37
Title: Econometric Analysis of Adopting Dual Princing for Museums: The Case of the National Museum of Iran Authors: SharifiTehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young The final version of this preprint (working paper) was published in an article entitled An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums: The Case of the National Museum of Iran in the journal Annals of Tourism Research. DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.annals.2013.04.001 Suggested citation: SharifiTehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums: The Case of the National Museum of Iran. Annals of Tourism Research, 43(2013), pp. 5880.

DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    2

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

Title:  Econometric Analysis of Adopting Dual Princing for Museums: The Case of the National Museum of Iran 

 Authors:  Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young   The  final  version  of  this  preprint  (working  paper)  was  published  in  an  article  entitled  An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums: The Case of the National Museum of Iran in the journal Annals of Tourism Research.  DOI:  http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.annals.2013.04.001   Suggested citation:  Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung  Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums: The Case of the National Museum of  Iran. Annals of Tourism Research, 43(2013), pp. 58‐80.   

Page 2: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF

ADOPTING DUAL PRICING FOR

MUSEUMS:

THE CASE OF THE NATIONAL

MUSEUM OF IRAN

Mohammad Sharifi Tehrani

Miroslav Verbič

Jin Young Chung

WORKING PAPER No. 63, 2012

Ljubljana, June 2012

Page 3: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

Econometric Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums: The Case of the National Museum of Iran .

Mohammad Sharifi Tehrani1, Miroslav Verbič

2, Jin Young Chung

3

Number of copies – 50 pieces

WORKING PAPER No. 63, 2012

Editor of the WP series: Boris Majcen

CIP - Kataložni zapis o publikaciji

Narodna in univerzitetna knjižnica, Ljubljana

330.4:069(55)

SHARIFI Tehrani, Mohammad

Econometric analysis of adopting dual princing for museums : the case of the National

Museum of Iran / Mohammad Sharifi Tehrani, Miroslav Verbič, Jin Young Chung. -

Ljubljana : Inštitut za ekonomska raziskovanja = Institute for Economic Research, 2012. -

(Working paper / Inštitut za ekonomska raziskovanja, ISSN 1581-8063 ; no. 63)

ISBN 978-961-6543-98-9

1. Verbič, Miroslav 2. Chung, Jin Young

262201088

1 Department of Tourism Management, Faculty of Management and Accounting, Allameh Tabataba’i University,

Tehran, Iran. 2 Faculty of Economics, University of Ljubljana, Slovenia & Institute for Economic Research, Ljubljana,

Slovenia. 3 Department of Recreation Management and Therapeutic Recreation, University of Wisconsin – La Crosse, La

Crosse, USA.

Printed by Institute for Economic Research – IER

Copyright retained by the authors.

Published by Institute for Economic Research in June, 2012

Page 4: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

Abstract

Dual pricing refers to the practice of setting prices, whereby foreign visitors are asked to pay

higher fees than domestic visitors. The purposes of this article are to estimate the admission

fees that foreign and domestic visitors are willing to pay, respectively, for the National

Museum of Iran, and also to examine the relationship between the visitors’ willingness-to-pay

and their various socio-economic, geographical, any psychological characteristics. It was

established that the two segments of visitors differ substantially, both in their characteristics

and in their behaviour. The entrance fees that foreign visitors are willing to pay are

substantially higher than the current single entrance fee, while domestic visitors’ willingness-

to-pay is not significantly different from the current entrance fee. The findings, if applied with

caution, could provide museum managers with the rationale for adopting dual pricing and

with practical directions for setting such schemes.

Key words: Attitude; Contingent valuation method; Dual pricing; Involvement; Museum

entrance fees; Willingness-to-pay.

JEL classification: C51, D01, Z11.

Page 5: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:
Page 6: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

1

1 Introduction

Museums are a main heritage tourism attraction in many countries and in some

instances, they play a considerable role in determining the image of destinations (Gil &

Ritchie, 2009). Museums can raise the awareness of tourists and local populations on

their cultural identity, history and the environment and help to protect them for future

generations, thereby contributing to the sustainable development of tourism (ICOM,

2007). To achieve these aims, though many factors seems to be involved, it is critical

for museums to acquire sufficient funds through internal and external organizational

resources, a process that tends to rely on a public-private collaboration system due to

their neither entirely public nor entirely private nature (Sanz, Herrero, & Bedate, 2003).

Nonetheless, it has still been believed that the government is the main funding

provider for museums. Indeed, the average allocation of government funding has been

greater than the total of a museum’s self-generated income (Gilmore & Rentschler,

2002; Kotler, Kotler, & Kotler, 2008). Of notable significance over time is a change in

this notion, as the government support for museums is reportedly declining (Jaffry &

Apostolakis, 2011; Luksetich & Partridge, 1997). Subsequently, this change highlights

the importance of other financial resources and draws attention to innovative ways to

cover operating costs. Museums in the United States are relevant examples of

demonstrating this change in that they are less likely to depend on direct public grants

(Kotler et al., 2008). Namely, government support for museums in the United States

accounts for only 13% to 33% of each museum’s total budget (Manjarrez, Rosenstein,

Colgan, & Pastore, 2008).

Museums in the developing world have far greater difficulty attaining sufficient

funds compared to those in the developed countries. In some developing countries, a

majority of museum visitors are foreign tourists, while nationals make up only a small

number of visitors (Boyan, 2006). Furthermore, due to recession or lack of interest in

the cultural industry, a government tends not to assign the necessary funds to the

museum industry. Such a situation has induced museum managers to expand their

portfolio of financial resources for long-term survival, and encouraged them to employ

their current resources efficiently. In this regard, discriminatory pricing for the different

segmentations of visitors has taken on great importance as a way to maximize museum

revenue (i.e., revenue management).

Discriminatory pricing refers to introduction of the same products with different

prices to separate groups of customers, who are prepared to pay different prices

(Vanhove, 2005). Its benefits have also been empirically analyzed in some museum

literature (cf. Prieto-Rodriguez &Fernandez-Blanco, 2006). Discriminatory pricing leads

to various types of pricing practices, including dynamic pricing (pricing that can change

quickly on the Internet), yield pricing (pricing that changes based on predicted demand;

usually applied to airfares) and dual pricing (one group of customers is asked to pay

higher prices than others).

In particular, a dual-pricing practice has sometimes been considered in the

museums of developing countries; i.e. foreign visitors are asked to pay higher entrance

fees than domestic visitors (Timothy & Nyaupane, 2009). This notion is based on

different price elasticities of demand between the categories of visitors from different

locations (Frey & Steiner, 2010), and it is called segment-based pricing (Ng, 2008;

Tasci, Gurbuz, & Gartner, 2006). The rationale for imposing dual pricing for heritage

attractions like museums in developing countries mainly results from the beliefs that

Page 7: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

2

tourists from developed countries have higher household incomes than residents,

tourists do not pay local taxes (Howard, 2009), and that it could allow residents with

marginal income easy access to such attractions (Timothy & Nyaupane, 2009).

The purpose of this article is twofold. First, to estimate the admission fees that

foreign and domestic visitors are willing to pay, respectively, for the National Museum

of Iran. This would provide empirical evidence and primary information as to whether

introducing dual admission fees would be feasible. The fundamental hypothesis of our

article is that foreign visitors are willing to pay higher entrance fees than domestic

visitors to the National Museum of Iran. Setting the admission fee at the appropriate

level would be challenging, as some studies have found that the fee could hinder low-

income citizens’ participation in recreational or cultural activities (More and Stevens,

2000; Schneider & Budruk, 1999). In this respect, the findings could provide museum

managers with the rationale of adopting dual pricing and with practical directions of

setting appropriate prices for different market segments of visitors. Thus, the current

article could contribute to the research about this emerging pricing strategy in the

museum industry.

The second purpose of the article is to understand the relationship between the

visitors’ willingness-to-pay (WTP) for museum admission fees and their various socio-

economic, geographical, and psychological characteristics. To this end, a relatively solid

theoretical framework is based for econometric estimation of the relationships between

the WTP and its various determinants. Specifically, we test the hypotheses of positive

relationships between the WTP and the socio-economic characteristics of visitors, their

attitudes towards museums, involvement in the museum experience, and distance

travelled.

We claim that foreign visitors to the National Museum of Iran exhibit different

“behaviour” in all these respects in comparison to domestic visitors, and that this

different behaviour is a further justification for adopting dual pricing, along with the

discrepancy between their income levels. More precisely, even though most tourism

managers in Iran regard the higher income of foreign visitors as the only justification

for adopting dual pricing, we argue that due to more culturally focused motivation of

inbound tourists to Iran they are willing to pay higher prices for the museum entrance

fee, compared to domestic visitors. Culturally focused motivation of travelling tend to

classify inbound tourists to Iran as a “professional segment” of the market that has on

average a finer attitude towards museums and is more involved in the museum

experience than domestic visitors. In addition, they traverse a greater distance to arrive

to the museum. These characteristics increase the WTP and thus may give further

justification for adopting dual pricing for admission to the National Museums of Iran.

Additionally, we shall study whether visitors’ attitudes and involvement are dependent

on their socio-economic and geographical characteristics.

Methodologically, the contingent valuation method (CVM) with eliminated protest

responses is employed as a means of quantifying public preferences and measuring

willingness-to-pay for admission to the National Museum of Iran. Contingent valuation

surveys were first proposed in theory by Ciriacy-Wantrup (1947) as a method for

eliciting market valuation of a non-market good. The first practical application of the

technique was done by Davis (1963) on the economic value of recreation in the Maine

woods. Numerous applications of the method to various public goods and studies of its

methodological properties were conducted worldwide in the 1970’s and 1980’s. Even

though the CVM has been initially and most frequently applied in the field of

Page 8: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

3

environmental economics (cf. Kinghorn & Willis, 2008; Snowball, 2008;

Venkatachalam, 2004), it is being increasingly used to estimate cultural values

(Noonan, 2003; Tuan and Navrud, 2008). Although several studies have recently used

the CVM to investigate a visitor’s willingness-to-pay for admission to a museum (cf.

Bedate, Herrero & Sanz, 2009; Borda, 2007; Lampi & Orth, 2009; Plaza, 2010;

Santagata & Signorello, 2000; Sanz, Herrero, & Bedate, 2003; Tohmo, 2004), we are

not aware of comprehensive studies using the CVM to adopt a dual pricing system for a

museum, especially for the developing countries.

The outline of the article is as follows. In Chapter 2, the argumentation of entry fees

for a museum is given and the variables affecting the willingness-to-pay are derived. In

Chapter 3, the case of the National Museum of Iran is presented in brief. In Chapter 4,

the contingent valuation method is outlined, with a theoretical framework for

econometric estimation of willingness-to-pay for admission to a museum. Additionally,

the questionnaire and the data are presented, with some of the issues that arose during

the conduct of the study. Chapter 5 presents the empirical results; the descriptive

statistics with unconditional willingness-to-pay on one hand and the results of

(conditional) econometric estimation of willingness-to-pay on the other. The article

concludes in Chapter 6 with the key findings of the analysis and some suggestions

regarding the adoption of dual pricing for a museum.

2 Entrance fees to a museum and variables affecting the willingness-to-pay

2.1 Argumentation of entrance fees to a museum

The essence of introducing admission fees to public museums has been controversial

and extensively discussed (Anderson, 1998; Lampi & Orth, 2009). On one hand, some

researchers, including Peacock (1994), O’Hagan (1995), Bailey and Falconer (1998) are

in favour of charging entrance fees, arguing that they could improve the quality and

standard of museums and even increase the number of audiences. On the other hand,

some researchers, museum directors and politicians (cf. Anderson, 1998; Johnson &

Thomas, 1998) propose another line of thought, whereby charges would more likely be

a barrier, particularly for those in lower socio-economic classes (Schrijvershop, 2007).

