24
Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it depends…” Two problems Some highlights from Chapter 6 Acid rain: the problems with the 1970 Clean Air Act Emissions trading Global warming: Kyoto and beyond Smoking: when is it a policy problem and when is it not?

Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

Chapter 6: Externalities In Action

Outline Addressing externalities: should we

focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

depends…” Two problems Some highlights from Chapter 6

Acid rain: the problems with the 1970 Clean Air Act

Emissions trading Global warming: Kyoto and beyond Smoking: when is it a policy problem and

when is it not?

Page 2: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

A More Realistic Externality Example: Acid Rain

Sulfur dioxide (SO2) and nitrogen oxides (NOX) released into the atmosphere, form sulfuric and nitric acids.

These acids may fall back to earth hundreds of miles away from their original source, known as acid rain.

Majority of acid rain in North America caused by SO2, much coming from coal-fired power plants concentrated in the Ohio River Valley. Acid rain is a negative production externality. It:

Makes lakes more acidic. Erodes forests. Causes damage to property ($5 billion/year). Reduces visibility. Leads to adverse health outcomes

Page 3: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

History of Acid Rain Regulation

1970 Clean Air Act set maximum standards for various substances, including SO2.

It set New Source Performance Standards (NSPS) for any new power plant, forcing the plant to either reduce emissions or install scrubbers. New plants, therefore, were made more expensive

relative to older plants. Companies thus kept older, dirtier plants on line longer that they otherwise would.

There’s an analogy to imposing regulation on new autos. Gruber calls this a consequence of “partial policy

reform.”

Page 4: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

History of Acid Rain Regulation

1990 Clean Air Act Amendments mandated a reduction of more than 50% of the level of SO2 nationwide, and included all plants.

It offered an SO2 allowance system that granted plants permits to emit SO2 in limited quantities, based on their historical fuel utilization.

Plants were allowed to buy, sell, or save their allowances.

The allowances involved very few restrictions– trading could occur anywhere within the United States, with no approval or review, and the frequency and mechanism of trading were unlimited.

Page 5: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

History of Acid Rain Regulation

The 1990 amendments and emissions trading drew opposition from two very diverse groups: Those opposed on economic grounds, like

utilities and coal miners. An industry study predicted the full cost of the

regulations to be up to $7.4 billion, with a loss of up to 4 million jobs.

It was also opposed by environmentalists. They opposed the 1990 amendments on the grounds

that they created a “market for vice and virtue.”

Page 6: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

History of Acid Rain Regulation

Estimates suggest that emissions trading significantly lowered the costs of the 1990 amendments. Over the 1995-2007 period, costs were lowered from $35

billion to $15 billion. Thus, trading has worked to greatly improve the efficiency

of regulation. Even environmentalists are now more sympathetic

to emissions trading, because it reduces economic opposition. “In less than a decade, emissions trading has gone from

being a pariah among policymakers to being a star.” -- Daniel Ellerman, expert on acid rain regulations

Page 7: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

Has the Clean Air Act Been a Success?

The overall success of the Clean Air Act is much harder to determine.

The regulations were costly. In its first 15 years, the Clean Air Act cost:

600,000 jobs. $75 billion in output.

They did result in benefits, too. Health improvements, such as reductions in infant mortality.

Burtraw, et al. (1997) estimate that the health benefits alone exceed the cost of reduction by a factor of seven, once the lower-cost trading regime was implemented.

Page 8: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

A Second Externality Example: Global Warming

The earth is heated by solar radiation that passes through our atmosphere and warms the earth’s surface.

A large portion of the heat is trapped by certain gasses in the earth’s atmosphere, which reflect the heat back toward the earth again.

This is known as the greenhouse effect. The concentration of greenhouse gasses like carbon

dioxide and methane has increased due to human activity.

Using fossil fuels like coal, oil, and natural gas produce carbon dioxide and contribute to this effect.

