Demonsant ERSA Workshop

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    1/33

    Family Prestige as Old-Age Security:

    Evidence from Rural Senegal

    Jean-Luc Demonsant1

    ABSTRACT

    This paper aims at studying the self-enforcing family contract between a migrant

    son and his ageing father who remained in the village and expects to receive

    support. In 2004, a household survey conducted in the Senegal River Valley was

    especially designed to account for the complex socio-political structure of the

    local institutions, which dates back to pre-colonial times. The empirical results

    suggest that the social rank of the family within the village, defined with respect

    to the former caste system is a key to the enforcement mechanisms at work.Indeed, while belonging to a prestigious family linked to an aristocratic lineage

    lowers the probability of migrating, it raises the probability of frequently

    remitting to the patriarch. Conversely, sons from historically disadvantagedgroups (e.g. slaves and artisans) are more likely to both migrate and cut ties with

    their village of origin, including their family. Additional qualitative evidence is

    rather suggestive that despite their economic success, low status migrants keep

    being stigmatized in their village of origin. Hence, inheriting his father's

    dominant position in the village represents a strong incentive for a migrant sonfrom a high-ranked family to remit. Under such circumstances, patriarchs from

    prestigious families only, can actually rely on their migrating sons as old-age

    security.

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    2/33

    INTRODUCTION

    Few years ago, working on old-age support in Africa sounded rather strange. This is mainly

    due to two preconceived ideas: first the continent is not concerned with ageing issues,

    second the myth of the vieux sage still pervasive, and has prevented thorough scientific

    studies on their actual situation. In 1994, the World Bank sent a warning about global

    ageing: Africa was no exception as the share of people over 60 year old was forecasted to

    double in the next 25 years. On the other hand, respect towards elders is believed to be

    working well in Africa, though there is a greater awareness about cases of elderly abuse.

    Miguel (2003), for instance, analyzed the extreme situation in which elderly widows of

    Tanzania were either killed or expelled in times of hardships. In a poor agrarian economy,

    food scarcity tends to favor most productive members over young children or elders.

    Whereas children will soon become productive, elders do not seem to be in a position toreciprocate. Nonetheless the livelihoods of the elderly mainly rely on the support of the

    kinship group, and more likely the children in most developing countries.

    From an economist point of view, there is an informal familial contract between the

    migrant adult son and his father. Though not denied to play a role, love and sense of duty

    alone do not provide credible enough incentives for the contract to be self-enforcing. This

    paper aims at finding out what enforcement mechanisms exist to make them abide by this

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    3/33

    the sustainability of the reciprocity without any commitment. Facing the same ex-ante

    idiosyncratic risks, villagers help each other today, keeping in mind that it could well be the

    other way around tomorrow. In comparison, economic theory does not provide a unified

    framework regarding the enforcement mechanisms in the case of children providing

    support to their elderly parents. Indeed, the reciprocity vanishes, as old parents are not in a

    position to reciprocate, yet some commitment exists. Laferrre and Wolff (2006) present a

    great variety of both theoretical and empirical microeconomic models on family transfers in

    general and the children as old-age security model in particular. In reality many

    mechanisms come into play at the same time, depending on the physical constraints as well

    as the cultural context.

    Ex-ante, economies of scales at the household level suggest that ageing parents should co-

    reside with their children, and indeed, intergenerational coresidence is quite common in

    developing countries.3

    However, low-income rural areas are risky environments, and once

    this feature is taken into account, sending a family member away in order to provide

    support for the family in times of hardships seems a much better response. The new

    economics of migration lead by Oded Stark (1990) views migration as one of family

    strategies to cope with a risky environment. This has been well documented in theoretical

    and empirical literature on the economics of migration and remittances.4

    Nonetheless, there remains an unsolved rationality problem: if the gains are obvious from

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    4/33

    in terms of cattle ownership receive more remittances. Hoddinott (1994) tested this model

    on rural Kenyan data, and found remittances responsive to bequeathable lands. What

    happens then in a changing society when land or cattle ownership are no longer sought

    after? Furthermore, in most countries, inheritance division is settled by law. Under such

    circumstances, this mechanism doesnt seem credible anymore.

    Since my first field trip in rural Senegal, I have had the opportunity to witness the influence

    that the former caste system still has in the decision-making process of any villager in both

    public and private spheres. However economic studies in Africa have usually put the

    emphasis on ethnic diversity, rarely incorporating social divisions within ethnic groups.

    Rephrasing Christopher Udry, I decided mixing methods confronting economic theory to

    other social sciences and direct observations from repeated fieldworks in Senegal, and

    among the Senegalese migrants here in France.6

    Having control over the whole data

    collection process from the questionnaire design to the choice of trusted enumerators, gives

    precise knowledge of the reliability of such sensitive variables as caste status.