The debate about museum entrance fees has been underway since the first national

museum – the British Museum – was established in the U.K. (Anderson, 1998). It

encompasses various political, cultural, recreational and educational subjects (Bailey et

al., 1997). Since the British Museum was established in 1753 as a result of Hans

Sloane’s donation, no one has been charged for an entrance fee to that museum (Frey &

Meier, 2006). The rationale of a no-fee policy is that imposing fees would serve as an

obstacle to the public attendance and oppose the ideology and mission of a museum in

terms of its educational grounds (Dickenson, 2005). Furthermore, in addition to the

British Museum, most of the later-established museums in 1980s were sufficiently

supported by donor groups and governmental institutions. Consequently, such a

situation offered little incentive to generate earned income (Frey & Meier, 2006).

However, under the pressure of decreasing public funds and cost extensions since

the late 1980s and into the early 1990s, many national museums and galleries have been

encouraged to raise revenue through admission fees, special exhibitions, event fees,

renting rooms or shop sales (Dickenson, 2005; Martin, 2007). Accordingly, they have

Page 9: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

4

adopted various pricing practices to generate revenue and promote efficient marketing

(Kotler et al., 2008). By considering various circumstances and influencing factors,

most museums in many countries have introduced a certain level of entrance fees as one

of their internal funding sources (Cowell, 2007; Trupiano, 2005). Most museums have

maintained their policies with the exception of a few countries, including the U.K.,

Ireland, Germany, France, Hungary and Denmark, where the free admission to public

museums policy has been set over the past few years (Lampi & Orth, 2009).

2.2 Variables affecting the willingness-to-pay

Estimating individuals’ willingness-to-pay for a commodity has generated considerable

attention from many studies, based on demand and utility functions (cf. Noonan, 2002;

2003; Venkatachalam, 2004). In spite of sometimes-conflicting findings, socio-

economic characteristics, such as age, gender, household size, education and income,

are the most common variables used to estimate the WTP. For instance, Santagata and

Signorello (2000) found a significant negative relationship between the age of

respondents and the WTP contributing to the continued existence of a museum, while

the size of the household and level of education were positively associated with the

WTP. Lampi and Orth (2009) also estimated visitors’ WTP for a museum before and

after implementing entrance fees, and analyzed the effects of their socio-economic

characteristics upon the WTP. They found that the introduction of entrance fees resulted

in a change in the structure of visitors towards more female and younger visitors.

Education plays an important role in appreciating heritage assets, being one of the

most efficient predictors of participation in cultural activities (Garrod & Fyall, 2000). In

other words, the higher the education level, the higher the likelihood of engaging in

cultural activities, including visiting museums (Kawashima, 1998; Richards, 2005;

Schrijvershop, 2007). Thus, it is not surprising that visitors’ WTP for cultural activities

is significantly influenced by their educational attainment.

In developing countries, charging higher prices for foreigners compared to other

segments of the population has been perceived by museum managers as fair,

fundamentally owing to higher income, on average, of foreign visitors. However, in this

article, in a novel line of thought, three variables – attitude, distance and involvement –

are also deemed an important justification for adopting a dual pricing strategy. In the

following, an attempt has been made to analyse how these variables make a distinction

in the behaviour of individuals in terms of their willingness-to-pay for a commodity or

service to be valued.

The first variable to consider is the so-called set of attitude characteristics1. The

findings of previous studies demonstrated that psychological constructs, such as

attitudes toward the goods or services in question extend the CVM models’ goodness of

fit (Bernath & Roschewitz, 2008); and – moving one step forward – some have also

indicated that the psychological variables are better predictors of WTP than socio-

economic variables (cf. López-Mosquera & Sánchez, 2011). Such findings have induced

more empirical research to gain a better understanding of how diverse psychological

variables influence consumers’ WTP, so as to provide guidelines on policy-making and

1 Eagly and Chaiken (1993, p. 1) defined attitude as a “psychological tendency that is expressed by

evaluating a particular entity with some degree of favour or disfavour”.

Page 10: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

5

marketing activities, such as delivering appropriate goods and services with optimal

prices based on priorities held by consumers2.

A positive attitude towards the goods to be valued is most likely to result in higher

WTP for the users. For instance, Chung et al. (2011) argued that individuals who

exhibit a positive attitude towards the purposes of fees in the national forest (e.g.

improving facilities, increasing environmental protection, and developing education

programs) are more likely to have a relatively higher WTP. In a study of economic

valuation of the Gullfoss Waterfall in Iceland, Reynisdottir et al. (2008) also

demonstrated that visitors’ attitudes towards environmental protection positively

affected their WTP. The theoretical implications given by the environmental

psychology literature are applicable in the cultural heritage context, where so far little

attention has been paid to this subject (Tufts & Milne, 1999).

Another aspect, related to this variable, is that cultural attitude may play a critical

role in deciding whether to visit cultural and heritage sites. This is particularly the case

for inbound tourists to Iran, positioned primarily as a cultural destination, thus one of

the main expected motivations for travelling is to visit cultural attractions. This tends to

suggest that the foreign visitors’ WTP may be substantially influenced by their cultural

motivations and attitudes, along with income levels. Given that there are differences in

income levels, cultural attitudes and motivation between foreign and domestic visitors,

it is suggested that a difference exists in WTP between the two segments of visitors to

the National Museum of Iran. The assessment of this gap is expected to provide

implications for the feasibility of dual pricing.

Distance is another variable used to examine its potential for justification of dual

pricing. Given that a museum admission fee constitutes only a small fraction of the total

travel costs, it appears reasonable that inbound tourists, travelling a long distance to

arrive at their destination, are less price-sensitive and are prepared to pay higher prices

for a cultural attraction, than local visitors (Frateschi, Lazzaro, & Martos, 2009;

Schrijvershop, 2007). Additionally, the greater the distance the higher (usually) the

travel cost (Bedate et al., 2004; Brons, Pels, Nijkamp, & Rietveld, 2002). Thus, it is

reasonable to assume that the distance travelled from the point of origin to the

destination is negatively related to visitors’ sensitivity to admission fees. The effect of

geographic distance has also been identified in some CVM-based studies that focused

on environmental goods, i.e. farther distance led to higher WTP for site entrance fees

(Hornsten & Fredman, 2000; Loomis and Santiago, 2011; Reynisdottir, Song, &

Agrusa, 2008). Consistent findings in the environmental psychology literature are likely

to extend to other contexts, including cultural heritage sites, where so far little is known

about this relationship.

One should also keep in mind in analyzing the WTP the involvement of a consumer

in the product or service under consideration3. There are some diverse findings in the

literature regarding the dimensions of involvement. Laurent and Kapferer (1985), for

example, revealed components of involvement, such as importance, pleasure, perceived

probability and consequence of risk, and sign value. McIntyre and Pigram (1992)

conceptualized three dimensions of involvement: attraction (perceived importance of an

2 With respect to entry fees, a large body of CVM research on visitors’ attitudes has been conducted,

particularly focusing on environmental goods (cf. Bernath and Roschewitz, 2008; Chung et al., 2011; Lee

and Han, 2002; Meyerhoff, 2006). 3 Involvement refers here to a psychological state of motivation, arousal and interest in an activity under

consideration (cf. Havitz and Dimanche, 1997; Kyle et al., 2004).

Page 11: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

6

activity and pleasure from the activity), self-expression (identity affirmation, derived by

participation in an activity), and centrality (the position the activity occupies in an

individual’s overall lifestyle). The former is relatively close to consumer involvement in

a product context, while the latter is rather applicable to the leisure activity context. It

has also been found that patterns of involvement vary by activities, products and

individual characteristics (Havitz & Dimanche, 1997; Kyle Graefe, Manning, &Bacon,

2004). Anyhow, what has been consistently demonstrated over the years is that the level

of involvement in an activity is determined by the degree of individual’s interest in the

activity and to what extent he or she is willing to engage in the activity.

Although visiting a museum and gallery is regarded as one of the recreational

activities, there seems to be few studies that examined the psychological or behavioural

involvement in cultural activities. Kirchberg (1998) suggested that individuals who

often visit museums are less likely to regard admission fees as an obstacle to attendance,

compared to those who make fewer visits. In a valuation study by Tuan and Navrud

(2008), foreign visitors were more willing to pay fees for preservation if the main

motivation was to visit historical cities and they experienced the site before the visit.

Salazar and Marques (2005) also found a positive relationship between the extent of

respondents’ interest in consuming cultural goods and their WTP.

Similarly to the attitude characteristics, it is expected that culturally focused

motivation of inbound tourists to Iran or at least those foreign visitors that have

travelled from afar to visit the National Museum of Iran, establish a “professional

segment” of visitors, who are more involved in the museum experience and

subsequently posses a higher WTP than domestic visitors.

3 The case of the National Museum of Iran

The National Museum of Iran, in the capital city of Tehran, was open to the public in

1944. In 1996, the museum extended to two separate buildings on the same site for the

pre-and post-Islamic periods, displaying an approximate 300,000 museum artefacts in

an area more than 20,000 square meters, with some 60 full-time employees. The

National Museum of Iran is the country’s largest museum of history and archaeology

that exhibits a variety of exquisite artefacts as long ago as the 800,000 BC through two

centuries ago mostly discovered in archaeological excavations from different areas of

Iran. The architectural style of the pre-Islamic building (two floors) and the post-Islamic

building (four floors) are fundamentally inspired by the ancient Persian Sassanid

dynasty (distinctive red bricks and a magnificent entry portal; see Figure 1) and a

combination of Islamic historical and modern elements, respectively (Mozaffary, 2007).

According to visitor statistics, nearly 200,000 visits were made to the museum from 1

December 2010 to 30 November 2011, of which about 21,500 were foreign tourists4.

4 More information about the National Museum of Iran, together with a presentation of its collections, can

be obtained from the official website: www.nationalmuseumofiran.ir.

Page 12: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

7

Figure 1: Main entrance to the National Museum of Iran (Sassanid architecture)

Source: Authors’ photograph.

The current entry charge to the pre-Islamic section of the National Museum of Iran

is RLS 10,000 (equivalent to USD 0.71) per adult. At the time, this pricing structure had

been established five years earlier5, with no price discrimination between residents and

foreign visitors. This has promoted a wide discussion by relevant domestic experts and

managers that the current entrance fee is too low to capture the economic value that

foreign visitors place on their visits and to contribute appropriate economic input into

the museum (cf. Tehrani, 2011). The relatively low level of the entrance fee to the

National Museum of Iran can also be criticized as not appropriately reflecting the

demand of the inbound tourists market. In other words, the National Museum of Iran

would be a “must-see” attraction for international tourists, as it has unbeatable

characteristics that no competitors in Iran can provide. Thus, it might be reasonable to

suppose that the foreign visitors of the National Museum of Iran are willing to pay more

than what has been charged (i.e. USD 0.71), due to the unique cultural heritage values

that the museum possesses.

5 Note that, as the post-Islamic section of the museum has been closed for the past four years, the current

study was conducted only at the pre-Islamic section.

Page 13: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

8

4 Methodology and the data

4.1 The contingent valuation method

The study employed the contingent valuation method (CVM), a widely applied

technique of economic valuation of non-priced public goods and services, where there is

neither accessible nor reliable information on prices (Aadland & Caplan, 2006; Chung,

2008; Throsby, 2003). A hypothetical scenario is given to individuals who are directly

asked their maximum WTP for the benefits received (Lee and Han, 2002; Sanz et al.,

2003; Veisten, 2007). The scenario informs the respondents of what would be charged

or what would be changed in a setting in terms of quality or quantity (Reynisdottir et

al., 2008). In fact, the WTP values are contingent upon the special hypothetical market

presented to respondents, thus the title (Mitchell & Carson, 1989). Historically, since

Davis (1963) first applied the CVM in general, it was first applied in the field of arts in

the early 1980s (Throsby, 2003) and in the field of cultural heritage in the 1990s

(Salazar & Marques, 2005), respectively.

