42
1 Stephanie Lee May, 2011 Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence from the Trading with the Enemy Act after World War II May, 2011 Stephanie Lee Economics Department Stanford University Stanford, CA 94305 [email protected] under the direction of Prof. Petra Moser ABSTRACT Compulsory licensing allows countries to produce patented foreign innovations without the consent of the foreign patent holders. During World War I and World War II, the Trading with the Enemy Act (TWEA) allowed the United States to vest all enemy-owned patents. The Alien Property Custodian systematically licensed the vested patents to U.S. firms. Moser and Voena (2010) found that compulsory licensing under the World War I TWEA increased U.S. domestic innovation by a minimum of 20 percent. My paper extends their analysis by examining how compulsory licensing under the World War II TWEA affected U.S. domestic innovation. During World War II, patents originally owned by Germany, Japan, and Italy were licensed to U.S firms. Did U.S. inventors face less economic incentive to produce domestic innovation because they could cheaply use foreign innovation after paying a low licensing fee? Or did compulsory licensing encourage domestic innovation (Moser and Voena, 2010)? For example, experience with producing foreign innovations could have encouraged the learning-by-doing of the compulsory licensees (Moser and Voena, 2010). To the extent that technologies were differently affected by the World War II TWEA, I use a difference-in-differences strategy to examine the effects of compulsory licensing on domestic innovation. My analysis provides evidence that compulsory licensing under the World War II TWEA had positive effects on domestic innovation activities. Keywords: Alien Property Custodian, patent law, innovation, invention, learning-by-doing, Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) Acknowledgements: I would like to thank Professor Petra Moser for her invaluable support, advice, and patience. I would also like to thank Professor Geoffrey Rothwell for his guidance and critical feedback. I am grateful to Professor Bruce Owen for his encouragement and inspiration.

Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

1

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation:

Evidence from the Trading with the Enemy Act after World War II

May, 2011

Stephanie Lee

Economics Department

Stanford University

Stanford, CA 94305

[email protected]

under the direction of

Prof. Petra Moser

ABSTRACT

Compulsory licensing allows countries to produce patented foreign innovations without the

consent of the foreign patent holders. During World War I and World War II, the Trading with

the Enemy Act (TWEA) allowed the United States to vest all enemy-owned patents. The Alien

Property Custodian systematically licensed the vested patents to U.S. firms. Moser and Voena

(2010) found that compulsory licensing under the World War I TWEA increased U.S. domestic

innovation by a minimum of 20 percent. My paper extends their analysis by examining how

compulsory licensing under the World War II TWEA affected U.S. domestic innovation. During

World War II, patents originally owned by Germany, Japan, and Italy were licensed to U.S firms.

Did U.S. inventors face less economic incentive to produce domestic innovation because they

could cheaply use foreign innovation after paying a low licensing fee? Or did compulsory

licensing encourage domestic innovation (Moser and Voena, 2010)? For example, experience

with producing foreign innovations could have encouraged the learning-by-doing of the

compulsory licensees (Moser and Voena, 2010). To the extent that technologies were differently

affected by the World War II TWEA, I use a difference-in-differences strategy to examine the

effects of compulsory licensing on domestic innovation. My analysis provides evidence that

compulsory licensing under the World War II TWEA had positive effects on domestic

innovation activities.

Keywords: Alien Property Custodian, patent law, innovation, invention, learning-by-doing,

Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS)

Acknowledgements: I would like to thank Professor Petra Moser for her invaluable support,

advice, and patience. I would also like to thank Professor Geoffrey Rothwell for his guidance

and critical feedback. I am grateful to Professor Bruce Owen for his encouragement and

inspiration.

Page 2: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

2

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Introduction

Compulsory licensing is when a government allows a third party to produce patented

product or process without the consent of the patent holder. The Agreement on Trade-Related

Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS), which came into effect in 1995 as part of the

Uruguay Round of trade discussions, is a modern treaty that specifically addresses compulsory

licensing (Bird and Cahoy, 2008). Article 31 permits WTO member states to issue compulsory

licensing under three circumstances: (1) “after efforts to obtain a license from the patent holder

on reasonable commercial terms and conditions have failed,” (2) “in situations of national

emergency or other circumstances of extreme urgency,” and (3) for public non-commercial use

(Bird and Cahoy, 2008). The World Trade Organization (WTO) Doha Declaration of 2001

endorsed developing countries’ rights to issue compulsory licensing when it proclaimed that

“each member has the right to grant compulsory licenses and the freedom to determine the

grounds upon which such licenses are granted.”

Developing countries including Thailand, India, South Africa, and Brazil have issued

compulsory licensing on patented pharmaceutical inventions to make HIV, AIDS, and malaria

drugs more affordable and accessible. For example, in 2007 Thailand issued compulsory

licensing on Abbot’s Kaletra and produced a generic version of Kaletra. Prior to compulsory

licensing, Thailand was not able to afford Kaletra for Thailand’s HIV patients, who received

treatment through the country’s universal healthcare system (Kaiser Daily HIV/AIDS Report,

2007). A generic version was sold at a price half of Kaletra’s (Chicago Tribune, 2007). In 2007,

Thailand estimated that the cheaper generic version increased the number of HIV patients who

received treatment by 400% (Ministry of Public Health and the National Health Security Office

Page 3: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

3

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

of Thailand).

Although developing countries that issue compulsory licensing enjoy an immediate

benefit of cheaply using an already existing innovation, the long-term effects of compulsory

licensing on innovation are highly controversial. Most prior studies have focused on the effects

compulsory licensing may have on the innovation of countries whose property rights are violated.

Some have argued that the violation of property rights will weaken the economic incentives to

invest (e.g., Bird and Cahoy, 2008, Fischs, 1994, Harris, 2009). Other studies have shown that

there is no decline in innovation by patent-owning companies affected by compulsory licensing

(e.g., Scherer, 1977, Chien, 2003). However, to examine the overall effects of compulsory

licensing on innovation, we need to be mindful that we are not simply looking at one aspect of

compulsory licensing.

To fully understand how compulsory licensing affects innovation, we also need to

examine its effects on innovation of countries that use compulsory licensing to cheaply access

foreign inventions. Although compulsory licensees still pay a licensing fee to a patent-holder, a

compulsory licensing fee is significantly low compared to a licensing fee under patent protection

(Danzon and Towse, 2005). Do compulsory licensees who benefit from compulsory licensing

face less economic incentive to produce domestic inventions because they can cheaply use

foreign innovation after paying a low licensing fee? Or does compulsory licensing encourage

compulsory licensees to invent more? (Moser and Voena, 2010) For example, experience with

producing foreign inventions can encourage the learning-by-doing of the compulsory licensees

(Moser and Voena, 2010). Economic literature suggests that learning-by-doing plays an integral

role in increasing productivity (e.g. Foster and Rosenzweig, 1995, Irwin and Klenow, 1994). In

addition, compulsory licensees can strengthen incentives to invest in skills and education

Page 4: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

4

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

(Landau, Mowery, and Rosenberg, 1992). My paper addresses these questions by studying the

compulsory licensing under the World War II Trading with the Enemy Act (TWEA).