    After briefly describing the cultural context of the fieldwork, i.e. the Haalpulaaren of the

    Senegal River Middle Valley, I will describe the theoretical framework placing the role of

    family prestige as a central enforcement device for the old-age support arrangements. The

    next section exposes the empirical strategy - from the data collection process to the

    econometric specification - developed to highlight the relevance of this hypothesis. After

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    5/33

    MATAM AND THE HAALPULAAR SOCIETY7

    Constraints from the physical environment on one hand, and the cultural context of the area

    on the other hand, make the strategic bequest motive not relevant. I collected data on

    remittance behavior in the Senegal middle valley where migration has long been considered

    a better strategy than working in the local agriculture sector. In this context, the return of

    physical bequests has become close to insignificant for a migrant son.

    A non-profitable environment

    Less than a century ago, the middle valley was relatively prosperous and therefore

    economically attractive. The keys to success were the navigability of the river, the cattle

    breeding and fishing activities along with the existence of two harvest seasons in October

    and in March. Rain-fed agriculture in the semi-arid highlands combined with the flood-fed

    culture by the river banks allowed such prosperity.

    Several factors contributed to render any agricultural activity very risky and almost not

    profitable at all. Since World War II, the region has a long tradition of migration: repeated

    droughts in the seventies and eighties accelerated the phenomenon. To curb rural exodus,

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    6/33

    impossible to make a self-sustainable business out of it. As a consequence, nowadays, there

    are many schemes and water supplies that are badly-kept. In fact, conventional wisdom

    admits that it is rather difficult to make a decent living out of agricultural activities in the

    valley. In the meantime, migrants engage in conspicuous consumption either for religious

    celebrations or in housing, after just a few years abroad.

    The cultural context: a pervading caste system

    Some historical background on the Haalpulaaren, who represent the majority of the

    population of the area, formerly known as Fuuta Tooro, can be found in Wane (1969). The

    Haalpulaaren are responsible for spreading Islam all over West-Africa, and are highly

    respected for that in the country and the sub-region. They are rigorous Muslim followers.This gives an additional argument against the strategic bequestmotive, as Islam has very

    precise inheritance sharing rules: a son gets one share and a daughter gets half a share.

    At the political level, if the administrative system is inherited from the French one, villages

    have remained in the hand of the traditional chiefs. Descending from religious or political

    figureheads of the Fuuta is the most sought-after social recognition. Another very importantaspect of the family prestige is determined by which social category the family belongs to.

    Traditional Haalpulaar society, like many Sahelian societies, (see Tamari, 1991) is based on

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    7/33

    controversial, as it usually refers to the different artisan social sub-categories: les casts in

    French. In this paper, I refer to the caste system as the whole stratified social organization.

    It is clear that all these social categories were not fixed, but that they evolved as some

    commoners have strategically been conferred a title of nobility as a reward for good

    services, or new warriors recruited among former slaves8. It is important to keep in mind

    that these categories corresponded to a genuine need for a specific job allocation during the

    former era. The official abolition of slavery along with the emergence of the modern

    market economy render this classification outdated on practical grounds. Likewise, artisans

    do not necessarily work in the branch of their groups specialization, though both the

    artisans and the descendants of slaves still suffer from discriminations nowadays. They

    mainly consist of marriage constraints, as well as denied access to land, and to political and

    religious leadership.9

    Indeed at the political level, if the administrative system is absolutely

    similar to the French one, villages have remained in the hand of the traditional chiefs. It is

    really striking how relevant this classification remains in contemporary Haalpulaar culture.

    In this traditional view, your birth determines your personality (cf. Wane 1969 who depicts

    each caste with a specific personal trait). It is said for instance that one should not trust an

    artisan because he may just be trying to seduce oneself in order to receive gifts. Not

    knowing the whole genealogy of ones family is also a problem: it is the case that former

    slaves in particular have lost track of their ancestors... The role played by this caste system

    i d lif h i f i li i l h h f ll

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    8/33

    have economic difficulties. There are great pressures to display generous behavior.

    Maintaining a high social status is expensive as it means giving to their griots and many

    clients (former slaves, artisans...). The size of the clientele represents the power of the

    family. Along with the warm-glow effect of giving, griots directly raise the utility of the

    giver by advertising his generosity, which directly improves his reputation12

    . Aristocratic

    families still ought to give to their former clientele during baptisms, weddings and religious

    events.

    THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK:THE SYMBOLICBARAKAMOTIVE

    In a stratified society ruled as a gerontocracy, an old man may benefit from an

    advantageous position in local politics if and only if he belongs to a high ranked family.

    Few families have a say in choosing the village leader, and even less have a chance to

    become one. Hence, the family name becomes a valuable symbolic bequest for such

    important families. At the same time, it is well known that nowadays, many former slaves,

    or bards take advantage of their position too, and like to remind their former masters of

    their duty to provide them with gifts. Thus respecting this social pressure to give requires

    high income. Migration appears as a solution to finance these conspicuous expenses.