In CVM-based direct stated preferences there are several ways to elicit WTP

information, including dichotomous choice (Verbič and Slabe-Erker, 2009), payment

cards and auction bidding (Choi, Ritche, Papandrea, & Bennett, 2010), referendum,

iterative bidding game and open-ended formats (Dutta, Banerjee, & Husain, 2007). In

this study, an open-ended format is used, whereby a respondent is asked to state his or

her maximum willingness-to-pay for a product or service in monetary terms, without

any suggested prices. An advantage of this kind of a format in comparison to closed-

ended questioning is that the former has no anchoring effects in that the respondents’

WTP is not influenced by a given price, and has therefore been frequently used in the

literature (cf. Hornsten & Fredman, 2000; Kyle, Graefe, & Absher, 2002; Lampi &

Orth, 2009; Sattout, Talhouk & Caligari, 2007; Solino, Prada & Vazquez, 2010).

However, there exists a sound criticism against open-ended questioning regarding

its high number of zero, “protest” zero, missing and extreme values, as there is no

implicit clue for respondents to think of their WTP (Lampi & Orth, 2009; Whitehead,

2006). In this study such problems have been tried to be avoided by using face-to-face

interviews and a question asking the reason of zero WTP, aimed at distinguishing valid

(i.e. zero WTP in accordance with economic behaviour, such as restrictions on income)

and protest zero responses (i.e. zero WTP indicating dissatisfaction with some aspects

of the presented hypothetical market or, in this case, the quality of a museum, cf. Bedate

et al., 2011). Additionally, the survey was conducted after the respondents’ experience

of the National Museum of Iran, so as to lead to real valuation.

As to the hypothetical nature of the CVM, it is argued that hypothetically measured

WTP may be higher than the real WTP (cf. Borda, 2007; Lusk and Hudson, 2004;

Venkatachalam, 2004). In order to reduce this “hypothetical bias” (i.e. the discrepancy

between the hypothetical WTP and the real payment), we used the so-called “cheap talk

script” prior to the WTP question. This was originally suggested by Cummings and

Taylor (1999), where respondents are explicitly reminded of potential biases in a

hypothetical scenario (Aadland & Caplan, 2006; Lampi & Orth, 2009). Previous

empirical studies show that the cheap talk script is useful in removing the hypothetical

bias (Casey, Brown, & Schumann, 2010).

In this article, based on the literature outlined in Chapter 2, the CVM is analyzed

using the following function to explain the maximum WTP (dependent variable wtp,

Page 14: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

9

obtained by an open-ended format) of respondents for an entrance fee to the National

Museum of Iran:

{ }, , ,wtp f= D G A I , (1)

where D is a vector of socio-economic characteristics, G measures geographical

characteristics, A measures attitude characteristics, and I is a vector of involvement

characteristics. Among the socio-economic characteristics, we have age, a, gender, g,

educational attainment of respondents, e, and their monthly income, y, i.e.

( , , , )a g e y=D . The geographical characteristics are represented by the distance from

respondent’s place of residence to the site, d, i.e. ( )d=G . The attitude characteristics

are represented by respondent’s general opinion about museums, o, i.e. ( )o=A . At last,

among the involvement characteristics, we have the respondent’s knowledge about

museums, k, the average number of visits to museums per year, v, and the respondent’s

knowledge of the National Museum of Iran before the visit, m, i.e. ( , , )k v m=I .

4.2 Questionnaire and the data

The interview questionnaire consisted of four sections6. Section 1 was designed to

measure the respondents’ level of involvement and their attitudes toward museums,

respectively. First, the respondents were inquired about the average number of visits to

museums per year, the knowledge about museums in general, and previous knowledge

of the National Museum of Iran. The latter two were subjectively evaluated based on a

five-point scale (ranging from 1 = “none at all” to 5 = “very high”). Subsequently, in

order to gauge respondents’ attitude towards museums, the following six statements

were presented and subjectively evaluated based on a five-point Likert scale (ranging

from 1 = “strongly disagree” to 5 = “strongly agree”):

1. “Museums play an important role in preserving communities’ heritage.”

2. “Museums facilitate communities’ perception of their history, culture and identity.”

3. “I attempt not to harm museums’ collections during my visit.”

4. “Visiting a museum is one of my main activities during the travel.”

5. “I support stringent regulations against smuggling museums’ collections.”

6. “Visiting a museum is an ideal recreational activity at leisure.”

In addition, motivation of a respondent for visiting Iran (Tehran), as well as the

National Museum of Iran was inquired using nominal items.

Section 2 measured the maximum WTP for entrance fee to the National Museum of

Iran. As mentioned earlier, we employed a “cheap talk script” prior to the open-ended

WTP question to reduce the possibility of a hypothetical bias. The hypothetical scenario

and the WTP question were then presented as follows:

6 The questionnaire was designed separately for foreign visitors in English language and for national

visitors in Persian language.

Page 15: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

10

“The scarcity of financial resources is a major challenge for the National Museum of

Iran, and cultural tourists and visitors seem viable means to generate revenues through

entry fees. The National Museum of Iran relies on this self-generated revenue for

fulfilling its main functions in society, including collecting, preserving and exhibiting

artefacts, as well as developing educational programs. Thinking about the experience

you have had visiting the National Museum of Iran, what is the maximum willingness-

to-pay in terms of an entrance fee, before you would decide not to visit this museum?”

If a respondent claimed that the entry fee should be zero, he or she was requested to

give a specific reason for this.

Section 3 had a single question, inquiring the city of residence of the respondent.

This question was aimed to gather information to calculate the distance between

respondent’s place of residence and the National Museum of Iran.

Section 4 included inquiries about the respondent’s socio-economic characteristics,

including age, gender (0 = “male”, 1 = “female”), education, and (net) monthly

household income. Information on education level was collected based on a five-point

scale (1 = “high school diploma or below”, 2 = “associate degree”, 3 = “bachelor’s

degree”, 4 = “master’s degree”, and 5 = “doctorate degree”). This was then converted to

years of schooling, taking into account (at least to some extent) different education

systems. Information on monthly household income was collected in Iranian rials (IRR)

for residents and US dollars (USD) for foreigners. Monthly household income of

residents was then converted to USD using the appropriate exchange rate.

In order to ensure the validity of measurement, the initial version of the

questionnaire was preliminarily examined by researchers with expertise in contingent

valuation and museum industry. A pre-test was then conducted in December 2010 using

two equal groups in size of domestic and foreign visitors to the National Museum of

Iran, totalling 60 visitors, to assess its logical consistency, ease of understanding and

applicability of the questions. The pre-test suggested that a few questions needed to be

changed in its wording.

The main survey was conducted by face-to-face interviews, which lasted for eight

days in Spring 2011, when no temporary exhibition existed (and thus no associated bias

arose) during that period at the museum. The sample included interviewees over 18

years of age, who were approached by random sampling at the main entrance of the

National Museum of Iran after their museum visit. Contrary to the willingness of almost

all domestic visitors for participation, approximately one third of foreign visitors

refused the survey due to scarce time of their travelling tours or language barriers. Of a

total of 613 interview questionnaires (392 from domestic visitors and 221 from foreign

visitors) 35 responses were excluded because of incomplete information. Consequently,

578 questionnaires (371 from domestic visitors and 207 from foreign visitors) were

considered for the analysis.

Finally, zero values of WTP from the sample were analyzed. It turned out that

domestic and foreign respondents gave 12.9% and 4.8% zero responses to the maximum

WTP question, respectively. The reasons for not being willing to pay the fee included

lack of attractiveness of exhibitions, inability to pay, lack of quality of museum

services, resistance to paying an entrance fee to the National Museum of Iran, and other

Page 16: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

11

reasons.7 This was then used to distinguish true (valid) zero response from protest zero

responses. In the following analysis, “resistance to paying an entrance fee” responses

(17 and 1 responses from domestic and foreign visitors, respectively) were regarded as

protest zero responses and thus eliminated, as it is argued that such responses may

produce bias in CVM estimates (cf. Solino et al., 2010; Verbič and Slabe-Erker, 2009).

Consequently, 560 questionnaires (354 from domestic visitors and 206 from foreign

visitors) were used in the analysis.

5 Empirical results and the analysis

5.1 Sample characteristics

Descriptive statistics of the sample, which was gathered as described in the previous

section, are given in Table 1 for the most important variables. Of the 560 respondents,

63.2% were domestic visitors and 36.8% were foreign visitors8. The mean age of

domestic and foreign visitors at the National Museum of Iran was 34.6 and 48.4 years,

respectively (39.7 years for the whole sample). Some 55.7% of domestic visitors were

female, while only 40.2% of foreign visitors were female (exactly 50% for the whole

sample). Foreign visitors were more educated than domestic visitors, which can be seen

from both the education level and years of schooling. In terms of the education level,

there were 32.2% of domestic visitors and only 12.6% of foreign visitors with high

school diploma or below on one end, and 6.2% of domestic visitors and as much as

9.2% of foreign visitors with a doctorate degree on the other end. In terms of years of

schooling, foreign visitors had on average one year more of educational attainment than

domestic visitors (14.5 years for the whole sample).

Foreign visitors reported substantially higher (net) monthly household income

(3,243 USD on average) than domestic visitors (404 USD on average), with a mean of

1,448 USD for the whole sample. This is understandable due to differences in the

standard of living. The distance from respondent’s place of residence was also, as

expected, substantially higher for foreign visitors (4,429 kilometres on average)

compared to domestic visitors (266 kilometres on average), with a mean of 1,780

kilometres for the whole sample.

In terms of respondents’ attitudes towards museums, measured through subjective

evaluation of the six statements, presented in the previous chapter, foreign visitors gave

a substantially higher percentage of favourable responses (“strongly agree”) and a

substantially lower percentage of unfavourable responses (“disagree” and “strongly

disagree”) than domestic visitors (see Table 2). Based on this, a new variable was

created, measuring the number of favourable attitudes towards museums. This attitude

variable was defined as the number of statements (values from 0 to 6), to which a

respondent answered with “agree” or “strongly agree”, and was significantly higher for

7 For domestic visitors, the most frequently cited reason for claiming zero entrance fees was “it is wrong

to impose an entrance fee to the National Museum of Iran” (4.6%), while for foreign visitors, “the service

quality of the museum is not good enough” (2.4%). 8 The foreign respondents arrived from 27 countries; mostly from Germany (10.6%), France (8.7%), Italy

(7.7%), Japan (6.8%), Spain (6.8%), and China (6.3%).

Page 17: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

12

foreign visitors (5.39) compared to domestic visitors (4.57), with a mean of 4.88

favourable attitudes towards museums for the whole sample.9

Table 1: Descriptive statistics of key variables

a) Domestic visitors (n = 354)

Variable Arithmetic

mean

Standard

deviation Lowest value Highest value

Respondent's age 34.60 10.34 20 64

Respondent's gender 0.5565 0.4975 0 1

Years of schooling 14.14 3.99 8 20

Monthly household income (in USD) 403.62 165.78 107 857

Distance from respondent’s

place of residence (in 1,000 kilometres) 0.266 0.378 0.05 1.8

Average number of visits to

museums per year 2.457 3.293 0 14

Knowledge about museums in general 1.257 0.638 1 5

Previous knowledge of the National

Museum of Iran 1.353 0.700 1 4

Attitude 4.573 1.730 0 6

Involvement 0.246 0.481 0 3

Maximum willingness-to-pay (in USD) 0.70 0.65 0 4.28

b) Foreign visitors (n = 206)

Variable Arithmetic

mean

Standard

deviation Lowest value Highest value

Respondent's age 48.38 10.60 23 74

Respondent's gender 0.4029 0.4917 0 1

Years of schooling 15.21 3.54 8 20

Monthly household income (in USD) 3,242.72 1,645.34 700 7,500

Distance from respondent’s

place of residence (in 1,000 kilometres) 4.429 2.119 0.5 9.6

Average number of visits to

museums per year 5.097 4.137 0 14

Knowledge about museums in general 1.675 1.034 1 5

Previous knowledge of the National

Museum of Iran 2.199 0.980 1 5

Attitude 5.393 1.085 0 6

Involvement 0.704 0.688 0 3

Maximum willingness-to-pay (in USD) 6.34 4.38 0 30

Source: Authors’ calculations.

9 Reliability of the attitude components was ensured with Cronbach’s alpha of 0.885 for domestic visitors

and 0.833 for foreign visitors, respectively.

