34
Domestic Determinants of International Institutional Design: The Case of Bilateral Investment Treaties * Daniel J. Blake Department of Political Science The Ohio State University [email protected] November 2008 Abstract Proponents of the rational design school in International Relations posit that international institutions are purposefully designed to help states overcome obstacles such as problems of collective action, asymmetric information, adverse selection and time-inconsistent preferences that inhibit cooperation and promote collectively sub-optimal outcomes. While this functional understanding of institutions can explain important differences in institutional design and de- velopment, there remain many cases where functionally similar institutions exhibit subtle but important differences in design and content. This often unexplained variation reflects the liter- ature’s tendency to focus more on the problem-solving role of institutions and less on theorizing states’ preferences over precise institutional outcomes. In this paper, I attempt to partly fill this gap by arguing that domestic political institutions play a central role in determining state pref- erences over institutions and develop two lines of argument that address: a) the ease with which domestic institutions facilitate credible commitments; b) the institutionally derived incentives that leaders have to ensure a steady flow of public vs. private goods to their supporters. Focus- ing on the degree of policy flexibility that formal institutions afford governments, I argue that: a) as autocratic governments are less able to credibly commit to future policies, they will form institutions that constrain policy decisions to a greater degree; b) as democratic governments, in contrast to autocratic leaders, need to provide a greater ratio of public to private goods to stay in power, they will be more likely to build in to institutions flexibility for policies that facilitate the provision of public goods, whereas autocratic governments will seek to maintain flexibility for policies that allow them to secure private gains for small groups of core supporters. I evaluate these propositions in the case of bilateral investment treaties (BITs) using an original data set consisting of measures of the degree of policy flexibility in four different investment treatment provisions in a random sample of 324 BITs. (Preliminary Draft: Comments Welcome, Please Do Not Cite Without Permission) * This paper was prepared for presentation at the 3rd Annual Meeting of the International Political Economy Society, Philadelphia, 14-15 November, 2008. 1

Domestic Determinants of International Institutional

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Domestic Determinants of International Institutional Design: The Case of BilateralInvestment Treaties∗

Daniel J. BlakeDepartment of Political Science

The Ohio State [email protected]

November 2008

Abstract

Proponents of the rational design school in International Relations posit that internationalinstitutions are purposefully designed to help states overcome obstacles such as problems ofcollective action, asymmetric information, adverse selection and time-inconsistent preferencesthat inhibit cooperation and promote collectively sub-optimal outcomes. While this functionalunderstanding of institutions can explain important differences in institutional design and de-velopment, there remain many cases where functionally similar institutions exhibit subtle butimportant differences in design and content. This often unexplained variation reflects the liter-ature’s tendency to focus more on the problem-solving role of institutions and less on theorizingstates’ preferences over precise institutional outcomes. In this paper, I attempt to partly fill thisgap by arguing that domestic political institutions play a central role in determining state pref-erences over institutions and develop two lines of argument that address: a) the ease with whichdomestic institutions facilitate credible commitments; b) the institutionally derived incentivesthat leaders have to ensure a steady flow of public vs. private goods to their supporters. Focus-ing on the degree of policy flexibility that formal institutions afford governments, I argue that:a) as autocratic governments are less able to credibly commit to future policies, they will forminstitutions that constrain policy decisions to a greater degree; b) as democratic governments,in contrast to autocratic leaders, need to provide a greater ratio of public to private goods tostay in power, they will be more likely to build in to institutions flexibility for policies thatfacilitate the provision of public goods, whereas autocratic governments will seek to maintainflexibility for policies that allow them to secure private gains for small groups of core supporters.I evaluate these propositions in the case of bilateral investment treaties (BITs) using an originaldata set consisting of measures of the degree of policy flexibility in four different investmenttreatment provisions in a random sample of 324 BITs.

(Preliminary Draft: Comments Welcome, Please Do Not Cite Without Permission)

∗This paper was prepared for presentation at the 3rd Annual Meeting of the International Political EconomySociety, Philadelphia, 14-15 November, 2008.

1

Introduction

The rational design of institutions research program in International Relations has provided scholars

with a clear framework through which to understand variation in design features across institutions.

This framework is unambiguously functionalist in nature; political leaders create institutions to

solve problems. Rationalist explanations typically link the dynamics of a problem - its “situation

structure” - to the institutional solutions that result (Hasenclever, Mayer & Rittberger 1997).

