Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    1/27

    CHAPTER 4EQUILIBRIUM OUTPUT

    AND THE MULTIPLIER EFFECT

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    2/27

    Equilibrium Output

    Equilibrium output happenswhen aggregate expendituresequal aggregate income.Aggregate expenditures mayalso be labeled as aggregate

    demand., while aggregateincome may also be labeled asaggregate supply. Hence,equilibrium output may beidentified as the point whereSa (aggregate supply)

    intersects (aggregate demand)in the expenditure and incomegraph.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    3/27

    The Aggregate of Income and

    Expenditure Aggregate income (Y) is

    calculated by adding allincomes received in theeconomy by all owners offactor inputs within a one-year

    period, hence, should equalaggregate supply. On the otherhand, aggregate expenditure isthat part of income spent onconsumption and investment(C + I). But since investment is

    merely a part of saving (S), wemust understand in relation toincome.

    The first general equationthat we need to be consider isthat Y = C + S, this equationgenerally tells us that, given acertain level of income, we can

    only dispose it either byspending (C) or saving (S),nothing more, nothing less.The money (Y) can only usedeither way, so that Y can onlybe the sum of C and S.

    Corollarilly, if w want todetermine savings (S), theequation is: S = YC

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    4/27

    Table 4.1

    Income, Consumption and Savings

    Y

    C

    S

    160 320 -160

    200 350 -150

    400 500 -100

    800

    800

    0

    1200 1100 100

    1600 1400 200

    2000 1700 300

    Table 4.1 shows that negative savings may happen because even at zero income

    need to spend, e.g., food and minimal clothing in order o keep themselves alive.

    Where do they get the money? Maybe from borrowing, spot from relatives,

    subsidies from government welfare agencies.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    5/27

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    6/27

    Consumption and Savings

    Propensities1. Average Propensity to

    Consume (APC). A portionof total income used forconsumption. It isexpressed as a percentage

    income (Y). Algebraically.APC = C / Y

    2. Average Propensity toSave (APS). A portion of

    total income not used forpresent consumption, andtherefore, saved.Algebraically, APS = S / Y

    Since Y = C + S, C / Y + S + Y= 1, hence, APC + APS = 1also, because income canonly be either spent orsaved. So adding two more

    columns to Table 4.2 forAPC and APS, the result canbe seen as follows.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    7/27

    Table 4.2

    Income, Consumption, Savings, Average Propensity to

    Consumeand Average Propensity to Save

    Y C S APC APS

    160 320 -160 2 -1

    200 350 -150 1.75 -0.75

    400 500 -100 1.25 -0.25

    800

    800

    0

    1

    0

    1200

    1100

    100

    0.92

    0.08

    1600 1400 200 0.86 0.14

    2000 1700 300 0.85 0.15

    Adding each row in the APC and APS columns gives us a uniform sum of 1. Also

    in table 4.2, we can see that APC and APS move in opposite directions, that is,as APC decreases, APS increases. Conversely, as APC rises, APS moves down.

    The APC and APS are useful tools in planning as they may be used by

    planner (economists) to determine the spending and saving patterns of various

    regions and localities of a country, which could guide decision makers in their

    policy-making activities.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    8/27

    Consumption and Savings

    Propensities

    1. Marginal Propensity to Consume (MPC). A portion ofchange in total income that is used for consumption.It is expressed as the ratio of total change inconsumption C to change in income Y.

    Algebraically. MPC = C / Y

    2. Marginal Propensity to Save (MPS).A portion of thechange in income that is not used for spending, and

    therefore, saved. It is expressed as the ratio of thetotal change in the amount saved to the change inincome. Algebraically. MPS = S / Y

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    9/27

    Table 4.3

    Relationship of Income, Consumption, Savings,

    APC , APS, MPC and MPS

    Y

    C

    S

    APC

    APS

    MPC

    MPS

    160 320 -160 2 -1 - -

    200 350 -150 1.75 -0.75 0.75 0.25

    400 500 -100 1.25 -0.25 0.75 0.25

    800 800 0 1 0 0.75 0.25

    1200 1100 100 0.92 0.08 0.75 0.25

    1600 1400 200 0.86 0.14 0.75 0.25

    2000

    1700

    300

    0.85

    0.15

    0.75

    0.25

    We can see that the first two row in the

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    10/27

    Consumption Function

    At equilibrium, income (Y) is equal to expenditure (C + I),and between C and I, C always comprises the larger shareof Y. This logical flow is an extension of Keynes observationthat saving is just a residual fund after an individual orhousehold had already satisfied his consumption needs,

    and that investment (Y) is merely a portion of (S), and atequilibrium S = I.