Page 18: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

13

Additionally, foreign visitors have more frequently visited museums than domestic

visitors (5.10 visits per year compared to 2.46 visits per year), with an average of 3.48

visits per year for the whole sample (Table 1). A similar conclusion can be made with

respect to visitors’ knowledge about museums in general (mean of 1.68 for foreign

visitors compared to 1.26 for domestic visitors), and interestingly visitors’ previous

knowledge about the National Museum of Iran (mean of 2.20 for foreign visitors

compared to 1.35 for domestic visitors). These three variables, i.e. the average number

of visits to museums, knowledge about museums in general and previous knowledge

about the National Museum of Iran, were combined to form a new variable, measuring

the involvement of a visitor in the experience of the museum. The involvement variable

was defined for every visitor as the sum of three components (values from 0 to 3): being

a frequent visitor of museums, having a comprehensive knowledge of museums in

general, and having a comprehensive knowledge of the National Museum of Iran.10

Involvement was significantly higher for foreign visitors (0.70) compared to domestic

visitors (0.25), with a mean of 0.41 for the whole sample.

Table 2: Respondents’ attitudes towards museums

Statement

Response (%)

Strongly disagree Disagree Neutral Agree Strongly agree

DV FV DV FV DV FV DV FV DV FV

1 0.56 0.00 3.39 0.00 7.06 1.94 46.33 31.07 42.66 66.99

2 0.85 0.00 3.11 0.00 6.78 2.91 41.81 27.18 47.46 69.90

3 0.85 0.00 3.95 0.00 8.19 1.94 38.70 29.61 48.31 68.45

4 4.80 0.49 18.36 10.19 37.85 23.79 24.29 21.36 14.69 44.17

5 0.85 0.00 4.24 0.00 7.91 3.88 32.77 29.13 54.24 66.99

6 2.82 0.00 10.73 0.49 20.34 15.05 36.44 33.01 29.66 51.46

Note: DV – domestic visitors, FV – foreign visitors.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

The significant distinction between the two segments (subsamples) of visitors can

be explained by the fact that cultural tourists account for the largest market share of the

country’s inbound tourists, placing high importance on museums, historical sites and

cultural attractions in general. Indeed, foreign respondents’ primary motivation to visit

Iran (Tehran) was “visiting museums and historical sites” with 72.9% of responses11

. In

addition, the vast majority of foreigners (86.0%) stated that the main motivation for

visiting the National Museum of Iran is “cultural,” while only a small number of

domestic visitors (39.6%) agreed with that. Domestic visitors had other, equally

important motivations, including “social activities” (19.1%), “recreational purposes”

(16.7%), and “college research” (12.1%). Culturally focused motivation of destination

choice thus tends to classify inbound tourists to Iran as a “professional segment” of the

market that has on average a finer attitude towards museums and is more involved in the

museum experience than domestic visitors. Since the National Museum of Iran is a

10

Frequent visitor status was defined as 1 for average number of visits per year greater than four (taking

into account the sample mean), and 0 otherwise. The two comprehensive knowledge indicators were

defined as 1 if a respondent answered with “high” or “very high”, and 0 otherwise. 11

Other, less frequent reasons included “visiting friends or relatives” (9.8%), “visiting religious sites”

(5.3%), “visiting natural sites” (4.9%), and “conducting business” (4.3%).

Page 19: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

14

“must-see” attraction for most inbound tourists to Iran12

, it could be expected that

profiles and characteristics of the foreign visitors to this museum are relatively similar

to that of foreign visitors visiting other attraction of the country.

After excluding protest zero responses from the sample, as described in the

previous chapter, the maximum willingness-to-pay for entrance fee to the National

Museum of Iran was evaluated. It turned out to be substantially higher for foreign

visitors (mean of 6.34 USD and median of 5.50 USD) than for domestic visitors (mean

of 0.70 USD and median of 0.64 USD), with a mean of 2.77 USD and median of 0.85

USD for the whole sample. The mean WTP of foreign visitors was thus 9.1-fold of the

mean WTP of domestic visitors, while the median WTP of foreign visitors was 8.6-fold

of the median WTP of domestic visitors. Even though we do not yet control for other

determinants of WTP in this section, it is worth noting that the differences in mean and

median WTP between the two subsamples were highly statistically significant. The

results also showed that for both groups the median WTP was lower than the mean

WTP, where 71.6% of domestic and 55.3% of foreign respondents reported,

respectively, their WTP below the mean WTP.

The mean and median WTP for the segment (subsample) of foreign visitors indicate

that the current entry fee to the National Museum of Iran (USD 0.71) is substantially

less than what they considered to be their maximum WTP, while on the contrary, the

mean and median WTP of domestic visitors are not significantly different from the

current entry fee. Furthermore, lower variance of the WTP estimates of domestic

respondents compared to foreign visitors could indicate that there was more consensus

among the residents on how much they were willing to pay for the fee.

5.2 Econometric analysis

Within the framework of contingent valuation, developed in this article, we propose the

following empirical model of the maximum willingness-to-pay of visitor i, wtpi, for

entrance fee to the National Museum of Iran:

2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10i i i i i i i i i i iwtp a a g e y att inv d nat uβ β β β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + + + + , (2)

where ai represents the age of respondent i in years, gi represents gender (0 = “male”, 1

= “female”), ei stands for years of schooling, yi is monthly household income in 1,000

USD, atti is the attitude variable, defined as explained in the previous section, invi is the

involvement variable, defined as explained in the previous section, di represents the

distance between respondent’s place of residence and the National Museum of Iran in

1,000 kilometres, and nati stands for the nationality of visitor i (0 = “domestic visitor”, 1

= “foreign visitor”). Added is the disturbance term 2(0, )u IID σ� , expressing the

stochastic nature of our empirical model. Expression (2) was estimated by the least

squares estimator, providing for all the assumptions necessary for the method to yield

minimum-variance linear unbiased estimates.

The estimation results are presented in Table 3, where the diversity between the two

segments (subsamples) of visitors is captured first by “nationality” (specifications 1–2)

12

Visiting this museum is one of main activities held by almost all Iranian tourism travel agencies

offering services to inbound tourists in Tehran.

Page 20: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

15

and then by the “distance” (specifications 3–4). This was done, among other reasons, to

illustrate the robustness of results. As can be seen from Table 3, the WTP was positively

and statistically significantly related to years of schooling, household income, attitude

and involvement. Gender was not a statistically significant determinant of WTP in any

of the model specifications, while the relationship between age of a respondent and his

WTP demonstrated the so-called “U–shape”, where the effect of age changes sign at a

certain number of years. Based on the standardized regression coefficients (“beta

coefficients”, not shown), the most important determinants of the maximum WTP were

income, nationality and age, followed by attitude and involvement. Let us look at these

results in more detail.

Table 3: Estimated parameters of the model of maximum willingness-to-pay

Explanatory variable Model specification

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Constant term –0.7767 –2.9056*** –0.9222* –3.3318***

(0.5395) (1.0954) (0.5543) (1.1221)

Age –0.0266*** 0.0906* 0.0211* 0.1179**

(0.0096) (0.0534) (0.0110) (0.0546)

Age squared – –0.0014**

– –0.0016**

(0.0006) (0.0006)

Gender –0.1224 –0.0972 –0.1238 –0.0951

(0.2022) (0.2018) (0.2088) (0.2082)

Years of schooling 0.0892*** 0.0753** 0.0688** 0.0796***

(0.0303) (0.0309) (0.0310) (0.0287)

Household income 0.9899*** 1.0081*** 1.3115*** 1.3243***

(0.1039) (0.1039) (0.0892) (0.0889)

Attitude 0.1420* 0.1579** 0.1368* 0.1549**

(0.0748) (0.0749) (0.0773) (0.0773)

Involvement 0.6226*** 0.6190*** 0.7298*** 0.7232***

(0.1862) (0.1856) (0.1905) (0.1896)

Nationality 2.6793*** 2.6249***

– – (0.3729) (0.3723)

Distance – – 0.2615*** 0.2561***

(0.0599) (0.0597)

n 560 560 560 560

se 2.3521 2.3437 2.4182 2.4072

R2 0.6286 0.6319 0.6074 0.6117

Adjusted R2 0.6239 0.6266 0.6024 0.6060

F–test 133.45 118.24 122.00 108.49

p–value 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

Notes: Maximum willingness-to-pay (in USD) is the endogenous variable of the model in all four

specifications. Standard errors are given in parentheses. Asterisks *, ** and *** denote significance at the

10 percent, 5 percent and 1 percent level, respectively.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Page 21: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

16

Based on our sample of data, each additional 1,000 USD of household income

increased on average, ceteris paribus, the maximum WTP of a respondent by some 1.0–

1.3 USD. Each additional year of schooling increased on average, ceteris paribus, the

maximum WTP of a respondent further by some 6.9–8.9¢. Excluding age squared from

expression (2), the impact of age on the maximum WTP was ambiguous (a negative

coefficient in specification 1 and a positive coefficient in specification 3), but after

taking into account the U–shaped relationship between the two variables (specifications

2 and 4), we can observe that each additional year of age increased on average the

maximum WTP of a respondent by some 9.1–11.8¢, however at a higher age this effect

obtained a slightly negative inclination. Each additional favourable attitude towards

museums in general that a respondent had increased on average, ceteris paribus, his or

her maximum WTP by some 0.14–0.16 USD. Each additional component of

involvement (frequent visitor of museums, comprehensive knowledge of museums

and/or comprehensive knowledge of the National Museum of Iran) that was

characteristic of a respondent further increased on average, ceteris paribus, his or her

maximum WTP by some 0.62–0.73 USD.

The two variables that were intended to test the level of dissimilarity between the

two segments (subsamples) of visitors, i.e. distance and nationality, were also highly

statistically significant. As we can observe from Table 3, every additional 1,000

kilometres of distance between respondent’s place of residence and the National

Museum of Iran resulted on average, ceteris paribus, in an increase in his or her

maximum WTP by 0.26 USD (specifications 3–4). Moreover, foreign visitors reported

on average, ceteris paribus, maximum WTP that was by some 2.62–2.67 USD higher

than domestic visitors (specifications 1–2). The maximum willingness-to-pay for

entrance fee to the National Museum of Iran is thus statistically significantly higher for

foreign visitors compared to domestic visitors; not only unconditionally (as shown in

the previous section), but also after controlling for socio-economic, attitude and

involvement characteristics of WTP. We find the explanatory power of the model

satisfactory for this type of analysis (determination coefficient amounted to some 0.61–

0.63).

Additionally, we estimated the logarithmic transformation of expression (2), as the

regression coefficients then represent approximations of elasticities:

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8ln ln ln ln ln lni i i i i i i i i

wtp a g e y att inv nat uβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + + . (3)

Expression (3) was also estimated by the least squares estimator, and the subsequent

results for both segments (subsamples) of visitors as well as for the pooled model are

presented in Table 4. As we can observe from Table 4, gender was again not a

statistically significant determinant of WTP. The impact of age by itself on the

maximum WTP was “dichotomous” – a negative elasticity for domestic visitors13 and a

positive elasticity for foreign visitors, explaining (to a certain extent) the ambiguity of

the effect from Table 3, even though this time we were not able to test for the “U-

shaped” effects14

. Let us look at the remaining results in more detail.

13

The negative elasticity of maximum WTP with respect to age may be attributed to the fact that the

unemployment rate of younger people in Iran (and in the wider region) is much higher than for older

people and, on average, their willingness-to-pay on the hypothetical market is expected to be lower. 14

Age squared was eliminated as explanatory variable from the model as it would cause perfect

multicollinearity in the log-transformed model with age included.

Page 22: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

17

Based on our sample of data, increasing the years of schooling by 1 percent would

increase on average, ceteris paribus, the maximum WTP of domestic and foreign

visitors by 0.15 and 0.55 percent, respectively. This elasticity is thus much higher for

foreign visitors than for domestic visitors and for the whole sample (0.28 percent).

