23
Critical Sociology  1  –23 © The Author(s) 2014 Reprints and permissions: sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.nav DOI: 10.1177/0896920514540187 crs.sagepub.com Agro-Industrialization, Petrodollar Illusions and the Transformation of the Capitalist World Economy in the 1970s: The Latin American Experience Roberto José Ortiz Binghamton University, USA Abstract A transformation of world capitalism took place during the 1970s. Profitability decline in core countries was compounded by an increase in world oil prices connected to the rise of OPEC’s oil rent. In this context, a fraction of the Latin American semiperiphery rose in industrial prominence but ultimately collapsed. A combination of recycled petrodollars and an agrarian transformation underwrote this semiperipheral agro-industrial rise. By 1982, however, illusions of advance resting on industrialization were undermined by the debt crisis. While part of the semiperiphery embraced debt-led industrialization, capitalism swi tched gears into a regime where financial power, not industrialization, became the main si gn of coreness. This process is examined through a perspective of capitalism as (simultaneously) world economy and world ecology, where the production of nature and the production of capital are organized in order to secure endless profitability. Nature, in the form of oil, labor-power and agricultural exports takes center stage. Keywords agro-industrialization, petrodollars, Latin American development, world-systems, political economy Introduction During the world-historical transition of the 1970s (ca 1966–82), amid the overall decline of advanced capitalist countries, it seemed that a reversal of fortunes was taking place. It was the decade when the semiperiphery of world capitalism caught up with the core in terms of degree of industrialization (see Figure 1). 1  There was a rise of ‘new industrializing countries’. Also, rentier Corresponding author: Roberto José Ortiz, Department of Sociology, Binghamton University–SUNY, PO Box 6000, Sociology LT 407, Binghamton, NY 13902-6000, USA. Email: [email protected] 540187CRS 0 0 10.1177/0896920514 540187Critical SociologyJosé Ortiz research-article 2014  Article  at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016 crs.sagepub.com Downloaded from 

Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

  • Upload
    max-ajl

  • View
    217

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 1/23

Critical Sociology

 1 –23

© The Author(s) 2014

Reprints and permissions:

sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.navDOI: 10.1177/0896920514540187

crs.sagepub.com

Agro-Industrialization, Petrodollar

Illusions and the Transformationof the Capitalist World Economyin the 1970s: The Latin AmericanExperience

Roberto José Ortiz

Binghamton University, USA

Abstract

A transformation of world capitalism took place during the 1970s. Profitability decline in corecountries was compounded by an increase in world oil prices connected to the rise of OPEC’s

oil rent. In this context, a fraction of the Latin American semiperiphery rose in industrialprominence but ultimately collapsed. A combination of recycled petrodollars and an agrariantransformation underwrote this semiperipheral agro-industrial rise. By 1982, however, illusions

of advance resting on industrialization were undermined by the debt crisis. While part of thesemiperiphery embraced debt-led industrialization, capitalism switched gears into a regime wherefinancial power, not industrialization, became the main sign of coreness. This process is examinedthrough a perspective of capitalism as (simultaneously) world economy and world ecology, where

the production of nature and the production of capital are organized in order to secure endlessprofitability. Nature, in the form of oil, labor-power and agricultural exports takes center stage.

Keywords

agro-industrialization, petrodollars, Latin American development, world-systems, politicaleconomy

Introduction

During the world-historical transition of the 1970s (ca 1966–82), amid the overall decline of

advanced capitalist countries, it seemed that a reversal of fortunes was taking place. It was the

decade when the semiperiphery of world capitalism caught up with the core in terms of degree of

industrialization (see Figure 1).1 There was a rise of ‘new industrializing countries’. Also, rentier

Corresponding author:Roberto José Ortiz, Department of Sociology, Binghamton University–SUNY, PO Box 6000, Sociology LT 407,

Binghamton, NY 13902-6000, USA.

Email: [email protected]

40187CRS0010.1177/0896920514540187Critical SociologyJoséOrtizcle2014

 Article

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 2/23

2  Critical Sociology

states like Venezuela became influential in world affairs through their command of oil. Supposedly,

imperialism, dependency and related structures of subordination were becoming obsolete (cf.

Lipietz, 1987; Ominami, 1989; Warren, 1973). After 1982 the Mexican default called into question

these developmentalist illusions (Arrighi, 1990). The collapse of industrialization and develop-

mentalism, particularly in Brazil and Mexico, was of world-historical significance. In the 1980s,

these countries were used as models of a ‘failure’ that, in the eyes of world elites, legitimized the

imposition of a liberalized regime on the Third World.2

This essay examines this world conjuncture of the 1970s. I put forward two related arguments; one

is theoretical and the other is historical. First, I argue that the crisis of the 1970s is not only a question

of the history of advanced capitalist countries (Aglietta, 2000; Brenner, 2006). What took place wasa world-historical transformation of capitalism (Arrighi, 2010). Second, I argue that this transforma-

tion was a transitional phase from the postwar configuration of sustained growth, or golden age

(1945–1966/73), to the rise of neoliberalism (1982–?). This cycle from the core decline that began

around 1966 to the semiperipheral collapse of 1982 is what I mean by the world-historical transfor-

mation of the 1970s.

My historical interpretation is as follows. First, I lay out my theoretical starting point. I concep-

tualize the world transition of the 1970s in the context of a hierarchical capitalist world-economy

which is also a ‘world-ecology’ (Moore, 2009, 2011; Wallerstein, 1974). Capitalism is an ecosys-

tem for accumulation where production of nature and production of capital are combined in search

of profitability (Moore, 2011; Smith, 1990). Moreover, I also describe capitalism as creating aworld hierarchy of wealth. Following this, the historical argument highlights three related themes:

a declining capitalist core, a newly powerful rentier bloc, and a rising industrial semiperiphery.3 

Figure 1.  The 1970s conjuncture: core de-industrialization, semi-peripheral industrial rise.Sources: Central Intelligence Agency (1982) and World Bank (2014b).

Note: This index measures the degree of industrialization of an economy as the ratio of industrial value added (IVA)to GDP. The ‘core’ is represented here by the IVA/GDP ratio of a sample of 16 advanced capitalist countries takentogether. The semi-periphery is represented, likewise, by a sample of 16 semi-peripheral countries. The Brazil/Mexicoline is the IVA/GDP of the two in simple average.

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 3/23

 José Ortiz 3

Each, however, will not be discussed in equal depth. The crisis of core capitalism will be discussed

only to the extent that it relates to the semiperipheral rentier and agro-industrial rise that marked

the decade. The core crisis is described in the second section as a generalized fall in profit rates

caused by a decline in the productivity of capital. I focus on the contemporaneity between this

decline and the end of US oil hegemony.

Afterwards, I present the general outline of the 1970s. I explain how the rise of the Organization

of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) and its oil rent in the 1970s provided a structural link

 between semiperipheral nature (in the form of OPEC oil) and semiperipheral industrialization. Oil

was a partial underwriter of the rise of semiperipheral industrialization in Latin America. The link

was materialized by the recycling of oil rents into loans for a number of countries, what I call the

 petrodollar illusion. Prominent among the selected debtors were Brazil and Mexico. These two

‘newly industrializing countries’ combined repressive states, growing domestic markets, industrial

regimes developing at least since the 1940s, and significant natural resources (of continental scope

in the case of Brazil). For Mexico, the discovery of new oil fields furthered bankers’ enthusiasm

(Barkin, 1990: 95). I discuss how these two countries were related to the world conjuncture. I also

discuss Venezuela’s role in the conjuncture as an OPEC member and underwriter of the semipe-

ripheral agro-industrial rise.

My overall picture of the 1970s is drawn from the perspective of three Latin American semipe-

ripheral states. Although I will refer to some quantitative indicators, I will not compare the three

trajectories in terms of such indicators. Using a world-historical framework (Tomich, 2004), I will

describe each state’s particular position in, and relation to, the global transformations of the 1970s.

Therefore, different processes will be emphasized in each case. I examine the main processes

through which each country was linked to world capitalist development: oil rents for Venezuela;

recycled  oil rents and debt-led agro-industrialization for Brazil and Mexico. Also, I show how their

trajectories in part shaped the character of capitalist development in the 1966–82 period. These

three trajectories marked this period as one of semiperipheral industrialization and rising oil rents.

For Brazil and Mexico, this transitional moment entailed the uneven development of import

substitution industrialization (ISI) into an export-led and highly indebted agro-industrial regime.4 

Since the semiperipheral industrial impetus of the 1970s was built upon this early state-led ISI, it

is clear that I am not describing the origins of semiperipheral industrialization. The world-historical

meaning of the 1970s conjuncture resides in that it was during this decade when the semiperiphery

 basically caught up with the core in terms of industrialization degree, in theory accomplishing the

developmental goal advocated by liberal ideologies of growth.

Because of rising debts made possible by petrodollar recycling, however, these successful semi-

 peripheral industrializers became vulnerable to changes in interest rates. This vulnerability would

 become central when the USA raised interest rates after 1979. Latin American development col-lapsed soon after this monetarist attack. The main consequences were the conversion of Third

World debt into an unbearable burden and a new subordination through debt-servicing. What

seemed to be a victory for the semiperiphery, thus, turned out to be a fortunate outcome for core

capital since it was able to defer its own accumulation crisis.

