Commodities as Asset Class

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    1/24

    For Institutional Investo

    Use Only. Not for Publi

    Distribution.

    Vanguard research March 201

    Investment case

    or commodities?

    Myths and reality

    Author

    Geetesh Bhardwaj, Ph

    Executive summary. Commodities are one o the least understood

    asset classes. Some investors wonder how owning a chunk o steel

    or a bushel o corn could provide them with any real return, particularly

    in times o deation. Still others contend that the high historical returns

    or commodities are primarily the result o two commodity bubbles, and

    that, excluding those abnormal periods, commodities have had only poor

    results. Then, too, some see commodities as highly volatile and as too

    risky or most investors.

    This paper describes the undamental properties o commodities to

    help institutional investors evaluate the case or investing in them.

    One challenge in understanding commodities as an asset class is theabsence o a long data series on the past perormance o commodity

    utures.1 To address this problem, Vanguard has recently constructed

    an equally weighted, well-diversifed commodities return series, using

    1 For example, historical data on the well-diversified DJ (Dow Jones) -UBS Commodity Index (hencefort h, DJ-UBSCI) are available

    only since 1991 (also, since the index was launched in 1998, it has a significant backfill).

    Connect with Vanguard > www.vanguard.com

    > global.vanguard.com (non-U.S. investors)

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    2/24

    2 Our commodities return series represents the broad commodity market; given equal weights, no one single commodity or sector can drive the results.

    3 We believe that one needs a long historical data record to understand the fundamental properties of anyasset class.

    2

    long historical commodity utures data beginning in 1959.2 Our aim here is to

    describe the basic properties o commodities, and not to provide an investable

    alternative to existing commodity indexes.3 But, as with historical analysis o

    any asset class (e.g., stocks, bonds, or short-term debt), it is difcult to know

    how the existence o a large and institutionally dominated market would haveaected past returns; or similar reasons, investors need to be mindul that past

    returns do not guarantee uture perormance.

    Can commodities rightfully be considered an

    asset class? Can a commodities investor expect

    to earn any real return, or were the two historical

    bubbles in commodities their only periods ofoutperformance? Are commodities too volatile

    for most investors to touch?

    This paper addresses these and other questions

    as it seeks to separate myth rom reality in helping

    investors evaluate the case or commodity investing.

    For instance, as we describe, an investor actually

    gains exposure to commodities as an asset class

    by investing in commodity futures, and not by

    investing in physical commodities. The undamental

    economic reason long-only investors in commodity

    utures have historically been expected to earn a

    risk premium is that long investors have provided

    price insurance to producers o commodities, who

    hedge price risk by taking the short side o positions

    in the utures market. Moreover, commodity utures

    have, in act, experienced long periods o signiicant

    returns or investors, as well as sequences o booms

    and busts similar to equities; there is thus little merit

    in the argument that relatively high long-term averagereturns o commodity utures are solely a result o a

    ew brie abnormal periods o high returns.

    First, we introduce the concept o commodity

    utures and explore the theoretical oundations o

    why a long-only investor may expect to earn a return

    or taking such a position. We then construct a

    commodities return series or a long-only investment

    in commodities utures, including detailed analysis o

    the data. Next, we compare the results o investing

    in commodity utures versus physical commodities,

    as well as the historical perormance o commodity

    uture returns versus equity returns. Finally, we look

    at the diversiication beneits o commodity utures

    rom a portolio perspective.

    Notes on risk: All investments are subject to risk. Investments in bonds are subject to interest rate, credit,

    and inflation risk. Foreign investing involves additional risks, including currency fluctuations and political

    uncertainty. Diversification does not ensure a profit or protect against a loss in a declining market. Past

    performance is no guarantee of future returns. The performance of an index is not an exact representationof any particular investment, as you cannot invest directly in an index.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    3/24

    Basics of commodity investment

    A commodity utures contract is a standardized

    agreement to buy (or sell) a prespeciied amount

    o a commodity at a uture date, called the maturity

    date. The price o the contract (the utures price) is

    eectively the price that the seller o the commodity

    will receive at the maturity date, and is determined

    on a utures exchange by the orces o demand

    and supply.4

    As stated early in this paper, its important

    to appreciate that commodity utures do not

    necessarily represent direct exposures to actual

    commodities. A long investor who agrees to buy

    a physical commodity at a uture date may not

    have the commodity actually delivered to him or

    her, because the investor has the option to sellthe utures contract beore the actual date o

    physical delivery.

    Determining the futures price

    To understand how commodity utures returns are

    derived, one must irst understand how a utures

    price is determined. The most important element

    making up the utures price is the spot price, that

    is, the price that market participants expect to

    prevail when a utures contract matures. I market

    participants expect the uture spot price to be much

    higher than the current spot price (due to utureexpected demand and supply or the commodity),

    then the utures price will be higher than the current

    spot price; otherwise, the utures price willbe lower

    than the current spot price (all else being equal). It

    is important to emphasize here that the utures price

    is set in relation to the spot price that is expected

    to prevail at the time o the maturity o the utures

    contract, and not the current spot price.

    A spot prices deviation at maturity rom what was

    expected when the utures contract was issued is

    by deinition subject to risk, and this is the risk that

    all utures investors ace. I the realized spot price at

    maturity ends up higher than the utures price, then

    the long investor will make a proit; otherwise, he or

    she aces a loss.

    So how can long-only investors consistently earna risk premium in this market? The only way this is

    likely to happen is i the utures price, on average,

    is set below the expected spot price that obtains

    at maturity. We would expect this to occur i there

    are sellers o commodity utures in the market that

    are willing to systematically accept a lower-than-

    expected price or the underlying commodity, in

    exchange or the utures buyers assurance o a

    certain price at maturity. These sellers are willing

    to pay a premium to insure against the price risk.

    This premium can be thought o as equaling the

    dierence between the utures price at which they

    sell in the utures market, and the uture spot price

    they would otherwise expect to be paid. Much

    academic work has been done on this concept

    since the 1930s, when both Keynes (1930) and

    Hicks (1939) developed the theory o normal

    backwardation, which holds that utures prices

    are set below expected uture spot prices.

    To understand Keynes and Hickss theory, consider

    a producer o corn who wants to insure against the

    risk that prices could all at harvest time (such a

    participant is called a hedger). The corn producer

    can obtain such insurance by selling corn utures

    to lock in a predetermined price or his crops.

    Participating on the other side o the trade are long

    investors (called speculators) who provide the

    insurance or the price o corn by buying utures

    contracts. These long investors, however, demand

    a risk premium or bearing the risk o uture price

    luctuations. Thus, the long investors would require

    that the utures price be set at least somewhat

    below the expected uture spot price.

    4 At the end of each trading day, gains and losses during the day are settled by the two parties to the contract via transfers from t heir margin accounts,

    through daily mark to market. To understand the ac counting, consider the hypothetical example of a buyer and seller entering into an oil futur es contract.

    Suppose the current fut ures price of oil for delivery the subsequent mon th is $70 (U.S. dollars). At the time of deliver y, if the spot price turns out to be

    $100 dollars, the seller of the commodity will receive $100 for oil. However the seller, through daily mark to market, would have paid the buyer $ 30, thus

    effectively exchanging oil at $70. On the f lip side, if at the time of delivery the spot price is $ 50, the seller of the commodity w ill receive $50 for oil. Further,

    the seller, through daily mark to market, would also have received $20 f rom the buyer, again effectively exchanging oil at $70.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    4/24

    The normal backwardation theory implicitly

    assumes that the number o producers requiring

    hedging outweighs the number o consumers

    requiring similar hedging in the market. For example,

    suppose iron ore were produced only by mining

    companies and used as an input only by steelmakers.I the hedging demands o both types o irms were

    equal, there would be no reason to assume one side

    o the utures contracting arrangement (long or short)

    would receive a premium or buying or selling an

    iron-ore uture. However, i one side o the market

    (either the producer or consumer) is more risk-averse

    than the other, the more risk-averse side clearly

    would be willing to provide an insurance premium

    to the other side o the transaction.