    From the equilibrium equation Y = C + I, we can see thatboth C and I are functions of Y. But because C comprises themore significant portion of Y, we need to study it moreclosely in relation to Y. Hence, we will state that C = f(Y),meaning the value of C depends on the value of Y.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    11/27

    Consumption Function

    From this graph, we can seethe value of C at any pointalong the C curve is C = a + bY.

    So that we can forecast the

    consumption behavior if weare able to establish the ratioof C and Y (change in C forevery change in Y). In thisassumed linear relationshipbetween C and Y, a = origin or

    starting value of C and b =slope of the curve or C line.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    12/27

    Consumption Function

    Revisiting the date we generated

    in Table 4.1, we will validate the

    linear relationship of C and Y by

    calculating its slopes are every

    paired rows:

    1. At Y = 160 and C = 320

    Y = 200 and C = 350

    Solve for B.

    2. At Y = 200 and C = 350

    Y = 400 and C = 500

    Solve for B.

    b=C

    Y

    b=150

    200

    b=0.75

    b=C

    Y

    b= 350

    320

    200 160

    b=30

    40

    b= 0.75

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    13/27

    Consumption Function

    3. At Y = 400 and C = 500

    Y = 800 and C = 800

    Solve for B.

    4. At Y = 800 and C = 800

    Y = 1200 and C = 1100

    Solve for B.

    b=C

    Y

    b=300

    400

    b=0.75

    b=C

    Y

    b=300

    400

    b=0.75

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    14/27

    5. At Y = 1200 and C

    =1100

    Y = 1600 and C = 1400

    6. At Y = 1600 and C

    =1400

    Y = 2000 and C = 1200

    b=C

    Y

    b=300

    400

    b=0.75

    b=C

    Y

    b=300

    400

    b=0.75

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    15/27

    Consumption Function

    Since the slope of s straightline is the same at any pairedpoints along the line, we areable to prove the linearrelationship between Y and C

    in our sample date. With thislinearity, we can forecast thevalue of C at any level of Y.

    Example:

    Y = 900

    a = 200

    Solve for C. C = ?

    Solution:

    C = a + bY

    C = 200 + 0.75 (900)

    C = 100 + 675C = 875

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    16/27

    Planned Investments

    And Its Multiplier Effect The second component of aggregate spending (aggregate demand) is

    planned investment; I. Planned investment is the type of investment madeby the firm voluntarily of intentionally. This is differentiated fromunplanned investment, which has a negative effect on output because itoccurs due to weakness in demand, therefore, is undesirable.

    Unplanned investment happens when inventories rise because of the fallin demand. For example, San Miguel Corporation expects to sell 100million bottles of beer for the year, but because of a change in consumerpreference, it is only able to sell 90 million bottles. So, without wanting it,SMC will have increased its investment (trough increase inventory) by theamount equivalent to 10 million unsold beers. This kind of investment

    (unplanned) definitely has a negative effect on output. It is for this reasonthat we will only consider planned investment as relevant to our presentanalysis.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    17/27

    Planned Investments

    And Its Multiplier Effect

    With this clarification, henceforth, we willconsider planned investments as investment

    Investment may be defined as that part ofsavings used to create future value, e.g.,sewing machine to create clothes I the future,

    beer mixing machines to crease future beers,buildings to create more space foewarehousing, etc.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    18/27

    Planned Investments

    And Its Multiplier Effect

    Planned investment is normally not

    dependent on income. Firms do not normally

    alter its investments expenditures as planned

    for a given year. Why? Because a capitalexpenditure plans which was made in prior

    years is very costly for the firm to change in

    terms of additional man-hour cost, which willrework the plan, and for cost opportunities in

    doing other things rather than reworking plan

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    19/27

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    20/27

    Planned Investments

    And Its Multiplier Effect If for example, a typhoon damaged the facilities of

    Meralco so, say in Manila. Meralco will have no choice butto increase its investment to rehabilitate its facilitiesimmediately. They cannot wait for the next budget cyclebefore repairing its facilities. Otherwise, they will be in big

    trouble from its customers.