The deferral was achieved by the unintended  transferring of core capitalism’s problems to those

states located directly below it in the world-economy. First World banking and dollar hegemony

did the trick. Capitalism was undergoing a transformation whereby control of finance capital, not

industrialization, became the road to coreness (see below). Moreover, I argue that the growing

financialization provided a framework where the USA could defer its 1970s crisis by reversing

world trends drastically, first by buying OPEC oil with devalued dollars and then collecting the benefits of Third World indebtedness through higher interest rates. The rise in US interest rates, of

course, was not implemented with the goal of cashing in on Third World debt. While unintended,

at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 4/23

4  Critical Sociology

this reversal in financial flows from semiperiphery to core was a fortunate outcome for First World

finance capital. First came loan pushing. Recycled petrodollars that were ‘lent, multiplied and re-

lent’ (Lipietz, 1987: 159) financed semiperipheral industrialization. Then came the rise in interest

rates that switched the weight of adjusting the debt economy to those indebted countries that were

touted as success stories a decade earlier.

In the conclusion, I discuss the emergence of neoliberalism out of the collapse of the 1970s

configuration. I argue that the 1970s did have an effect on the structure of world capitalism. That

decade showed that, notwithstanding the neoliberal setback, industrialization and autonomous

development are possible for Third World countries. While industrialization is not a sufficient  con-

dition for development, it can become its basis if real autonomy from core capital is conquered.

Dependent development could be turned into auto-centered development, as dependency theory

would say (Amin, 1979; Cardoso and Faletto, 1972).5 Ultimately, this possibility of future Third

World development will create new struggles over the hierarchy of accumulated socio-natural

wealth that underpins world capitalism.

A Global Ecosystem for Accumulation

I conceptualize capitalism, first, as a global ecosystem rooted in the endless commodification,

appropriation and transformation of natures, human and extra-human (Moore, 2010).

Simultaneously, it is a three-tiered world economy (Braudel, 1984). In the first instance, since its

origins in the long 16th century (1450–1640), capitalism formed a new ‘world-ecology’ where ‘the

accumulation of capital and the production of nature [are joined] in dialectical unity’ (Moore,

2009: 396). It is through this process of production that the capitalist class achieves the goal of

endless accumulation. The wealth capital accumulates, i.e. profits, is nothing more than the pro-

ductive combination of human labor and nature’s wealth (Marx, 1976: 133–134, 1979).

Therefore, capitalism organizes socio-ecological relations under the requirements of accumula-

tion (Moore, 2011: 18). It accumulates via the production of a mass of commodities in their dual

existence as embodiments of abstract labor-power and of a natural substratum. Along these lines, I

explain how the 1970s world conjuncture ascended through its production of agro-industrial trans-

formations and appropriation of specific forms of nature, namely, the natural force of labor-power

(Marx, 1972: 282) and the socio-ecological products of agriculture and oil.

The capital-nature dialectic derives from capitalism’s requirement to organize, transform and

 produce nature in order to accumulate at least average profits. Therefore, the contradictions

 between capital and its environmental conditions of production (Foster et al., 2010) have to be

conceptualized as internal contradictions of the capitalist ecosystem. There is a dialectic between

capitalism’s requirement of un- or under-capitalized nature to be appropriated cheaply (for exam- ple cheap un-commodified labor and natural resources) and capital’s own tendency towards eras-

ing this un-capitalized nature from the planet through its commodification. In other words, there is

a rise in the share of capitalized world nature (Moore, 2010) that raises costs and, potentially, pulls

down profit rates. This process of rising capitalization of nature works hand in hand with the ten-

dency of the profit rate to fall caused by the declining productivity of capital caused by mechaniza-

tion. In order to avoid the overall outcome, falling profitability, capitalism develops unevenly.

Capital moves out of some sectors and into others; for example, from productive investments into

financial instruments, as occurred in the 1970s (Gunnoe and Gellert, 2010: 271). Simultaneously,

it moves in and out of regions in the search for lower costs and higher returns. In the 1970s, it

moved massively into the Latin American semiperiphery, mainly in the form of finance capital.6 The outcome of this uneven development, however, seldom changes the hierarchy of wealth that,

together with accumulation, characterizes the capitalist world economy.

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 5/23

 José Ortiz 5

This brings another central aspect of world capitalism: its organization in a tri-modal hierarchy

of wealth. Alongside its existence as ecosystem for accumulation, capitalism is defined by a world

hierarchy of wealth. As Braudel argued (1984), since its beginnings capitalism has always been a

‘world-economy’, determined by the economic links and exchanges that form its global structure

and enable accumulation. Capitalism developed by subsuming external regions, incorporating

them as semiperipheries and peripheries. The capitalist world economy, then, ‘is a sort of a jigsaw

 puzzle, a juxtaposition of zones interconnected, but at different levels’ (Braudel, 1984: 39, empha-

sis in original).

At least three main zones can be described: a core which accumulates/appropriates the big share

of world wealth, a peripheral zone that stands as its opposite concentrating poverty and the most

violent forms of exploitation, and an intermediate semiperipheral zone. The semiperiphery, then,

functions as a middle-tier of the world economy, able to accumulate/appropriate more than the

 periphery but less than the core in the struggle over the hierarchy of wealth. Late industrializers

(Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, South Korea and Taiwan) and rentier regimes (OPEC) belong to this

zone. The existence of industrial and rentier semiperipheries means that it is not a particular accu-

mulation regime but instead the differential degree in the command of world wealth vis-a-vis other

zones that defines a region or state as semiperipheral.

As for ‘coreness’, it is indicated by a higher than semiperipheral accumulation/appropriation of

world wealth, by any means necessary (Arrighi, 1990). Empirically, this can be assessed through

long-term statistics of national income per capita.7 In the long-run it is not necessarily an accumu-

lation strategy that ultimately indicates coreness, but the successful use of such a strategy in climb-

ing to, and staying at, the top of the hierarchy. In sum, a particular strategy of accumulation can be

described as a sign of coreness during the historical periods when it provides the elements for a

successful attainment and long-run stability of core-level incomes.

During the golden age of capitalism influential liberal theorists argued that industrialization was

a path that all  states could follow in attaining levels of income per capita that, in time, would paral-

lel those of core capitalist societies (Rostow, 1959). Up to that point the leading economies of the

world had undergone a process of broad based industrialization, or better agro-industrialization

since the process included the industrialization of agriculture. In a way, then, agro-industrialization

was a sign of coreness. Agro-industrialization was a sign of capitalist development in theory but

also, in part, in reality. Therefore, the developmentalist illusion was not the perception of a link

 between industrialization and development. The illusion resided in seeing this link a-historically,

as if the strategy that worked for some states would simply work for all others and in all instances.8 

In other words, while Western European and American industrialization (of course, with the sup-

 port of imperialism) did correlate with a path towards coreness, most Third World industrialization

experiences led to semiperipherality. Also, semiperipheral industrialization has brought importantagrarian transformations that underpin it and that I will examine here. On the other hand, oil pro-

vided a parallel road to this middle-tier position. OPEC states have benefited from the command

of a primary fuel for industrialization. As of today some OPEC members have core-level incomes.

The long-run stability of this oil income, however, remains an open question.

 Nonetheless, in arguing that all could reproduce the path of advanced capitalist societies, liberal

theories of development disregarded the fact that in capitalism there is a recurrent ‘adding-up’ prob-

lem. As more rising states adopt a particular strategy, the less effective it becomes in time (Arrighi

et al., 2003). My argument builds upon Arrighi et al.’s (2003) claim that this sort of process took

 place during the 1970s. The growing significance of finance as a way out of declining profitability

in industry constituted a new accumulation strategy. The link between industry and coreness wasundermined and developmentalist illusions became disillusions with developmentalism. Here I pro-

vide a broad picture of this transition by examining the world-historical conjuncture of the 1970s.

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 6/23

6  Critical Sociology

The 1970s World-Historical Conjuncture

The transition from core decline to semiperipheral collapse took place in the years between 1966

and 1982. The turning point was around 1966, with the simultaneous peak and consequent crisis of

the USA-led world regime of accumulation, the onset of the so-called Brazilian miracle and its

agro-industrial transformation, the emergence of a second Green Revolution in Mexico andOPEC’s new claim to higher rents (Barkin, 1990; Coronil, 1997; DeWalt, 1985; Furtado, 1981;

Singer, 1980). The signaling crisis came in 1982 when Mexico, the biggest Third World debtor,

defaulted on its debt. Before events undermined semiperipheral development, the 1970s exempli-

fied of one of historical capitalism’s main traits: in times of cyclical crisis those in the middle-tier

of the world-economy gain in competitiveness (semiperipheral agro-industrial rise) and bargaining

 power (OPEC’s rent) (Wallerstein, 1976). A world conjuncture materialized: recycled oil rents

linked OPEC’s rise with the semiperipheral industrialization of Brazil and Mexico. By 1982, this

conjuncture ended with the debt crisis. I provide a broad outline of this conjuncture, beginning with

an examination of the onset of the crisis in the core, where it all began.

The Onset of Crisis

The accumulation crisis that became a global phenomenon in the 1970s began as an exhaustion of

core Fordism in the late 1960s, when the golden age of postwar capitalism (1945–66/73) gave way

to a downturn of advanced capitalist economies (1973–82). The crisis emerged around 1966, when

 profit rates in advanced capitalist economies started declining. Manufacturing profit rates in the

G-7 economies declined 25% between 1965 and 1973, ending the impressive rise in profitability

that took place between 1950 and 1965 (Brenner, 2006: 117, 141). An analysis of the reasons for

the sustained accumulation characteristic of the golden age that preceded this decline falls outside

the scope of this article (Aglietta, 2000; Harvey, 1989). Also, I will not examine thoroughly the break from upturn to downturn. The crisis of USA-led world capitalism is relevant here only to the

extent that it unleashed petrodollar circulation. Therefore, I will focus the discussion on how rising

oil prices corresponded to the unfolding accumulation crisis.

