of alternative 1Utility of other outcome =(p)(utility of best outcome, which is 1)+ (1 – p)(utility of the worst outcome, which is 0)Utility of other outcome =(p)(1) + (1 – p)(0) = p

Page 34: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Investment Example Jane Dickson wants to construct a utility curve

revealing her preference for money between $0 and $10,000

A utility curve plots the utility value versus the monetary value

An investment in a bank will result in $5,000 An investment in real estate will result in $0 or

$10,000 Unless there is an 80% chance of getting $10,000

from the real estate deal, Jane would prefer to have her money in the bank

So if p = 0.80, Jane is indifferent between the bank or the real estate investment

Page 35: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Investment Example

Figure 3.8

p = 0.80

(1 – p) = 0.20

Invest in

Real Estate

Invest in Bank

$10,000U($10,000) = 1.0

$0U($0.00) = 0.0

$5,000U($5,000) = p = 1.0

Utility for $5,000 = U($5,000) = pU($10,000) + (1 – p)U($0)= (0.8)(1) + (0.2)(0) = 0.8

Page 36: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Investment Example

Utility for $7,000 = 0.90Utility for $3,000 = 0.50

We can assess other utility values in the same way For Jane these are

Using the three utilities for different dollar amounts, she can construct a utility curve

Page 37: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility Curve

U ($7,000) = 0.90

U ($5,000) = 0.80

U ($3,000) = 0.50

U ($0) = 0

Figure 3.9

1.0 –

0.9 –

0.8 –

0.7 –

0.6 –

0.5 –

0.4 –

0.3 –

0.2 –

0.1 –

| | | | | | | | | | |

$0 $1,000 $3,000 $5,000 $7,000 $10,000

Monetary Value

Uti

lity

U ($10,000) = 1.0

Jane’s utility curve is typical of a risk avoider

Page 38: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Risk Avoiders vs. Risk Takers

A risk avoider will have a concave utility function. Individuals purchasing insurance exhibit risk avoidance behavior.

A risk taker, such as a gambler, pays a premium to obtain risk. His/her utility function is convex. This reflects the decision maker’s increasing marginal value of money.

A risk neutral decision maker has a linear utility function. In this case, the expected value approach can be used.

Most individuals are risk avoiders for some amounts of money, risk neutral for other amounts of money, and risk takers for still other amounts of money.

Page 39: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility Curve

Figure 3.10Monetary Outcome

Uti

lity

Risk Avoider

Risk

Neutra

l Dec

isio

n Mak

er

Risk Seeker

Page 40: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility as a Decision-Making Criteria

Once a utility curve has been developed it can be used in making decisions

Replace monetary outcomes with utility values

The expected utility is computed instead of the EMV

Page 41: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility as a Decision-Making Criteria

Mark Simkin loves to gamble He plays a game tossing thumbtacks in

the air If the thumbtack lands point up, Mark wins

$10,000 If the thumbtack lands point down, Mark

loses $10,000 Should Mark play the game (alternative 1)?

Page 42: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility as a Decision-Making Criteria

Figure 3.11

Tack Lands Point Up (0.45)

Alternative 1

Mark Plays the Game

Alternative 2

$10,000

–$10,000

$0

Tack Lands Point Down (0.55)

Mark Does Not Play the Game

Page 43: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility as a Decision-Making Criteria

Step 1– Define Mark’s utilities

U (–$10,000) = 0.05U ($0) = 0.15

U ($10,000) = 0.30

Step 2 – Replace monetary values with

utility valuesE(alternative 1: play the game) = (0.45)(0.30) + (0.55)(0.05)

= 0.135 + 0.027 = 0.162E(alternative 2: don’t play the game)= 0.15

Page 44: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility as a Decision-Making Criteria

Figure 3.12

1.00 –

0.75 –

0.50 –

0.30 –0.25 –

0.15 –

0.05 –0 –| | | | |

–$20,000 –$10,000 $0 $10,000 $20,000Monetary Outcome

Uti

lity

Page 45: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Utility as a Decision-Making Criteria

Figure 3.13Tack Lands Point Up (0.45)

Alternative 1

Mark Plays the Game

Alternative 2

0.30

0.05

0.15

Tack Lands Point Down (0.55)

Don’t Play

UtilityE = 0.162

E(alternative 1: play the game) = (0.45)(0.30) + (0.55)(0.05)= 0.135 + 0.027 = 0.162

E(alternative 2: don’t play the game)= 0.15

Page 46: Chapter 3 Decision Analysis (cont). Decision Trees decision tree Any problem that can be presented in a decision table can also be graphically represented

Homework 03

Prob. 3.28, 3.29, 3.31, 3.34, 3.36, 3.38, 3.42, 3.45