    Gorton and Rouwenhorst (2006) have also recently

    studied this topic, and summarized the undamentals

    o commodity utures returns as ollows:

    1. The expected return to the long investor in

    commodity utures in excess o the risk-ree rate

    o return is the risk premium. The return realized

    by the long investor is the risk-ree rate, plus the

    (insurance) risk premium, plus any unexpected

    deviation o the uture spot price rom the

    expected uture spot price at the time the long

    position was established.

    2. A long position in utures is expected to earn a

    positive risk premium as long as the utures price

    is below the expected spot price at maturity. A

    risk premium may exist and be earned regardless

    o whether the utures price is higher or lower

    than the current spot price or the commodity

    in question.

    3. Expected trends in spot prices are not a source

    o return to an investor in utures, because that

    would assume successul market-timing on the

    part o the utures investor.

    Confusion about terminology.Backwardation and

    another term, contango, have oten been used to

    characterize the current state o the utures market.

    Yet, use o these terms has resulted in some

    conusion. Contangocommonly reers to a market

    in which utures prices are higherthan the current

    spot pricethat is, the term structure o the utures

    curve is upward sloping. In backwardation, utures

    prices are lowerthan the current spot, and the term

    structure o the utures curve is downward sloping.

    The deinitions just cited, as well as those used by

    the U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission,5

    reer to the slope o the utures curve at a point in

    time, and not to the movement o utures prices over

    the lie o a contract. However, as stated earlier, the

    theory o normal backwardation contends that

    utures prices are set below expected spotprices at

    maturity. This theory is about utures prices relative

    to expected spot prices. However, the prevailing

    terminology describes utures markets by reerring

    to utures prices relative to the current spot. The

    use o the term backwardation to characterize the

    state o the utures market vis--vis the current

    spot price has led to a widespread, but alse, belie

    that the theory somehow implies that a commodity

    utures return premium exists only when markets

    are in backwardation. As emphasized earlier in this

    discussion, however, this is not the case.

    Further, given the preceding deinitions o contango

    and backwardation as relative to the current spot

    price, the natural state o virtually all (historically,

    this has actually occurred close to 70% o the time)

    commodity utures markets is reasonably expected

    to be in contango. This is implied by the existence o

    a cost o carry, according to which those holding

    a physical commodity must pay or storage and

    other expenses, coupled with a simple arbitrage.

    Arbitrage in this case is a inancially equivalent

    alternative to buying a commodity uture and selling

    it at expiry. In an arbitrage transaction, the investor

    buys the underlying physical commodity now in

    the spot market, stores it until the utures contract

    maturity date, and then sells it in the spot market. Ithe commodity is costly to store (there is a cost o

    carry), then investors ability to make this alternative

    trade should tend to push utures prices higher than

    the current spot price, all else equal, which would

    5 The U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC ) defines these market conditions as: Backwardation: Market situation in which futures prices ar e

    progressively lower in the distant delivery mon ths and Contango: Market situation in which prices in succeeding delivery months are pr ogressively higher

    than in the nearest delivery month. Source: http://www.cftc.gov/educationcenter/glossary/glossary_b.html.

    4

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    5/24

    imply contango. This logic, coupled with a mistaken

    belie that commodities-utures risk premiums cannot

    exist when markets are in contango, has led some to

    conclude that all commodities utures returns come

    rom the ew market events when the market is in

    backwardation (relative to the current spot price).

    This argument ails to recognize that prevailing

    terminology compares utures prices with current

    spot prices, whereas the theory o normalbackwardation suggests a relationship between the

    utures price and the expected spot price at maturity.

    To illustrate how a risk premium can potentially be

    obtained when the market is in contango, consider

    the ollowing hypothetical example (see Figure 1).

    Suppose the current spot price is $100 and the

    expected spot price is $110. The theory o normal

    backwardation suggests that the utures price

    should be less than the expected spot price. Thus,

    suppose the utures price is $105. This implies that

    the expected risk premium is $5 ($110 $105 =$5). Notice, however, that the market is in contango:

    that is, the utures price is greater than the current

    spot price. This example shows that normal

    backwardation can be present while a utures market

    is in contango; the long-only investor would expect

    to earn a premium o $5, although the realized return

    will o course be dierent rom $5 i the spot price at

    maturity is dierent rom the expected $110.

    Now consider an example in which the utures

    markets are in backwardation (see Figure 2).

    Suppose the current spot price is $115 and that the

    expected spot price is $110. The theory o normal

    backwardation suggests that the utures price shouldbe less than the expected spot price. Suppose

    the utures price is $105thus, the expected risk

    premium would be $5. This example also illustrates

    a market condition in which there is delationary

    pressure, since the spot price is actually declining

    rom $115 to $110; however, the utures investors

    are expected to get a positive risk premium as a

    result o normal backwardation.

    In summary, a long-only utures investor in a

    commodity market can expect to earn a positive

    risk premium by providing valuable insurance, iproducers or other risk hedgers are willing to pay

    or such insurance regardless o whether markets

    are in backwardation or contango. The positive risk

    premium is the reward or assuming the price risk.

    Commodity risk premium in a

    contango market

    Figure 1.

    Note: This hypothetical illustration does not represent the return on

    any particular investment.

    Source: Vanguard.

    Inception (t) Expiration (T)

    Expectedspot pricerise, $10

    Expected riskpremium, $5

    $110: Expected

    spot price (ST)

    $100: Currentspot price (St)

    $105: Futuresprice (Ft)

    Commodity risk premium in a

    backwardation market

    Figure 2.

    Note: This hypothetical illustration does not represent the return on

    any particular investment.

    Source: Vanguard.

    Inception (t) Expiration (T)

    Expectedspot pricedecline, $5

    Expected riskpremium, $5

    $110: Expectedspot price (ST)

    $115: Currentspot price (St)

    $105: Futuresprice (Ft)

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    6/24

    6

    Historical data and construction

    of commodities return series

    Unortunately, a long historical data series on the

    perormance o commodity utures as an asset class

    is not available. For example, historical data on the

    well-diversiied DJ (Dow Jones) -UBS Commodity

    Index (henceorth, the DJ-UBSCI) are available only

    rom 1991. Yet, we believe that to ully understand

    an asset classs undamental properties, longer-term

    historical data are necessary. Thereore, to carry

    out a robust historical analysis o the behavior o

    commodity utures markets, we have constructed a

    commodities return series extending back in history

    to August 31, 1959.

    Figure 3 lists the commodities that make up our

    return series and the inception dates o uturescontracts or each. In all, the return series contains

    30 commodities, broadly characterized in seven

    sectors (energy, precious metals, grains, animal

    products, sots, industrial materials, and industrial

    metals). Figure 3 also reports the cumulative

    annualized excess returns (beyond the 3-month

    U.S. Treasury bill return) or each commodity since

    the start o its utures contract through April 30,

    2009. The last column reports t-statistics denoting

    signiicance o the average excess return. Thus, we

    tested or the statistical hypothesis that, on average,

    the excess returns were positive. We ound thisto be true or only 5 out o the 30 commodities

    (at a 95% signiicance levelsee the asterisked

    commodities in the igure)a result that supports

    the well-documented high volatility o individual

    commodity utures returns.