As I will explain shortly, for the USA the crisis of postwar capitalism was in part the crisis of

 petroleum-dependent Fordism, even if oil was not the main driver of decline. In fact, the problem

of an overall declining productivity of capital in light of increased expenditure in fixed  capital was

the trigger of core capitalism’s problems (Duménil and Lévy, 2004; Lipietz, 1986). I take this

explanation, based on the Marxist notion of the rising organic composition of capital (OCC), as

highlighting the main reasons for the profitability decline of the 1970s. The crisis was rooted in a

declining productivity of capital, measured as the ratio of the market price of commodities pro-duced to the costs of constant capital (machinery and physical infrastructure, but also raw materials

as we will see). This productivity of capital, in turn, was inversely correlated to a rising OCC. A

rise in the latter indicated a fall in the former (Lipietz, 1986). Both can be seen as describing the

movement of the same ratio but in different directions.

Accordingly, Duménil and Lévy (2004) explain that productivity of capital began declining in

the USA and Europe during the second half of the 1960s. Labor-saving investments continued,

holding down the increase in wages, but they were not beneficial in terms of productivity of capital

and, thus, profitability. A rising OCC trend was taking place as the cost of fixed capital overtook

the price to be realized from the commodities produced. As they explain,

This increased weight of capital reached such proportions that its total price, in relation to that of the goods

and services produced, didn’t stop growing until the early 1980s, as the decline in capital productivity

at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 7/23

 José Ortiz 7

indicates. Although mechanization made labor productivity growth possible, its cost limited its potential

in terms of profitability. Mechanization may have turned out to be effective in making it possible to save

labor, but it was expensive. (Duménil and Lévy, 2004: 33)

The authors conclude, then, that unprofitable mechanization lay behind the 1970s crisis

(Duménil and Lévy, 2004: 37). Of course, the horizontal pressure of inter-capitalist competition(Brenner, 2006) and the vertical pressure of workers struggles for higher wages (Arrighi, 2010:

314–315) can be seen as simultaneously causing and exacerbating the tendency of capital

towards unprofitable mechanization. I will take these insights as a point of departure. But I will

highlight the possible relation of oil production to the accumulation crisis explained by rising

OCC. While declining oil production may not have been a main cause of the productivity/profit-

ability decline described by Marxists, it did contribute in transforming the crisis of core capital-

ism into a global phenomenon. The decline in US oil production corresponded in time with the

 profitability crisis. It brought rising oil prices and increased oil imports. The USA paid for

imports of oil with devalued dollars. By the time these petrodollars were recycled as loans a

world conjuncture had materialized.

Productivity Decline and American Petro-Fordism

In the postwar era up to 1973, American hegemony led world oil production by managing oil sup-

 ply and regulating prices (Mommer, 2002: 64). The mechanisms of US oil hegemony were various

forms of national and international cartelization (Bina, 2013; Mommer, 2002). Price movements

 based on American high-cost producers or oil states seeking higher rents based on differential pro-

ductivities were minimized.

By managing the oil supply and regulating prices the USA secured ‘cheap enough’ oil. 9 This

cheap-enough oil lowered the cost of a myriad of products that affected the price of labor-power.The costs of food, plastic, asphalt and transportation, among others, were lowered by cheap enough

oil. It was ‘the fluid lubricating the flow of capital and labor alike … a contingent factor facilitating

the remarkable accumulation of capital in post-World War II USA’ (Huber, 2009: 475). Until the

late 1960s, petro-Fordism created a virtuous cycle of high profitability, high productivity and rising

wages. By 1972 this accumulation regime was unraveling. There was the overall productivity

decline/rising composition of capital in core capitalist economies. Also, in US oil production,

nature was increasingly capitalized. The problem was not natural scarcity, but the inability of crude

oil production to keep up with the norm of cheap enough oil.

A socio-ecological productivity decline, rather than a strictly technical one, was developing:

crude oil output could not grow fast enough and be produced cheaply enough so as to fuel Fordism(Huber, 2009; Moore, 2009). US oil production ‘peaked’ in 1972 at 9.6 million barrels per day

(b/d). The problem resided not only in declining national production in terms of b/d, but in the

global implications of this decline. The norm of cheap enough oil led to a point where oil produc-

tion/consumption became problematic for US accumulation. Thus, in the 1970s we witnessed a

 passage from cheap enough oil regulated by the USA to oil prices determined outside the USA. The

overall profitability decline corresponded with the decline of US oil hegemony.

In terms of political ecology, we can explain the problem of oil using Moore’s notion of ‘capital-

ized composition of world nature’, the ratio of capitalized nature to un- or under-capitalized nature

at the world scale (Moore, 2010). Un- or under-capitalized nature is a relative notion that denotes

nature that is appropriated cheaply enough, because of higher productivity of extraction. The pointis that un-capitalized nature can lower the composition of capital on the circulating side. On the

contrary, capitalized nature is nature that has been completely integrated into the circuit of capital.

at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 8/23

8  Critical Sociology

It depends on costly investments for its expanded production. Think of the difference between less

capitalized (relatively lower cost/high productivity) newly opened oil frontiers versus highly-

capitalized oil production (relatively high cost/lower productivity) in old fields. In the end, capi-

talization of nature induces a general rising of the organic composition of capital because of an

increase in the costs of circulating  capital. A ‘world-ecological’ reading broadens the perspective

on capitalist contradictions (Moore, 2010). In most analyses there is an emphasis on the fixed char-

acter of constant capital, where it means mechanization. This emphasis might be empirically justi-

fied, as in Duménil and Lévy (2004). Nonetheless, constant capital is investment in both fixed

(machinery and built environment) and   circulating (raw materials and natural inputs) capital

(Marx, 1959). Higher circulating capital costs because of greater capitalization of world nature

means higher constant capital costs. Greater capitalization of world nature can contribute to the

(tendential) fall in profitability.

In the USA, from the postwar era up the 1970s, the trend was one of rising capitalization of oil

as a natural resource. Oil production was becoming a problem as demand increased and costly

activities such as extension of old fields and maximization of recovery became a main avenue to

satisfy this demand (Bina, 2013: 28–36). This greater significance of investment in older fields

increased the capitalization of oil in the USA and, by association, in the global oil sector. Production

of oil depended on expensive investments to extract amounts of crude which, in terms of US

national production, never achieved the 1970 peak. The capitalized composition of nature was ris-

ing. While US oil was the regulator of world prices up to 1973, its own capitalization was pushing

 prices upward. In time, expensive oil would turn into expensive inputs for large-scale agriculture

and multiple industries.

More relevant for us is the global dimension. The USA compensated for the decline in oil pro-

ductivity through imports. The overall tendency was reflected in increasing dependency: in 1966

US imports of oil represented 20 percent of consumption, in 1973 it was 36 percent (Huber, 2013:

188). From this angle also, prices would go up since the USA was losing control of the market.

While from 1966 to 1972 the average wellhead price of oil in the USA increased from US$2.88 to

US$3.89, with the oil shocks real prices exploded. These trends exacerbated the decline of

American petro-Fordism as a national regime; it could no longer satisfy domestic demand with

regulated prices.

Core Decline, Semiperipheral Industrial Rise

Semiperipheral rentier states became increasingly central in world oil supply. The USA could not

regulate prices permanently. Growing American dependency on OPEC oil reflected this problem.

Moreover, Third World industrialization enlarged the number of oil importers competing for a frac-tion of world oil (Moore, 2009: 31–33).

In this context, the OPEC shock of 1973–4 imposed a quadrupling of oil prices in a couple of

months (Coronil, 1997: 55; Hausmann, 1981: 253). The shock contributed to turning a core

decline into a transformation of world capitalism. US loose monetary policy before and after the

OPEC shock helped American corporations in buying foreign oil (Arrighi, 2010: 322–324). In

time, the American trade deficit with OPEC was transformed, through petrodollar recycling, into

cheap credit for a group of semiperipheral industrializers (Lipietz, 1987: 140–145). Of course,

industrializers did not wait for recycled petrodollars to come in order to begin this process.

Semiperipheral industrialization can be traced back to the 1940s and 1950s, the moment when

capital-intensive accumulation became the organizing principle of economic policy in Argentina,Brazil and Mexico. But it was in the 1970s that the semiperiphery closed the distance vis-a-vis the

core in terms of degree of industrialization. Almost simultaneously, however, control of finance

at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 9/23

 José Ortiz 9

capital, not industrial accumulation, became the dominant logic in world capitalism. In time, core

countries deferred their crisis by passing the hot potato of the declining significance of industriali-

zation to a set of states located directly below them in the hierarchy of wealth.

One can talk of a ‘transfer’ of the most harmful effects of the core crisis since the rise and fall

of semiperipheral industrial power in the 1970s was a planetary outcome of the exhaustion of the

core regime of accumulation and the monetary policies and financial mechanisms it used to weather

the problems created by higher input prices and declining profitability. First it was loose monetary

 policy which provided the impetus to petrodollar circulation in First World banks. The last step was

the monetarist orthodoxy of the early 1980s.

Petrodollar Illusions

Capitalism’s socio-natural dialectic underlay the transition to neoliberalism. In emphasizing petro-

dollar circulation I argue that the transition rested on the petrodollar illusion. A situation was cre-

ated where capital, in the form of an OPEC surplus deposited in First World banks, created an

illusion of unlimited sources of debt-financing industrialization. Between 1973 and 1982 OPEC

nations accumulated a surplus of some US$400b. Of this amount, 24 percent was deposited in

European banks. The USA got 22 percent mainly from Saudi Arabia through bilateral deals. Of the

USA’s share half went into government bonds. Thus, the other half, 11 percent of OPEC’s surplus,

could have gone into American banking (Spiro, 1999: 128).