    Conducting focus groups and individual interviews, I was told many times during my

    investigations - both in France among the Diaspora, and in Senegal - that a very strong

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    9/33

    blessing: the duhahu - in Pulaar - which transmits barka - in Pulaar. This Islamic word

    could roughly be translated as Allahs blessing, and it has strong influence throughout the

    whole Islamic world. It is important to bear in mind that it is strongly linked to good luck,

    wealth, happiness, health, fertility, and social success. Baraka can be acquired hereditarily

    through genealogical link to saints, or their contacts (see Schmitz, 2000), but also by a strict

    observance of the five pillars of Islam. It can be transmitted by blessings. Being old and a

    well known good Muslim puts oneself in a good position to have some.

    Since living abroad makes it rather difficult to be physically near your dying parents,

    sending money appears as one practical alternative. Of course, the value of this baraka in

    the eyes of the migrant strongly depends on the notability of his patriarch and consequently

    on the status of the family. Obviously belonging to a prestigious family yields considerable

    returns in terms of prospects for marriage and political position in the village. While on

    migration, he could also benefit from the status of the family to rely on migrants from the

    same village. Besides, migrants from the same village usually live in neighboring rooms in

    workers hostels -foyers de travailleurs in French - reconstituting the village society. It has

    been repeatedly suggested that this is a way of reproducing hierarchic village society (e.g.

    see Ba 1996: 207). In other geographic areas, Whitehouse (1994) describes baraka as one

    motive for returning migrants among Soninke in Mali. Again, remitting can be a way for

    the migrant to pay tribute to the village stratified socio-political structure.

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    10/33

    religious grounds. Many migrants associations were indeed created in order to collect

    money for the repatriation of dead bodies.14

    Aware that it may not be the only mechanism at work, I will emphasize here the role of

    social status. In a patriarchal stratified society. Within the family the patriarch is the

    decision-maker. At the village level, there are two groups of families: the nobles and the

    others (non-nobles). Only the patriarchs from noble families can accede to influential

    positions. To deserve their advantageous dominant position, the nobles must pay non-

    nobles substantial gifts in monetary terms. The non-nobles who benefit from these transfers

    must in return renounce basic human rights: not choose a spouse among the nobles, give up

    their political ambitions, and admit the superiority of the nobles in community decision-

    making. There is an implicit family contract between the patriarch and his adult sons. The

    patriarch sends his most promising sons on migration, expecting them to remit. The

    motivation of migrant sons is to obtain the fathers position on their return. In this view,

    remittances should be observed for high ranked migrants only. The migration of the lower

    status migrants relates to other motivations: trading monetary gifts for social mobility. They

    will loosen ties with their community, and make their new life abroad, taking advantage of

    the anonymity of city life.

    Let us now turn to the data collected to test this scenario.

    DATA

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    11/33

    The survey was conducted just before the rainy season from April to June 2004, when

    weather conditions are particularly tough. It is a time of drought and food scarcity as the

    granaries are empty. The good thing is that since peasants are preparing the fields for the

    rain cultivations, all members of the household who are away, but within reach, come back

    to give a hand.

    The survey covers 149 patriarchs over six villages randomly chosen around Matam.16 Three

    are located by the Senegal river, in the so-called waalo region, the other three are located

    approximately 10 km away from the river, in the jeeri region, one of them being right by

    the highway (the others being 4km away on a dirt track). Waalo villages are isolated (at

    least) 3 months a year during the rainy season as roads become unfit for vehicles, which

    can only be reached by pirogues (2-3 hour instead of 20 minute ride during the dry season).

    Jeeri villagers do not own irrigated lands which are located near the river, but some noble

    families do own waalo lands by the river.

    It is an exhaustive survey, as all the men of the selected villages who met chosen criteria

    were selected. The criteria are that they must be born before 1939, and that their eldest

    living son should have been born before 1979. Information was gathered at three levels:

    The patriarch level: Information on both his social status and his living conditionswere gathered. To measure social status information on the family background were

    gathered such as which caste it belongs to, the family tenure in the village, the

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    12/33

    links between household members, and some basic information on each one, such

    as: education level, economic activity, sources of revenue...

    Finally, information on each child has been collected. Special attention was given to

    children living outside the household, for which I gathered indirect information with

    spouses, mother, siblings, or the father. The main focus was on remittances sent by

    migrant sons to their old father, and the rest of the family. Information on news and

    visits given to the family were also collected.

    Much effort was put on making sure to have at hand the most precise and reliable

    information on the social status of the families. For double-checking purposes, the status of

    the family was gathered twice. First, I obtained the information directly by asking the

    patriarch, then indirectly, on a second round, asking informants (mainly the village chief).

    As it can be a very sensitive subject, the question was asked towards the end of the survey,

    in order to prevent the patriarch from being offended or upset, or even from refusing to be

    surveyed. The question was asked among a series of question on historical background of

    the family, to make it sound like the family social origin. For the same reasons, I dared to

    ask the village chief about the status of my surveyed families, on a second round in

    September, so that we had already got to know each other better.