Although some progress has been made in recent years, what has yet to be answered definitively

in extant research is why institutions that aim to solve the same or similar problems, should be

structured differently in different domains. For example, Abbot and Snidal (2000) argue that high

levels of institutional legalization will be favored by states in environments where the potential

for opportunistic defection is high. However, we see variation in the design of trade agreements

where the potential for opportunistic defection is similarly high (e.g. Yarbrough & Yarbrough 1987,

Pevehouse & Buhr 2005). Moreover, Kahler (2002), argues that, in the case of global monetary

institutions, existing functionalist or demand-side explanations “fail to explain a crucial portion

of observed institutional variation over time” (p.42) because they fail to acknowledge that the

preferences of states can vary.

Kahler’s criticism is well founded in this regard as is his assertion that “domestic politics and

political economy offer a superior baseline for defining state preferences in functionalist models”

(p.42). In notable surveys of the field, several prominent scholars have stressed that an impor-

tant link exists between domestic politics and political institutions and international institutions

(Kahler 2000, Martin & Simmons 1998), but very little research has been conducted into the

effect of domestic political institutions on the design of international institutions. In Interna-

tional Political Economy, much focus has instead been on the role of domestic institutions in

framing foreign economic policy (e.g. Gowa 1988, Lohmann & O’Halloran 1994, Mansfield, Milner

& Rosendorff 2000, McGillivray 1997, Milner & Kubota 2005). One notable exception is Bernhard

and Leblang’s (1999) investigation of the effect of democratic electoral and legislative institutions

on governments’ exchange rate mechanism preferences. More recent studies have linked domestic

political institutions to the probability of a state joining a preferential trading arrangement and the

2

legalization of preferential trading agreements’ dispute settlement mechanisms (Mansfield, Milner

& Pevehouse 2007, Pevehouse & Buhr 2005). However, these studies remain the exception, rather

than the norm.

This paper takes up Kahler’s suggestion to look to domestic politics to determine the preferences

of state leaders with respect to the design of international institutions. In particular, I look to

domestic political institutions, and primarily regime type, to explain why some states choose to

conclude highly constraining bilateral investment treaties (BITs) that limit policy flexibility while

others choose to conclude agreements that contain exceptions and loopholes that allow governments

greater freedom to influence the environment in which multinational enterprises (MNEs) operate.

The government-MNE relationship is characterized by time-inconsistency of preferences with

governments unable to credibly commit to guarantee investors secure property rights and favorable

investment conditions in the long run. Many have argued that the constraining power of democratic

political institutions can help overcome this credible commitment problem. Others have suggested

that institutions at the international level, in the form of investment treaties can raise the costs

governments incur for reneging on past promises to foreign investors and thus enhance their abilities

to credible commit to treat MNEs favorably. This suggests that BITs are in a position to substitute

for domestic institutions that are not conducive to facilitating credible commitments. Arguments in

the extant literature extol the virtues of democratic institutions vis-a-vis the ability of government

to make credible commitments (e.g. Jensen 2003) and lead us to expect that autocratic governments

seeking to credibly commit, and their treaty partners seeking credible commitments from autocrats,

would favor more constraining BITs that greatly limit policy flexibility.

The influence of domestic institutions on leaders’ institutional design preferences extends po-

tentially beyond considerations of credible commitments. Bueno de Mesquita et al. (2003) identify

a clear distinction between democratic and autocratic governments in terms of the goods they must

provide their supporters to stay in power. Democratic leaders seeking the support of a larger con-

stituency favor the provision of public goods while autocratic leaders maintain power by rewarding

their smaller group of supporters with private goods. Recent scholarship has applied this insight

to explain trade liberalization and trade volatility in response to leadership turnover (McGillivray

3

& Smith 2004, Milner & Kubota 2005) but not to the design of international institutions. I argue

that the “logic of political survival” extends to leaders’ preferences over institutional design and

to the relative degree of policy flexibility and constraint that institutions establish. Specifically,

autocratic governments should seek to preserve greater policy flexibility in areas where policy is

conducive to the provision of private goods. In contrast, democratic governments should seek to

maintain greater control over policy levers that facilitate the provision of private goods. Thus, while

entering into an institution such as an investment treaty entails an enhanced level of commitment

and constraint on future policy, leaders should seek to temper these constraints in areas where

policy tools are most integral to their ability to stay in power.