While not OPEC’s entire surplus went to semiperipheral industrializers through First World

 banks’ recycling, a significant amount did. These banks received up to 35 percent of the surplus:

24 percent in Europe plus up to 11 percent in the USA (although we need to consider OPEC’s own

 borrowing as somewhat lowering this amount). Nonetheless, OPEC’s surplus created the illusion 

of a flood of deposits. Their unregulated recycling, in turn, exploded into a flood of credit.

Petrodollars were multiplied and re-lent through emerging financialization (Lipietz, 1987: 159).

Brazil and Mexico were among the selected debtors. Both had been prominent in the history of

Third World debt and their particular characteristics as leading semiperipheral economies made

them attractive: strong states, growing domestic markets, already industrializing economies. They

also had some under-capitalized nature. Brazil had the Amazon and Mexico had oil. By 1978,

Brazil and Mexico together accounted for 38 percent of publicly guaranteed Third World debt held

 by commercial banks (Spiro, 1999: 130). There was a connection between the expansion of bank

lending as a result of petrodollars and the expansion of the external debt in Brazil and Mexico.

Economists have made the link with empirical data that connects the recycling of petrodollars with

the Latin American debt of the 1970s (Wiegand, 2008: 4).

Later, it was in part the collapse of Latin American debtors in the 1980s, particularly Mexico,that imposed the generalization of neoliberalism in the world economy. In the 1970s, however, the

monetarist shock had not yet arrived to end the credit boom. The petrodollar illusion created an

articulation where semiperipheral nature (oil, but also agrarian change, as we will see) became an

underwriter of semiperipheral industrialization.

Venezuela and OPEC: The Rise of a New Oil Rent

Let us now examine the conditions for the emergence of the petrodollar illusion. The petrodollar

illusion has its origins in 1973–4 when world oil prices increased four-fold between October 1973

and January 1974. OPEC’s extraordinary command of the most productive oil fields in the worldmade possible its claim to a higher rent than in the pre-1973 period.10 At this stage of the story, the

early 1970s, we can observe three main currents in world capitalism.

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 10/23

10  Critical Sociology

First, there was falling profitability in the core. Second, there was a process of inflationary

growth in the most dynamic economies of the middle-tier of world capitalism. This growth went

hand in hand with the rise of multiple dictatorships (Argentina, Chile, Brazil and South Korea) or

 persistence of de facto single-party rule (Mexico) throughout the semiperiphery (Borón, 1981).

The victory of political repression in the semiperiphery was partly the reason why an increasing

 proportion of global capital moved there in the form of finance capital (i.e. loans).

The third factor, the link between core stagnation and semiperipheral inflationary growth: the

oil shocks and the increase of OPEC’s oil rent. These rents, recycled as loans, provided a form of

articulation between semiperipheral states’ oil and semiperipheral industrialization. OPEC coun-

tries became exporters of money-capital (Ominami and Hausmann, 1985: 457). This way, the

appropriation of nature by the oil states was fully integrated into the financialized circuits of

capitalism.

The shock of 1973–4 was not the product of oil scarcity or of a rise in production costs in OPEC

countries. Although capitalization of world oil was under way its main cause was US production.

Behind OPEC’s quadrupling of oil prices was a reorganization of global power relations. It was the

outcome of the struggle between the oil states as landowners and core capitalist states over who

sets prices and who appropriates the bigger share of net earnings (see endnote 10). Breaking with

a period where they received a rent determined by world market prices managed by US hegemony,

in the 1970s OPEC was able to transform this relation and impose on the world what Venezuelan

scholars conceptualized as an ‘absolute rent’. In their view, it was the transition from an OPEC rent

determined by world market prices to world market prices determined by the level of OPEC rent

(Coronil, 1997; Hausmann, 1981). OPEC’s ‘absolute rent’ was an outcome of power relations

 between core capitalist states and oil states. It enlarged the oil sector’s net earnings by increasing

 prices. These higher prices, in fact, were consistent with the rising US oil production costs that

American policy tried to control through cartelization. In time, then, the absolute rent of OPEC

established the world oil market as we know it today.

In this history Venezuela had a leading role. The creation of OPEC in 1960, in part an outcome

of Venezuela’s lead, coincided with the creation of Venezuela’s first state-owned oil company

(Mommer, 1996: 133). The country was one of the early advocates for higher oil rents, be it through

taxation or through higher prices, as in absolute rent (Hausmann, 1981: 241). Following these

initiatives, by 1970 OPEC had decided on a series of arrangements that could increase world mar-

ket prices and untie them from US control. These developments were given impetus by OPEC’s

reaction to the Yom Kippur War and culminated in the oil shocks of the 1970s (the two peaks in

Figure 2). These shocks were outcomes of a struggle by oil states to appropriate a higher rent

through the expansion of net earnings. The shocks signaled a new conjuncture, where petrodollars

globalized the decline of petro-Fordism.OPEC was able to profit from this new relation between global capital and oil states. By 1976

all oil-exporting states had nationalized their oil industry. The process was translated into an OPEC

 boom. This is indirectly shown by the trajectory of the oil rent as a percentage of OPEC’s GDP as

seen in Figure 2. The graph uses the World Bank’s ‘oil rent’, defined as the difference between the

value of crude oil production at world prices and total cost of production. I take it as an indirect

manifestation of the notion of rent discussed here.

All through the 1970s, oil rents increased as a proportion of the overall OPEC product. By 1979

rents contributed 49 percent of Venezuela’s GDP and an average of 69 percent of GDP for the rest

of OPEC. The USA entered into a trade deficit with OPEC nations and used devalued dollars to

 buy oil. The rentier regimes, in turn, experienced ‘petrolization’ (Ominami, 1986: 128). That is,they experienced negative substitution: non-oil production and particularly manufacturing stag-

nated while oil exports rose. For OPEC (excluding Venezuela) while oil rents averaged 39 percent

at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 11/23

 José Ortiz 11

of GDP in the 1970–82 period, manufacturing averaged 8 percent. Venezuelan averages were 28 percent for oil rents and 16 percent for manufacturing.

Venezuelan negative substitution was not as dramatic but still the share of manufacturing in its

 product was much lower than it was for semiperipheral industrializers (World Bank, 2014b).

While Venezuela and OPEC had a boom in oil rents but did not industrialize massively, some-

thing different happened in other semiperipheral countries like Brazil and Mexico. These acquired

massive debts but did transform their agro-industrial bases. I will not try to explain Venezuela’s

(much less OPEC’s) failure to industrialize significantly, a puzzling phenomenon when one con-

siders the potential of rents as financing industrialization or a more broad based development. But

the so-called Dutch disease, experienced in Venezuela under the form of petrolization, cannot be

discarded as a preliminary explanation. In fact, Coronil argued that since the Dutch disease seldomafflicts advanced economies, while seeming endemic to many Third World countries, it should be

renamed the ‘neo-colonial disease’ (Coronil, 1997: 7). He shows nonetheless that ethnographic

research is needed to explain why abundance fueled a circulation boom in Venezuela’s case of neo-

colonial disease. The particularity of Venezuela’s bourgeoisie with an esprit de corps that unifies it

as a rentier class above all its fissures should be taken into account. There were struggles, but they

tended to gravitate around the distribution and circulation of rents. They were contradictions within 

a predominantly rentier class rather than contradictions opposing a rentier to an industrializing

 bourgeoisie. Therefore, the rentier character of this class, derived from Venezuela’s position in

world accumulation as oil supplier, undermined its role as industrializing bourgeoisie (Coronil,

1997: 284, 358). For the rentier bourgeoisie, however, not all was lost. Oil could provide higher

incomes for all (without redistribution) in boom times, as in the 1970s. Rents acted as a deterrent

to class conflict until prices decreased with the negative oil shocks of the 1980s. By 1995

Figure 2.  Evolution of OPEC, Venezuelan and Mexican oil rents.Source: World Bank (2014b).

Note: The ‘OPEC’ line represents the average Oil Rent/GDP ratio of Algeria, Iran, Iraq, Kuwait, Nigeria, Qatar, SaudiArabia, the United Arab Emirates and Indonesia taken together (it does not include Venezuela which has its own line).

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 12/23

12  Critical Sociology

Venezuela’s exceptional place in Latin America was undone; it combined the highest rate of infla-

tion with the lowest rate of growth on the continent (Coronil, 1997: 42).

Latin American Agro-Industrialization: Brazil and Mexico in

the 1970sBrazil and Mexico, the other main semiperipheral economies of Latin America, could not go for

the rentier option, although the discovery of important oil fields in Mexico in the late 1970s

 brought temporary petrolization (Dávila Aldás, 1983). The contribution of oil exports to total

exports increased from 3 percent in 1970 to 62 percent in 1982. On the other hand, the contribu-

tion of manufactured exports to total merchandise exports decreased from 32 percent in 1970 to 9

 percent in 1982 (Bazdresch and Levy, 1991: 245). Merchandise exports declined in real terms. All

in all, between 1979 and 1982 Mexico temporarily fell into the neo-colonial disease through

 petrolization.

 Nevertheless, the Mexican and Brazilian starting point in the 1970s was at a significantly higher

degree of industrialization than most of the semiperiphery (Figure 1), and their industrial peak in

the 1970s was more impressive than the most. In order to de-industrialize their economies a tem-

 porary case of neo-colonial disease like that of Mexico would not do. It had to be a real world-

historical change in the rules of the game like the one imposed by neoliberalism. Before that

world-historical reversal came, Brazilian and Mexican elites adopted an industrializing semipe-

ripheral path.