    Our commodities return series is an equally

    weighted average o these 30 commodities; the

    series is well-diversiied and represents the broad

    commodity market. The accompanying Appendix

    summarizes the steps we used in constructing

    the return series and the details o our analysis.Given the return series diversiied nature, no single

    commodity or sector can drive the results. To derive

    the total returns that would result rom holding a

    ully collateralized commodity utures position (we

    ruled out use o leveraging), we incorporated the

    3-month U.S. Treasury bill return into the price return.

    Numerous academic studies have analyzed the

    commodity markets using equally weighted returns

    o a commodity basket. For example, Bodie and

    Rosansky (1980) constructed an equally weightedcommodities return series using quarterly data rom

    1950 through 1976. Fama and French (1987) reported

    average monthly excess returns or 21 commodities

    as well as or an equally weighted portolio. Unless

    otherwise noted, rom here on, when reerring to

    commodities utures returns, we are reerring to

    returns as measured by the perormance o our

    newly constructed commodities return series.

    Commodity futures versus spot returns:

    Case for insurance-risk premium

    The previous section included a hypothetical

    example o how an investor in commodity utures

    could potentially expect to earn a positive return

    when commodity prices are alling. To illustrate the

    impact o an insurance-risk premium in a delationary

    market, consider the crude oil market. Figure 4, on

    page 8, compares the cumulative returns o a ully

    collateralized investment in crude oil utures with

    that o physical crude oil rom April 30, 1983, through

    April 30, 2009. Taking a conservative approach, we

    ignored the costs o physical storage, insurance,

    and shipping, and so on, which would otherwisehave reduced the returns o the physical crude.

    Nevertheless, despite a high monthly correlation

    between spot and utures returns (0.97), the total

    average annual return or a spot investment (2.1%)

    was but a raction o the utures average annual

    return (11.6%). In act, or a signiicant portion o

    this time (April 30, 1983December 31, 1998), spot

    oil prices were actually declining. For the ull, nearly

    16-year, period, active spot investment produced

    an annual total return o 5.7%, while the annual

    return o utures investments over the same period

    was 7.1%. This example illustrates the case or an

    insurance-risk premium or long-only investors in

    commodity utures, even during delationary

    market conditions.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    7/24

    Commodity futures and coverage data for our commodities return seriesFigure 3.

    Cumulative annualized

    Contracts excess returns (inception

    Name start date Sector through April 30, 2009) t-Statistic

    Aluminum 6/1/1987 Industrial metals 2.7% 0.02

    Coal 7/12/2001 Energy 6.1% 0.18

    Cocoa 7/1/1959 Sots 0.4% 0.98

    Coee 8/16/1972 Sots 0.4% 1.17

    Copper 7/1/1959 Industrial metals 7.7% 2.83*

    Corn 7/1/1959 Grains 5.4% 0.89

    Cotton 7/1/1959 Industrial materials 1.2% 0.47

    Crude oil 3/30/1983 Energy 6.4% 1.78

    Feeder cattle 11/30/1971 Animal products 1.5% 1.08

    Gold 12/31/1974 Precious metals 1.4% 0.15

    Heating oil 11/14/1978 Energy 5.5% 1.76

    Lean hogs 2/28 /1966 Animal products 2.5% 1.49

    Live cattle 11/30/1964 Animal products 4.4% 2.21*

    Lumber 10/1/1969 Industrial materials 7.9% 0.81

    Natural gas 4/4/1990 Energy 13.5% 0.08

    Nickel 4/23/1979 Industrial metals 0.9% 1.04

    Oats 7/1/1959 Grains 6.3% 0.58

    Orange juice 2/1/1967 Sots 0.4% 0.89

    Palladium 1/3/1977 Precious metals 0.3% 1.08

    Platinum 3/4/1968 Precious metals 0.5% 1.03

    Propane 8/21/1987 Energy 13.5% 2.16*

    Rough rice 8/20 /1986 Grains 7.8% 0.89

    Silver 6/12/1963 Precious metals 1.7% 0.66

    Soybean meal 7/1/1959 Grains 3.8% 1.88

    Soybean oil 7/1/1959 Grains 0.9% 1.13

    Soybeans 7/1/1959 Grains 4.6% 2.01*

    Sugar 1/4/1961 Sots 3.6% 0.83

    Unleaded gasoline 12/3/1984 Energy 11.2% 2.33*

    Wheat 7/1/1959 Grains 4.4% 0.52

    Zinc 1/3/1977 Industrial metals 0.5% 0.54

    Notes: The second column provides the date w hen price quotes were first available for various commodities. The fourth column reports cumulative annualized excess

    returns (over the 3-month Treasury bill return). T he last column reports t-statistics for testing the statistical significance of the average excess return (the five

    commodities found to have significant excess returns are denoted by an asterisk).

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    8/24

    8

    Cumulative returns of long crude oil futures versus long crude oil (log scale):

    April 30, 1983, through April 30, 2009

    Figure 4.

    Cumulative returns

    10

    100

    1,000

    10,000

    1983 1985 1987 1989 20091991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007

    Crude oil futures Crude oil spot

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau data.

    Year

    Cumulative real returns of historical commodity futures and equities (inflation-adjusted):

    August 31, 1959, through April 30, 2009

    Figure 5.

    Cumulative real returns

    0

    500

    1,000

    1,500

    2,000

    2,500

    3,000

    1959 1964 1969 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 20041974

    Year

    Commodities Equities

    Note: Equity returns for this and subsequent figures in this paper are based on the following equity series: pre-1971: Standard & Poors 500

    Index; 1971 through April 22, 2005, Dow Jones Wilshire 5000 Index; April 23, 2005, through April 30, 2009, MSCI US Broad Market Index.

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    9/24

    Bursting the commodities bubbles?

    As noted early in this paper, some investors hold

    that commodities high historical returns can be

    attributed primarily to two commodity bubbles,

    and that, outside o those periods, returns are

    unattractive. This sections discussion reveals that

    this argument is alse, based on an analysis o the

    historical record.

    For the period August 31, 1959, through April 30,

    2009, commodity utures (i.e., our commodities

    return series) have produced an average annual

    return o 9.8%, which is comparable to the 9.0%

    average annual return or U.S. equities or the same

    period. Figure 5 plots the cumulative real returns

    (net o inlation) o commodities and equities or

    August 31, 1959, through April 30, 2009.

    Identifying historical subperiods

    for the commodities return series

    To isolate historical episodes or commodity

    returns, we divided the 51-year period covered by

    our commodities return series into ive subperiods,

    to capture the dierent cycles experienced by the

    commodity utures markets. Figure 6 plots these

    subperiods and the corresponding annual returns

    or investors. Over the irst subperiodAugust 31,

    1959, through December 31, 1971the average

    annual return or commodity utures was 7.7%,

    similar to the 8.0% average annual return o U.S.equities or the same period. The next subperiod

    January 31, 1972, through December 31, 1973

    saw commodities utures return 58.5%. Clearly,

    this was a time o abnormally high returns or

    commodities, particularly compared with the 2.0%

    return o U.S. equities or the same period. Over

    the third subperiodJanuary 31, 1974, through

    December 31, 2003commodity utures returned

    9.1%, a ew points below the corresponding equities

    result o 12.3%. For the next subperiodJanuary 31,

    2004, through June 30, 2008commodity utures

    advanced 19.5%, a high result compared with the

    corresponding equities return o 6.0%. Over the inal

    subperiod analyzedJuly 31, 2008, through April

    30, 2009commodity utures returned 51.5%, a

    low result compared with the corresponding equities

    return o 35.1%. (Note: All returns in this paragraph

    are average annual returns or the periods stated.)