Increasing the household income by 1 percent would increase on average, ceteris

paribus, the maximum WTP of domestic and foreign visitors by 0.31 and 0.26 percent,

respectively. Income elasticity is thus comparable for foreign visitors with the one for

domestic visitors and for the whole sample (0.31 percent). Increasing the favourable

attitude towards museums in general by 1 percent would increase on average, ceteris

paribus, the maximum WTP of domestic and foreign visitors by 0.13 and 0.38 percent,

respectively. This elasticity is thus much higher for foreign visitors than for domestic

visitors and for the whole sample (0.14 percent). Increasing the involvement in the

experience of visiting the museum by 1 percent would increase on average, ceteris

paribus, the maximum WTP of foreign visitors by 0.36 percent, while this elasticity was

not statistically significant for domestic visitors.

Table 4: Estimated elasticities of the model of maximum willingness-to-pay

Explanatory variable Model specification

Domestic visitors Foreign visitors Pooled model

Constant term –0.1534 0.4069 –0.0005

(0.1983) (0.7159) (0.2611)

Logarithms of age 0.1036** –0.3129** –0.0522

(0.0461) (0.1500) (0.0593)

Gender –0.0359 0.0761 –0.0193

(0.0266) (0.0702) (0.0321)

Logarithms of years of schooling 0.1536*** 0.5498*** 0.2790***

(0.0485) (0.1459) (0.0610)

Logarithms of household income 0.3064*** 0.2633*** 0.3063***

(0.0306) (0.0645) (0.0337)

Logarithms of attitude 0.1257*** 0.3753*** 0.1357***

(0.0273) (0.1301) (0.0380)

Logarithms of involvement –0.0618 0.3591*** 0.1851***

(0.0437) (0.0896) (0.0474)

Nationality – – 0.6412***

(0.0751)

N 354 206 560

se 0.2459 0.4839 0.3741

R2 0.4153 0.4058 0.7811

Adjusted R2 0.4052 0.3878 0.7783

F–test 41.07 22.65 281.42

p–value 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

Notes: Logarithms of maximum willingness-to-pay is the endogenous variable of the model in all three

specifications. Standard errors are given in parentheses. Asterisks *, ** and *** denote significance at the

10 percent, 5 percent and 1 percent level, respectively.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Again, the relationship between the maximum WTP and its socio-economic,

attitude and involvement characteristics, measured by the regression coefficient of the

dummy variable on nationality, was highly statistically significantly different for

foreign visitors, as compared to domestic visitors. This is also evident from the increase

Page 23: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

18

in explanatory power of the model, when transitioning from one of the subsamples to

the whole sample (pooled model).

Finally, we were interested in visitors’ psychological characteristics, i.e. attitudes

and involvement, in more detail. In particular, we wanted to establish whether these two

variables are to a certain extent dependant on the socio-economic, geographical and

other determinants from our initial model of the maximum WTP. For this reason, we

estimated the following two regressions by the least squares estimator:

2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8i i i i i i i i iatt a a g e y v d uβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + + , (4)

2

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8i i i i i i i i iinv a a g e y a4 d uβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + + , (5)

where, besides the variables that were already indicated in expression (2), vi represents

the average number of visits to museums of respondent i per year, and a4i denoted

respondents, for whom visiting a museum was a major activities during the travel15

.

The estimation results of expressions (4) and (5) are presented in Table 5. As we

can see from Table 5, the explanatory power of the three model specifications is

relatively low (the value of determination coefficient varies from 0.25 to 0.30), but the

regression coefficients have interesting values and are statistically significant, thus the

models deserve some attention. Based on the standardized regression coefficients (not

shown), the most important determinants of attitude in expression (4) were age and

education, while the most important determinants of involvement in expression (5) were

distance and income, followed by education. Gender was again not a statistically

significant determinant in any of the model specifications.

If we look at these results in more detail, we can observe from Table 5 that based

on our sample age exhibited a “U-shaped” impact on visitors’ attitude towards museums

in general (specification 2). Namely, each additional year of age decreased on average

the number of favourable attitudes towards museums by 0.07; however at a higher age

this effect obtained a slightly positive inclination. Each additional year of schooling

increased on average, ceteris paribus, the number of favourable attitudes towards

museums by 0.16–0.17 (specifications 1–2). Each additional 1,000 USD of household

income increased on average, ceteris paribus, the number of favourable attitudes

towards museums further by 0.70–0.78. An increase in the average number of visits to

museums per year by one increased on average, ceteris paribus, the number of

favourable attitudes towards museums by 0.07. Every additional 1,000 kilometres of

distance between respondent’s place of residence and the National Museum of Iran

resulted on average, ceteris paribus, in an increase in the number of favourable attitudes

towards museums by 0.08. Older, more educated, wealthier and more involved visitors

thus had more favourable attitudes towards museums.

On the other hand, based on our sample age did not exhibit a statistically significant

effect on involvement (specification 3), neither linearly nor “U-shaped”. Each additional

year of schooling increased on average, ceteris paribus, the (composite) involvement in

the experience of visiting the museum by 0.02. Each additional 1,000 USD of

household income increased on average, ceteris paribus, the involvement further by

0.07. Respondents, for whom visiting a museum was a major activities during the travel,

15

This variable was constructed as an indicator variable that took the value 1 if a respondent answered to

Statement 4 (see Chapter 4) with “agree” or “strongly agree”, and 0 otherwise.

Page 24: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

19

exhibited involvement in the experience of visiting the museum that was on average,

ceteris paribus, higher by 0.32 compared to the rest of the visitors. Every additional

1,000 kilometres of distance between respondent’s place of residence and the National

Museum of Iran resulted on average, ceteris paribus, in an increase in involvement by

0.02. More educated, wealthier and more museum-oriented visitors were thus more

involved in the experience of visiting the museum.

Table 5: Estimated parameters of the models of attitude and involvement

Explanatory variable Attitude Involvement

(1) (2) (3)

Constant term 1.8287*** 3.0741*** –0.1597

(0.2925) (0.6022) (0.1177)

Age 0.0025 –0.0670** –0.0002

(0.0053) (0.0299) (0.0021)

Age squared – 0.0008**

– (0.0004)

Gender 0.2251 0.2167 –0.0166

(0.1142) (0.1462) (0.0456)

Years of schooling 0.1621*** 0.1684*** 0.0200***

(0.0155) (0.0156) (0.0064)

Household income 0.7817** 0.70176** 0.0707***

(0.2871) (0.2883) (0.0194)

Number of visits to

museums

0.0685*** 0.0694*** –

(0.0160) (0.0160)

Visiting museums as a

major activity – –

0.3172***

(0.0508)

Distance 0.0771** 0.0789** 0.0249*

(0.0328) (0.0327) (0.0130)

N 560 560 560

se 1.3271 1.3217 0.5289

R2 0.2969 0.3039 0.2485

Adjusted R2 0.2893 0.2951 0.2404

F–test 38.92 34.43 30.48

p–value 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000

Notes: Standard errors are given in parentheses. Asterisks *, ** and *** denote significance at the 10

percent, 5 percent and 1 percent level, respectively.

Source: Authors’ calculations.

Page 25: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

20

6 Concluding remarks

Since the early 1990s, the notion of museum entrance fees has drawn attention to many

studies, even though scarce attention has been paid in the literature so far to pricing

policies, adopted by museums in developing countries. One of the controversial,

frequently applied, but rarely researched is dual pricing for entrance fees in order to

increase revenue. The purposes of the present article were to estimate the admission fees

that foreign and domestic visitors are willing to pay, respectively, for the National

Museum of Iran, and also to examine the relationship between the visitors’ willingness-

to-pay for museum admission fees and their various socio-economic, geographical, and

psychological characteristics. The findings obtained have several policy implications for

this museum in particular and for other museums and tourism heritage attractions

generally in developing countries.

To begin with, along with the fundamental hypothesis of our article, the average

maximum willingness-to-pay for entrance fees turned out to be substantially higher for

foreign visitors and substantially higher than the current entrance fee, while on the

contrary, the average WTP of domestic visitors is not significantly different from the

existing entrance fee; not only unconditionally, but also after controlling for socio-

economic, attitude and involvement characteristics. This prompts considering the

implementation of a dual pricing strategy, whereby a reasonable increase in the existing

admission fees strategy be applied for foreign (and possibly domestic) visitors in order

to increase the economic impact of visitors for the museum.

Based on econometric estimation of the maximum willingness-to-pay, the most

important determinants of WTP for domestic visitors were income, attitude, and

education, while for foreign visitors these were income, education, involvement and

attitude. For both groups of visitors, the maximum WTP was positively and statistically

significantly related to the above variables. Thus, as the second major policy

implication, we could underline the significance of education, involvement, attitude and

distance travelled for justification of adopting dual pricing for admission fee to the

National Museums of Iran, in addition to higher income levels of foreign visitors – thus

far the only legitimate motive for introducing dual pricing among most museum

mangers in Iran and other developing countries.

This justification is corroborated when we take into account that foreign visitors on

average had higher education level, higher income, more favourable attitudes towards

museums and were more involved in museums experience, as well as their substantially

higher elasticities of WTP with respect to years of schooling, attitudes and involvement,

compared to domestic visitors. These findings give credibility to the belief that foreign

visitors are much more likely to be willing to pay a reasonably increased entrance fee

than domestic visitors, other things being equal.

However, what also needs to be considered is visitors’ compliance and agreement

with price differences, which is essential for a successful discriminatory pricing policy

(Mudie and Pirrie, 2006). Setting different prices for different segments of visitors

might evoke price unfairness and negative emotional responses, and could even make

some visitors resistant to the policy (Howard, 2009).16

This is somewhat in line with the

findings of this article. Even though a significant difference in the WTP between the

two segments of visitors was found, the optimal level of disparity needs to be set, to

16

In practise, dual pricing in developing countries has been one of the challenges that causes much

resentment and often deters return visits (e.g. in case of the cultural attractions in Thailand).

Page 26: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

21

avoid violating the notions of equity and dissatisfying the inbound visitors.

Furthermore, perceived equity resulting from this disparity needs to be further studied in

future research.

The inclusion of two main behavioural and psychological variables in the article,

i.e. attitude and involvement, allowed us to have a more in-depth analysis of visitors’

behaviour. In particular, we studied whether visitors’ attitudes and involvement were

dependant on their socio-economic and geographical characteristics. The results suggest

that older, more educated, wealthier and more involved visitors had more favourable

attitudes towards museums, while more educated, wealthier and more museum-oriented

visitors were more involved in the experience of the museum. This is consistent with the

general evidence that museum visitors on average belong to higher socio-economic

classes (Maddison & Foster, 2003). It could be interpreted in the sense that imposing a

same entrance fee for foreign and domestic visitors is more favourable for higher-

income visitors and to a lesser extent an effective policy for attracting poorer people.

The third main policy implication drawn from the finding is that foreign visitors’

most frequently cited reason for zero WTP was the poor quality of services provided by

the museum. Chung et al. (2011) found that visitors’ WTP would become higher if they

are more likely to believe that the fees will be used to increase the quality of facilities

and services, and to enrich visitor programs. This brings support to the view that

developing the service quality17

will lead to a greater willingness-to-pay for an entrance

fee. Management could compensate to some extent the costs of increased quality with

the revenue gained through dual entrance fees.

From the museum management perspective, in addition to providing satisfactory

services, public relations will be a critical factor of success for adopting a dual pricing

practice. Howard (2009) found that a majority of foreign visitors to a developing

country felt “serious challenging experiences” when they encountered dual pricing

without having prior knowledge. Thus, efforts to deliver justifiable reasons and

purposes for the fees should be announced to the visitors through various information

channels (e.g. a brochure, notice at the gate or ticket office, and on the website). This

type of persuasive communication, in line with the attribution theory, is also expected to

mitigate price unfairness, which, in turn, positively affects the WTP (Chung & Petrick,

2012). Conversely, failure to properly explain the rationale for dual pricing to the public

could damage the image of the museum or even the government (O’Hagan, 1995).