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    13/33

    belong to free- born families, whereas they represent 71% of the remitters. Table 1

    displays the caste composition of the different samples studied:

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    14/33

    Table 1: Caste composition of samples of interest

    Categories Patriarchs (%) All sons Migrants (%) Remitters (%)

    (N=147) (N=470) (N=213) (N=133)

    Free Men 70.1 72.1 65.7 70.7

    Artisans 12.9 11.7 16.9 15.8

    Slaves 17.0 16.2 17.4 13.5

    As mentioned earlier, the largest caste is the free men category, which encompasses

    aristocrats as well as commoners. To differentiate them, the list of notables was collected

    from our informants. As le conseil des sages is supposed to be composed of the elderly men

    of the village, barely 40% of them were designed as notables. They represent the actual

    and only decision-makers in the village.

    Migrants destinations

    The destination distribution is very similar to previous studies of Haalpulaar migration:

    mainly domestic, the international migration is mainly African, and very few have left the

    continent. 44% of all migrations are domestic migrations, or migrations to the neighboring

    countries, i.e. Mauritania, Mali, Gambia and Guinea. Dakar concentrates 77% of these

    domestic (Senegal or neighboring countries) destinations. However, the capital city is

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    15/33

    destination, but this is still a recent phenomenon, so that the network is still weak, not to

    mention the cost of migration. During my field investigations, I met returning or visiting

    migrants from Germany and Denmark, and also surprisingly distant destinations like

    Australia and even China! Even if this is not statistically significant, it indicates that

    diversification of destinations is used to circumvent tough migration policies.

    It is important to bear in mind that information about migrants is only second hand. I

    assumed the best information I could collect about them would be from the mother or the

    wife of the migrant. I also asked the brothers and the father if necessary. As a consequence,

    one common criticism to my findings is that low-rank migrants are simply not in a position

    to remit as they could not benefit from the network. This is rather difficult to find out from

    the data at hand. At the same time, a recent popular saying circulates in the villages:

    Migrations are blind to castes. Indeed, among migrants outside the continent (mainly

    Europe-US), where expected earnings are higher, the proportion of non-notables is greater

    than the one of notables, and yet the proportion of notables is higher than non-notables to

    regularly remit. Figure 1 gives a more detailed picture of this phenomenon:

    Figure 1: Migrants distribution of destinations, and propensity to remit according to their notability

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    16/33

    Empirical Strategy

    The descriptive statistics evidence found in the previous section need to be checked all

    things being equal. Hence, let us now turn to the regression results.

    Since only those who have migrated can make transfers, a two-step Heckman model

    generalized for probit models was used to take into account the selection bias.19 The

    question is: do the ones with a higher probability of being on migration have a higher or

    lower probability of remitting? As pointed out in the appendix, no such effects are found:

    both decisions to migrate and then to remit are not correlated, which implies that these two

    regressions can be studied separately.

    Furthermore, since there are migrants from the same families (up to 7 brothers), the

    correlation within the family was accounted for using a robust estimator of standard errors

    with family clusters.

    Regressions with different model specifications are displayed to show the robustness of the

    results, putting much effort on the specification of the family social status and wealth.

    RESULTS

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    17/33

    Table 2: Probability of being on migration (marginal effects)

    On migration 1 2 3 4

    (adult son)

    age 0.065 0.073 0.074 0.072

    (2.94)*** (3.69)*** (3.61)*** (3.54)***

    (age) -0.001 -0.001 -0.001 -0.001

    (-2.51)** (-2.98)*** (-2.97)*** (-2.90)***

    Birth order -0.003

    (-0.13)=1 if married 0.02

    (0.32)

    =1 if has ever been to formal school -0.033

    (0.48)

    (patriarch)

    Age 0.009 0.006 0.005 0.006

    (1.23) (1.14) (0.9) (1.16)

    Size of the household 0.008

    (0.72)

    Years spent on migration 0.008 0.008 0.008 0.008

    (2.39)** (3.00)*** (2.76)*** (2.91)***

    =1 if receives a pension 0.025

    (0.28)

    =1 if has received bequeathable wealth 0.013

    (0.67)=1 if landless -0.118

    (-1.02)

    =1 if doesnt possess any cattle -0 157 -0 177 -0 173

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    18/33

    Overall this model correctly predicts 74% of migrating behavior. In contrast to previous

    studies, the number of migrating brothers appears not to be significant. In reality, there are

    two opposite effects: a network and a saturation effect. Having a brother can facilitate

    migration: older brothers can finance their cadets, creating shifts of migrants.20

    On the other

    hand, when there are already migrants in the family, the patriarch may require other sons to

    stay to help him manage the household. Here it seems that both effects are neutralized.

    The age of the father has no significant effect, but the older the son is, the higher the

    probability of being on migration, though with a decreasing effect, as the significantly

    negative squared age variable indicates.

    The fact that the having attended formal schooling is not significant is relevant to the fact

    that migrants do not need to hold literacy skills for the job they will find in migration. One

    must keep in mind that most migrants work in the informal sector, in Dakar and Africa, and

    in unskilled jobs in industrialized countries (mainly in the hotel or catering trades).