Brazil: Semiperipheral Agro-Industrialization in Forced-March Mode

In the context of global petrodollar recycling Brazil attempted an ambitious economic transforma-

tion. While the origins of industrialization in Brazil date from the 19th century, it the forced indus-

trialization brought about by the II Plano Nacional de Desenvolvimento of 1974 marked a historical

transition. This was a plan instituted by the military dictatorship as a response to the world crisis.

Some called it ‘forced-march industrialization’ (Castro and Souza, 1985; Hirschman, 1987).

During the unfavorable context of the oil shock, the dictatorship forced the process of industrializa-

tion. Via massive indebtedness, it attempted the endogenous production of strategic raw materials

and capital goods. This was not the ISI of the postwar era. A new agro-industrialization for exports 

was its new foundation.

In the context of core de-industrialization, the Brazilian dictatorship carried on with debt-led

industrialization. The appearance of new credits was made possible by petrodollar recycling

(Carneiro, 2002: 96). The natural resources of OPEC became partial underwriters of Brazil’s own

experiment with producing strategic socio-ecological resources: oil, metallurgy and hydroelectric-

ity. In the case of oil, notwithstanding the effort, its production remained sluggish throughout the

1970s, and from 1973 to 1979 the quantity of oil imports increased by 50 percent (Carneiro, 2002:

74). No oil earnings for Brazil, as opposed to Mexico.

Still, the notion was that the production of these resources was a necessary condition for endog-

enous development. There is still debate around the question of the success of Brazil’s forced-

march industrialization. Some found it to be a success in liquidating the crisis and underdevelopment

at the same time (Castro and Souza, 1985), while others, on the other hand, describe it as a failed

structural adjustment (Carneiro, 2002). A world-historical perspective helps in solving this impasse.

The II Plano was successful as a response to the crisis and as a project for Brazilian industrializa-

tion, as is evident from the fact that Brazil’s IVA/GDP ratio is higher than in most advanced econo-

mies. It probably marked the consolidation of the passage from restricted to capital intensive

at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 13/23

 José Ortiz 13

industrialization (Cardoso de Mello, 1982). This industrial rise, however, came during what, in the

longue durée, was a cyclical phase. While Brazil, Mexico and others collectively closed the indus-

trialization gap between their economies and the core, world capitalism transited towards a neolib-

eral regime where industrialization lost its trait as a sign of coreness. As Figure 1 shows, the

neoliberal era shows an overall decline in industry’s significance. While the core’s industrial

decline has been the most far-reaching, in terms of national per capita income core countries have

 been able to maintain a comfortable lead (Arrighi, 1991; Arrighi et al., 2003).

While the Latin American semiperiphery got into serious debt in order to compete with the

industrialized world ‘the USA [was to] cut short these struggles by establishing a new development

game that valorized the species of capital that First World countries in general, and the USA in

 particular, preferentially possessed. This species of capital is finance capital’ (Arrighi et al., 2003:

21). This decline of industry is probably temporary. A post-neoliberal era might revive its central-

ity. However, the historical irony is that Brazil’s industrialization was successful at the same time

that financialization, not industrialization, became the dominant logic of the capitalist ecosystem.

The 1970s industrialization, then, was successful in keeping Brazil (and Mexico) from falling back

into the periphery of capitalism, but it simultaneously affirmed its middle-tier character by betting

on means which were rendered secondary by emerging financialization. The 1970s were a success

from the perspective of semiperipheral  development. Brazil’s average GDP growth in the 1966–81

 period was 7.5 percent.

The II Plano of 1974 was a turning point from the semi-autonomous ISI of the postwar era

(1945–73) to the export-led industrialization of the 1970s and 1980s. It was the moment when

 petrodollar recycling expanded the scope of the semiperipheral rise. However, agrarian change

 preceded this process, something often overlooked in discussions of Brazil’s turning point. The

uneven development of ISI into an export-led agro-industrialization was under way in agriculture

since the late 1960s, when the Brazilian miracle of rapid growth began (Furtado, 1981). The ‘con-

servative modernization’ of agriculture after 1966 transformed a predominantly extensive agricul-

tural regime based on frontier expansion to one that combined extension with a new emphasis on

intensive exploitation of nature. This strategy produced a higher rate of exploitation in the country-

side. There was an introduction of Green Revolution technologies, genetically modified seeds and

the increased use of chemical fertilizers. Also, there was a mechanization of production and the

emergence of new export crops such as soy (Brussi, 1998: 259–264, 2000).

This strategy marked the military regime’s technological fix to the decline of the coffee econ-

omy. The use of technological and chemical methods to increased yields signified a new impetus

for the intensive aspect of exploitation. With this new drive, Brazil’s nature provided another

source of financing for the industrial rise of the 1970s. Export of commodities such as soy and

oranges became more important after 1975 (Carneiro, 2002: 75). The ‘modernized’ agriculturalsector increased Brazil’s exports from US$2.74b in 1970 to US$25.5b in 1985 (Brussi, 1998: 266).

A socio-ecological transformation underpinned this growth, symbolized by the growth of land

covered by soy production, which overtook that of coffee in the early 1970s (see Figure 3). Also,

it was symbolized by an increasing ‘meatification’ of the agricultural sector, where the growth in

 pastures for cattle partly accounts for the persistence of an extensive regime of agrarian expansion.

All in all, a new intensive-extensive agricultural regime kept growing: an intensive exploitation of

labor and nature based on genetics, chemistry and mechanization combined with extensive depre-

dation of land, including the Amazonian and Center-West regions (Brussi, 1998; Ianni, 1979).

It was in this context that new voices emerged opposing the deforestation of the Amazon where,

 by 1970, more than 10 million hectares had been deforested (Prates and Bacha, 2011). The Brazilianagricultural frontier, the main driver of deforestation, expanded at a higher rate than that of indus-

trializers such as Mexico and de-industrializers such as the USA. During the period from 1961 to

at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 14/23

14  Critical Sociology

2001, for example, the ratio of agricultural land to total land increased by 6.2 percent in Mexico

and decreased  by 7.9 percent in the USA. In Brazil this ratio increased by 82.7 percent! Soy pro-

duction, together with cattle ranching, accounts for the high rate of deforestation taking place in the

Amazon.

The deep cause of deforestation was the incorporation of Brazilian nature into the capitalist

world economy as a way of garnering export earnings (Brussi, 1998, 2000). The acceleration of

incorporation came during the 1970s, after the dictatorship’s forced-march industrialization of

agriculture. The logic of this agro-industrial change was not the attainment of food self-sufficiency

(even if that is a reality for Brazil, as opposed to Mexico; see Barkin, 1990), but rather the trans-

formation into a ‘nature-exporting society’ (Coronil, 1997). Displacement of peasants, intensive

and extensive exploitation of nature and the emergence of new class struggles in the countryside

mark the legacy of the 1970s socio-ecological transformation (Ianni, 1979).

Agro-industrialization in the 1970s was far from delivering the better conditions for all that

liberal economists predicted. As for what is commonly called industrialization, that is the growth

of urban industries, they also depended on the combined exploitation of nature and labor at high

rates. In terms of rural labor, during Brazil’s industrialization era the price of labor-power was

determined primarily by the production of the small agricultural producers (Furtado, 1981); thus,

the easiest way of lowering this price for urban industries was to lower the prices paid to small

farmers and peasant producers. Implicated in the process through which small farmers, rural labor-

ers and peasant producers ‘subsidized’ urban wages was the extensification of agricultural food

 production (contemporary with soy-led intensification). The low price of labor-power was made

 possible by agriculture’s combination of cheap labor-power and newly opened lands (Oliveira,

1972). Particularly, rural laborers and small peasants were subject to a double structural subordina-

tion: to rural landowners and to urban capital. And in their role as bearers of labor-power, they

contributed to the expansion of industrial capitalist accumulation in three ways. First, producers

engaged in subsistence agriculture followed the commodity frontiers opened by new roads and

Figure 3.  The rise of soy in Brazil during the 1970s.Source: FAO (2014).

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 15/23

 José Ortiz 15

development projects that penetrated deep into the Amazonian, the Northeast and the Center-West

regions (Brussi, 1998; Ianni, 1979; Sá, 1973). There, they could be used for the deforestation and

initial cultivation of the land, and later displaced or controlled by landowners. These landowners

 benefited from this socio-ecological preparation of land, this accumulation of labor, which they

expropriated from rural producers. Second, the high rates of exploitation of rural laborers, small

farmers and peasants as producers of basic consumption goods for urban markets secured another

form of transfer of value, from their expenditure of labor, towards urban classes. The low cost of

foodstuffs derived from the exploitation of rural labor made possible the lowering of the price of

 both urban and rural labor-power (Oliveira, 1972: 18). Third, the migration of rural laboring popu-

lations to urban areas provided a pool of cheap labor for urban/industrial accumulation.

Urban workers were the other forced underwriters of industrializing capitalist accumulation, as

quantitative data on the divergence between real wages and productivity during Brazil’s industri-

alization shows (Colistete, 2007). Today precarization has become a main theme for militants, but

in the case of Brazilian industrialization precarity has been a central element since the early devel-

opment of Brazil’s variant of semiperipheral Fordism (Braga, 2012).

In terms of the capitalist ecosystem for accumulation, however, the story was one of success.