The TWEA provides a rare opportunity to examine an exogenous event of compulsory

licensing. During World War I and World War II, the TWEA allowed the United States to vest

all enemy-owned patents. The TWEA was created to protect the U.S. from the war enemies and

to destroy “Germany’s great industrial army on American soil” (Alien Property Custodian, 1919,

p.14). As a part of the act, the vested patents were systematically licensed to U.S. firms. Moser

and Voena (2010) measure the effects of compulsory licensing under the World War I TWEA by

comparing the number of U.S. patents by domestic inventors before and after the TWEA in

treated and untreated chemical subclasses. Because different chemical United States Patent

Office (USPTO) subclasses were differently affected by the TWEA, Moser and Voena (2010)

use difference-in-differences and conclude that compulsory licensing had a strong and persistent

positive effect on domestic innovation. Moser and Voena (2010) show that in subclasses where

at least one enemy-owned patent was licensed to a domestic firm under the TWEA, domestic

patenting in the respective subclass increased by about 20 percent after the TWEA. The finding

is robust after controlling for pre-existing time-trends, tariffs, demand effects, patent novelty

(controlling for the remaining lifetime of patents), patent quality (controlling for license fees and

citation), triple differences, and placebo treatments.

This paper contributes to the existing literature by examining how U.S. domestic

inventions changed after the World War II TWEA. Under the authority of the World War II

TWEA, the Office of Alien Property Custodian was established in March 1942. Executive Order

No. 9139 authorized the Alien Property Custodian “to direct, manage, supervise, control or vest

[…] any patent, patent application” (Alien Property Custodian, 1943, p.4). As a result, patents

Page 5: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

5

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

originally owned by Germany, Japan, Italy, Hungary, Rumania, and Bulgaria were vested by the

Alien Property Custodian. If a difference-in-differences analysis using the World War II TWEA

data also shows that domestic invention increased more for technologies that benefitted more

from the TWEA, the argument that compulsory licensing can increase domestic invention would

be strengthened. The World War II data can be better than the World War I data. The World War

II data is larger and more recent. The World War I Alien Property Custodian seized

approximately 10,000 patents belonging to enemy aliens (Sommerich, 1955) while the World

War II Alien Property Custodian seized approximately 50,000 patents (Alien Property Custodian,

1943, p.1). Also, this paper extends the analysis of Moser and Voena (2010) by conducting an

economy-wide study of the effects of compulsory licensing. Because Moser and Voena (2010)

exclusively focus on chemical patents, their result can be specific to chemical class. My analysis,

which encompasses 144 different USPTO main classes, can help shed new light on how

compulsory licensing affects domestic invention.

The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. Literature Review summarizes key

economic literature on the effects of compulsory licensing. Arguments both for and against

compulsory licensing are introduced. Study Design details my paper’s methodology, which

builds on the analysis used in Moser and Voena (2010). Data Description summarizes my

dependent and independent variables. Analysis presents estimation results. Conclusion

summarizes the paper’s main findings.

Literature Review

The patent system was built to provide an economic incentive for innovation. Information

as a good has characteristics that set it apart from ordinary private goods. Information is a public

Page 6: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

6

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

good because it is non-excludable and non-rivalrous (Scotchmer, 2006). As a result, information

is under-produced in a competitive market (Scotchmer, 2006). To encourage innovation,

intellectual property protection offers a limited monopoly to patentees. Despite the deadweight

loss a monopoly creates, property protection has been widely accepted as a crucial solution to the

incentive problem. At the same time, fear that removing property protection will hurt innovation

has largely prevented the widespread use of compulsory licensing (Chien, 2003).

Opponents of compulsory licensing argue that the violation of property protection will

weaken the economic incentives to invent. Fisch (1994) argues that compulsory licensing of

pharmaceutical patents will significantly curtail future pharmaceutical research because

pharmaceutical industries are aware that breakthroughs may result in loss due to compulsory

licensing. Because the level of research expenditures directly corresponds to the creation of new

pharmaceuticals, a reduction in research expenditures can lead to a reduction of new

pharmaceuticals (e.g., Fisch, 1994, Schwartzman, 1975). In addition, compulsory licensing can

make other countries avoid engaging in foreign direction investment (FDI) with the nation

violating property protection (e.g., Bird and Cahoy, 2008, Lee and Mansfield, 1996). The

widespread usage of compulsory licensing will lead pharmaceutical companies and other

industries that depend on intellectual property protection to mistrust licensing nations’ promises

to protect patent rights and decrease their FDI (Bird and Cahoy, 2008). Because FDI is an

important source of economic growth for developing nations, the loss of FDI arising from

compulsory licensing can outweigh the benefit of cheaply accessing foreign patented innovation

(Bird and Cahoy, 2008).

Evidence on compulsory licensing’s effects on future research is controversial. Fisch

(1994) supports his argument that compulsory licensing will lower inventive activity by

Page 7: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

7

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian

legislation authorized compulsory licensing over pharmaceuticals under the Canadian Patent Act

(Chien, 2003). Canada routinely and widely used compulsory licensing. From 1969 to 1983,

almost 80% of the applications for compulsory licenses were granted, which amounts to

approximately twenty compulsory licenses per year on average (Chien, 2003). Fisch (1994) finds

that only three new pharmaceuticals were introduced in Canada during a 20-year period from

1969 to 1989. In contrast, 30 new pharmaceuticals were introduced in the United States in 1991

alone (Fisch, 1994). Fisch (2009) puts forth this finding as evidence against compulsory

licensing. Despite a large numerical difference between Canadian and American pharmaceuticals,

I am not completely convinced by Fisch’s argument. Canada’s low pharmaceutical innovations

may be driven by other factors, such as differences in technology, government funding, and luck.

In contrast to Fisch’s study, other studies show that compulsory licensing does not lead to

a decline in innovation. After comparing R&D intensities in Canada to R&D intensities in other

developed countries, the Eastman Commission study concludes that compulsory licensing did

not significantly affect innovation in Canada (Chien, 2003). The study demonstrates that the

Canadian pharmaceutical market was too small and insignificant relative to the worldwide

market to be negatively affected by compulsory licensing (Chien, 2003). In 1994, Canadian

R&D expenditures as a percentage of worldwide expenditures were less than 2% (McFetridge,

1998). I find the Eastman Commission study more convincing than Fisch’s study (1977) because

the Commission uses a better measure of inventive activities - R&D intensities - instead of the

number of new pharmaceuticals. Scherer (1977) examines about seven hundred U.S. companies,

forty-two of which were subject to compulsory licensing, to show that compulsory licensing does

not cause firms to invest less in R&D. For each company, Scherer (1977) calculates the ratio of

Page 8: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

8

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

R&D expenditures to sales for the year 1975. He then compares the ratios of companies that

were subject to significant compulsory licensing to the ratios of companies that were not subject

to compulsory licensing. On average, companies that were subject to compulsory licensing spent

more on R&D than similar firms that were not subject to compulsory licensing (Scherer, 1977).