Finally, it should be emphasized that the findings of this article do not suggest that

a museum should commercialize for dealing with financial issues. Rather, a museum is

a not-for-profit institution, and it is noted that, “any commercial activities of the

museum, and any publicity relating to these, should be in accordance with a clear

policy, should be relevant to the basic educational purposes and must not compromise

the quality of collections” (Edson, 2005). It is thus recommended that the revenues

generated through entrance fees, though little in magnitude, be returned to communities

as a means of providing facilities, as well as for acquisition, conservation, and

exhibition of collections, and generally to meet the museums missions, all with the

purpose of preserving our tangible and intangible heritage.

17

The service quality could be improved, e.g., by operating English guided tours, providing audio-visual

devices, presenting useful information related to other tourism attractions, and enhancing facilities for

disabled and elderly people.

Page 27: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

22

References

Aadland, D., & Caplan, A. J. (2006). Cheap talk reconsidered: New evidence from

CVM. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 60(4), 562-578.

Anderson, R. G. W. (1998). Is charging economic? Journal of Cultural Economics,

22(2), 179-187.

Bailey, S., & Falconer, P. (1998). Charging for admission to museums and galleries: A

framework for analysing the impact on access. Journal of Cultural Economics,

22(2), 167-177.

Bailey, S., Falconer, P., Foley, M., McPherson, G., & Graham, M. (1997). Charging for

admission to museums and galleries: Arguments and evidence. Museum

Management and Curatorship, 16(4), 355-369.

Bedate, A., Herrero, L. C., & Sanz, J. A. (2004). Economic valuation of the cultural

heritage: application to four case studies in Spain. Journal of Cultural Heritage,

5(1), 101-111.

Bedate, A. M., Herrero, L. C., & Sanz, J. A. (2009). Economic valuation of a

contemporary art museum: Correction of hypothetical bias using a certainty

question. Journal of Cultural Economics, 33(3), 185-199.

Bedate, A., Herrero, L. C., & Sanz, J. A. (2011). Ex ante and ex post valuations of a

cultural good. Are preferences or expectations changing? Journal of Environmental

Planning and Management, 55(1), 127-140.

Bernath, K., & Roschewitz, A. (2008). Recreational benefits of urban forests:

Explaining visitors’ willingness to pay in the context of the theory of planned

behavior. Journal of Environmental Management, 89(3), 155-166.

Borda, J. S. (2007). Valuing congestion costs in small museums: The case of the

Rubenshuis museum in Antwerp. Unpublished M.A. dissertation, Erasmus

University Rotterdam, Netherland.

Boyan, P. J. (2006). Musuems: Targets or instruments of cultural policies? Museum

International, 58(4), 8-12.

Brons, M., Pels, E., Nijkamp, P., & Rietveld, P. (2002). Price elasticity of demand for

passenger air travel: A meta-analysis. Journal of Air Transport Management, 8(3),

165-175.

Casey, J. F., Brown, C., & Schumann, P. (2010). Are tourists willing to pay additional

fees to protect corals in Mexico? Journal of Sustainable Tourism, 18(4), 557-573.

Choi, A. S., Ritche, B. W., Papandrea, F., & Bennett, J. (2010). Economic valuation of

cultural heritage sites: A choice modeling approach. Tourism Management, 31(2),

213-220.

Chung, H.-K. (2008). The contingent valuation method in libraries. Journal of

Librarianship and Information Science, 40(2), 71-80.

Chung. J. Y., & Petrick, J. F. (2012). Price fairness of airline ancillary fees: An

attributional approach. Journal of Travel Research, forthcoming.

Chung, J. Y., Kyle, G. T., Petrick, J. F., & Absher, J. D. (2011). Fairness of prices, user

fee policy and willingness to pay among visitors to a national forest. Tourism

Management, 32(5), 1038-1046.

Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. V. (1947). Capital returns from soil-conservation practices. Journal

of Farm Economics, 29(4), 1188-1190.

Cowell, B. (2007). Measuring the impact of free admission. Cultural Trends, 16(3),

203-224.

Page 28: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

23

Cummings, R., & Taylor, L. (1999). Unbiased value estimates for environmental goods:

A cheap talk design for the contingent valuation method. American Economic

Review, 89(3), 649-666.

Davis, R. (1963). The value of outdoor recreation: An economic study of the Maine

Woods. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation. Harvard University, United States.

Dickenson, V. (2005). The economics of museum admission charges. In Moore, K.

(Ed.). Museum management (pp. 105-114). London: Routledge.

Dutta, M., Banerjee, S., & Husain, Z. (2007). Untapped demand for heritage: A

contingent valuation study of Prinsep Ghat, Calcutta. Tourism Management, 28(1),

83-95.

Eagly, A., & Chaiken, S. (1993). The psychology of attitudes. Orlando: Harcourt Brace

Jovanovich.

Edson, G. (2005). ICOM Code of Professional Ethics. In Edson, G. (Ed.). Museum

Ethics (pp. 212-228). London: Routledge.

Frateschi, C., Lazzaro, E., & Martos, L. (2009). A comparative econometric analysis of

museum attendance by locals and foreigners: The cases of Padua and Seville.

Estudios de Economia Aplicada, 27(1), 175-196.

Frey, B. S., & Meier, S. (2006). Cultural economics. In Macdonald, S. (Ed.). A

companion to museum studies (pp. 398-414). Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.

Frey, B. S., & Steiner, L. (2010). Pay as you Go: A new proposal for museum pricing.

Working Paper No. 485. Zurich: University of Zurich, Institute for Empirical

Research in Economics.

Garrod, B., & Fyall, A. (2000). Managing heritage tourism. Journal of Tourism

Research, 27(3), 682-708.

Gil, S. M., & Ritchie, J. R. B. (2009). Understanding the museum image formation

process: A comparison of residents and tourists. Journal of Travel Research, 47(4),

480-493.

Gilmore, A., & Rentschler, R. (2002). Changes in museum management: A custodial or

marketing emphasis? Journal of Management Development, 2(10), 745-760.

Havitz, M. E., & Dimanche, F. (1997). Leisure involvement revisited: Conceptual

conundrums and measurement advances. Journal of Leisure Research, 29(3), 245-

278.

Hornsten, L., & Fredman, P. (2000). On the distance to recreational forests in Sweden.

Landscape and Urban Planning, 5(1), 1-10.

Howard, R. (2009). Risky business? Asking tourists what hazards they actually

encounered in Thailand. Tourism Management, 30(3), 359-365.

ICOM. (2007). Declaration of the International Council of Museums (ICOM) and the

World Federation of Friends of Museums (WFFM) for worldwide Sustainable

Cultural Tourism. Paris: The International Council of Museums.

Jaffry, S., & Apostolakis, A. (2011). Evaluating individual preferences for the British

Museum. Journal of Cultural Economics, 35(1), 49-75.

Johnson, P., & Thomas, B. (1998). The economics of museums: A research perspective.

Journal of Cultural Economics, 22(2-3), 75-85.

Kawashima, N. (1998). Knowing the public: A Review of museum marketing literature

and research. Museum Management and Curatorship, 17(1), 21-39.

Kinghorn, N., & Willis, K. (2008). Valuing the components of an archaeological site:

An application of choice experiment to Vindolanda, Hadrian’s Wall. Journal of

Cultural Heritage, 9(2), 117- 124.

Page 29: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

24

Kirchberg, V. (1998). Entrance fee as a subjective barrier to visiting museums. Journal

of Cultural Economics, 22(1), 1-13.

Kotler, N. G., Kotler, P., & Kotler, W. (2008). Museum marketing and strategy:

Designing missions buuilding audiences generating revenue and resources. San

Francisco: Jossey-Bass/Wiley.

Kyle, G. T., Graefe, A. R., & Absher, J. D. (2002). Determining appropriate prices for

recreation on public lands. Journal of Park and Recreation Administration, 20(2),

69-89.

Kyle, G. T., Graefe, A. R., Manning, R., & Bacon, J. (2004). Predictors of behavioral

loyalty among hikers along the Appalachian Trail. Leisure Sciences, 26(1), 99-108.

Lampi, E., & Orth, M. (2009). Who visits the museums? A comparison between stated

preferences and observed effect of entrance fee. Kyklos, 62(1), 85-102.

Laurent, G., & Kapferer, J. N. (1985). Measuring consumer involvement profiles.

Journal of Marketing Research, 22(1), 41-53.

Lee, C.-K., & Han, S.-Y. (2002). Estimating the use and preservation values of national

parks’ tourism resources using a contingent valuation method. Tourism

Management, 23(5), 531- 540.

Loomis, J., & Santiago, L. E. (2011). Testing differences in estimation of river

recreation benefits for international and domestic tourists as a function of single-

versus multiple-destination day trips. Journal of Hospitality Marketing &

Management, 20(2), 143-165.

López-Mosquera, N., & Sánchez, M. (2011). Emotional and satisfaction benefits to

visitors as explanatory factors in the monetary valuation of environmental goods.

An application to periurban green spaces. Land Use Policy, 28(1), 151-166.

Luksetich, W. A., & Partridge, M. D. (1997). Demand functions for museum services.

Applied Economics, 29(12), 1553-1559.

Lusk, J. L., & Hudson, D. (2004). Willingness-to-pay estimates and their relevance to

agribusiness decision making. Review of Agricultural Economics, 26(2), 152-169.

Maddison, D., & Foster, T., (2003). Valuing congestion consts in the British Musuem.

Oxford Economics Papers, 35, 173-190.

Manjarrez, C., Rosenstein C., Colgan, C., & Pastore, E. (2008). Exhibiting public value:

Museum public finance in the United States (IMLS-2008-RES-02). Washington,

DC: Institute of Museum and library Services.

Martin, A. (2007). The impact of free entry to museums. In Sandell, R. & Janes, R. R.

(Eds.). Museum management and marketing (pp. 406-415). London: Routledge.

McIntyre, N., & Pigram, J. J. (1992). Recreation specialization reexamined: The case of

vehicle-based campers. Leisure Research, 14(1), 3-15.

Meyerhoff, J. (2006). Stated willingness to pay as hypothetical behavior: Can attitudes

tell us more? Journal of Environmental Planning and Management, 49(2), 209-226.

Mitchell, R.C., & Carson, R.T. (1989). Using surveys to value public goods: The

contingent valuation method. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.

More, T. A., and Stevens, T. (2000). Do user fees exclude low-income people from

resource-based recreation? Journal of Leisure Research, 32(9), 341-357.

Mozaffary, A. (2007). Modernity and identity: The National Museum of Iran. In Knell

S. J., MacLeod, S., & Watson, S. (Eds.). Museum revolutions: How museums

change and are changed (pp. 87-104). London: Routledge.

Mudie, P., & Pirrie, A. (2006). Service marketing management. Oxford: Elsevier

Science.

Page 30: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

25

Ng, I. C. L. (2008). The pricing and revenue management of services: A strategic

approach. London: Routledge.

Noonan, D. S. (2002). Contingent valuation studies in the arts and culture: An annotated

bibliography. Working Paper No. 11. Chicago: University of Chicago, Cultural

Policy Center.

Noonan, D. S. (2003). Contingent valuation and cultural resources: A meta-analytic

review of the literature. Journal of Cultural Economics, 27(3-4), 159-176.

O’Hagan, J. W. (1995). National museums: To charge or not to charge? Journal of

Cultural Economics, 19(1), 33-47.

Peacock, A. (1994). A future for the past: The political economy of heritage.

Proceedings of the British Academy, 87, 189-226.

Plaza, B. (2010). Valuing museums as economic engines: Willingness to pay or

discounting of cash-flows? Journal of Cultural Heritage, 11(2), 155-162.

Prieto-Rodriguez, J., & Fernandez-Blanco, V. (2006). Optimal pricing and grant

policies for museums. Journal of Cultural Economics, 30(3), 169-181.

Reynisdottir, M., Song, H., & Agrusa, J. (2008). Willingness to pay entrance fees to

natural attractions: An Icelandic case study. Tourism Management, 29(6), 1076-

1083.