 New Brazilian exports became central in world capitalism. The historical convergence of the ‘con-

servative modernization’ of agriculture since 1967 and the emergence of petrodollar recycling after

1973 made Brazilian agro-industrialization possible during the 1970s. There was no upward mobil-

ity into First World status, but Brazil did not fall into a ‘newly underdeveloping country’ condition

as happened, for example, to South Africa (Martin, 1990, 2013). Of course, the high cost of the

Brazilian strategy (measured by the degree of indebtedness and therefore subordination to core

monetary policy) was to turn the success of the 1970s into a ‘failure’ in the early 1980s. The turn

only came when monetarism avoided the worsening of advanced capitalism’s crisis by switching

its problems onto the semiperiphery.

 Mexico: Industrial and Socio-ecological Change

Mexico’s socio-ecological transformation provides a different angle on the semiperipheral rise of

the 1970s. While industrial activities were the organizing center of accumulation in Mexico since

the 1940s (De la Garza Toledo, 1988; Fujigaki Cruz, 1997), it was only in the 1970s that the degree

of significance of industry for the Mexican economy surpassed that of industry for core economies.

There was a significant expansion of classic Fordist industries in Mexico during this decade. ISI

attained its peak in 1975, when 80 percent of the materials used in the fabrication of cars were of

Mexican origin (Carrillo and García, 1987: 310). After 1976, however, an industrial change began.

The guiding principle was the need to change the industrialization model, basically the need for anagro-industrialization for exports. While the transformation had its roots in the conjuncture of the

1970s, particularly in the recession of 1976, it developed more forcefully after the 1982 default.

Under pressure from international institutions such as the IMF and World Bank, Mexican authori-

ties implemented different industrialization programs such as the  Programa de Fomento Integral

de Exportaciones in 1985 or the Programa de Concertación con Empresas Altamente Exportadoras 

of 1987. Under these programs the auto, petrochemical and computer industries among others were

given incentives which ranged from subsidizing the buying of machinery to the providing of water,

electricity and petroleum inputs at subsidized prices (Cypher, 1991). Overall, as in Brazil, while

the end of the decade was a difficult period, in terms of economic performance the 1970s were a

success. Mexico’s average GDP growth for the 1966–81 period was 6.7 percent.The crisis first arrived in Mexico with the recession of 1976. The Mexican peso was devalued

and both the desarrollo estabilizador   and desarrollo compartido  discourses were bankrupt.

at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 16/23

16  Critical Sociology

With the Mexican recession came the turning point in the uneven development of ISI into an

export-led regime. That same year, however, Mexico announced important discoveries of oil fields

which became important in deferring the effects of the crisis (Barkin, 1990: 92). Thus, while Brazil

was restricted to the receiving side of petrodollar recycling, Mexico joined in the boom in rentier

earnings (see Figure 2), making it more attractive to international lenders (Barkin, 1990: 95). While

the ephemeral richness of oil made possible the deferral of conflict through government spending

in social programs, the emergence of the maquila regime in the auto industry prefigured a new era

of precariousness for labor. The combination of this new industrial regime with a socio-ecological

transformation of agriculture, which I will unpack shortly, had deleterious effects for development

in the future. It deepened the distorted nature of the Mexican economic model (Barkin, 1990).

The auto industry’s use of semiperipheral labor as cheap labor-power meant that laborers’ wages

were significantly depressed. Consequently, ceteris paribus, the use of semiperipheral workers

secured a higher rate of exploitation than the use of core workers. And as in Brazil, the labor of

 peasants and small agricultural producers was central in the reproduction of urban labor-power

(Warman, 1988: 9). But, in contrast to Brazil, the import of traditional foodstuffs became increas-

ingly problematical for Mexican development. By the early 1980s, imports of maize were between

25 percent and 35 percent of domestic consumption.

Moreover, in order to impose lower wages, two methods were used by the auto industry. First

was the moving of a part of the production process to areas without a tradition of militant labor.

This meant establishing factories in the northern states. Second was the feminization of labor com-

mon to the maquila regime (De la Garza Toledo et al., 2001). The turn towards the world economy

symbolized by this process of export substitution and institutionalization of precarious labor condi-

tions led to the increased indebtedness of the Mexican state, since it needed to compensate for the

low wages paid by companies engaged in flexible accumulation.

In terms of agrarian structure, the re-orientation of the economies towards the world market led

to a loss of food self-sufficiency for Mexico and the rise of a neoliberal food regime in both Mexico

and Brazil (McMichael, 2009). Mexico with its sorghum and Brazil with its soy were implicated in

this process. Production capacity was reoriented towards the middle and upper classes, local and

foreign. Resources were used in a manner that assured high protein diets for the wealthy and mid-

dle classes and only partial reproduction for the poor. This socio-ecological transformation was the

 product of the successful industrialization of agriculture. In the case of Mexico, it was the second

Green Revolution of the late 1960s, when animal feed used in the production of meat began to be

embraced as a substitute for food production (DeWalt, 1985). This second Green Revolution, fol-

lowing the steps of the earlier revolution in wheat yields, joined together the introduction of these

new feed crops with the increased mechanization of production (see Figure 4).

In Mexico, during the 1970s there was an annual rate of increase of 13 percent in the use offertilizers, while the use of tractors grew at a rate of 9 percent during the postwar era (Barkin,

1990). As Figure 4 shows, there was an impressive increase in the production of sorghum (an ani-

mal feed) from the mid-1960s, and it contributed to the disarticulation of food production. While

the land used for the cultivation of animal feed increased, the land devoted to the three basic

sources of food (corn, wheat and beans) was reduced from 10.6 million hectares in 1965 to 7.2

million in 1979. It peaked again at 11 million in 1994 and as of 2011 it was back to 7.6 million

hectares (FAO, 2014). The process went on while the population increased and the total land

involved in agriculture was extended by 50 percent (Barkin, 1990). And while the ‘meatification’

of Mexican agriculture was under way, the fact remained that during the 1970s more than 35 per-

cent of Mexicans had no access to meat (Barkin, 1990).This model of development contributed to a disarticulation of these economies (De Janvry

and Garramón, 1977). Semiperipheral agro-industrialization, however, did not implode from

at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 17/23

 José Ortiz 17

within alone. It was undermined by its link to the world-economic cycle of the 1970s. Furthermore,

as with the case of Brazil, while from the perspective of socio-natural wellbeing this agro-

industrialization can be considered a step backwards, it was in fact a success for capitalist accu-

mulation, for a time.

The End of the Petrodollar Illusion and the Debt Crisis

The effects of the global crisis were deferred by debt-led growth in the semiperiphery. But this

impressive growth depended on unstable factors. First, it depended on the import capacity of core

countries. This import capacity was fragile, itself resting on credit-based consumption. Second, it

depended on historically low interest rates, like those of the 1970s. Thus, when US economic

 policy took a monetarist turn around 1979–82, the corresponding rise in interest rates broke down

the global conjuncture. The consequences were deleterious for highly indebted countries of the

Third World. In 1982, Mexico announced that it would suspend payment on its debt. The LatinAmerican debt crisis that followed was the unintended consequence of the crisis of core Fordism

and its management: first cheap credit (Keynesianism), then spiking interest rates (monetarism).

Monetarism brought temporary orthodoxy. It meant an emphasis on ‘macroeconomic stability’

indicated by opposition to debt finance and support of balanced budgets. It lowered inflation

through high interest rates. But it disregarded the issue of stagnant growth. Keynesianism was

inflationary; monetarism was disastrous for debtors. This world-historical reversal prefaced the

neoliberal restructuring of the 1980s, when semiperipheral countries transferred billions of dollars

to the core of world capitalism via debt-servicing and cheap primary commodities.

Mexico and Brazil were not the victims of excessive debt. The problem was the hegemony of

the dollar (Parboni, 1986) and the change in the rules of the capitalist game that the USA was aboutto impose. Dollar hegemony made Third World debtors vulnerable to the effects of US monetary

 policy. The raising of interest rates by the Federal Reserve reversed the 1970s trend.

Figure 4.  The rise of Mexico’s green revolutions (wheat and sorghum).Source: FAO (2014).

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 18/23

18  Critical Sociology

The interest on the external debt of developing countries rose from negative rates in the 1970s

to positive rates in the 1980s. Latin American debts reflected changes in US interest rates (Furtado,

1981: 51–52). Thus, the share of interest on the debt in the GDP of Third World countries increased

in tandem with the rise in US interest rates from 1980 (Duménil and Lévy, 2002: 397).

The collapse of GDP growth rates in the 1980s (2.9% for Brazil; 2.3% for Mexico) indicates the

harmful effects of this turn of events. The high cost of the debt, in its turn, can be blamed on the

concatenation of two factors. First, there was the highly indebted and politically repressive agro-

industrial rise of the semiperiphery. And second, a monetarist attack that broke the link between

cheap credit and industrialization. What followed was a decade of net transfers of capital from the

Latin American semiperiphery to core financial institutions. As is clear from Figure 5, all throughthe 1980s Latin America made net transfers to core banks, since much of the debt paid in that dec-

ade was debt accumulated from First World banks during the 1970s. Mexico and Venezuela had the

most erratic trajectory in terms of this variable, always above (in the positive trends of the 1970s)

and below (in the negative trends of the 1980s) the Latin American aggregate. Latin America as a

whole, of course, reflects the trends in these three economies. In any case, the net positive transfers

 peaked in the 1970s, and the net negative transfers did so in the 1980s, clearly tracing a cycle from

 boom to bust in external financing fueled by the petrodollar illusion.