    High historical real returns for commodities: A result of two commodity bubbles?

    (August 31, 1959, through April 30, 2009)

    Figure 6.

    Cumulative real returns

    0

    500

    1,000

    1,500

    2,000

    2,500

    3,000

    1959 1964 1969 1979 1984 1989 1994 1999 20041974

    Year

    Note: Return figures are average annual nominal returns for the period.

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

    August 31, 19591971: 7.7%

    January 31, 19721973: 58.5%

    January 31, 19742003: 9.1%

    January 31, 2004June 30, 2008: 19.5% July 31, 2008April 30, 2009:51.5%

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    10/24

    The bubble of the early 1970s

    As stated, it has been argued that two o the

    ive subperiods19721973 and 20042008

    are commodity bubbles. To analyze this historical

    phenomenon urther, we examined these two

    periods more closely.

    The irst period, January 31, 1972, through

    December 31, 1973, can be associated with two

    major events in the history o inance. The irst

    event was the all o the Bretton Woods monetary

    management system. It should be noted, however,

    that the high returns o commodities or this period

    cannot be attributed directly to luctuations in the

    price o gold, as gold utures contracts were not

    introduced until 1975 and thus were not part o

    the equally weighted commodities return seriesin 19721973.6

    The other major historical event o 19721973 was

    the irst oil shock: In October 1973, members o the

    Organization o Arab Petroleum Exporting Countries

    (OAPEC, consisting o the Arab members o OPEC

    plus Egypt and Syria) proclaimed an oil embargo.

    Again, as in the case o gold, no energy utures were

    traded in the 1970s; as indicated in Figure 3, crude

    oil contracts were not available until 1983. Thus, to

    claim that the high prices o gold and energy were

    responsible or commodity utures returns in the

    period is incorrect.

    To better understand the period, we looked at the

    average annual returns o individual commodities or

    the two years (see Figure 7). As the igure shows,

    no single commodity caused the high returns. Wheat

    garnered the best return, but other grains also

    experienced unusually high results. Gorton, Hayashi,

    and Rouwenhorst (2008) postulated that these

    high returns were generated by broad inventory

    shortages in a number o commodities, which led

    to higher uncertainty in the market, greater risk or

    long investors to insure, and temporarily higher risk

    premiums or long investors. Thus, according to this

    theory, these exceptional returns were the result o

    undamental actors, and were not speculative in

    nature. Supporting the view that this isolated period

    o rocketing returns was not a bubble is that there

    was no corresponding correction, no subsequent

    crash in returns to support the notion o a bubble

    to begin with.

    6 Even after adjusting for inflation, the overall return for commodities for the period was 50.1%.

    10

    Selected individual commodity returns:

    19721973

    Figure 7.

    Average annual returns

    (January 31, 1972, through

    Commodity December 31, 1973)Silver 52%

    Platinum 18%

    Live cattle 17%

    Lean hogs 46%

    Feeder cattle 36%

    Corn 51%

    Soybeans 70%

    Soybean oil 82%

    Wheat 113%

    Soybean meal 81%

    Oats 29%Cocoa 81%

    Coee 4%

    Sugar 38%

    Orange juice 16%

    Cotton 99%

    Lumber 56%

    Copper 59%

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau;

    Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    11/24

    The bubble of the early 2000s

    Over the second historical period (January 31,

    2004, through June 30, 2008 ), commodities

    experienced annual returns o 19.5%. Figure 8

    reports selected commodity-level average annual

    returns or this period. Clearly, the returns weredominated by the energy sector; however, copper,

    oats, soybean oil, silver, and platinum also had

    impressive returns. In contrast to the 1970s,

    commodity utures returns underwent a dramatic

    correction during the period July 2008 through

    April 2009, which strongly suggests that there was

    a signiicant bubble component to the 20042008

    returns. Nevertheless, i we ignore the period o

    the irst bubble (January 31, 1972December 31,

    1973), commodity utures produced a solid average

    annual return o 8.7% or the period August 31,

    1959December 31, 2003. I we urther ignore both

    bubbles rom the sample (while retaining the

    recent 20082009 correction), commodity utures

    have produced an average annual return o 7.1% or

    the period August 31, 1959, through April 30, 2009

    (taking out 19721973 and January 31, 2004, through

    June 30, 2008). These data support the view that

    high historical returns or commodities cannot just be

    attributed primarily to two commodity bubbles, and

    that, outside o those periods, long-only investors

    still have earned signiicant positive returns.

    Commodity futures versus equities:

    Comparing returns and volatility

    As the preceding analysis suggests, there is little

    validity to the claim that a ew historical periods have

    determined returns or commodities utures. In act,

    investors can point to a long period o substantial

    returns rom commodities utures. Clearly, the

    early 1970s was a unique time or commodities.

    Although we have reuted the notion that 1972 and

    1973 represented a bubble, one still has to question

    whether that kind o return can happen again.

    1

    Selected individual commodity returns:

    20042008

    Figure 8.

    Average annual returns

    (January 31, 2004, through

    Commodity June 30, 2008Crude oil 33%

    Heating oil 36%

    Natural gas 19%

    Gasoline 33%

    Coal 26%

    Propane 38%

    Gold 19%

    Silver 26%

    Platinum 27%

    Palladium 19%

    Live cattle 11%Lean hogs 2%

    Feeder cattle 15%

    Corn 8%

    Soybeans 17%

    Soybean oil 20%

    Wheat 6%

    Soybean meal 13%

    Oats 23%

    Rough rice 12%

    Cocoa 18%

    Coee 10%Sugar 8%

    Orange juice 12%

    Cotton 9%

    Lumber 14%

    Copper 49%

    Zinc 16%

    Nickel 16%

    Aluminum 15%

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau;

    Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    12/24

    I we ignore the high returns o the 1970s, the

    period January 31, 1980, through April 30, 2009,

    provided average annual commodity returns o

    6.2%, as opposed to 10.3% or U.S. equities;

    however, during this period, our analysis shows that

    commodities had 25% lower volatility than

    equities (sources: calculations based on CommodityResearch Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters).

    This brings us to a more in-depth look at returns

    and volatility or commodity utures versus equities.

    As reported in the previous section, average annual

    historical returns or commodity utures (9.8%) and

    U.S. equities (9.0%) are comparable. To compare the

    perormance o the two asset classes more closely,

    Figure 9 plots their historical 12-month returns rom

    May through April (that is, the irst 12-month period

    is deined as beginning on May 31, 1960, and the

    inal 12-month period ends on April 30, 2009, just

    to include the last data point in our sample, which

    is April 2009; the results are similar, however, i we

    deine the 12 months as the calendar year). This

    graph is also important to address the myth that

    commodities have returns only once in 20 years,

    and then only poor returns or the next 20 years.

    At irst glance, its diicult to tell in Figure 9 which

    plotted time series is commodities utures and which

    one is equities. The giveaway is the outlier in 1972

    and 1973, in which commodities had returns o more

    than 50% in one year. The igure reveals that both

    commodities and equities have had multiple years

    o returns in the 20%40% range. These multiyear

    runs contradict the view that one has to endure zero

    returns or decades beore experiencing any positive

    returns in commodities.

    12

    Twelve-month returns for commodity futures versus equities: May 31, 1960, through April 30, 2009Figure 9.