Richards, G. (2005). The social context of cultural tourism. In Richards, G. (Ed.).

Cultural tourism in Europe (pp. 39-52). Wallingford: Atlas Publishing.

Salazar, S. D. S., & Marques, J. M. (2005). Valuing cultural heritage: The social

benefits of restoring and old Arab tower. Journal of Cultural Heritage, 6(1), 69-77.

Santagata, W., & Signorello, G. (2000). Contingent valuation of a cultural public good

and policy design: The case of ‘Napoli Musei Aperti’. Journal of Cultural

Economics, 24(3), 181-204.

Sanz, J. A., Herrero, L. C., & Bedate, A. M. (2003). Contingent valuation and

semiparametric methods: A case study of the National Museum of Sculpture in

Valladolid, Spain. Journal of Cultural Economics, 27(3-4), 241-257.

Sattout, E. J., Talhouk, S. N., & Caligari, P. D. S. (2007). Economic value of cedar

relics in Lebanon: An application of contingent valuation method for conservation.

Ecological Economics, 61(2-3), 315-322.

Schneider, I. E., & Budruk, M. (1999). Displacement as a response to the federal

recreation fee program. Journal of Park and Recreation Administration, 17(3), 76-

84.

Schrijvershop, C. (2007). Do (not) blame the price: A quantitative analysis of the

different determinants of the museum demand. Unpublished M.A. dissertation,

Erasmus University Rotterdam, Netherland.

Snowball, J. D. (2008). Measuring the value of culture: Methods and examples in

cultural economics. Berlin: Springer.

Solino, M., Prada, A., & Vazquez, M. X. (2010). Designing a forest-energy policy to

reduce forest fires in Galicia (Spain): A contingent valuation application. Journal of

Forest Economics, 16(3), 217-233.

Tasci, A. D. A., Gurbuz, A. K., & Gartner, W. C. (2006). Segmented (differential or

discreiminatory) pricing and its consequences. In Kozak, M., & Andreu, L. (Eds).

Progress in tourism marketing (pp. 171-183). Oxford: Elsevier Science.

Tehrani, M. Sh. (2011). Affecting factors on museums entrance fees pricing with the

focus on developing countries: The case of the National Museum of Iran.

Unpublished M.A. dissertation. Allameh Tabataba’i University, Iran.

Page 31: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

26

Throsby, D. (2003). Determining the value of the cultural goods: How much (or how

little) does contingent valuation tell us? Journal of Cultural Economics, 27(3), 275-

285.

Timothy, D. J., & Nyaupane, G. P. (2009). Protecting the past: Challenges and

opportunities. In Timothy, D. J., & Nyaupane, G. P. (Eds.). Cultural heritage and

tourism in the developing world: A regional perspective (pp. 20-41). London:

Routledge.

Tohmo, T. (2004). Economic value of a local museum: Factors of willingness-to-pay.

Journal of Socio-Economics, 33(2), 229-240.

Trupiano, G. (2005). Economy and sociology in cultural heritage: Financing the culture

in Italy. Journal of Cultural Heritage, 6(4), 337-343.

Tuan, T. H., & Navrud, S. (2008). Capturing the benefits of preserving cultural heritage.

Journal of Cultural Heritage, 9(3), 326-337.

Tufts, S., & Milne, S. (1999). Museums: A supply-side perspective. Annals of Tourism

Research, 26(3), 613-631.

Vanhove, N. (2005). The economics of tourism destinations. Oxford: Elsevier Science.

Veisten, K. (2007). Contingent valuation controversies philosophic debates about

economic theory. The Journal of Socio-Economics, 36(2), 204-232.

Venkatachalam, L. (2004). The contingent valuation method: A review. Environmental

Impact Assessment Review, 24(1), 89-124.

Verbič, M., & Slabe-Erker, R. (2009). An econometric analysis of willingness-to-pay

for sustainable development: A case study of the Volčji Potok Landscape Area.

Ecological Economics, 68(5), 1316-1328.

Whitehead, J. (2006). A practitioner's primer on the contingent valuation method. In

Alberini, A., & Kahn, J. R. (Eds.). Handbook on contingent valuation (pp. 66-91).

Massachusetts: Edward Elgar Publishing.

Page 32: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

PUBLISHED PAPERS IN THE SERIES

1. Lado Rupnik: THE NEW TAX SYSTEM IN SLOVENIA, IER, Ljubljana, 1993, 16 p.

2. Franc Kuzmin: SOME DILEMMAS IN THE THEORY OF COST-PUSH INFLATION –

SLOVENIAN CASE, IER, Ljubljana, 1993, 17 p.

3. Miroslav Glas: SLOVENE SMALL BUSINESS, IER, Ljubljana, 1993, 26 p.

4. Tine Stanovnik: SOCIAL SECURITY IN SLOVENIA, IER, Ljubljana, 1993, 14 p.

5. Peter Stanovnik, Ivo Banič: THE ROLE OF FDIs IN SLOVENIA'S ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT,

IER, Ljubljana, 1993, 13 p.

6. Vladimir Lavrač: THE ADJUSTMENT OF THE SLOVENIAN MONETARY SYSTEM TO THE

EUROPEAN MONETARY INTEGRATION PROCESS, IER, Ljubljana, 1993, 14 p.

7. Andrej Kumar: EUROPEAN INTEGRATION – REALITY OR A DREAM?, IER, Ljubljana, 1994,

20 p.

8. Frančiška Logar, Danica Zorko: UPSWING OF TOURISM IN SLOVENIA, IER, Ljubljana, 1994, 23 p.

9. Milena Bevc: EDUCATIONAL CAPITAL IN SLOVENIA IN THE EARLY 90s, IER, Ljubljana, 1994,

28 p.

10. Franc Kuzmin: THE MAIN CHARACTERISTICS OF SLOVENE LABOUR MARKET DURING

TRANSITION PERIOD – THE PROBLEM OF UNEMPLOYMENT, IER, Ljubljana, 1994, 9 p.

11. Emil Erjavec, Miroslav Rednak, Jernej Turk: THE MAIN ISSUES INVOLVED IN THE ECONOMIC

TRANSITION OF SLOVENE AGRICULTURE, IER, Ljubljana, 1994, 16 p.

12. Stanka Kukar: THE HIDDEN ECONOMY AND THE LABOUR MARKET IN SLOVENIA IN THE

PERIOD OF TRANSITION, IER, Ljubljana, 1994, 16 p.

13. Milan Lapornik, Peter Stanovnik: INDUSTRIAL AND ENTERPRISE RESTRUCTURING IN

SLOVENIA, IER, Ljubljana, 1995, 24 p.

14. Vladimir Lavrač: COMMON CAPITAL MARKET OF CEFTA COUNTRIES – A POSSIBLE WAY

OF DEEPENING CEFTA, IER, Ljubljana, 1997, 15 p.

15. Valentina Prevolnik: HEALTH CARE REFORM IN SLOVENIA, IER, Ljubljana, 1997, 17 p.

16. Tine Stanovnik: THE TAX SYSTEM AND TAX REFORM IN SLOVENIA, IER, Ljubljana, 1997,

16 p.

Page 33: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

WORKING PAPERS

1. Vladimir Lavrač: EXCHANGE RATE OF THE SLOVENIAN TOLAR IN THE CONTEXT OF

SLOVENIA'S INCLUSION IN THE EU AND IN THE EMU, IER, Ljubljana, 1999, 18 p.

2. Tine Stanovnik, Nada Stropnik: ECONOMIC WELL-BEING OF THE ELDERLY AND PENSION

REFORM IN SLOVENIA, IER, Ljubljana, 1999, 34 p.

3. Marjan Simončič, Franc Kuzmin: MACROECONOMIC EFFECTS OF THE PENSION REFORM IN

SLOVENIA, IER, Ljubljana, 1999, 26 p.

4. Jože Pavlič Damijan: EFFICIENCY OF FREE TRADE AGREEMENTS: DID THE REDUCTION

OF TRADE BARRIERS HAVE ANY EFFECT ON INCREASING TRADE BETWEEN

SLOVENIA AND THE CEFTA COUNTRIES?, IER, Ljubljana, 1999, 18 p.

5. Boris Majcen: SECTOR PERFORMANCE IN THE SLOVENE ECONOMY: WINNERS AND

LOSERS OF EU INTEGRATION, IER, Ljubljana, 2000, 37 p. + appendix

6. Peter Stanovnik, Art Kovačič: SOME QUESTIONS OF THE INTERNATIONAL

COMPETITIVENESS OF NATIONAL ECONOMIES WITH EMPHASIS ON SLOVENIA, IER,

Ljubljana, 2000, 24 p.

7. Janez Bešter: TAKEOVER THEORIES AND PREDICTION MODELS – THE CASE OF

SLOVENIAN PRIVATISED COMPANIES, IER, Ljubljana, 2000, 16 p.

8. Jeffrey David Turk, Hedvika Usenik: BUYER SUPPLIER RELATIONSHIPS IN THE

ENGINEERING INDUSTRIES IN SLOVENIA AND COMPARISONS WITH HUNGARY, IER,

Ljubljana, 2000, 22 p.

9. Jože Pavlič Damijan, Boris Majcen: TRADE REORIENTATION, FIRM PERFORMANCE AND

RESTRUCTURING OF SLOVENIAN MANUFACTURING SECTOR, IER, Ljubljana, 2001, 16 p.

10. Jože Pavlič Damijan, Boris Majcen, Matija Rojec, Mark Knell: THE ROLE OF FDI, R&D

ACCUMULATION AND TRADE IN TRANSFERRING TECHNOLOGY TO TRANSITION

COUNTRIES: EVIDENCE FROM FIRM PANEL DATA FOR EIGHT TRANSITION

COUNTRIES, IER, Ljubljana, 2001, 26 p.

11. Matija Rojec, Jože Pavlič Damijan, Boris Majcen: EXPORT PROPENSITY OF ESTONIAN AND

SLOVENIAN MANUFACTURING FIRMS: DOES FOREIGN OWNERSHIP MATTER?, IER,

Ljubljana 2001, 22 p.

12. Nevenka Hrovatin, Sonja Uršič: THE DETERMINANTS OF FIRM PERFORMANCE AFTER

OWNERSHIP TRANSFORMATION IN SLOVENIA, IER, Ljubljana, 2001, 21 p.

13. Vladimir Lavrač, Tina Žumer: EXCHANGE RATE ARRANGEMENTS OF ACCESSION

COUNTRIES IN THEIR RUN-UP TO EMU: NOMINAL CONVERGENCE, REAL

CONVERGENCE AND OPTIMUM CURRENCY AREA CRITERIA, IER, Ljubljana, 2002, 35 p.

14. Vladimir Lavrač: MONETARY, FISCAL AND EXCHANGE RATE POLICIES FROM THE

VIEWPOINT OF THE ENLARGEMENT OF THE EUROZONE: SURVEY OF THE

LITERATURE, IER, Ljubljana, 2002, 21 p.

15. Jože Pavlič Damijan, Črt Kostevc: THE EMERGING ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN SLOVENIA,

IER, Ljubljana 2002, 30 p.

16. Boris Majcen: THE EFFECTS OF FOREIGN TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND FINANCIAL

FLOWS BETWEEN SLOVENIA AND EU AFTER THE ACCESSION, IER, Ljubljana 2002, 33 p.

17. Jože Pavlič Damijan, Mark Knell, Boris Majcen, Matija Rojec: TECHNOLOGY TRANSFER

THROUGH FDI IN TOP-10 TRANSITION COUNTRIES: HOW IMPORTANT ARE DIRECT

EFFECTS, HORIZONTAL AND VERTICAL SPILLOVERS?, IER, Ljubljana, 2003, 23 p + appendix

Page 34: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

18. Jože Pavlič Damijan, Črt Kostevc: THE IMPACT OF EUROPEAN INTEGRATION ON

ADJUSTMENT PATTERN OF REGIONAL WAGES IN TRANSITION COUNTRIES: TESTING

COMPETITIVE ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY MODELS, IER, Ljubljana, 2003, 27 p.