    Turning to variables capturing wealth of the family, they all seem to be not significant, but

    two. Firstly, the fact of owning cattle increases the chance of being on migration. Second,

    the fact that his father spent many years on migration increases the chance of the son

    migrating. There are here 2 intertwined positive effects: a wealth and a network effect. Allmigrations are costly but especially for distant destinations: fares, bribing to get documents,

    or to get across the border safely. It usually represents far more than what a basic rural

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    19/33

    airport, then in France. Or even working as boy or cook for French colonizers who then

    took them to France to work for them. This result is in line with other studies.

    Finally, sons of families belonging to the higher castes are less inclined to migrate. This

    result contradicts Guberts (2000) findings among Soninke: she found that only aristocrats

    migrate. It is necessary to turn to migrants remitting behavior to understand if migrants

    from high and low status have the same behavior once in migration.

    Probability of remitting

    Among the migrants, I turn now to their probability of frequently remitting. This model has

    a good predictive power as overall nearly 77% of migrants are properly predicted to remit

    or not. Table 3 displays five different model specifications.

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    20/33

    Table 3: Probability of remitting among migrants (marginal effects are displayed)

    Remitting 1 2 3 4 5

    (adult son)

    Ages -0.004 -0.003 -0.004 -0.005 -0.005

    (0.55) (0.55) (0.59) (0.71) (0.81)

    Borders 0.002

    (0.07)

    =1 if has ever been to formal school -0.223 -0.244 -0.244 -0.192 -0.198

    (2.46)** (2.55)** (2.55)** (2.07)** (2.17)**Years spent on migration 0.017 0.015 0.016 0.016 0.018

    (1.90)* (1.63) (1.68)* (1.76)* (2.00)**

    =1 if lives outside the African continent 0.361 0.371 0.372 0.378 0.377

    (3.48)*** (3.84)*** (3.90)*** (4.34)*** (4.20)***

    # of brothers on migration -0.004

    (0.13)

    =1 if one spouse lives with the patriarch 0.16 0.146 0.147 0.194 0.181

    (1.72)* (1.68)* (1.69)* (2.22)** (2.05)**(patriarch)

    Age 0.02 0.02 0.02 0.018 0.017

    (2.10)** (2.60)*** (2.60)*** (2.45)** (2.36)**

    Household size 0.001

    (0.06)

    Years spent on migration 0.006

    (1.54)

    =1 if has received bequeathable wealth -0.018

    (0.61)

    =1 if landless -0.288 -0.291 -0.28 -0.281

    (1.93)* (1.95)* (1.90)* (1.94)*

    1 if d t ttl 0 026

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    21/33

    significantly positive, which reflects the idea that it usually takes time for a migrant to

    obtain a secure earning, i.e. regular wages. Similarly, living in a developed country

    positively affects his probability of remitting. This is obviously linked to the higher

    earnings available there: he earns more than his own living expenses and can accordingly

    send back a part of his earning.

    Naturally, having a spouse who remained in the fathers household increases significantly

    the probability of remitting. When turning to the strategic bequest motive, results similar to

    Hoddinott (1994) are found: if the father owns land, it increases the probability of

    remitting.

    Surprisingly, no monitoring effects are found here: having brothers living in the same place

    of migration has no significant effect on his remitting behaviour. More surprising still, the

    number of years of completed formal schooling decreases the probability of remitting. This

    is not due to sons studying abroad, as only seven migrants are actually finishing their

    studies, which represents less than 3% of migrants. As shown in the appendix table A-2, the

    average years of schooling is very low: around two. But still, few years of formal schooling

    could be enough to acquire such basic skills as reading and writing, and lead to better job

    opportunity. This could in turn give the migrant more incentive to settle in the host

    destination, and cut ties with the hierarchical village society.

    Finally, central to the main point of this article: belonging to a politically powerful family

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    22/33

    Other Supportive Evidence

    Unfortunately the lack of social status variables in other larger statistical surveys makes it

    impossible to compare this result with other studies so far. As a complement to the

    empirical evidence some other qualitative pieces of evidence which confirm the hypothesis

    made in this paper: some are listed here.22

    To gain respectability in the village the most efficient way is to contribute to the building of

    a mosque. There are several anecdotes I heard during my stay in the valley, about the

    boycott of mosques built by migrant slaves. The Imam who is necessarily a noble, simply

    refused to lead the prayers... I heard a similar story about a well built by a successful slave

    that the nobles boycotted, opting for the more distant well. These anecdotes show that it is

    rather inefficient for a slave to invest in order to raise his respectability in the village: he

    will always be considered as a slave and accordingly will be reminded to keep his low-

    profile rank. The only way to get rid of these social stigmas is to migrate. In anonymous

    cities or foreign countries, he will more easily merge into society and be free in his acts.

    It is noticeable that during my repeated visits at different workers hostels, I met very few

    descendants of slaves or artisans23. This is consistent, with reported cases of continuing

    discrimination against slaves on migration. The pattern is that slaves are excluded from any

    decision-making position in the migrants association. Ba (1996) reports such a case in

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    23/33

    migrants. The study of Delaunay (1984) goes in the same direction as my results. He finds

    that any type of caste can be found among the migrants from the Senegal valley, but

    recognizes that the former slaves are more likely to settle definitively, whereas the nobles

    go on temporary migration returning to the village, and sending remittances.