This finding is true for all industries, including pharmaceuticals (Scherer, 1977).

Other studies show that compulsory licensing can negatively affect FDI. However, most

present evidence is anecdotal. Lee and Mansfield (1996) conduct a survey on one hundred

American firms. The selected firms are in the chemical, pharmaceutical, machinery, food, metals,

electrical equipment, and transportation industries. Lee and Mansfield (1996) review how

selected firms perceive intellectual property protection rights in various countries and how such

perceptions impact FDI decisions. Lee and Mansfield (1996) conclude that an increased

perception by firms that a given nation has strong intellectual property rights can lead to an

increase in as much as hundreds of millions of dollars in FDI. Conversely, weak intellectual

property rights can negatively affect FDI (Bird and Cahoy, 2008, Lee and Mansfield, 1996). Bird

and Cahoy (2008) argue that Egypt’s broad and ambiguous compulsory licensing statue can, in

part, explain decreasing FDI flows to Egypt. Despite the Egyptian government’s effort to attract

FDI, FDI continued to decline from $948 million in 1987 to $598 million in 1995 to $428.2

million in 2001 (Bird and Cahoy, 2008). Egypt’s flexible compulsory licensing allows the

government to issue compulsory licenses when drugs are placed outside the reach of most

consumers or when high prices are politically troublesome (Bird and Cahoy, 2008). Bird and

Cahoy (2008) argue that the mere presence of a broad compulsory license statue can negatively

affect investment climate and lower FDI flow into Egypt. In fact, the United States’ ambassador

to Egypt in 2001 stated that “Egypt’s ability to attract foreign investors in many fields will hinge

Page 9: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

9

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

on adequate protection of copyrights, patents, and other intellectual property” (Bird and Cahoy,

2008). The Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers Association of American (PhRMA)

also reports that Egypt’s weak intellectual property laws prevented PhRMA from investing $300

million in Egypt’s pharmaceutical sector (Bird and Cahoy, 2008). Despite the active discussions

surrounding compulsory licensing’s effects on FDI, there are no rigorous empirical studies that

test compulsory licensing’s effects on FDI.

Proponents of compulsory licensing, on the other hand, argue that countries that use

compulsory licensing to access foreign inventions can benefit from great welfare gains because

experience with producing foreign inventions will encourage the learning-by-doing of the

compulsory licensees (Moser and Voena, 2010). Learning-by-doing refers to the decline in

production costs resulting from greater experience with the production process (Irwin and

Klenow, 1994). Also, the licensees can benefits from the “spillover” effects of the original

innovation (Chien, 2003).

Prior studies show that compulsory licensing can have positive effects on the licensee

(Chaudhuri, Goldberg, and Jia, 2006, Moser and Voena, 2010). Chaudhuri, Goldberg, and Jia

(2006) conduct a case study of quinolones in the Indian pharmaceuticals market. Quinolones are

a family of synthetic antibiotics that are widely used in the pharmaceutical market. Although

quinolones were under patent in the U.S., India did not recognize patents for pharmaceuticals

between 1972 and 2005 (Chaudhuri, Goldberg, and Jia, 2006). The authors carry out

counterfactual simulations of what prices, profit, and consumer welfare would have been if

quinolone had been under patent in India (Chaudhuri, Goldberg, and Jia, 2006). As previously

introduced, Moser and Voena (2010) examine the effects of compulsory licensing on licensees

by studying compulsory licensing under the World War I TWEA. Moser and Voena (2010)

Page 10: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

10

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

examine changes in annual chemical patents by U.S. domestic inventors to measure the effects of

compulsory licensing under the World War I TWEA.

Chaudhuri, Goldberg, and Jia (2006) use product-level data on monthly pharmaceutical

prices and sales from January 1999 to December 2000 to estimate demand and supply for

quinolones (Chaudhuri, Goldberg, and Jia, 2006). Afterward, the estimated demand and supply

were used to predict what would have happened if quinolones patents were enforced in India

(Chaudhuri, Goldberg, and Jia, 2006). Moser and Voena (2010) use difference-in-differences

across treated and untreated chemical patent subclasses. Subclasses are regarded as treated if the

subclass includes at least one enemy-owned patent that was licensed to a domestic firm. This

empirical strategy allows the authors to compare technological subfields that are subject to the

same shocks except for compulsory licensing. The data on treatment consist of 699 enemy-

owned chemical patents that were licensed to U.S. firms. The data on the outcome include all

165,400 U.S. patents (1875-1939) in 21 USPTO classes of organic chemicals (Moser and Voena,

2010).

Although Chaudhuri, Goldberg, and Jia (2006) analyze a contemporary event while

Moser and Voena (2010) analyze a historical event, both studies reach a similar conclusion.

Chaudhuri, Goldberg, and Jia (2006) find that patent enforcement would result in an enormous

welfare loss for the Indian economy. The estimated loss ranges from $144 million to $450

million annually (Chaudhuri, Goldberg, and Jia 2006). The authors also argue that an

overwhelming portion of welfare loss will result from the loss of consumer welfare (Chaudhuri,

Goldberg, and Jia, 2006). Moser and Voena (2010) show a high and statistically significant

correlation between compulsory licensing and patenting by domestic inventors. In chemical

subclasses where domestic firms received at least one enemy-owned patent, domestic inventors

Page 11: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

11

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

produced between 0.118 and 0.234 additional patents per year after 1919. This implies a 15 to 30

percent increase in domestic invention (Moser and Voena, 2010). Both studies suggest that

compulsory licensees can benefit from compulsory licensing.

The review of prior studies indicates that compulsory licensing is not a simple event with

a conclusive consequence. Some studies demonstrate that compulsory licensing can have

negative effects, while others show that compulsory licensing can have positive effects. Before

any consensus on the overall effects of compulsory licensing can be reached, more research

needs to be done. I wish that my analysis of the World War II TWEA can contribute to the

ongoing discussions on compulsory licensing.

Study Design

(1) The TWEA as a Natural Experiment

Most contemporary compulsory licensing decisions, such as Thailand’s decision to issue

compulsory licensing on Kaletra, are not completely exogenous because compulsory licensing is

issued after much deliberation. For example, a government may be more likely to issue

compulsory licensing on a highly-demanded innovation. To measure the effects of compulsory

licensing on domestic innovation, we need to analyze an exogenous event of compulsory

licensing. The timing of the TWEA and the types of technologies that were available for

licensing are exogenous. World War I and II triggered compulsory licensing, not the other way

around. Also, TWEA non-discriminatorily vested all enemy-owned patents.

The vested enemy-owned patents covered “inventions in every field of applied science

and represent millions of man-hours of research and the expenditure of many million dollars”

(Alien Property Custodian, 1943, p.1). The vested inventions included “some of the finest

Page 12: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

12

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

foreign research in modern science, particularly in the production of dyestuffs, plastics,

pharmaceuticals, and electrical goods” (Alien Property Custodian, 1943, p.1). For the war

purposes and for the general use in the national interest, vested patents were made cheaply

available to American industry. All patents classes were sold for 10 cents each, except nine

patent classes, which were sold 25 cents each (Alien Property Custodian, 1943).