Page 9: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

GLOBAL WARMING The surface temperatures have increased by more

than 1 degree Fahrenheit in the past 30 years. Projections for the next 100 years suggest an

unprecedented increase by as much as 6-10 degrees. Carbon emissions in Boston and Bangkok have the same

effect on the global environment. The stock, not the flow, of carbon dioxide cause the

warming. Thus, it takes a long time to undo the damage. Global warming is a thus a complicated externality

involving many nations and many generations of emitters.

Page 10: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

Table 2

Top 25 Fossil Fuel CO2 Emitters in 2000

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

UN

ITE

D S

TA

TE

S

CH

INA

RU

SS

IAN

FE

D.

JAP

AN

IND

IA

GE

RM

AN

Y

UN

ITE

D K

ING

DO

M

CA

NA

DA

ITA

LY

SO

UT

H K

OR

EA

ME

XIC

O

SA

UD

I A

RA

BIA

FR

AN

CE

AU

ST

RA

LIA

UK

RA

INE

SO

UT

H A

FR

ICA

IRA

N

BR

AZ

IL

PO

LAN

D

SP

AIN

IND

ON

ES

IA

TU

RK

EY

TA

IWA

N

TH

AIL

AN

D

NO

RT

H K

OR

EAM

illi

on

s o

f M

etri

c T

on

s o

f C

arb

on

The U.S. is currently responsible for nearly 25% of the planet’s

carbon dioxide emissions.

Japan contributes only 5% of annual emissions.

Developing counties like China and India emit large quantities of

greenhouse gasses.

Page 11: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

The Kyoto Treaty The goal of the Kyoto treaty in 1997 was to reduce

the emissions of greenhouse gasses to 5% below their 1990 levels.

United States and Russia have not signed on; many other of the 38 industrialized nations have, however.

For the United States, the Kyoto treaty would: Mean reducing emissions in 2010 by roughly 30% With a present discounted cost of $1,100,000,000,000

($1.1 trillion) The United States would bear 90% of the total world

cost, even though it contributes only 25% of annual greenhouse gas emissions.

Page 12: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

Can Trading Make Kyoto More Cost-Effective?

Kyoto treaty introduced international emissions trading. Under the Kyoto treaty, the industrialized signatories are

allowed to trade emissions rights among themselves, as long as the total emissions goals are met.

There are tremendous differences across developed nations in terms of meeting these goals, for two reasons:

Slow growth in some countries: Relatively easy for a country like Russia to meet its goal. Estimates suggest that emissions trading (say, from Russia to United States) could lower the cost of the treaty by 75%.

Environmentally conscious growth: Other countries, like Japan, tend to use more gas and nuclear-powered production.

Figure 3Figure 3 shows the benefits of international emissions trading (the readings for today give an update from the Montreal, the site of the most recent international climate change meetings).

Page 13: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

Figure 3 The benefits of trading

Yet the treaty calls for the U.S. to reduce

emissions a lot.

Carbon Reduction (millions of metric tons)

Price of carbon reduction

0 630

It is fairly expensive for the U.S. to reduce

its emissions.SUS SR

$210

$20

440190

It is easier for Russia and others to reduce

their emissions.

And the requirements are lower, too.The total cost to the

U.S. is 440x$210.

The overall cost, with no emissions trading,

is $96 billion.

ST

$50

With emissions trading, the supply curve is

summed horizontally.

The cost of worldwide emission reduction is $50

per ton with ST.

590

The total cost to Russia and others is

190x$20.The U.S. buys 400 permits (440-40).

The overall cost, with emissions trading, is

$32 billion.

40

Page 14: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

A Third Externality Example: The Economics of Smoking

Smoking causes more than 440,000 deaths each year, four times as much as AIDS, motor vehicle accidents, homicide, and suicide combined.

What is the role for government intervention in the case of a decision like smoking? Several possible arguments: Smoking is bad for you. Smoking is addictive. It generates negative externalities to the health system,

workplace, and fire departments. It generates positive externalities to the Social Security and

Medicare system. It creates negative externalities to other family members

through secondhand smoke.

Page 15: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

THE ECONOMICS OF SMOKING

Smoking is bad for you. Smoker lives about 6 fewer years than a

nonsmoker. A year of life is valued by economists at about $200,000.