    After deducting the reduction in income brought about bythe damaged facilities, will a 100 million increase ininvestment in Meralco to repair the facilities bring anadditional income of 100 million in the economy? Since Y= C + I, hence an increase by 100 million of I will result in100 million of I will result in Y also increase by 100million.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    21/27

    Planned Investments

    And Its Multiplier Effect After deducting the reduction in income brought about by

    the damaged facilities, will a 100 million increase ininvestment in Meralco to repair the facilities bring anadditional income of 100 million in the economy? Since Y= C + I, hence an increase by 100 million of I will result in

    100 million of I will result in Y also increase by 100million.

    The answer is flat NO. Why? Because an increase inplanned investment has a multiplier effect in the economy.Income, Y, will actually increase by a multiple of I. This isbecause an increase in I will also include an increase in C.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    22/27

    Planned Investments

    And Its Multiplier Effect Let us explain this phenomenon. Initially, income will increase by

    the same amount as the increase in I. But the money from theinvestment will be paid o additional workers who will work to repairthe damaged facilities and/or to those existing employees who willrender overtime; some will be paid to suppliers of equipment,wires, transformer, bus-station spare parts, etc.

    The recipient of this investment money will naturally spend all or apart of this additional disposable income on consumption.Therefore, C will also be effectively increased. For the rest nextround, further recipients of this investment money paid to workers

    and suppliers will spend part of it for their own familysconsumption needs. Then, there will be another round of spending,and another and another, until there will be no more residualmoney left for further spending.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    23/27

    Planned Investments

    And Its Multiplier Effect

    The graph in Figure 4.4

    shows the effect of I to

    Y. By ocular inspection,

    we can easily see that the

    distance from Y0to Y1is

    longer than the distance

    from I0to I1. Hence, Y >

    I because of the

    multiplier effect of I in

    the economys income.

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    24/27

    The Value of the Multiplier

    The value of the investmentmultiplier can be derived byputting together the variousequilibrium relationships that wehave established in this chapter.

    First we have to establish that:Y = C + S

    But since at equilibrium,

    S = I

    Hence, Y = C + I at equilibrium

    It was also established that:

    C= a + bY

    Therefore, Y = a + bY + I

    By rearranging this equation, wefind:

    Y by = a + I, and

    Y (1 b) = a + I, and

    Y= a + I

    1 bor Y= a + I 1

    1 b

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    25/27

    The Value of the Multiplier

    Since a is the

    intercept (starting

    value) of C, its value is

    assumed to beconstant.

    Hence, if I is increased

    by I,

    Y=

    I 1b

    and because b=MPC

    Y= I1

    1-MPC

    Hence, the value of the multiplier is1

    1-MPC

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    26/27

    The Value of the Multiplier

    Example:

    Using the computed MPC of 0.75 in Figure 4.4, estimate the effect onincome at equilibrium of the change in planned investment using thefollowing data:

    Given:I0 = 850

    I1= 900

    a = 350

    b = 0.75

    Calculate:

    I change in investment= ?

    Y change in income= ?

    Y (resulting income)= ?

    Y0income before I appears= ?

  • 8/10/2019 Chapter 4: Equilibrium Output and Multiplier Effect

    27/27

    The Value of the Multiplier

    Solution:

    1. I=I1-I0

    = 900 850

    = 50

    2. Y = I 1

    1-MPC

    = 50

    1

    0.25

    = 200

    3.Y = C + I + I

    = a + bY + I +

    I

    =350 + 0.75Y + 50

    Y 0.75Y = 350 + 50

    0.25Y = 400

    Y=400

    0.25

    Y=1,600

    4.Y0= Y Y

    = 1600 200

    = 1400