In addition to licensing the vested patents, the Alien Property Custodian promoted the use

of vested patents through various measures. The Custodian published the specifications of

pending applications (Sommerich, 1955, p.588). It also published catalogues of vested patents

and abstracts of all vested chemical patents. American Chemical Society then compiled and

published a 34-volume set of abstracts of 8,000 vested chemical patents. In addition, the

Custodian “organized libraries of vested patents serviced by technical field representatives in

various cities, exhibited a traveling library of vested patents in every major industrial area of the

United States, [and] co-operated with other governmental agencies in developing new uses for

vested patents in both the military and civilian field” (Sommerich, 1955, p.588). Because all

vested patents, including the ones that were not licensed, were readily available to the U.S.

inventors, this paper examines the effects of compulsory licensing by examining vested enemy-

owned patents.

(2) Data

In this paper, the independent variable is the number of patents vested by the World War

II Alien Property Custodian. These vested patents refer to enemy-owned patents that were made

publicly available for licensing, regardless of whether the patents were licensed to U.S. firms or

not. My paper is different from Moser and Voena (2010) in that Moser and Voena (2010)’s main

Page 13: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

13

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

specification uses the data on licensed patents, not vested patents. However, the licensing

decisions of U.S. firms may not have been exogenous because U.S. firms were more likely to

license in subclasses where initial levels of domestic invention were weak (Moser and Voena,

2010). To address such a selection bias, Moser and Voena (2010) uses intent to treat regressions.

Because my paper uses the data on vested patents, it does not suffer from a selection bias, and

can improve on Moser and Voena (2010).

The data on vested patents comes from Patents at Work: A Statement of Policy published

in January 1943. In Patents at Work, the number of patents vested before October 1942, the

number of additional patents vested before January 1943, and the number of patent applications

vested before November 1942 are recorded for each USPTO main class. A portion of the data is

replicated below (see Table 1). USPTO Class No. 51 denotes “Abrading,” and within the class, a

total of 165 patents were vested before October 2, 1942. This paper uses the data on the number

of U.S. patents that were vested before October 1942.

Table 1 – Patents Vested by the Alien Property Custodian

Class Class title

Number of Patents

1st Edition

Oct. 2, 1942

51 Abrading 165

181 Acoustics 75

244 Aeronautics 336

259 Agitating 52

Source: Alien Property Custodian of the United States. 1943. Patents at Work

Page 14: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

14

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

The original data include 300 USPTO main classes. Among those 300 USPTO main

classes, the number and title of 144 of them have not changed over the years. 18 USPTO main

classes had minor changes in class titles. For example, USPTO Class No. 7 denoted “Compound

Tools” in 1942, but USPTO Class No. 7 now refers to “Compound Hand Tools.” For 42 of the

USPTO main classes, either the class number or class title has changed. For each of them, I

could locate a class title that roughly matches the original title. For example, USPTO Class No.

133 denoted “Coin Handling,” but under the current system, USPTO Class No. 453 refers to

“Coin Handling.” For 92 of the USPTO main classes, the class number and title have both

changed and I could not locate a title that roughly matches the original title. Some main classes

seemed to be no longer present because they became obsolete. For example, USPTO Class No.

55 denoted “Harrows and Diggers,” but the current USPTO system does not have such a main

class. For my analysis, I examine 144 USPTO main classes whose class number and title have

not changed.

The dependent variable is the number of U.S. patents per USPTO main class per year. I

collected this data from Patenting By Geographic Region (State and Country), Breakout by

Technology Class, Count of 1963 - 2009 Utility Patent Grants and USPTO Master Classification

File.

(3) Empirical Strategy

I use a difference-in-differences strategy to study the effects compulsory licensing under

the World War II TWEA had on domestic innovation activities. This paper relies on the

following estimation, which closely resembles the one Moser and Voena (2010) use:

Total U.S. Patents per Main Classc,t = α0 +ß Vested Patentsc ⋅ postTWEAt + δt + fc + εc,t .

Page 15: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

15

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

For this analysis, the dependent variable is the number of total U.S. patents per USPTO main

class per year (1900-1971). Total U.S. patents data include both U.S. patents granted to U.S.

inventors and U.S. patents granted to foreign inventors. It would have been ideal to use the

number of U.S. patents granted to U.S. inventors per main class per year as a dependent variable,

because the purpose of this paper is to find the effects TWEA had on innovation activities of U.S.

inventors. However, the data on the number of U.S. patents granted to U.S. inventors per main

class per year is unavailable for years from 1900 to 1962. As a result, I instead use the data on

total U.S. patents and provide a robustness check using patent data from year 1963 to 1971.

Vested Patents measures the number of enemy patents per USPTO main class. postTWEA equals

1 for every year starting from 1942. δ is year fixed effects and f is USPTO main class fixed

effects. If the result is statistically significant, it would suggest that compulsory licensing under

the World War II TWEA could have had effects on patenting by domestic inventors.

As a robustness check for using the number of total U.S. patents per main class per year

(1900-1971) as a dependent variable, I examine whether an analysis using total U.S. patents

(1963-1971) yields results that are similar to results I get using U.S. patents granted to U.S.

inventors (1963-1971). I estimate two simple linear models:

Patents Granted to U.S. Inventorsc,t = α0 +ß Vested Patentsc + γ ⋅ Zc,t + δt + fc + εc,t and

Total U.S. Patents per Main Classc,t = α0 +ß Vested Patentsc + δt + fc + εc,t .

In the first model, the dependent variable is the number of U.S. patents granted to U.S. inventors

per USPTO main class per year (1963-1971). Patents Granted to U.S. Inventors is measured by

subtracting foreign patents from the total number of U.S. patents per year (Moser and Voena,

2010). In the second model, the dependent variable is the number of total U.S. patents per

USPTO main class per year (1963-1971). In both models, Vested Patents measures the number

Page 16: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

16

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

of enemy patents per USPTO main class. Z in the first model measures the total number of

foreign patents and it controls for unobservable factors, such as technological progress within

main classes (Moser and Voena, 2010). Moser and Voena (2010) also use the total number of

foreign patents as a control variable. δ is year fixed effects and f is USPTO main class fixed

effects. If the results from two regressions are similar, I can draw some valid conclusions from

the difference-in-differences estimation.

Data Description Section

(1) Descriptive Statistics on Patents Vested by the Alien Property Custodian

My independent variable is the number of patents vested by the World War II Alien

Property Custodian. Specifically, I examine the number of vested patents per USPTO main class

for 144 USPTO main classes, whose class number and title have not changed.

Table 2 shows the summary statistics of patents vested by the Alien Property Custodian.

Included in the 144 USPTO main classes are 13,236 vested patents. On average, each main class

has 92 vested patents. A main class with the most number of patents vested is USPTO Main

Class No. 250 titled “Radiant Energy.” Class No. 250 had 1,672 patents that were vested by the

Alien Property Custodian.