In the sections that follow, I develop these two lines of argument that link domestic institutions

to leaders’ preferences over institutional design, and then, ultimately to the institutions we observe,

in the issue area of foreign direct investment (FDI) and BITs. I then test these propositions

employing an original data set that contains measures of policy flexibility and constraint for multiple

BIT components. I find a robust relationship between regime type and policy flexibility in BITs,

however, statistical tests show that the relationship between greater institutional constraints at the

domestic level are positively correlated with constraints at the international level. This suggests

that BITs establish hard constraints when they are least necessary. However, I argue that these

results should not necessarily lead to such a pessimistic conclusion. Furthermore, I find support

for the “political survival” argument as democratic host states are more likely to be sign BITs

where there is greater flexibility over tax and fiscal policies which are essential for public goods

provision whereas BITs with greater flexibility over national treatment which eases the ability of

host governments to privilege local firms are more likely to be signed by autocratic host states.

Commitment, Democracy and Foreign Direct Investment

The problem of time-inconsistency occurs in dynamic environments where policymakers have incen-

tives to promise one thing and then do another after other actors have made decisions and/or taken

actions based on these earlier promises (Maggi & Rodriguez-Clare 1998, Persson & Tabellini 2000).

The “obsolescing bargain” that characterizes much FDI reflects such a situation (Vernon 1971,

4

Moran 1995). Under the obsolescing bargain, multinational enterprises (MNEs) are often in a

position to choose to locate operations in one of multiple possible locations around the world. Gov-

ernments have significant incentives to attempt to attract these enterprises as their investments are

a potential source of employment, tax revenue and technology transfer. Furthermore, FDI is an

important source of foreign exchange in developing countries facing balance of payments problems.

Given the potential benefits of incoming FDI, potential host governments are often forced to com-

pete to attract MNEs by offering inducements to investors before they invest in the hope that such

benefits will tempt investors to locate in their state. These inducements range from tax holidays

and export duty exemptions to investment grants and wage subsidies (Li & Resnick 2003).

Thus, before location, bargaining power is with the firm. After entry, however, bargaining power

shifts to host state because FDI is often characterized by a relatively high degree of irreversibility

and sunk costs (Jensen 2003, Moran 1999, Stasavage 2002). Thus, governments, having made

significant concessions in the original bargain with investors, may now be tempted to renege on

their promises and establish a new bargain involving policies that direct a greater share of the foreign

enterprise’s revenue towards the government which it then may chose to redistribute to important

constituents. Examples of such policy changes include: changes to performance requirements; direct

expropriation, nationalization, and confiscation of foreign owned assets; and changes in capital

taxation and regulation (Henisz 2000, Jodice 1980, Moran 1995). Investors, wary of the potential

for such changing circumstances may be reluctant to invest. Thus, FDI-seeking governments have

an incentive to find a way to credibly guarantee that the original terms of their investment contracts

will be upheld.

Many have argued that political institutions at the domestic level influence the ease with which

governments can make credible commitments and that democratic regimes possess those institu-

tional traits that enhance credibility. The first of those traits is institutional checks and balances

that give multiple actors a veto over the executive’s policy decisions and thus make policy change

more difficult and costly (e.g. Cowhey 1993, North & Weingast 1989, Snidal & Thompson 2003). In

this line of argument, the ease of policy reversal is a decreasing function of the number of veto points

and democratic leaders typically have to overcome a greater number of vetoes than autocratic lead-

5

ers (Leeds 1999). The second trait is the need for democratic leaders to secure the support of a large

winning coalition, typically through popular elections, to maintain power. This is because publics

tend to disapprove of leaders who back down from previous positions and break their commitments

resulting in punishment at the polls (Fearon 1994). Such “audience costs” are higher in democratic

than in non-democratic regimes because democratic leaders are more responsive to public opinion

as it is upon that opinion that their political survival rests (Gartzke & Gleditsch 2004, Mansfield,

Milner & Rosendorff 2002).