    Returns

    April1961

    April1965

    April1969

    April1973

    April1977

    April1985

    April1989

    April1993

    April1997

    April2005

    April2009

    April2001

    April1981

    60

    40

    20

    0

    20

    40

    60%

    Commodities Equities

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    13/24

    Figure 10 plots a histogram o monthly returns or

    commodities and equities, and Figure 11 shows

    summary statistics o the monthly data. Several

    things stand out: First, equities have a slightly longer

    negative tail, and commodities have a slightly longer

    positive tail. Second, while equities have returns

    that are comparable to those o commodities utures,they have had higher volatility. Third, commodities

    utures have positive skewness, while equities have

    negative skewness.

    Potential diversification benefits

    of commodity futures

    Advocates o commodity utures have argued that

    commodities provide diversiication because o their

    low correlation with equities and bonds, while critics

    point out that the historical diversiication argument

    is no longer valid, since the correlations have

    increased signiicantly; urther, they claim there are

    no diversiication beneits during deep recessions.

    1

    Histogram of commodity futures and equity monthly returns: August 31, 1959, through April 30, 2009Figure 10.

    Returns

    < 20% > 20%20%, 15% 15%, 10% 10%, 5% 5%, 0% 5%, 10% 10%, 15% 15%, 20%0%, 5%

    0

    20

    40

    60%

    Volatility

    Commodities: slightly longer positive tailEquities: slightly longer negative tail

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

    Comparing commodity futures and

    equity monthly returns: Summary statistics

    (August 1959 through April 2009)

    Figure 11.

    Commodity

    utures Equities

    Monthly average returns 0.85% 0.82%

    Standard deviation 3.70% 4.40%

    Skewness 0.26 0.66

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau;

    Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    14/24

    During negative shocks for equities

    This section irst addresses the potential

    diversiication beneits o commodities during

    negative shocks or equities, when the diversiication

    beneits really matter. Figure 12 reports the average

    monthly returns or domestic equities, commodities,

    and international equities or months when these

    securities experienced extreme negative and/or

    positive shocks. The analysis covers two timeperiods: the ull historical sample rom August 31,

    1959, through April 30, 2009 (the igure doesnt

    include international equity returns or this period),

    and the inal decade starting January 31, 1999.

    For the longer historical period, while the average

    monthly return or the worst 12 domestic-equity

    months was 12.6%, commodities utures declined

    at a much smaller average monthly rate o 1.1%.

    The relative picture is not as clear over the inal

    decade: The worst 12-month average monthly

    return or domestic equities was 9.6% (international

    equities, 9.7%), while or the same 12 months,

    commodities lost an average o 2.7% per month.

    Figure 12 indicates that even though commodities

    experienced modest declines or the worst months

    o domestic equities, commodities still provided

    some diversiication beneit, since or the same

    months international equities declined 9.7% permonth. O course, commodities have not always

    perormed well during equity-market downturns;

    thus, or investors concerned about worst-case

    outcomes, diversiiers such as cash may be more

    eective. However, the signiicantly lower overall

    returns or holding cash make the reliable protection

    it oers more costly over time.

    14

    Worst 12 equity months Best 12 equity months

    Domestic Commodity International Domestic Commodity International

    Period equity returns utures returns equity returns equity returns utures returns equity returns

    August 31, 1959April 30, 2009 12.6% 1.1% 11.7% 0.7%

    January 31, 1999April 30, 2009 9.6% 2.7% 9.7% 7.5% 1.6% 6.6%

    Worst 12 commodity utures months Best 12 commodity utures months

    Domestic Commodity International Domestic Commodity International

    Period equity returns utures returns equity returns equity returns utures returns equity returns

    August 31, 1959April 30, 2009 4.0% 9.8% 1.4% 12.2%

    January 31, 1999April 30, 2009 4.9% 7.4% 7.1% 0.1% 6.9% 1.5%

    Notes: International equities are represented by the MSCI EAFE + EM Index. As this index does not go back to the 1950s, the international equity returns are reported

    only for the more recent sample.

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

    Average monthly returns for domestic equities, commodity futures, and international equities

    during their 12-worst and 12-best months (selected periods)

    Figure 12.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    15/24

    Correlation of U.S. equities

    with commodities versus international stocks

    What about the correlation o monthly U.S. equity

    returns and commodity utures returnsand,

    or urther comparison, o domestic equities and

    international equities? The results o our analysisin Figure 13show that the historical correlation

    o U.S. equity and commodity utures returns has

    been very low; or the period August 31, 1959,

    through April 30, 2009, the correlation was only 0.13.

    However, the correlation has risen steadily over time.

    For January 31, 2001, through April 30, 2009, the

    correlation was much higher, at 0.37. Many investors

    conidently include exposure to international equities

    or diversiication purposes; however, the correlation

    o international equity returns with U.S. equities

    has also increased over time. From January 31,

    2001, through April 30, 2009, the correlation o

    international equity returns with U.S. equities was

    0.90, ar higher than the 0.37 or commodity utures.

    The purpose o this analysis is not to suggest that

    investors should abandon international stocks as

    potential diversiiers in avor o commodities; ater

    all, commodities have been experiencing increasing

    correlation with equities over time.

    Commodity futures can lessen volatility

    of all-equity andstock/bond portfolios

    Another way to characterize the diversiicationbeneits o commodity utures is to analyze

    the impact o including commodities utures on

    the historical volatility o a diversiied portolio.

    Figure 14, on page 16, reports the average

    annualized change in portolio volatility as commodity

    utures are added to the asset mix. We considered

    two hypothetical base portolios, one all equities and

    the other 60% equities/40% bonds (in the second

    example, as we added commodities to the portolio,

    we assumed the mix o stocks and bonds in the rest

    o the portolio was let constant, at 60%/40%).

    Figure 14 is based on data rom January 31, 1974,through April 30, 2009 (however, results are similar

    or the ull historical period beginning in 1959). For

    this exercise, we excluded the market conditions

    o the early 1970s to show that, as with returns,

    diversiication beneits are not dependent on a

    ew historical periods. In our hypothetical example,

    adding commodities to the portolio clearly had the

    potential to reduce the portolios volatility. Even or

    the 60% stocks/40% bonds portolio, which has

    much lower volatility than the all-equity portolio,

    1

    Comparing correlation of domestic equities

    with commodities, international equities

    (selected periods)

    Figure 13.

    Correlation

    Correlation of U.S. equities with commodities

    Correlation of U.S. equities with international equities

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research

    Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

    0

    20

    40

    60

    80

    100%

    Aug. 1959April 2009

    Jan. 1971April 2009

    Jan. 1981April 2009

    Jan. 1991April 2009

    Jan. 2001April 2009

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    16/24

    16

    signiicant diversiication gains could have resulted

    rom adding commodities. For example, adding

    10%20% commodities would potentially have

    reduced volatility in the 60%/40% portolio by about

    1 percentage point and almost twice that or the

    all-equity portolio (see Figure 14).

    Figure 15 reports the hypothetical impact o a 20%

    exposure to commodities on portolio returns andvolatility. The irst two columns report total returns,

    standard deviations, and Sharpe ratios or the all-

    equity and 60%/40% equity/bond portolios. The

    next two columns report total returns or these

    two portolios ater adding a 20% exposure to

    commodities. In this hypothetical example, the

    eect on perormance o adding commodities tothe portolio was marginal; average returns improved

    by roughly 50 basis points. However, the potential

    impact on volatility was highly signiicant. Adding

    commodities to the all-equity portolio increased the

    Sharpe ratio rom 0.29 to 0.35. Another interesting

    comparison is 100% equity exposure versus 80%

    exposure to the 60% equity/40% bond portolio and

    20% commodity exposure. The returns o the two

    portolios are comparable (equity portolio returns

    are potentially higher by 11 basis points), while the

    diversiied portolio potentially has 41% less volatility.