Page 17: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

17

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Table 2 – Summary Statistics of Patents Vested by Alien Property Custodian

Vested Patents per Main Class

Mean 92

Standard Error 15.60

Median 41

Mode 0

Standard Deviation 187

Kurtosis 43.7

Skewness 6.0

Range 1672

Minimum 0

Maximum 1672

Sum 13236

Count 144

Table 3 is a frequency table for the number of vested patents. It shows how many USPTO

main classes each had a specific number of vested patents. For example, a total of 137 USPTO

main classes each included 1 to 100 vested patents. As Table 3 shows, most USPTO main classes

each included 0 to 500 vested patents. However, there are three main classes that included a

much greater number of vested patents. Main Class No. 250 “Radiant Energy” included 1,672

vested patents, Main Class No. 260 “Chemistry, carbon compounds” included 1,208 vested

patents, and Main Class No. 123 “Internal-combustion engines” included 522 vested patents. I

checked these three outliers, and I concluded that they are actual observations, not mistakes.

Page 18: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

18

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Table 3 – Frequency Table

Number of Patents Vested Main Class Frequency

0 7

1-100 99

101-200 23

201-300 8

301-400 1

401-500 3

501-600 1

601-700 0

701-800 0

801-900 0

901-1000 0

1001-1100 0

1101-1200 0

1201-1300 1

1301-1400 0

1401-1500 0

1501-1600 0

1601-1700 1

Total 144

Figure 1 shows histograms that plot the distribution of vested patents. The first histogram

plots Table 3 and shows that vested patent data is skewed to the right with outliers at the upper

range of the data. The second histogram plots main class frequency with a smaller bin width and

shows the frequency of main classes that included 0 to 500 vested patents.

Page 19: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

19

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Figure 1 – Frequency Histograms of Vested Patents

7

99

23

8 1 3 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 1

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

900

1000

1100

1200

1300

1400

1500

1600

1700

Ma

in C

lass

Fre

qu

ency

Number of Vested Patents

Distribution of Vested Patents (Bin Width = 100)

Frequency

7

37

28

13 13

8 9 7

2 2 3 6

1 0 1 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 1 1 0 3

0

20

40

60

80

10

0

12

0

14

0

16

0

18

0

20

0

22

0

24

0

26

0

28

0

30

0

32

0

340

36

0

38

0

40

0

42

0

44

0

46

0

48

0

50

0

More

Ma

in C

lass

Fre

qu

ency

Number of Vested Patents

Distribution of Vested Patents (Bin Width = 20)

Frequency

Page 20: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

20

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

(2) Descriptive Statistics on Total U.S. Patents (1900-1971)

To the extent that different technologies were differently affected by the World War II

TWEA, this paper uses difference-in-differences to examine the effects World War II TWEA

had on domestic innovation. This paper uses total U.S. patent counts per main class per year data

(1900-1971). I collected this data from the USPTO Master Classification File I received from the

USPTO. Ideally, I would like to use data on U.S. patents granted to U.S. residing inventors.

Unfortunately, U.S. patent data that goes back to 1900 cannot be broken by the nationality of

inventors. If results I get from using total U.S. patents (1900-1971) are robust to different

specifications, I would be able to draw some useful conclusions from total U.S. patents data

(1900-1971).

Table 4 shows the summary statistics of total U.S. patents (1900-1971). There are a total

of 10,368 observations because I am studying 144 USPTO main classes over a 72 year time span

(144*72 = 10,368). From 1900 to 1971, a total of 1,306,239 patents were assigned to the 144

USPTO main classes. On average, each main class has 126 patents per year.

Page 21: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

21

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Table 4 – Summary Statistics of Total U.S. Patents (1900-1971)

Total U.S. Patents (1900-1971)

Mean 126

Standard Error 1.29

Median 84

Mode 0

Standard Deviation 131

Kurtosis 4.9

Skewness 1.9

Range 1113

Minimum 0

Maximum 1113

Sum 1306239

Count 10368

Because TWEA was established in 1942, I define observation to be treated if data is from

1942 to 1971. I define observation to be untreated if data is from 1900 to 1941. Table 5 provides

the summary statistics of untreated observations while Table 6 provides the summary statistics of

treated observations. From 1900 to 1941, a total of 798,815 patents were assigned to the 144

USPTO main classes. On average, each main class has 135 patents per year (See Table 5). From

1942 to 1971, a total of 507,424 patents were assigned to the 144 USPTO main classes. On

average, each main class has 114 patents per year (See Table 6). Correlation between total U.S.

patents (1942-1971) and vested patents is 0.288582.

Page 22: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

22

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Table 5 – Summary Statistics of Untreated Total U.S. Patents (1900-1941)

Total U.S. Patents (1900-1941)

Mean 135

Standard Error 1.71

Median 93

Mode 0

Standard Deviation 131

Kurtosis 3.2

Skewness 1.6

Range 939

Minimum 0

Maximum 939

Sum 798815

Count 5904

Table 6 – Summary Statistics of Treated Total U.S. Patents (1942-1971)

Total U.S. Patents (1942-1971)

Mean 114

Standard Error 1.94

Median 73

Mode 0

Standard Deviation 130

Kurtosis 7.7

Skewness 2.3

Range 1113

Minimum 0

Maximum 1113

Sum 507424

Count 4465

Page 23: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

23

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

(3) Descriptive Statistics on U.S. Patents Granted to U.S. Inventors (1963-1971)

Even though U.S. patent data that goes back to 1900 cannot be broken by the nationality

of inventors, U.S. patent data from 1963 can be broken by the nationality of inventors. So, in a

robustness check, this paper uses data on U.S patents granted to U.S. inventors per USPTO main

class per year for years from 1963 to 1971. I collected this data from Patenting By Geographic

Region (State and Country), Breakout by Technology Class, Count of 1963 - 2009 Utility Patent

Grants published by USPTO Patent Technology Monitoring Team.

Table 7 shows the summary statistics of U.S. patents granted to U.S. inventors (1963-

1971). There are a total of 1,296 observations because I am studying 144 USPTO main classes

over a nine year time span (144*9 = 1,296). From 1963 to 1971, a total of 143,453 patents

granted to U.S. inventors were assigned to the 144 USPTO main classes. On average, each main

class has 111 patents per year.

Table 7 – Summary Statistics of Patents Granted to U.S. Inventors (1963-1971)

Patents Granted to U.S. Inventors (1963-1971)

Mean 111

Standard Error 3.57

Median 69

Mode 0

Standard Deviation 129

Kurtosis 6.7

Skewness 2.2

Range 875

Minimum 0

Maximum 875

Sum 143,453

Count 1,296

Page 24: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

24

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Figure 2 plots the number of vested patents per main class on the x-axis and the number

of patents granted to U.S. inventors per main class per year (1963-1971) on the y-axis. As

discussed in the descriptive statistics on vested patents, there are only three main classes which

have more than 500 vested patents. Because of these three observations, Figure 2 has plots that

are heavily clustered between 0 and 500. Only 27 observations (three main classes over a nine

year time span= 3*9 observations) have x-value which is greater than 500. As a result, it is hard

to understand scatter plots as it is presented in Figure 2.