In standard utility-maximization, any damage individuals do to themselves from dangerous activities results from a rational tradeoff of benefits against potential costs. Perhaps a rationalization can be given because young

people make decisions to smoke when they are not capable of sensibly assessing the benefits and costs of their decisions

Or cigarettes are so additive that people don’t understand they can’t quit (or have a very hard time quitting).

Page 16: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

THE ECONOMICS OF SMOKING

Smoking is addictive. “Rational addicts” understand that each cigarette

that they smoke today increases their addiction. Smokers consider not only the cost of today’s pack

of cigarettes, but the cost of all additional future packs that will now be purchased because their addiction is deepened.

Smokers also understand that smoking doesn’t just reduce health through the current cigarette, but all future cigarettes that will be consumed because of the addiction.

With this model, smoking remains a rational choice.

Page 17: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

The Externalities of Smoking Smoking generates negative externalities due

to higher health costs. Smoking-related disease increases U.S.

medical care costs by $75 billion annually, 5% of the total.

If insurance companies can make actuarial adjustments, they simply charge smokers higher rates. Such adjustments internalize the medical cost

externality from smoking. In a simple model, there are no health externalities because smokers pay for the high medical costs through higher premiums.

Page 18: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

The Externalities of Smoking In fact, actuarial adjustments are often not made with

employer health insurance. In this case, the externality is financial, not physical. This is an

externality because the social marginal benefit from an individual’s cigarette consumption is below the private marginal benefit–the individual’s coworkers have to pay higher premiums.

In addition to higher health costs to the private sector, individuals who receive government insurance exert a negative externality onto taxpayers.

The same is true of the uninsured (smokers and non-smokers alike)–they exert negative externalities onto medical providers, who pass along the costs to consumers.

Page 19: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

The Economics of Smoking

Smoking generates negative externalities due to lower workplace productivity and more frequent absences.

Firms may be able to adjust wages to compensate for this type of problem. If workers’ wages adjust to compensate

for their lower expected productivity, then the externality is internalized, akin to the adjustments in health premiums.

Page 20: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

The Economics of Smoking

Smoking generates negative externalities due to fires, mostly due to falling asleep with a burning cigarette.

To the extent the smoker only damages himself and his own property, there is not an externality. But if the fire spreads to other properties, there is an externality.

Also costs to fire departments and insurance companies that may not be fully internalized.

Page 21: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

The Externalities of Smoking

Smoking generates positive externalities to taxpayers due to the early deaths of smokers and lower payouts for some social insurance programs. Often contribute payroll tax for Social

Security and Medicare during working life, but smokers may not be alive to collect benefits when they are elderly.

Page 22: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

The Economics of Smoking

Smoking generates negative externalities (mostly to other family members) through secondhand smoke. Considerable medical uncertainty about the

damages done from this. Moreover, if the smoker maximizes family utility

rather than individual utility, he/she rationally trades off the benefits to himself/herself versus the harm to his/her family.

Evidence suggest family utility maximization is incomplete, however.

Page 23: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

The Economics of Smoking

Taken together, the external costs of smoking are roughly 40¢ per pack of cigarettes in 2003 dollars.

Estimates of external costs of secondhand smoke vary widely, from 1¢ to $1.16 per pack.

The average federal plus state cigarette tax is over $1 per pack.

Page 24: Chapter 6: Externalities In Action Outline Addressing externalities: should we focus on prices or on quantities? Understand why the answer is that “it

Should We Care Only About Externalities, or Do “Internalities”

Matter Also?

Traditional economics approach cares only about externalities that smokers impose on others.

Model ignores some key features of the smoking decision that may motivate government intervention. Youth smoking decisions Inability of adults to quit

Maybe policymakers should decide that people are unable to do what is best for them, and consequently policy should try to influence choices. This, of course, is a slippery slope.

Information/outreach campaigns–these have reduced the smoking rate a lot over the last 30 years.

Reducing access to cigarettes for teenagers. Taxation–elasticity of demand for cigarettes is around -0.5, and higher for

youth smokers.