    To urther understand the undamental source o

    diversiication beneits o commodity utures, we

    compared the equity and commodity utures returns

    during dierent stages o the business cycle.

    Adding commodity futures can benefit

    during different stages of business cycle

    It is also instructive to look at the relationship o

    commodity utures returns and equities over a

    typical business cycle. As identiied by the National

    Bureau o Economic Research (NBER), the businesscycle can be divided into our stages: late expansion,

    early recession, late recession, and early expansion.

    Figure 16 illustrates these patterns using the

    historical record.

    As shown in Figure 16, during late expansion and

    beore the onset o recession, the equity market

    has tended to experience low returns, which

    continue during the early part o the recession.

    Further, because equities are a leading indicator

    o the business cycle, equity markets tend to

    recover beore a recession is over; also, during

    the late-recession period, equities have typically

    Average annualized change in portfolio

    volatility as a result of adding commodities:

    January 31, 1974, through April 30, 2009

    Figure 14.

    Annualized volatility change relative

    to no-commodities portfolio

    100% equities 60% equities/40% bonds

    Percentage of portfolio in commodities

    100%90%0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80%

    6

    4

    2

    0

    2

    4%

    Notes: This hypothetical illustration does not represent the return on

    any particular investment.

    Corporate bond returns for this and subsequent figures in this paper

    are based on the following series: before 1968, Standard & Poors

    High Grade Corporate Index; 19691972, Citigroup High Grade Index;

    and January 1, 1973, through April 30, 2009, Barclays Capital U.S.

    Credit Bond Index.

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau;

    Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    17/24

    7 For details, see Gorton et al. (2008).

    experienced higher returns. Commodities utures,

    however, have behaved very dierently rom equitiesover the course o the business cycle. Commodity

    utures returns are plausibly linked to the state o

    inventories in the economy,7 and their returns can

    thereore be expected to be a lagging indicator

    o recession.

    Thus, during the late-expansion period (anticipating a

    recession), while equity markets tend to experience

    relatively poor returns, low inventory levels would

    imply that commodity utures are experiencing

    higher-than-normal returns. Further, because o

    inertia in inventories, it is not until a recession sets

    in that commodities experience low returns. As

    stated, coming out o a recession, equities have

    tended to revive beore the recession ends, while

    commodities utures returns have tended to improve

    only ater the early expansion period has begun.

    To deine earlyand laterecession, we divided

    each o the eight recessions rom 1959 through

    2009 into two equal halves. For example, or the

    2001 recession that lasted rom April to November,

    we deined the period o April 2001 through

    July 2001 as early recession, and August 2001

    through November 2001 as late recession. For the

    current recession, we deined the irst 12 months

    (January 2008 through December 2008) as earlyrecession, and January 2009 through April 2009

    as late recession. For the expansionary period, the

    12 months beore a recession were deined as late

    expansion, and the 12 months ater a recession as

    early expansion.

    1

    80% (60% equities/

    60% equities/ 80% equities/ 40% bonds)/

    100% equities 40% bonds 20% commodities 20% commoditiesTotal return 9.05% 8.45% 9.51% 8.94%

    Standard deviation 15.34% 10.46% 12.86% 8.98%

    Sharpe ratio 0.29 0.31 0.35 0.40

    Note: This hypothetical illus tration does not represent the return on any particular investment. The first t wo columns report total returns, standard deviations,

    and Sharpe ratios for the all-equity and 60%/40% equity/bond port folio. The next two columns report the same for these two portfolios after adding a 20% exposure to

    commodities.

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

    Effects on portfolio returns and Sharpe ratios of adding commodities to portfolio:

    August 31, 1959, through April 30, 2009

    Figure 15.

    Potential diversification benefits of

    integrating commodities with equities during

    different stages of business cycle

    Figure 16.

    Note: NBER, National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Source: Vanguard.

    Late expansion(High commodityreturns, lowequity returns)

    Early recession

    Earlyexpansion

    Late recession(Low commodityreturns, high equityreturns)

    NBER Peak

    NBER Trough

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    18/24

    Figure 17 reports equity and commodity utures

    returns during the dierent stages o the business

    cycle: We analyzed the eight recessions since 1959,and we also segregated the last three recessions (all

    three occurring ater 1990). During the late-recession

    period, the average annual return or equities was

    32.39%, while commodities declined 1.14%. During

    the late-expansion period, although equities had

    started their decline and experienced average annual

    returns o 1.72%, commodity utures markets were

    actually booming, with average annual returns o

    22.67%. These results were robust, and the pattern

    persisted or the shorter period o three recessions

    since 1990, including the current recession. In the

    current recession, equities peaked in October 2007,beore the start o the recession, and commodities

    peaked in June 2008, six months ater the economy

    was in recession. For the period November 2007 to

    June 2008, the average monthlyreturn or equities

    was 1.98%, while that or commodities was 3.11%.

    The results o this section suggest that

    commodities can have diversiication beneits

    because commodities behave undamentally

    dierently than equities at dierent stages o the

    business cycle. Note, however, that this analysis can

    only become clear in hindsight. Predicting periods o

    outperormance or underperormance or any asset

    class can be extremely diicult, i not impossible.

    Commodity futures returns and inflation

    Inlation is a serious concern or investors who care

    about the real purchasing power o their returns.Given the relationship between commodity utures

    returns and the stages o the business cycle, it

    is instructive to explore the relationship between

    commodity returns and inlation. Many traditional

    asset classes are a poor hedge against inlation

    at least over short- and medium-term horizons.

    Figure 18, which reports the correlation o inlation

    with commodity utures, equities, and bond returns,

    suggests that commodity utures might be a slightly

    better inlation hedge than stocks or bonds. We

    calculated correlations at monthly as well as rolling

    quarterly and annual horizons.

    18

    Eight recessions since 1959 Last three recessions, since 1990

    Equities Bonds Commodities Equities Bonds Commodities

    Late expansion 1.72% 1.01% 22.67% 5.40% 7.84% 10.74%

    Early recession 25.04% 3.03% 4.48% 27.88% 1.57% 18.05%

    Late recession 32.39% 20.30% 1.14% 14.62% 9.41% 14.74%

    Early expansion 13.68% 8.64% 5.48% 0.09% 9.37% 7.91%

    Note: This table reports equity and commodity futures returns during different stages of the business cycle. To define early and late recession, we divided each of

    the historical recessions into two equal halves. The 12-month period before a recession was defined as late expansion, and the 12-month period after a recession

    was defined as early expansion. All returns are average annualized returns.

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

    Business cycle and diversification benefits of commoditiesFigure 17.

    Correlation of equities, bonds, and

    commodity return series with inflation:

    August 31, 1959, through April 30, 2009

    Figure 18.

    Equities Bonds Commodities

    Monthly requency 0.09 0.10 0.08

    Quarterly requency 0.05 0.14 0.25

    Annual requency 0.10 0.25 0.34

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau;

    Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    19/24

    Although it appears that commodity utures come

    out in ront o equities and bonds as an inlation

    hedge, the asset class is not a perect hedge or

    inlation. To the extent that commodity utures

    represent a bet on commodity prices, they are

    directly linked to the undamental components oinlation. However, they do not provide a hedge

    against certain other components o inlation, such

    as increasing health cost. Further, because utures

    prices include inormation about oreseeable trends

    in commodity prices, commodity utures returns are

    likely to rise and all with unexpected components

    o inlation. A detailed analysis o the relationship

    o commodity utures returns to inlation is beyond

    the scope o this paper, and is a subject o uture

    research. I the investors primary objective is

    to obtain an inlation hedge, then, clearly, TIPS

    (Treasury Inlation Protected Securities) would be

    a much better option.