Figure 3 drops the 27 observations and plots the number of vested patents per main class

on the x-axis and the number of patents granted to U.S. inventors per main class per year (1963-

1971) on the y-axis. For each main class that has vested patents, I have nine outcome

observations because I examine data from year 1963 to 1971. Figure 3 plots 1,269 observations.

Correlation between patents granted to U.S inventors (1963-1971) and vested patents is

0.329816.

Page 25: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

25

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Figure 2 – Plot of the Number of Patents Granted to U.S. Inventors (1963-1971) on the Number of Vested Patents

0 500 1000 1500

02

00

40

06

00

80

0

Number of Vested Patents

Nu

mb

er

of P

ate

nts

Gra

nte

d to

U.S

. In

ve

nto

rs (

19

63

-19

71

)

Page 26: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

26

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Figure 3 – Plot of the Number of Patents Granted to U.S. Inventors (1963-1971) on the Number of Vested Patents

(Without 27 Extreme Observations)

0 100 200 300 400

02

00

40

06

00

80

0

Number of Vested Patents

Nu

mb

er

of P

ate

nts

Gra

nte

d to

U.S

. In

ve

nto

rs (

19

63

-19

71

)

Page 27: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

27

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Analysis

(1) Difference-in-differences Analysis Using Data on Total U.S. Patents (1900-1971)

In this section, I use a difference-in-differences strategy to study the effect of TWEA on

innovation activities. Using a difference-in-differences strategy across USPTO main classes

before and after the World War II TWEA, I examine whether the number of patents increased

more in USPTO main classes that had more vested patents. I specifically focus my analysis on

144 USPTO main classes whose USPTO class number and title have not changed since 1942.

The dependent variable is the number of total U.S. patents per main class per year (1900-

1971). Regression results are present in Table 8. Model 1 estimates:

Total U.S. Patents per Main Classc,t = α0 +ß Vested Patentsc ⋅ postTWEAt + εc,t

where postTWEAt equals 1 if data is from 1942 to 1971. Model 2 controls for year fixed effects.

Model 3 controls for both year fixed effects and main class fixed effects.

I hypothesize that the coefficient on Vested Patentsc ⋅ postTWEAt would be positive

because the vested patents would have had positive effects on total U.S. patents. I hypothesize

that the main classes that had more vested patents experienced a greater increase in innovation

activities after the World War II TWEA compared to the main classes that had less vested

patents. The vested patents would likely have had long-term positive effects on U.S. innovation

activities. Previous literature suggests that easy access to foreign patents can benefit domestic

innovation. For example, experience with producing foreign inventions can encourage the

learning-by-doing of the compulsory licensees (Moser and Voena, 2010). Using a difference-in-

differences strategy, Moser and Voena (2010) show that the chemical subclass that had received

at least one vested patent produced between 0.118 and 0.234 additional patents per year after

Page 28: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

28

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

1919. If my analysis shows that the coefficient on Vested Patentsc ⋅ postTWEAt is positive, it

would suggest that compulsory licensing under the World War II TWEA might have had a

positive effect on the number of total patents that the U.S. granted to inventors.

Table 8 –Dependent Variable is the Number of Total U.S. Patents per USPTO Main Class per

Year (1900-1971)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Number of vested patents per

main class times postTWEA

0.148***

(0.010)

0. 201***

(0.010)

0.116***

(0.008)

Year fixed effects

No

Yes

Yes

Main class fixed effects

No No Yes

Number of observations 10,368 10,368 10,368

Number of main classes

144

144

144

R-squared 0.0216 0.0746 0.7095

Adjusted R-squared 0.0215 0.0682 0.7033

Standard errors in parentheses

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Page 29: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

29

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

For Model 1, the coefficient on Vested Patentsc ⋅ postTWEAt is positive and statistically

significant at the 99% level (see Table 8, column for Model 1). Adding year fixed effects does

not change the coefficient on Vested Patentsc ⋅ postTWEAt. It remains positive and statistically

significant at the 99% level (see Table 8, column for Model 2). The coefficient remains positive

after adding both year fixed effects and main class fixed effects (see Table 8, column for Model

3).

I believe Model 3, which includes both year fixed effects and main class fixed effects,

would best estimate the effects of compulsory licensing under TWEA. This is because I expect

investors’ patenting activities to differ across years and across main classes. As Moser (2005)

shows, propensity to patent varies across industries, which suggests that the addition of main

class fixed effects is valid. Model 3 shows that each vested patent produced about 0.116

additional patents per year after 1942 (see Table 8, column for Model 3). If a main class included

100 vested patents, the number of total patents increased by about 11.6 patents per year between

1942 and 1971. In 1942, each main class, on average, included 92 vested patents. This implies

that total patents increased on average by 10.672 (0.116*92=10.672) patents per year for years

between 1942 and 1971. On average, there were 114 total U.S. patents per main class per year

between 1942 and 1971. Thus, 10.672 additional patents imply about 9 percent increase in total

U.S. patents. The regression analysis provides some evidence that each vested patent had

positive effects on the number of total U.S. patents granted after 1942.

Page 30: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

30

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

(2) Analysis Using Data on U.S. Patents Granted to U.S. Inventors (1963-1971)

As discussed in details in Study Design, it would have been ideal to use the data on U.S.

patents granted to U.S. inventors (1900-1971) when using a difference-in-differences strategy.

Due to data limitation, Section 1 of Analysis instead uses the data on total U.S. patents (1900-

1971). As a robustness check for using the number of total U.S. patents per main class per year

(1900-1971) as a dependent variable, I examine whether an analysis using U.S. patents granted

to U.S. inventors (1963-1971) yields results that are similar to the results of an analysis using

total U.S. patents (1963-1971). In this section, I use the data on U.S. patents granted to U.S

inventors per USPTO main class per year (1963-1971) to examine the relationship between the

number of vested patents per USPTO main class and the number of U.S patents granted to U.S.

inventors per USPTO main class (1963-1971). Then, Section 3 of Analysis replicates what is

done in this section, but using the data on total U.S. patents (1963-1971) instead of the data on

U.S. patents granted to U.S. inventors (1963-1971). If the results from Section 2 and Section 3

are similar, the difference-in-differences estimation would be robust.

In this section, I use ordinary least squares (OLS) regression to examine the relationship

between the number of vested patents and the number of U.S patents granted to U.S. inventors

(1963-1971). The dependent variable is U.S. patents granted to U.S. inventors per USPTO main

class per year (1963-1971). OLS regression results are present in Table 9. Model 1 estimates:

Patents Granted to U.S. Iinventorsc,t = α0 +ß Vested Patentsc + εc,t

where Vested Patents measures the number of vested patents per USPTO main class. Model 2

adds to Model 1 an independent variable, Vested Patents Squared:

Patents Granted to U.S. Iinventorsc, t= α0 +ß1 Vested Patentsc + ß2 Vested Patents Squaredc + εc,t

Page 31: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

31

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

and it examines whether the marginal benefit of an additional patent is decreasing. Model 3

controls for year fixed effects. Model 4 controls for both year fixed effects and main class fixed

effects. Model 5 estimates:

Patents Granted to U.S .Inventorsc,t = α0 +ß Vested Patentsc + γ ⋅ Zc,t + δt + fc + εc,t

where the control variable Z measures the total number of foreign patents per main class per year,

and Moser and Voena (2010) use the same control variable in their paper. δ measures year fixed

effects and f measures USPTO main class fixed effects.