    CONCLUDING REMARKS

    These empirical findings suggest that migration is available to any social category, but for

    different aims: it can either be seen as an individual decision to escape from a poor socialposition with dire prospects in the village or, conversely, as a family decision to maintain

    its dominant local position. As a consequence, it is obvious that the first type of migrants

    will not be interested in investing in the development of the village but will benefit from the

    urban melting pot to get rid of their social stigmas. The good side of this is that they are

    factors of change as they move from a network-based to a modern market economy. In

    order to prevent rural exodus and urban concentrations, an efficient policy would be to

    invest in intensive consciousness-raising campaigns to get rid of the obsolete caste system.

    This will probably take time and be hard to implement as I found out that this was still a

    highly taboo subject in contemporary Senegal.

    Central to political debates in France, republican values of racial integration andassimilation may differently appeal to both types of migrants previously described.

    Frances model of integration aims to assimilate immigrants by instilling French cultural

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    24/33

    often draw conclusions from surveys that were lacking the social context. As this was a

    limited study, it would be interesting to pursue on a broader range. The recent World Bank

    bookCulture and Public Action (Rao & Walton, 2006) sends a good signal that things are

    changing and that more and more cooperation between economists and anthropologists will

    be expected in the near future.

    REFERENCES

    Azam, Jean-Paul. 1995. LEtat Autogr en Afrique. Revue d'Economie duDveloppement4: 3-19.

    Azam, Jean-Paul and Flore Gubert. 2006. Migrants Remittances and the Household in

    Africa: A Review of Evidence.Journal of African Economies 15 (AERC sup. 2): 426-

    62.

    Ba, Cheikh Oumar. 1996. Dynamiques Migratoires et Changements Sociaux au Sein des

    Relations de Genre et des Rapports Jeunes/Vieux des Originaires de la Moyenne Valle

    du Fleuve Sngal. PhD thesis, Universit Cheikh Anta Diop de Dakar.

    Bernheim, B. Douglas, Andrei Schleifer and Lawrence H. Summers. 1985. The Strategic

    Bequest Motive.Journal of Political Economy 93:1045-76.

    Coate, Stephen and Martin Ravallion. 1993. Reciprocity without Commitment:

    Characterization and Performance of Informal Insurance Arrangements. Journal of

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    25/33

    Fafchamps, Marcel. 1992. Solidarity Networks in Preindustrial Societies: Rational

    Peasants with a Moral Economy. Economic Development and Cultural Change 41

    (1), 147-174.

    Gubert, Flore. 2000. Migration et Gestion Collective des Risques. L'exemple de la rgion

    de Kayes. Ph.D. dissertation in Economics, Universit de Clermont-Ferrand I.

    Hoddinott, John. 1992. Rotten Kids or Manipulative Parents: Are Children Old-Age

    Security in Western Kenya?Economic Development and Cultural Change 40:545-65.

    Klein, Martin A. 2005. The Concept of Honour and the Persistence of Servility in the

    Western Soudan. Cahiers d'Etudes Africaines 45, 179-180: 831-51.

    Laferrre, Anne and Franois-Charles Wolff. 2006. Microeconomic Model of Family

    Transfers. InHandbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity, Vol. 2,

    edited by S.C. Kolm and J.M. Ythier, ch11. Amsterdam: North-Holland/Elsevier.

    Lucas, Robert and Oded Stark. 1985. Motivations to Remit. Evidence from Botswana.

    Journal of Political Economy 93 (5), 901-918.

    Luke, Nancy and Kaivan Munshi. 2005. Women as Agents of Change: Female Income,

    Social Affiliation and Household Decisions in South India. Mimeo, Brown University.

    Ly, Boubakar. 1966. Honneur et Valeurs Morales dans les Socits Ouolofs et Pular.

    Ph D dissertation Universit de Paris

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    26/33

    Stark, Oded. 1991. The Migration of Labor. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Schmitz, Jean. 2000. Le Souffle de la Parent. Mariage et Transmission de la Baraka chezles Clercs Musulmans de la Valle du Sngal.L'Homme 154-155: 241-77.

    Sy, Kalidou. 2002. Castes et droit de lhomme au Senegal. The International Dalit

    Solidarity NetworkWorking globally against discrimination by work and descent

    Statement to the Committee on the Elimination of Racial Discrimination.

    Wane, Yaya. 1969. Les Toucouleurs du Fouta Toro: Stratification Sociale et Structure

    Familiale. Dakar: IFAN.

    Whitehouse, Bruce. 1994. Centripetal Forces: The Construction of Hometown Loyalty in

    a West African Migrant-Sending Community. Presentation at the PPA Annual

    Meeting in Boston, MA.