    Conclusion

    This paper has addressed the attractiveness o a

    broadly diversiied portolio o commodity utures

    as an asset class. It is critical to understand that

    an investment in commodity utures does not

    represent direct exposure to physical commodities.

    Commodities utures prices are set in relation to

    expected spot prices at maturity, and not to current

    spot prices. A historical analysis o commoditiesutures return patterns suggests there is little

    merit in the argument that relatively high long-term

    average commodities utures returns are solely a

    result o a ew brie abnormal periods o high

    returns. Commodities utures have experienced long

    periods o signiicant returns or investors, as well as

    sequences o booms and busts similar to equities.

    Historically, commodity utures returns and equity

    returns have had very low correlation, and although

    this correlation has risen over time, recent data

    suggest the correlation between equities and

    commodities utures is lower than that between

    equities and other broadly accepted diversiiers,

    such as international equity. In addition, while

    equities are leading indicators o the business

    cycle, commodity utures have tended to be lagging

    indicators. There is no reason to expect that this

    relationship to the business cycle will change.

    This would suggest that uture corrections between

    equities and commodity utures could remain

    relatively low, oering potential diversiication

    beneits to investors who are willing to accept the

    unique risks and opportunities o this asset class.

    References

    Bodie, Zvi, and Victor Rosansky, 1980. Risk and

    Return in Commodity Futures. Financial Analysts

    Journal(May/June): 2739.

    Davis, Joseph H., and Roger Aliaga-Daz, 2009.

    The Global Recession and International Investing.

    Valley Forge, Pa.: Vanguard Investment Counseling

    & Research, The Vanguard Group.

    Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1987.

    Commodity Futures Prices: Some Evidence on

    Forecast Power, Premiums, and the Theory o

    Storage. Journal of Business60: 5573.

    Gorton, Gary, and K. Geert Rouwenhorst, 2006.

    Facts and Fantasies about Commodity Futures.

    Financial Analysts Journal62(2): 4768.

    Gorton, Gary, Fumio Hayashi, and K. Geert

    Rouwenhorst, 2008. The Fundamentals of

    Commodity Futures Returns. Yale ICF WorkingPaper No. 07-08. New Haven, Conn.:

    Yale University.

    Hicks, John R., 1939. Value and Capital. Oxord:

    Oxord University Press.

    Keynes, John M., 1930. A Treatise on Money,

    vol. 2. London: Macmillan Publishers.

    Santos, Joseph, 2008. A History o Futures Trading

    in the United States. In EH.Net Encyclopedia of

    Economic and Business History, edited by Robert

    Whaples, March 16; available at http://eh.net/

    encyclopedia/article/Santos.utures.

    Working, Holbrook, 1960. Speculation on

    Hedging Markets. Food Research Institute

    Studies1: 185220.

    1

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    20/24

    Appendix. Construction and methodology

    of the commodities return series

    We ollowed the methodology o Gorton and

    Rouwenhorst (2006) in constructing our equally

    weighted commodities return series. The steps in

    constructing the return series were:

    1. For each month, we constructed price returns on

    each commodity uture using the nearest contract

    not expiring in that month.

    2. For a mechanical trading strategy, on the last

    business day o the month beore the expiration

    date o a utures contract, we rolled the contract

    into the next nearest utures contract.

    3. Using monthly returns or each commodity utures

    contract, we constructed the return series by

    adding the monthly returns together or eachmonth and then dividing them by the number o

    commodities in the return series or that month.

    Thus, we essentially have an equally weighted

    indexing approach with monthly rebalancing.

    4. A commodity enters the return series on the

    last business day o the month ollowing its

    introduction date.

    5. Finally, to obtain the total returns o holding a

    ully collateralized commodity utures position,

    we added to the price returns the 3-month U.S.

    Treasury bill return.8

    Selection of commodities

    The list o 30 commodities that were selected or

    this study is based on most o the 23 commodities

    eligible for inclusion in the DJ-UBS Commodity

    Index (DJ-UBSCI). We augmented this list with nine

    more commodities: coal, eeder cattle, lumber, oats,

    orange juice, palladium, propane, rough rice, and

    soybean meal. Also, because o data limitations, we

    did not include tin and lead;9 tin and lead are part o

    the eligiblecommodities, but are not in the inal list

    o 19 commodities currentlyin the DJ-UBSCI.

    The reason we included the additional nine

    commodities was to broaden our commodities

    universe. Some o the commodities, like oats and

    soybean meal, have long trading histories going

    back to 1959. These additional nine commodities

    represent broad sectors o the commodities

    universe: energy (coal and propane), grains (oats,

    soybean meal, and rough rice), sots (orange juice),

    industrial materials (lumber), animal products (eeder

    cattle), and precious metals (palladium).

    To test the impact o membership o these

    30 commodities in our commodities return series,

    we constructed three series o returns, using

    the ive steps just described. The irst series is

    based on the 19 commodities currently in the

    DJ-UBSCI. The second series is based on just the

    21 commodities (not including tin and lead) eligible

    or inclusion in the DJ-UBSCI. The third series

    represents our broad-based commodities return

    series, which includes all 30 commodities listed

    in the text in Figure 3. Figure A-1 cites the total

    8 Source: http: //research.stlouisfed.org/fred2 /.

    9 These commodities are traded on the London Metal Exchange, and their data are not covered by the Commodity Research Bureau, our primary data source.

    20

    Commodity futures returns:

    Summary statistics (August 31, 1959,

    through April 30, 2009)

    Figure A-1.

    Commodities universe

    All 30DJ-UBSCI: DJ-UBSCI: commodities

    19 current 21 eligible in our

    commodities commodities* return series

    Total returns 10.52% 10.23% 9.85%

    Volatility 13.84% 13.58% 12.79%

    Sharpe ratio 0.40 0.39 0.38

    Correlation

    with equities 0.11 0.12 0.13

    *Does not include tin and lead (for explanation, see Appendix text).

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau;

    Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    21/24

    returns, volatility, Sharpe ratios, and correlation

    with equities or the three commodity return

    series rom August 31, 1959, through April 30,

    2009. The results were very similar or all three

    measures. The volatility o our commodities return

    series, however, was the lowest, because o theimpact o greater diversiication. Given this papers

    objective to study the behavior o commodities as

    a broad asset class, we thus avored the equally

    weighted return series based on all 30 commodities.

    Why equally weighted returns?

    Since our commodities return series is an

    equally weighted average o individual commodity

    returns, it is well-diversiied and represents the

    broad commodities market. Given equal weights,

    no one single commodity or sector can drive the

    results. However, one can still question whether

    the results o our analysis are conditional on

    the commodities return series. Recall the two

    components o our return series construction:

    equal weighting and monthly rebalancing (an

    outcome o the equally weighted average). Gorton

    and Rouwenhorst (2006) have shown that returns

    and volatility properties o commodity utures are

    robust to annual rebalancing as well. An alternative

    to equal weighting would be a weighting scheme

    such as that adopted by the DJ-UBSCI, whose

    weights are based on the production volume and/or liquidity o individual commodities. Serious data

    restrictions apply, however, in constructing such an

    index; urther, such backill could arguably amount to

    or lead to a data-mining eort; the agnostic, equally

    weighted approach has the virtue o simplicity and

    transparency. Later in this Appendix we nonetheless

    compare our commodities return series with both

    the DJ-UBSCI and the S&P-GSCI over the time

    period common to all three.