19. Vladimir Lavrač: ERM 2 STRATEGY FOR ACCESSION COUNTRIES, IER, Ljubljana, 2003, 21 p.

20. Renata Slabe Erker: ENVIRONMENTAL SUSTAINABILITY IN SLOVENIA, IER, Ljubljana, 2003,

25 p.

21. Tine Stanovnik, Miroslav Verbič: PERCEPTION OF INCOME SATISFACTION AND

SATISFACTION WITH THE QUALITY OF LIVING; AN ANALYSIS OF SLOVENIAN

HOUSEHOLDS, IER, Ljubljana, 2003, 18 p.

22. Vladimir Lavrač: FULFILLMENT OF MAASTRICHT CONVERGENCE CRITERIA FOR

SLOVENIA AND OTHER ACCEDING COUNTRIES. IER, Ljubljana, 2004, 15 p.

23. Janez Bešter: ANATOMY OF A POST-MERGER INTEGRATION: THE CASE OF SLOVENIA.

IER, Ljubljana, 2004, 21 p.

24. Miroslav Verbič: ECONOMETRIC ESTIMATION OF PARAMETERS OF PRESERVATION OF

PERISHABLE GOODS IN COLD LOGISTIC CHAINS. IER, Ljubljana, 2004, 33 p.

25. Egbert L. W. Jongen: AN ANALYSIS OF PAST AND FUTURE GDP GROWTH IN SLOVENIA.

IER, Ljubljana, 2004, 42 p.

26. Egbert L. W. Jongen: FUTURE GDP GROWTH IN SLOVENIA: LOOKING FOR ROOM FOR

IMPROVEMENT. IER, Ljubljana, 2004, 37 p.

27. Peter Stanovnik, Marko Kos: TECHNOLOGY FORESIGHT IN SLOVENIA. IER, Ljubljana, 2005,

22 p.

28. Art Kovačič: COMPETITIVENESS AS A SOURCE OF DEVELOPMENT. IER, Ljubljana, 2005, 25 p.

29. Miroslav Verbič, Boris Majcen, Renger van Nieuwkoop: SUSTAINABILITY OF THE SLOVENIAN

PENSION SYSTEM: An ayalysis with an overlapping-generations General Equilibrium Model. IER,

Ljubljana, 2005. 24 p.

30. Miroslav Verbič: AN ANALYSIS OF THE SLOVENIAN ECONOMY WITH A QUARTERLY

ECONOMETRIC MODEL. IER, Ljubljana, 2006. 26 p.

31. Vladimir Lavrač, Boris Majcen: ECONOMIC ISSUES OF SLOVENIA'S ACCESSION TO THE EU.

IER, Ljubljana, 2006. 37 p.

32. Miroslav Verbič, Renata Slabe Erker: ECONOMIC VALUATION OF ENVIRONMENTAL VALUES

OF THE LANDSCAPE DEVELOPMENT AND PROTECTION AREA OF VOLČJI POTOK. IER,

Ljubljana, 2007. 28.p.

33. Boris Majcen, Miroslav Verbič. MODELLING THE PENSION SYSTEM IN AN OVERLAPING-

GENERATIONS GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM FRAMEWORK. IER, Ljubljana, 2007. 37 p.

34. Boris Majcen, Miroslav Verbič (corresponding author), Ali Bayar and Mitja Čok. THE INCOME TAX

REFORM IN SLOVENIA: SHOULD THE FLAT TAX HAVE PREVAILED? IER, Ljubljana, 2007.

29 p.

35. Miroslav Verbič. VARYING THE PARAMETERS OF THE SLOVENIAN PENSION SYSTEM: AN

ANALYSIS WITH AN OVERLAPPING-GENERATIONS GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL.

IER, Ljubljana, 2007. 28 p.

Page 35: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

36. Miroslav Verbič, SUPPLEMENTARY PENSION INSURANCE IN SLOVENIA: AN ANALYSIS

WITH AN OVERLAPPING-GENERATIONS GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODEL. IER,

Ljubljana, 2007. 32 p.

37. Matjaž Črnigoj: RISK AVERSE INSIDERS WITH SPECIFIC OBJECTIVE FUNCTION AND

CAPITAL STRUCTURE. IER, Ljubljana, 2007. 13 p.

38. Renata Slabe Erker, Janez Filiplič: MONITORING SUSTAINABILITY FOR SLOVENIA’S

REGIONS. IER, Ljubljana, 2007, 22 p.

39. Jože P. Damijan, Črt Kostevc: TRADE LIBERALIZATION AND ECONOMIC GEOGRAPHY IN

TRANSITION COUNTRIES: CAN FDI EXPLAIN THE ADJUSTMENT PATTERN OF

REGINAL WAGES? IER, Ljubljana, 2008, 40 p.

40. Jože P. Damijan, Matija Rojec, Boris Majcen, Mark Knell: IMPACT OF FORM HETEROGENEITY

ON DIRECT AND SPILLOVER EFFECTS OF FDI: MICRO EVIDENCE FROM TEN

TRANSITION COUNTRIES. IER, Ljubljana, 2008, 25 p.

41. Jože P. Damijan, Črt Kostevc, Matija Rojec. INNOVATION AND FIRMS’ PRODUCTIVITY

GROWTH IN SLOVENIA: SENSIVITY OF RESULTS TO SECTORAL HETEROGENEITY AND

TO ESTIMATION METHOD. IER, Ljubljana, 2008, 37 p.

42. Jože P. Damijan, Jose de Sousa, Olivier Lamotte. DOES INTERNATIONAL OPENNESS AFFECT

PRODUCTIVITY OF LOCAL FORMS? EVIDENCE FROM SOUTHERN EUROPE. IER,

Ljubljana, 2008, 29 p.

43. Jože P. Damijan, Črt Kostevc, Sašo Polanec. FROM INNOVATION TO EXPORTING OR VICE

VERSA? IER, Ljubljana, 2008, 28 p.

44. Milena Bevc. DEVELOPMENT OF THE NATIONAL SYSTEM OF INTERNATIONALLY

COMPARABLE INDICATORS OF FORMAL EDUCATION – CASE STUDY FOR A NON-OECD

COUNTRY. IER, Ljubljana, 2009, 27 p.

45. Miroslav Verbič, Boris Majcen, Mitja Čok. EDUCATION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN

SLOVENIA: A DYNAMIC GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM APPROACH WITH ENDOGENOUS

GROWTH. IER, Ljubljana, 2009, 21 p.

46. Miroslav Verbič, Boris Majcen, Mitja Čok. R&D AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN SLOVENIA: A

DYNAMIC GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM APPROACH WITH ENDOGENOUS GROWTH. IER,

Ljubljana, 2009, 21 p.

47. Valentina Prevolnik Rupel, Marko Ogorevc. LONG TERM CARE SYSTEM IN SLOVENIA. IER,

Ljubljana, 2010, 34 p.

48. Jože P. Damijan, Črt Kostevc. LEARNING FROM TRADE THROUGH INNOVATION: CAUSAL

LINK BETWEEN IMPORTS, EXPORTS AND INNOVATION IN SPANISH MICRODATA. IER,

Ljubljana, 2010, 30 p.

49. Peter Stanovnik, Nika Murovec. TERRITORIAL ICT KNOWLEDGE DYNAMICS IN SLOVENIA.

IER; Ljubljana, 2010, 35 p.

50. Nika Murovec, Peter Stanovnik. THE KNOWLEDGE DYNAMICS OF ICT IN SLOVENIA – Case

study. IER; Ljubljana, 2010, 59 p.

Page 36: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

51. Vladimir Lavrač. INCLUSION OF SLOVENIA IN THE EURO AREA AND PERSPECTIVES OF

ENLARGEMENT AFTER THE GLOBAL FINANCIAL CRISIS. IER, Ljubljana, 2010. 15 p.

52. Sašo Polanec, Aleš Ahčan, Miroslav Verbič. RETIREMENT DECISIONS IN TRANSITION:

MICROECONOMETRIC EVIDENCE FROM SLOVENIA. IER, Ljubljana, 2010. 24 p.

53. Tjaša Logaj, Sašo Polanec. COLLEGE MAJOR CHOICE AND ABILITY: WHY IS GENERAL

ABILITY NOT ENOUGH? IER, Ljubljana, 2011. 41 p.

54. Marko Ogorevc, Sonja Šlander. SHAREHOLDERS AND WAGE DETERMINATION. IER, Ljubljana,

2011. 13 p.

55. Boris Majcen, Miroslav Verbič, Sašo Polanec. INNOVATIVENESS AND INTANGIBLES: THE CASE

OF SLOVENIA. IER, Ljubljana, 2011. 31 p.

56. Valentina Prevolnik Rupel, Marko Ogorevc. QUALITY COUNTRY REPORT FOR SLOVENIA. IER,

Ljubljana, 2011. 13 p.

57. Mitja Čok, Jože Sambt, Marko Košak, Miroslav Verbič, Boris Majcen. DISTRIBUTION OF

PERSONAL INOCME TAX CHANGES IN SLOVENIA. IER, Ljubljana, 2011. 13 p.

58. Miroslav Verbič, Rok Spruk, AGING POPULATION AND PUBLIC PENSIONS: THEORY AND

EVIDENCE. IER, Ljubljana, 2011. 35 p.

59. Boris Majcen, Mitja Čok, Jože Sambt, Nataša Kump. DEVELOPMENT OF PENSION

MICROSIMULATION MODEL. IER, Ljubljana, 2012. 40 p.

60. Tine Stanovnik, Miroslav Verbič. THE DISTRIBUTION OF WAGES AND EMPLOYEE INCOMES

IN SLOVENIA, 1991-2009. IER, Ljubljana, 2012. 20 p.

61. Mitja Čok, Ivica Urban, Miroslav Verbič. INCOME REDISTRIBUTION THROUGH TAX AND

SOCIAL BENEFITS: THE CASE OF SLOVENIA AND CROATIA. IER, Ljubljana, 2012. 16 p.

62. Nika Murovec, Damjan Kavaš, Aidan Cerar. CLUSTERING, ANALYSIS AND CHALLENGES OF

THE CREATIVE INDUSTRIES IN SLOVENIA. IER, Ljubljana, 2012. 18 p.

Page 37: DOI: citation - IER paper-63.pdf · 2015. 4. 22. · Suggested citation: Sharifi‐Tehrani Mohammad, Verbič Miroslav, Chung Jin Young: An Analysis of Adopting Dual Pricing for Museums:

OCCASIONAL PAPERS

1. Helen O'Neill: IRELAND'S ECONOMIC TRANSITION: THE ROLE OF EU REGIONAL FUNDS

– AND OTHER FACTORS, IER, Ljubljana, 2000, 16 p.

2. Sanja Maleković: CROATIAN EXPERIENCE IN REGIONAL POLICY, IER, Ljubljana 2000, 13 p.

3. Peter Backé, Cezary Wójcik: ALTERNATIVE OPTIONS FOR THE MONETARY INTEGRATION

OF CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPEAN EU ACCESSION COUNTRIES, IER, Ljubljana, 2002,

17 p.

4. Andreas Freytag: CENTAL BANK INDEPENDENCE IN CENTRAL AND EASTERN EUROPE ON

THE EVE OF EU-ENLARGEMENT, IER, Ljubljana, 2003, 29 p.

5. Jasmina Osmanković: REGIONALIZATION AND REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN BOSNIA AND

HERZEGOVINA IN THE POST-WAR PERIOD, IER, Ljubljana, 2004, 16 p.

6. Carlos Vieira, Isabel Vieira, Sofia Costa: MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICIES IN EMU: SOME

RELEVANT ISSUES, IER, Ljubljana, 2004, 36 p.

7. Bojan Radej. THE FOUR CAPITAL MODEL, MATRIX AND ACCOUNTS. IER, Ljubljana, 2007.

25 p.

8. Bojan Radej. APPLES AND ORANGES IN PUBLIC POLICIES. MESO-MATRICAL SYNTESIS

OF THE INCOMMENSURABLE. IER, Ljubljana, 2008. 23 p.