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    27/33

    APPENDIX

    Document A1: More on the Haalpular Society

    1. Historical background of the Haalpulaaren25

    The Haalpulaaren26

    make up the majority of the inhabitants in the Middle Valley. Towards

    the river delta lay the former Walo empire of the Wolof whereas in the upper valley are the

    Soninke. Haalpulaaren can be found on both banks of the river, further North are the Moors

    and more to the South in the Ferlo Fulani nomads can be found. Indeed, Haalpulaaren are

    believed to be descendant of Fulani nomads who settled in the valley and mixed with local

    populations (Serer, Wolof, Moore, Soninke...). In the Xth century, the region was referred to

    as Tekrur which is where the name Tukulors comes from27. It was first annexed by the

    Ghana Empire, and then the Mali Empire, until Koly Tengala Ba (a Denyanke clan of

    Fulani) in the XVIth century, freed the region from the Manding domination and founded

    the Futa Toro28. Islamization began as early as the IX th century in the area and spread until

    charismatic religious leaders took power in 1776. The Torrobe29

    revolution brought an

    end to two centuries ofDenyanke dynasty. In the XIXth

    century, El Hajj Futyu Umar Tall

    led a jihad recruiting among the Futankobe to resist the French army and founded theMacina Empire in modern Mali.

    Th H l l ibl f di I l ll W t Af i d hi hl

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    28/33

    aspect of the familys fame is determined by which social category the family belongs to.

    The Haalpulaar caste system is rather complex, let us now consider its major features.

    2. Social stratification

    In the next section, we shall turn to a brief description of each category, and the main

    subcategories.

    The free-born (sometimes called nobles, Rimbe in Pulaar) make up the majority and

    consequently are definitely the most heterogeneous group. The standard designation of thefree-born as nobles may seem a little misleading, since this group includes even the

    most impoverished peasants. Indeed, the hereditary aristocratic lineages make up a minority

    within this category: they are the only families entitled to accede to political power (village

    chieftainship). Four main subgroups compose this first category depending on the main

    activity they relate to. At the top of the hierarchy are the Torrobe who are the religious

    leaders, along with some Fulbe traditionally cattle breeders. Usually of lesser prestige

    than former sub-categories are the fishermen (Subalbe) and the warriors (Sebe).

    The artisans (Nyenbe) are referred to as the casted (les cast s in French) as this group

    matches best the idea of caste with job specialization (along with the usual endogamous

    feature it shares with the other categories). All the traditional crafts are represented fromthe blacksmith (Waylibe) to the leather workers (Sakebe) and the wood workers (

    Laobe ). Along with the craftsmen are the bards (Griots in French, Aolube in Pulaar).

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    29/33

    society descendants of slaves are still expected to be deferential to nobles, to cook on

    festive occasions and sometimes repair their former masters house32

    . They distinguish

    themselves by their willingness to work hard. An illustration of their position in the society

    can be found in joking relationships. Depending on ones family name, one is allowed to

    tease people from another clan (ones joking kin) without offending anybody. Usually the

    jokes are very humiliating and are centred on either greed for food or calling the other your

    slave (and the other reciprocates) During my fieldwork, I once had the opportunity to work

    with a man of slave origin who would systematically refuse to interview people belonging

    to his joking kinship. No matter how bright an educated he was, he explicitly told me how

    he felt uncomfortable with such jokes, and did not feel like reciprocating.

    The main form of discrimination is the fact that only the free born and the most important

    artisans may traditionally own the most valuable lands by the river banks (walo in

    Pulaar). Nowadays, cases can be found of slaves families that now own such lands after

    their former masters gave them away but it is still rather an exception. Regularly in

    Senegalese newspapers, there are articles about mixed marriages (inter-castes) which

    prove that it is still a scandal, even in the capital city, or abroad33

    . In villages it is all the

    more difficult for an artisan or the descendant of slaves to marry a noble woman. As a

    consequence, before a marriage occurs, there is always a preliminary enquiry led by the in-

    laws, to make sure of the compatibility between both social categories of the groom and the

    b id

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    30/33

    It is striking how relevant this classification remains in contemporary Haalpulaar culture.

    There is for instance a set of implicit rules that each group must abide by. These rules are

    mainly driven by the sense ofhonour which is specific to the nobles. Let us now turn to

    this aspect in details and in its implications.

    3. The Nobles Code of Honour

    There are many ways for higher status individuals to distinguish themselves from lower

    status ones. Bodily posture, where one sits and how one addresses others in public meetings

    are manners of displaying ones rank. Typically, although not specific to Haalpulaar

    society, lengthy traditional greetings are relevant to the social status of protagonists. One

    aspect is the repetition of the family name, which is called yetode in Pulaar and literally

    means the name that honours.

    Ly (1966) described the attitude of the Haalpulaar aristocrats very precisely in his thesis.