Page 32: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

32

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Table 9 – OLS Regressions, Dependent Variable is the Number of Patents Granted to U.S.

Inventors per USPTO Main Class per Year (1963-1971)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5

Number of vested patents per

main class

0.227***

(0.018)

0.718***

(0.043)

0.227***

(0.018)

0.241***

(0.010)

0.147***

(0.009)

Number of vested patents

squared

-0.00038***

(3.06e-05)

Number of patents by foreign

inventors

1.242***

(0.055)

Year fixed effects

No

No

Yes

Yes

Yes

Main class fixed effects

No No No Yes Yes

Number of observations 1,296 1,296 1,296 1,296 1,296

Number of main classes

144

144

144

144

144

R-squared 0.1088 0.2040 0.1174 0.9398 0.9585

Adjusted R-squared 0.1081 0.2028 0.1112 0.9318 0.9529

Standard errors in parentheses

*** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

Page 33: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

33

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

For Model 1, I hypothesize that the coefficient on Vested Patents would be positive and

that that the number of vested patents per main class and the number of U.S. patents granted to

U.S. inventors per main class would have a positive relationship. As hypothesized, the

coefficient on Vested Patents is positive and statistically significant at the 99% level (see Table 9,

column for Model 1). OLS results show that the greater the number of vested patents in a main

class, the greater the number of patents granted to U.S. inventors per main class between 1963

and 1971.

Model 2 adds a quadratic term for the number of vested patents. If the marginal benefits

of an additional knowledge are decreasing, the coefficient on the number of vested patents

squared would be negative (Moser and Voena, 2010). Based on the principle of diminishing

marginal benefit, I hypothesize that the coefficient on Vested Patents would be positive and that

the coefficient on Vested Patents Squared is negative. Table 9 (see the column for Model 2)

shows that the coefficient on Vested Patents is positive and the coefficient on Vested Patents

Squared is negative. The estimate of coefficient on Vested Patents Squared, -0.00038, is very

close to zero, suggesting that the effect of diminishing marginal benefit is not very strong. Both

coefficients are statistically significant at the 99% level.

Model 3 controls year fixed effects. As can be seen in Table 9 (see the column for Model

3), adding year fixed effects does not change the coefficient on Vested Patents. Compared to

Model 1, standard error on the coefficient remains the same. Controlling for both year fixed

effects and main class fixed effects does not change the sign of the coefficient on Vested Patents

(see Table 9, column for Model 4). For Model 4, the estimate of coefficient of Vested Patents is

0.241.

Page 34: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

34

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Model 5 adds the total number of foreign patents per main class per year as a control

variable. Model 5 also controls for year fixed effects and main class fixed effects. As

hypothesized, the sign of the coefficient on Vested Patents is positive (see Table 9, column for

Model 5). The coefficient on the total number of foreign patents per main class is 0.147 and

statistically significant at the 99% level.

The regression analysis provides some statistical evidence that the relationship between

the number of vested patents and the number of patents granted to U.S. inventors (1963-1971) is

positive and significant.

(3) Analysis Using Data on Total U.S. Patents (1963-1971)

This section replicates what has been done in Section 2 of Analysis (see page 29-33),

except this time using the data on total U.S. patents (1963-1971) instead of using the data on U.S.

patents granted to U.S. inventors (1963-1971). OLS regression results are present in Table 10.

Page 35: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

35

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Table 10 – OLS Regressions, Dependent Variable is the Number of Total U.S. Patents per

USPTO Main Class per Year (1963-1971)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

Number of vested patents per

main class

0.310***

(0.022)

0. 986***

(0.052)

0.310***

(0.022)

0.316***

(0.012)

Number of vested patents

squared

-0.00052***

(3.73e-05)

Number of patents by foreign

inventors

Year fixed effects

No

No

Yes

Yes

Main class fixed effects

No No No Yes

Number of observations 1,296 1,296 1,296 1,296

Number of main classes

144

144

144

144

R-squared 0.1291 0.2442 0.1408 0.9349

Adjusted R-squared 0.1284 0.2430 0.1348 0.9263

Page 36: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

36

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Model 1 estimates: Number of Total Patentsc,t = α0 +ß Vested Patentsc + εc,t where

Vested Patents again measures the number of vested patents per USPTO main class. Model 2

adds to Model 1 an independent variable, Vested Patents Squared and examines the marginal

benefit of an additional patent. Model 3 controls for year fixed effects. Model 4 controls for both

year fixed effects and main class fixed effects.

I hypothesize that the coefficient on Vested Patents would be positive and that that the

number of vested patents per main class and the number of total U.S patents per main class per

year would have a positive relationship. As hypothesized, the coefficients on Vested Patents are

positive for all four models present in Table 10. The coefficients are statistically significant at the

99% level. Model 2 suggests that the marginal benefit of an additional patent is decreasing

because the coefficient on Vested Patents is positive and the coefficient on Vested Patents

Squared is negative (See Table 10, column for Model 2).

Because the number of total U.S. patents per main class is always greater than the

number of U.S. patents granted to U.S. inventors, I expect that the coefficient on Vested Patents

to be larger when I use the total number of U.S. patents per main class per year (1963-1971) as a

dependent variable. As expected, Table 9 and Table 10 show that the coefficient on Vested

Patents tends to be larger when I use the total number of U.S. patents per main class per year

(1963-1971) as a dependent variable instead of the number of U.S. patents granted to U.S.

inventors per main class per year (1963-1971). Nevertheless, using the total number of U.S.

patents per USPTO main class per year (1963-1971) as a dependent variable still yields results

that are similar to the results I get when using the number of U.S. patents granted to U.S.

inventors per USPTO main class per year (1963-1971) as a dependent variable. Section 2 and

Section 3 show that the coefficients on Vested Patents for all models remain positive and

Page 37: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

37

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

significant when I use the total number of U.S. patents per main class per year (1963-1971).

Thus, I conclude that although using the total number of U.S. patents (1900-1971) in difference-

in-differences strategy may create bias in measuring the effects of TWEA on domestic

innovation, that bias may not be too serious. I can draw such a conclusion because Section 2 and

Section 3 show that the coefficients on Vested Patents are positive and significant regardless of

whether I use total U.S. patent data or U.S. patent granted to U.S. inventors data.

Figure 4 plots the number of vested patents per main class on the x-axis and the number

of total U.S. patents per main class per year (1963-1971) on the y-axis. The figure shows the

positive correlation between the number of vested patents and the number of total U.S. patents

(1963-1971).