Conclusion

After 1982, the world-economic conjuncture of the 1970s was undermined. During the 1970s core

countries stagnated while some semiperipheral states seemed to be undoing the historical legacy of

Figure 5.  From absorption of foreign capital to a decade of net transfers abroad.Source: Author’s calculations based on World Bank (2014a).

Note: The thick solid line represents Latin America’s aggregate net transfers. Net transfers on total external debt, inturn, refer to net lending (difference between disbursements received and principal repaid) minus interest paymentsmade during the year. A negative ratio indicates a net transfer made by the borrower to the creditor. ‘Brazil’ (thin solidline) is always close to the ‘Latin America’ trajectory, probably a reflection of the weight of Brazil in Latin Americanaggregate indicators.

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 19/23

 José Ortiz 19

imperialism and of the core/semiperiphery/periphery structure. However, this historical transfor-

mation of the 1970s was a transition from the postwar configuration of sustained growth and pref-

aced the rise of neoliberalism after 1982. What the neoliberal turn of the 1980s brought was a new

wave of net transfers of financial resources from the Latin American semiperiphery to core coun-

tries. The rise of monetarism in the core made the semiperipheral advance difficult to sustain. The

efficacy of the monetarist attack was possible, nonetheless, because semiperipheral industrializa-

tion was being questioned from within by popular movements. Workers and peasants had no inter-

est in the maintenance of a regime that was premised on their exclusion from its benefits while at

the same time increasing the degradation of environmental conditions. The capitalist solution to

resistance was a neoliberal regime even more exploitative (of labor and nature). The neoliberal

 promise of a biotech-based revolution in agricultural yields, and thus of a reduction in official

world hunger, has been a failure (Moore, 2010: 400).

I examined the historical conjuncture that prefaced neoliberalism through the Latin American

experience and its relation to petrodollar circulation. The analysis centered on the involvement of

Brazil, Mexico and Venezuela in this configuration. Essentially, the world-historical transforma-

tion of the 1970s turned out to be useful for core capitalism. It provided an outlet for the capitals

that were undergoing valorization problems in First World countries. For the Latin American semi-

 periphery this conjuncture was paradoxical. Successful industrialization liquidated old forms of

subordination (Prebisch, 1986: 482–483), but brought new ones under financialization.

The question is what happened after this successful industrialization, a process extended to the

countryside as agro-industrialization. The new competition with the core in terms of agro-exports

and manufacture was increasingly dominated by finance capital and its valuation of labor and

nature in terms of short-term profitability. Speculation and the abstract processes of financial prof-

itability transformed the world economy. Time was required before the Latin American industrial-

izers could ‘adjust’. The IMF and the World Bank stepped in with the aim of short-circuiting this

adjustment. The deleterious effects of that intervention are well known: forced debt-servicing,

environmental degradation, industrial deceleration, corporatization of food production, etc.

The semiperipheral industrialization of the 1970s, then, was a temporary way out of the world

crisis. The transformation of 1966–82 belongs to the temporality of the ‘conjoncture’ (Braudel,

2009): a transitional phase within the overall cycle of postwar rise and fall of the USA-led world

regime of accumulation. The precarious 1970s configuration was not reproducible in the long term.

But the reversal since the 1980s is relative. While the mid-level position of the Latin American

semiperiphery was re-affirmed, the conditions of the overall core/semiperiphery/periphery struc-

ture were transformed. If auto-centered accumulation via extension of the home market is to be

realized, the industrialized semiperiphery has an agro-industrial base to support it. Therefore,

future struggles over the world hierarchy of wealth will be of a different nature. A historical per-spective grounded on the notion of capitalism as global ecosystem for accumulation will be tasked

with explaining the meaning of these new struggles.

Acknowledgements

I want to thank Jason Moore and Dale Tomich for their support and for our discussions regarding the ideas pre-

sented here. Ben Marley and Brendan McQuade read early versions of this article and offered useful suggestions.

Finally, I want to thank the anonymous reviewers for their detailed comments and useful criticism.

Funding

A Clark Fellow Travel Grant from Binghamton University contributed towards the cost of travel to Brazil for

research used in this article.

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 20/23

20  Critical Sociology

Notes

  1. Figure 1 uses Arrighi and Drangel’s (1986) classification of core and semiperipheral countries based on

long-term statistical analysis. My ‘core’ includes 16 of the 18 countries they classified as core, namely:

Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Japan, the Netherlands, New

Zealand, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, the UK and the USA. The ‘semiperiphery’ sample includes

Algeria, Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Hungary, Iran, Malaysia, Mexico, South Africa,

South Korea, Turkey, USSR (with data from the Central Intelligence Agency, 1982), Uruguay and

Venezuela. For the post-1989 period, the USSR’s contribution to the ‘semiperiphery’s’ trajectory is sub-

stituted by the average IVA/GDP (see Figure 1 note) of Russia and Ukraine. The selection criterion for

the ‘semiperiphery’ was to use countries included by Arrighi and Drangel for which comparable data was

available. China and India were still members of the periphery during the period discussed here (Arrighi

and Drangel, 1986: 66–69). In the graph in Figure 1, ‘industry’ is mainly manufacturing, mining, energy

 production and construction activities. Throughout the article ‘industrialization’ will be used as signi-

fying productivity growth based on more or less capital-intensive accumulation. Moreover, I will use

‘industrialization’ as implying agro-industrialization, in the sense of the extension of capital-intensive

Green Revolution techniques to the agro-export sector and in rural areas of intensive exploitation.

  2. My account can be seen as complementing the popular laboratory theory of neoliberalism, centered

on Chile’s experience as laboratory for neoliberalism. This laboratory account can be located within

the world-historical trend outlined here, marked by the collapse of the biggest  semiperipheral debtors,

Mexico and Brazil.

  3. A broader picture would include an analysis of the underdeveloped periphery struggling to undo the

legacy of imperialism. I will focus here instead on the relation between the first two zones. A broader his-

tory of the semiperiphery itself would include a detailed outline of the 1970s de-industrializing trend of

Argentina and Chile, which followed the same trajectory towards semiperipheral collapse in the 1980s.

East Asia does require special treatment (Amsden, 1990). While East Asia rose in the 1970s, its crisis

came in the 1990s. I leave the question of East Asia open.

  4. Therefore, I discard the notion of ISI’s ‘failure’ (cf. Williamson, 1990). Instead, there was an unevenly

developed combination of ISI policies (in select industries) and export-led agro-industrialization. This

combination was turned into an outright export-oriented model after 1982.

  5. Typically, ‘development’ is defined as bringing some equalization of economic conditions between

countries. ‘Development,’ however, is always conditioned by the system within which it unfolds. Under

capitalism there is only capitalist  development, thus, more or less inequality and asymmetric relations

of power will always exist. Across the board equality can only be achieved by transforming the world-

economy from one based on the unevenness of levels and conditions of accumulation to one where

equality becomes the organizing principle.

  6. Foreign external debt, total of private and public, provides verification. Indebted countries absorb for-

eign finance capital in the form of loans, be it to compensate for trade deficits caused by credit-based

consumption (which can be seen as a foreign investment in the country’s future production) or in order

to fuel national investment. In any case, Brazil’s external debt stock as percentage of GNI rose from 20

 percent in 1972 to 51 percent in 1983. Venezuela’s external debt stock was 17 percent of GNI in 1972.

By 1983 it was 50 percent. For Mexico the numbers are 19 percent in 1972 and 67 percent in 1983 (see

World Bank, 2014a).

  7. Here I follow analyses that take gross national income per capita (GNIPC in constant US$) as a practical

indicator of the share of accumulation/appropriation of world wealth (Arrighi, 1990, 1991; Arrighi et al.,

2003). It indicates national income including that from net transfers and investments form abroad. Using

this method, Arrighi et al. (2003) have demonstrated that industrial convergence between First World and

Third World countries has not led to significant convergence in income levels.

  8. This theory of a link between development and industrialization has been widely influential. For exam-

 ple, the UN’s Economic Commission for Latin America, the theoretical support for ISI in the 1950s, was

 based on the identification of industrialization with development (Ocampo, 2004: 749). Then 20 years

later, a Marxist was arguing that industrialization implied development and, in turn, that both signified a

weakening of imperialism’s harmful effects on the Third World (Warren, 1973).

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 21/23

 José Ortiz 21

  9. It could not be too cheap as this would undermine important high-cost producers (Huber, 2013: 185).

10. ‘Rent’, as used here, is simply the share of the oil state in the net earnings of oil production. Oil net earn-

ings are divided into profit for capital and rent for the oil state. OPEC’s oil shock, by securing higher

 prices for oil, was able to establish higher rents without necessarily lowering profit rates in the oil sector.

The shocks enlarged oil net earnings.

References

Aglietta M (2000) A Theory of Capitalist Regulation. New York, NY: Verso.

Amin S (1979) La acumulación a escala mundial. Mexico: Siglo XXI.

Amsden AH (1990) Third World industrialization: ‘global Fordism’ or a new model? New Left Review I(182):

5–31.

Arrighi G (1990) The developmentalist illusion: a reconceptualization of the semiperiphery. In: Martin WG

(ed.) Semiperipheral States in the World-Economy. New York, NY: Greenwood Press, 11–42.

Arrighi G (1991) World income inequalities and the future of socialism. New Left Review I(189): 39–65.

Arrighi G (2010) The Long Twentieth Century. New York, NY: Verso.

Arrighi G and Drangel J (1986) The stratification of the world-economy: an exploration of the semiperipheral

zone. Review 10(1): 9–74.

Arrighi G, Silver BJ and Brewer BD (2003) Industrial convergence, globalization, and the persistence of the

north-south divide. Studies in Comparative International Development  38(1): 3–31.