    According to Ly, they are characterized by their sense of honour which does not exist in

    other classes. At the core of this principle, is the importance of always being in the position

    of giving and never asking. It is by giving and being publicly generous that the noble will

    be able to demonstrate his worthiness. When belonging to such families it is an unbearable

    shame to have economic difficulties. There are great pressures to display generous

    behaviour. Maintaining a high social status is expensive as it means giving to their griots

    and many clients (former slaves, artisans...). The size of the clientele represents the power

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    31/33

    Table A-1. The Haalpulaar complex caste system (translated from Wane 1969: 33).34

    Main

    Social

    Categories

    Strata (sub-division) Caste sub-divisions Occupation and Title

    Rimbe(free men)

    Rimbe ardiibe

    (free)Toorobbe Lawakoobe or fileteebe Temporal power

    Jangube or ardiibe diine Spiritual power : ceerno

    Miiskineebe Free men, farmers: demoowo

    Rimbe huunybe

    (courtiers)

    Sebbe

    Worgankoobe Former monarchs: farba ceddo

    Kolyaabe Kolys soldiers : jagaraf

    Mbonaabe

    Local variants of kolyaabeAwgalnaabe

    Helgalagel, etc.

    Jaawambe Courtiers and advisers: sooma

    Subalbe Fishermen: jaaltaabe

    Nyeenybe

    (artisans

    and

    griots)

    Fecciram golle

    (artisans)

    Maabube sanyoobe Weavers: jarno

    Wayilbe Baleebe Blacksmiths: farba baylo

    Sayakoobe Jewelers: farba baylo

    SakkeebeAlawbe Shoemakers: foosiri

    Wodeebe or garankoobe Cobblers

    LawbeLaade Pirogue builders: kalmbaan

    Worworbe (bobi) Kitchen tools makers: maalaw

    Buurnaabe Potters and ceramicists

    Griots: Naalankoobe

    (entertainers) or

    nyaagotoobe (praise

    singers)

    Wambaabe Traditional guitar playersMaabube suudu Paate

    SingersMaabube jaawambe

    Lawbe gumbala (kontimpaaji)

    http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste2http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste3http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste4http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste5http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste6http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste7http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste9http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste9http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste5http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste5http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste3http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste8http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste8http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste3http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste5http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste5http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste9http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste9http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste7http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste6http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste5http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste4http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste3http://web.archive.org/web/20021231022603/http:/www.pulaaku.net/defte/yWane/toucouleurFT/ch01.html#caste2
  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    32/33

    32

    Table A-2 : Descriptive statistics for the initial sample, the migrants and the remitters.

    Initial Adult Sons (N=470) Migrants (N=213) Remitters (N=133)

    Mean Std. Min. Max. Mean Std. Min. Max. Mean Std. Min. Max.

    SON

    On migration 45%

    Remitting 62%

    Age 30.8 8.4 17 61 33.2 8.1 17 61 34.5 8.5 18 61

    Age when leaving the household 27.4 8.3 3 50 27.8 8.3 11 50

    Birth order 2.6 1.6 1 8 2.4 1.5 1 8 2.3 1.6 1 8

    Formal schooling 36% 33% 27%

    Years of (formal) schooling 2.4 3.7 0 17 2.4 4.2 0 17 1.8 3.6 0 13

    Years on migration 6.1 5.7 0 25 6.9 5.8 0 25

    In migration for over 3 years 54% 66%

    Residing in a developed country 18% 26%

    Spouse (of the son) left in the household 41% 52%# of brothers already on migration 1.0 1.3 0 7 1.0 1.3 0 6 1.0 1.4 0 5

    # of brothers remitting 1.3 1.5 0 6 1.6 1.7 0 5

    # of brothers who don't remit 0.8 1.0 0 4 0.4 0.9 0 4

    FAMILY

    Age of the patriarch 73.9 6.3 66 91 74.9 6.4 66 91 76.2 6.3 66 91

    Age of the patriarch when son migrated 69.1 8.4 42 89 69.5 8.4 42 89

    Number of dependants of the patriarch 7.6 3.8 2 17 7.4 3.7 2 16 7.0 3.7 2 16

    Family in region of migration 33% 32%

    # of years the father went on migration 10.6 12.9 0 47 13.9 14.2 0 47 15.0 15.1 0 47

    Family of higher castes 72% 66% 71%

    Local power of the lineage 42% 46% 56%

    Valuable agric land on bequest 58% 61% 56%

    VILLAGES

    Thiempeng 31% 28% 31%

    Bow 18% 15% 15%

    Thially 5% 5% 3%

    Galoyabe 14% 15% 16%

    Hombo 16% 18% 18%

    Thiambe 16% 18% 17%

  • 8/3/2019 Demonsant ERSA Workshop

    33/33

    33

    Table A-3: Probability of remitting conditional on being on migration: Heckit regression results

    1st

    step: On migration : cf. (5) table 2

    2ndstep : Remit (conditional on being on migration)(adult son)

    Age -0.008

    (1.31)

    =1 if has ever been to formal school -0.185

    (1.93)*

    Years spent on migration 0.018

    (1.94)*

    =1 if lives outside the African continent 0.342

    (3.42)***

    =1 if one spouse lives with the patriarch 0.177(2.02)**

    (patriarch)

    Age 0.016

    (2.01)**

    =1 if landless -0.278

    (1.96)*

    =1 if belongs to Family of higher caste 0.256

    (2.85)***

    Rho -0.282

    Wald test H0:(rho = 0) chi2(1) =0.85 p-value= 0.3561

    Presenting only the most suited specification