    Investability

    Could an investor have actually earned the returns

    shown by our return series? Like other indexes, the

    equally weighted return series results do not relect

    any transaction costs, which would apply in the real

    world. However, clearly, commodity utures marketshistorically have had the depth that an investable

    strategy requires. As documented by Santos (2008)

    and numerous others, the commodities markets in

    the United States have a long history, with trading

    in agricultural commodities voluminous even in the

    19th century. Santos reported that between 1884

    and 1888, the volume o grain (wheat, corn, oats,

    barley, and rye) utures traded in the U.S. market

    was eight times the average annual amount o crops

    produced. For cotton, by 1879 utures volume had

    outnumbered production by a actor o ive. Working

    (1960) estimated that or the period 19541958,

    the average dollar value o short hedging contracts

    or cotton, wheat, soybean, corn, and soybean oil

    was close to $500 million. Certainly a relatively

    small investor could have bought the contracts

    listed and analyzed in our commodities return series

    and endeavored to replicate the equal weighted

    methodology. But as with historical analysis o

    any asset class (e.g., stocks, bonds, or short-term

    debt), it is diicult, i not impossible, to know how

    the hypothetical development o a large, liquid, and

    institutionally dominated market would have aected

    past returns.

    Comparing commodities return series

    with DJ-UBSCI and S&P-GSCI

    DJ-UBSCI data are available rom 1991, and the

    index itsel was launched in 1998. S&P-GSCI

    data are available rom 1970, and the index was

    launched in 1992. This section compares the

    perormance o these two indexes with our equally

    weighted commodities return series on a number

    o parameters over the period common to all three

    2

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    22/24

    22

    measures: January 31, 1991, through April 30,

    2009. For this period the DJ-UBSCI and the

    commodities return series had a high correlation

    o 0.91 at monthly requency; the correlation

    with the S&P-GSCI was much lower, at 0.75 (see

    Figure A-2). As the igure shows, the commodities

    return series had a marginally higher correlation with

    domestic equities than did the DJ-UBSCI. In terms

    o inlation and bond returns, the DJ-UBSCI was

    correlated almost exactly (inlation) or exactly (bond

    returns) with the commodities return series.

    The DJ-UBSCI is well recognized as a broad-based

    commodities index, while the weighting structure

    o the S&P-GSCI makes it primarily an energy index.

    As o April 30, 2009, the energy subsector weightingin the S&P-GSCI was more then 70%, whereas the

    energy sector weighting in the DJ-UBSCI is capped

    at 33%. The DJ-UBSCIs greater diversiication

    makes it much less volatile than the S&P-GSCI.

    However, as shown in Figure A-3, the commodities

    return series is clearly the least volatile o the

    three measures; this is to be expected, given the

    equally weighted nature o the return series and the

    embedded diversiication beneits. Figure A-4 plots

    the cumulative returns o the three measures.

    Composition of commodities return series

    The composition o the commodities return series

    as constructed here changed signiicantly rom the

    1960s to the 1990s as dierent contracts were

    added to the return series. For example, or the irstsubperiod identiied in this paper (19591971), there

    were no energy utures contracts. It is possible that

    the historical return and diversiication properties

    o the return series are distorted owing to its

    composition.

    To address the issue o composition, we considered

    three subperiods (see Figure A-5). During the irst

    subperiod (1959 through 1971), commodities in the

    return series were cocoa, copper, corn, cotton, oats,

    soybean meal, soybean oil, soybeans, wheat, sugar,

    silver, live cattle, lean hogs, orange juice, platinum,

    and lumber. These commodities represented the

    ollowing sectors: sots, grains, industrial metals,

    industrial materials, animal products, and precious

    Commodities

    Domestic equities Inlation Bonds return series

    Commodities return series 0.28 0.22 0.16

    DJ-UBSCI 0.23 0.23 0.16 0.91

    S&P-GSCI 0.17 0.28 0.11 0.75

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

    Commodities return series, DJ-UBSCI, and S&P-GSCI: Correlation with domestic equities, inflation, and bonds

    (January 31, 1991, through April 30, 2009)

    Figure A-2.

    Commodities return series, DJ-UBSCI,

    and S&P-GSCI: Summary statistics

    (January 31, 1991, through April 30, 2009)

    Figure A-3.

    Commodities

    return series DJ-UBSCI S&P-GSCI

    Average 0.51% 0.44% 0.36%

    Variance 0.11% 0.17% 0.37%

    Skewness 0.95 0.66 0.46

    Kurtosis 5.65 3.16 1.88

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau;

    Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    23/24

    metals. Notable exceptions were gold and energy

    products, both o which were introduced in the

    second subperiod, 1975 through April 30, 2009;

    natural gas was added in 1990, and coal in 2001. The

    last subperiod, 1988 through April 30, 2009, included

    almost all o the energy contracts as well.

    For the irst subperiod, 1959 through 1971, the

    commodities return series had no energy or gold

    utures contracts; yet, it produced a return o 7.74%

    with a volatility o 8.68%; this was nearly equal to

    the 8.02% return o equities, which had a volatility

    o 12.92%. The higher volatility o the second and

    third subperiods has not just been a characteristic

    o commodities, however; all the asset classes have

    had higher volatility.

    2

    Commodities return series, DJ-UBSCI, and S&P-GSCI:

    Cumulative returns (January 31, 1991, through April 30, 2009)

    Figure A-4.

    Cumulative returns

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

    S&P-GSCICommodities return series DJ-UBSCI

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    600

    Year20081990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006

    Commodities

    Equities (%) Inlation (%) Bonds (%) return series (%)

    19591971 8.02 (12.92) 2.81 (0.7) 3.52 (5.38) 7.74 (8.68 )

    1975April 30, 2009 11.45 (15.84) 4.19 (1.14) 8.66 (7.3) 8.08 (12.45)

    1988April 30, 2009 8.57 (15.03) 2.90 (0.93) 7.35 (5.28) 6.86 (11.53)

    Sources: Vanguard calculations, based on Commodity Research Bureau; Datastream, Thomson Reuters.

    Total returns (volatility) for equities, inflation, bonds, and commodities return series: Subperiod analysisFigure A-5.

  • 8/3/2019 Commodities as Asset Class

    24/24

    Vanguard research >

    Vanguard Center for Retirement Research

    Vanguard Investment Counseling & Research

    Vanguard Investment Strategy Group

    E-mail> [email protected]

    The funds or securities referred to herein are not sponsored,

    endorsed, or promoted by MSCI, and MSCI bears no liability

    with respect to any such funds or securities. For any such

    funds or securities, the prospectus or the Statement of

    Additional Information contains a more detailed description

    of the limited relationship MSCI has with T he Vanguard Group

    and any related funds.

    Standard & Poors, S&P, and Standard & Poors 500are

    trademarks of The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc., and have

    been licensed for use by T he Vanguard Group, Inc. Vanguard

    mutual funds are not sponsored, endorsed, sold, or promoted

    by Standard & Poor s, and Standard & Poors makes no

    representation regarding the advisability of investing in

    the funds.

    P.O. Box 2900

    Valley Forge, PA 19482-290 0

    Connect with Vanguard > www.vanguard.com

    > global.vanguard.com (non-U.S. investors)