Page 38: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

38

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Figure 4 – Plot of the Number of Total U.S. Patents (1963-1971) on the Number of Vested Patents

0 500 1000 1500

02

00

40

06

00

80

01

00

0

Number of Vested Patents

To

tal U

.S. P

ate

nts

(1

96

3-1

97

1)

Page 39: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

39

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Conclusion

This paper examines the World War II TWEA to study the effects of compulsory

licensing on domestic inventions. Difference-in-differences analysis suggests that each vested

patent had positive effects on the number of total U.S. patents granted after 1942. USPTO main

classes that had more vested patents experienced a greater increase in the number of total U.S.

patents granted. A robustness check shows that I can study the effects TWEA had on domestic

innovation by using total U.S. patents (1900-1971) as a dependent variable in my difference-in-

differences estimation. My paper extends the analysis of Moser and Voena (2010) by showing

that analysis encompassing different USPTO main classes leads to the conclusion that

compulsory licensing had positive effects on domestic innovation.

Even though my analysis suggests that compulsory licensing under the World War II

TWEA may have had positive effects on domestic innovation, my paper is neither in favor nor

against compulsory licensing. As past literature has shown, compulsory licensing is a complex

issue. Compulsory licensing not only affects countries whose property rights are violated, but it

also affects countries that use compulsory licensing to cheaply access foreign innovation. In

addition, compulsory licensing has both short-term and long-term effects on innovation activities.

Before any conclusion on the overall effects of compulsory licensing on innovation can be

reached, we need to carefully weigh the different effects of compulsory licensing on different

parties. I wish that my paper can contribute to current debates on compulsory licensing.

Page 40: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

40

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Reference List

Alien Property Custodian of the United States. 1919. A Detailed Report by the Alien Property

Custodian of All Proceedings Had by Him under the Trading with the Enemy Act

During the Calendar Year 1918 and to the Close of Business on February 15, 1919.

Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.

Alien Property Custodian of the United States. 1943. Patents at Work: A Statement of Policy,

Washington, DC: Office of Alien Property Custodian.

Alien Property Custodian of the United States. 1946. Annual Report, Washington, DC: Office

of Alien Property Custodian.

Bird, R.C. and Cohey D.R. 2008. “The Impact of Compulsory Licensing on Foreign Direct

Investment: A Collective Bargaining Approach,” American Business Law Journal,

Summer 45(2): pp. 2-48.

Chaudhuri, S., Goldberg, P.K., and Jia, P. 2006. “Estimating the Effects of Global Patent

Protection in Pharmaceuticals: A Case Study of Quinolones in India,” American

Economic Review, December 96(5): pp. 1477-1514.

Chien, C.V. 2003. “Cheap Drugs at What Price to Innovation: Does the Compulsory Licensing

of Pharmaceuticals Hurt Innovation?,” Berkeley Technology Law Journal, Summer 18(3):

pp. 853-907.

Danzon P.M. and A. Towse. 2005. “Theory and Implementation of Differential Pricing for

Pharmaceuticals” in K.E. Maskus and J.H. Reichman, eds., International Public Goods

and Transfer of Technology under a Globalised Intellectual Property in Regime,

Cambridge, U.K: Cambridge Press.

Fisch, A.M. 1994. “Compulsory Licensing of Pharmaceutical Patents: An Unreasonable Solution

to an Unfortunate Problem,” Jurimetrics, Spring 34(3): pp. 295-316.

Foster, A.D. and Rosenzweig M.R. 1995. “Learning by Doing and Learning from Others:

Human Capital and Technical Change in Agriculture,” Journal of Political Economy,

December 103(6): pp. 1176-1209.

Harris, J.E. 2009. “Why We Don't Have An HIV Vaccine, And How We Can Develop One,”

Health Affairs, November 28(6): pp. 1642-1654

Irwin, D.A. and Klenow, P.J. 1994. “Learning-by-Doing Spillovers in the Semiconductor

Industry,” Journal of Political Economy, December 102(6): pp. 1200-1227.

Page 41: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

41

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

Kaiser Daily HIV/AIDS Report. 2007. “Thailand Will Maintain Compulsory Licenses for

Kaletra, Efavirenz, Despite Companies' Drug Price Reductions, Health Minister Says,”

Kaiser Daily HIV/AIDS Report, April 16.

Landau, N, Mowery, D.C., and Rosenberg N. 1992. Technology and the Wealth of Nations,

Stanford, California: Stanford University Press.

Lee, J.Y. and Mansfield E. 1996. “Intellectual property protection and US foreign direct

investment,” Review of Economics and Statistics, May 78(2): pp. 181-186

Miller, James. 2007. “Abbott to Cut AIDS Drug Cost in Poor Nations,” Chicago Tribune, April

10.

Ministry of Public Health and the National Health Security Office of Thailand. 2007. Facts and

Evidences on the 10 Burning Issues Related to the Government Use of Patents on Three

Patented Essential Drugs in Thailand, February.

Moser, Petra. 2005. “How Do Patent Laws Influence Innovation? Evidence from Nineteenth-

Century World’s Fairs,” American Economic Review, August 95(4): pp. 1214-1236.

Moser, Petra and Voena, Alessandra. 2010. “Compulsory Licensing: Evidence from the Trading

with the Enemy Act,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 15598,

January.

Scherer, F.M. 1977. The Economic Effects of Compulsory Patent Licensing (Monograph Series

in Finance and Economics, 1977-2). New York: New York University, Graduate School

of Business Administration, Center for the Study of Financial Institutions.

Schwartzman David. 1975. The expected return from pharmaceutical research: sources of new

drugs and the profitability of R & D investment, Washington, DC: American Enterprise

Institute for Public Policy Research.

Scotchmer, Suzanne. 2006. “Investing in Knowledge,” in Suzanne Scotchmer, ed., Innovation

and Incentives. Cambridge, Massachusetts and London, England: MIT Press, pp. 31-64.

Scotchmer, Suzanne. 2006. “On the Optimal Design of Intellectual Property,” in Suzanne

Scotchmer, ed., Innovation and Incentives. Cambridge, Massachusetts and London,

England: MIT Press, pp. 98-123.

Sommerich, O.C. 1955. “Treatment by United States of World War I and II Enemy-Owned

Patents and Copyrights,” American Society of Comparative Law, Autumn 4(4): pp. 587-

600.

Page 42: Compulsory Licensing and Domestic Innovation: Evidence ...Stephanie Lee May, 2011 examining the Canadian experience of pharmaceutical licensing. From 1923 to 1993, Canadian legislation

42

Stephanie Lee

May, 2011

United States Patent and Trademark Office. USPTO Master Classification File. Retrieved

January 12, 2011. from http://www.google.com/googlebooks/uspto-patents.html.

United States Patent and Trademark Office Patent Technology Monitoring Team. 2009.

Patenting By Geographic Region (State and Country), Breakout by Technology Class,

Count of 1963 - 2009 Utility Patent Grants.

World Trade Organization. 2001. Ministerial Declaration, November 20.