Barkin D (1990) Distorted Development . Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

Bazdresch C and Levy S (1991) Populism and economic policy in Mexico, 1970–1982. In: Dornbusch R

and Edwards S (eds) The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America. Chicago, IL: University of

Chicago Press, 223–259.

Bina C (2013) A Prelude to the Foundation of Political Economy. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.

Borón A (1981) Latin America: between Hobbes and Friedman. New Left Review I(130): 45–66.

Braga R (2012) A Política do Precariado. São Paulo: Boitempo Editorial.

Braudel F (1984) The Perspective of the World . New York, NY: Harper and Row.Braudel F (2009) History and the social sciences: the longue durée. Review 32(2): 171–203.

Brenner R (2006) The Economics of Global Turbulence. New York, NY: Verso.

Brussi A (1998) From pequi to soybean: agricultural expansion and the incorporation of central Brazil.

Unpublished doctoral thesis, Binghamton University, New York.

Brussi A (2000) Do pequi à soja: expansão da agricultura e incorporação do Brasil Central. Antropolítica 8:

77–104.

Cardoso FH and Faletto E (1972) Dependencia y desarrollo en América Latina. Mexico City: Siglo XXI.

Cardoso de Mello JM (1982) O Capitalismo Tardio. São Paulo: Editora Brasiliense.

Carneiro R (2002) Desenvolvimento em Crise. Campinas: Editora de Unicamp.

Carrillo J and García P (1987) Etapas industriales y conflictos laborales: la industria automotriz en México.

 Estudios Sociológicos 5(14): 303–340.Castro AB and Souza FP (1985) A Economia Brasileira em Marcha Forçada. São Paulo: Paz e Terra.

Central Intelligence Agency (1982) USSR: Measures of Economic Growth and Development, 1950–1980.

Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.

Colistete RP (2007) Productivity, wages, and labor politics in Brazil, 1945–1962. The Journal of Economic

 History 67(1): 93–127.

Coronil F (1997) The Magical State. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

Cypher J (1991) La política de México para la promoción de exportaciones: ¿un nuevo patrón de acumula-

ción? Revista Mexicana de Sociología 53(3): 81–110.

Dávila Aldás FR (1983) La economía mexicana, sus problemas y repercusiones sociopolíticas (1976–1983).

 Revista Mexicana de Sociología 45(3): 751–779.

De Janvry A and Garramón C (1977) Laws of motion of capital in the center-periphery structure. Review of Radical Political Economics 9(2): 29–38.

De la Garza Toledo E (1988) Estado y acumulación del capital en México (1940-1976). Mexico City: Colegio

de México.

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 22/23

22  Critical Sociology

De la Garza Toledo E, Lara Flores SM and Torres Franco JL (2001) Flexibilidad y trabajo femenino en la

industria manufacturera de México. Revista Mexicana de Sociología 63(2): 113–136.

DeWalt BR (1985) Mexico’s second green revolution: food for feed. Mexican Studies/Estudios Mexicanos 

1(1): 29–60.

Duménil G and Lévy D (2002) Neoliberalism: the crime and the beneficiary. Review 25(4): 393–400.

Duménil G and Lévy D (2004) Capital Resurgent . Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.FAO (2014) FAOSTAT . Available (consulted 28 February 2014) at: http://faostat3.fao.org/faostat-gateway/

go/to/home/E

Foster JB, Clark B and York R (2010) The Ecological Rift . New York, NY: Monthly Review Press.

Fujigaki Cruz E (1997) Periplo industrial: 1940–1960. Una ojeada al surgimiento de algunas ramas. In:

Romero Sotelo ME (ed.) La industria mexicana y su historia. Mexico City: Universidad Autónoma de

México, 367–418.

Furtado C (1981) O Brasil Pós-’Milagre’ . Rio de Janeiro: Paz e Terra.

Gunnoe A and Gellert P (2010) Financialization, shareholder value, and the transformation of timberland

ownership in the USA. Critical Sociology 31(3): 265–284.

Harvey D (1989) The Condition of Postmodernity. Malden, MA: Blackwell.

Hausmann R (1981) State sanded property, oil rent and accumulation in Venezuela: an analysis in terms ofsocial relations. Unpublished doctoral thesis, Cornell University, New York.

Hirschman AO (1987) The political economy of Latin American development: seven exercises in retrospec-

tion. Latin American Research Review 22(3): 7–36.

Huber M (2009) The use of gasoline: value, oil, and the ‘American way of life’. Antipode 41(3): 465–486.

Huber M (2013) Fueling capitalism: oil, the regulation approach, and the ecology of capital.  Economic

Geography 82(2): 171–194.

Ianni O (1979) Ditadura e Agricultura. Rio de Janeiro: Civilização Brasileira.

Lipietz A (1986) Behind the crisis: the exhaustion of a regime of accumulation. Review of Radical Political

 Economics 18(1/2): 13–32.

Lipietz A (1987) Mirages and Miracles. London: Verso.

McMichael P (2009) A food regime genealogy. The Journal of Peasant Studies 36(1): 139–169.Martin WG (ed.) (1990) Semiperipheral States in the World-Economy. New York, NY: Greenwood Press.

Martin WG (2013) South Africa and the ‘new scramble for Africa’: imperialist, sub-imperialist, or victim?

 Agrarian South: Journal of Political Economy 2(2): 161–188.

Marx K (1959) El Capital, Volumen 3. Mexico City: Fondo de Cultura Económica.

Marx K (1972)  Elementos fundamentales para la crítica de la economía política (Borrador) 1857–1858.

Mexico City: Siglo XXI.

Marx K (1976) Capital, Volume 1. New York, NY: Penguin Books.

Marx K (1979) Crítica del Programa de Gotha. Beijing: Ediciones en Lenguas Extranjeras. Available (con-

sulted 1 April 2013) at: http://www.marxists.org/espanol/m-e/1870s/gotha/gothai.htm

Mommer B (1996) Integrating the oil: a structural analysis of petroleum in the Venezuelan economy. Latin

 American Perspectives 23(3): 132–158.Mommer B (2002) Global Oil and the Nation State. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

Moore J (2009) Ecology and the accumulation of capital: a brief environmental history of neoliberalism.

Paper presented at the Food, Energy, Environment: Crisis of the Modern World-System Conference,

Fernand Braudel Center, 9–10 October, Binghamton, New York NY, USA.

Moore J (2010) The end of the road? Agricultural revolutions in the capitalist world-ecology, 1450–2010.

 Journal of Agrarian Change 10(3): 389–413.

Moore J (2011) Transcending the metabolic rift: a theory of crises in the capitalist world-ecology.The Journal

of Peasant Studies 38(1): 1–46.

Ocampo JA (2004) La América Latina y la economía mundial en el largo siglo XX. El Trimestre Económico 

71(284[4]): 725–786.

Oliveira F (1972) A Economia Brasileira: Critica a Razão Dualista. Estudos Cebrap 2: 4–82.Ominami C (1986) Le tiers monde dans la crise. Paris: La Découverte.

Ominami C (1989) North-South relations in the 1980s: the return of imperialism? International Journal of

 Political Economy 18(4): 80–112.

 at CORNELL UNIV on January 22, 2016crs.sagepub.comDownloaded from 

7/25/2019 Crit Sociol-2014-Ortiz-0896920514540187

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/crit-sociol-2014-ortiz-0896920514540187 23/23

 José Ortiz 23

Ominami C and Hausmann R (1985) Crisis e internacionalización: de la ruptura de la acumulación intensiva

en el centro a la heterogeneización de la periferia. El Trimestre Económico 52(206[2]): 411–463.

Parboni R (1986) The dollar weapon: from Nixon to Reagan. New Left Review I(158): 5–18.

Prates RC and Bacha CJC (2011) Os process de desenvolvimento e desmatamento de Amazonia. Economia e

Sociedade, Campinas 20(3): 601–636.

Prebisch R (1986) El desarrollo económico de la América Latina y algunos de sus principales problemas. Desarrollo Económico 26(103): 479–502.

Rostow WW (1959) The stages of economic growth. The Economic History Review 12(1): 1–16.

Sá F (1973) O desenvolvimento da agricultura nordestina e a função das atividades de subsistência. Estudos

Cebrap 4: 89–147.

Singer P (1980) A Crise do ‘Milagre’ . Rio de Janeiro: Paz e Terra.

Smith N (1990) Uneven Development . 2nd Edition. Malden, MA: Basil Blackwell.

Spiro D (1999) The Hidden Hand of American Hegemony. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

Tomich D (2004) Through the Prism of Slavery. New York, NY: Rowman and Littlefield.

Wallerstein I (1974) The Modern World-System I . New York, NY: Academic Press.

Wallerstein I (1976) Semi-peripheral countries and the contemporary world crisis.Theory and Society 3(4):

461–483.Warman A (1988) Los campesinos en el umbral de un nuevo milenio. Revista Mexicana de Sociología 50(1):

3–12.

Warren B (1973) Imperialism and capitalist industrialization. New Left Review I(81): 3–44.

Wiegand J (2008) Bank Recycling of Petro Dollars to Emerging Market Economies during the Current Oil

 Price Boom. IMF Working Paper 08/180. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund.

Williamson J (1990) Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? Washington, DC: Institute for

International Economics.

World Bank (2014a) International Debt Statistics. Available (consulted 20 April 2014) at: http://datatopics.

worldbank.org/debt/

World Bank (2014b) World Development Indicators. Available (consulted 28 February 2014) at: http://data-

 bank.worldbank.org/data/home.aspx