These arguments regarding the virtues of democratic institutions vis-a-vis credible commitments

have been applied to the domain of foreign direct investment. Nathan Jensen (2003) argues that

the institutional checks on policy reversal and heightened audience costs characteristic of democ-

racies impairs the ability of the executive to reverse earlier commitments of favorable treatment

towards foreign MNEs. With respect to audience costs, Jensen forcefully argues that, “if govern-

ments make agreements with multinational firms and renege on the contracts after the investment

has been made, democratic leaders may suffer electoral costs” because commitment violations scare

away further FDI (p.595). He does not deny that reneging on commitments to FDI may be po-

litically beneficial in the short run as increased income flows from policy changes can be directed

to core political supporters. However, this is equally likely to be the case in autocracies as it is

in democracies. Meanwhile, Li and Resnick (2003) stress that democratic governments are better

able to commit to securing the property rights of foreign investors. Drawing on earlier work by

North and Weingast (1989) and Olson (1993), they argue that the effective political representation

of diverse groups, meaningful legislature, electoral constraints and independence of the judiciary

found in established democracies helps them attain strong property rights and uphold contracts,

thereby protecting investments from “predatory banditry” by the executive. It is precisely because

democracy itself rests on such institutions that established democracies display high levels of prop-

erty rights protection. The causal logic underlying this argument falls under the umbrella of the

institutionalized veto points perspective as a meaningful legislature and an independent judiciary

in this argument act as institutional checks on the executive.

Working from the reasonable assumption that ceteris paribus investors will locate in places where

6

policy shifts are less likely and property rights are more secure, Jensen, and Li and Resnick find

that countries with strong property rights and democratic regimes attract more investment after

controlling for other economic and political factors that influence investment location. However,

Li and Resnick find find that once controlling for property rights protection, democracies do not

attract more FDI. This suggests that the institutional veto points upon which effective property

rights rests plays a greater role than audience costs in enabling governments to credibly commit.

This is perhaps not surprising because audience costs are a function of issue salience as monitoring

government behavior is a costly exercise (Gartzke & Gleditsch 2004). A decision to go to war

or escalate an international crisis has high visibility and is salient for most of the selectorate

in a democracy and thus there may be, as Fearon (1994) argues, genuine audience costs from

backing down from a previous position. On the other hand, citizens will not find it rational to

become familiar with the minutiae of investor-state contracts and monitor the behavior of their

elected leaders to see if they renege on their contractual obligations. Furthermore, while backing

down in a crisis can have audience costs, as Jensen acknowledges there can be domestic audience

gains from backing out of commitments to foreign investors. Indeed, many large scale acts of

nationalization of foreign assets, from Nasser to Morales, have had a powerful populist dimension

to them. Finally, in an issue area as complex as international and contract law, it is difficult for

voters to independently determine, in an environment of competing claims by their government

and foreign investors, whether or not their leaders have indeed violated previous commitments1.

Thus, at best, the role of audience costs in helping governments to make credible commitments to

FDI is limited. However, the effect of institutional checks and balances is still significant.

Bilateral Investment Treaties as Commitment Devices

International institutions are diverse in their membership, design and objectives and not all in-

stitutions are designed with the purpose of enhancing the credibility of commitments. However,

the ability of international institutions to perform such a function has achieved broad acceptance

1This may not always be the case, especially in instances of large scale nationalization and expropriation. However,such acts have been much less common since the 1980s (Kobrin 1984) and smaller violations of investment contracts,or “creeping expropriation”, which are harder to observe and interpret are increasingly the norm.

7

in the institutionalist literature in International Relations. International institutions do this by

making the consequences of reneging on commitments more costly to governments. In some cases

they do this by increasing the probability that non-compliance with commitments will be de-

tected by clearly specifying standards of conduct and facilitating the monitoring of state activity

(Keohane 1984, Oye 1986). This increases the likelihood of detection and the risks that states will

incur reputation and audience costs from non-compliance (Dai 2005). Some institutions such as the

World Trade Organization’s dispute settlement procedure contain a mechanism that allows audience

costs to be accompanied by material costs from sanction or retaliation for violating commitments.

Furthermore, institutions help facilitate issue-linkage which can raise the costs of defection in one

issue area because defection may then be punished through loss of benefits in linked issue areas

(Martin 1992).

The principal institution(s) governing foreign direct investment is an increasingly dense net-

work of thousands of bilateral investment treaties (BITs). Since 1959, over 2600 BITs have been

concluded by more than 175 countries (UNCTAD 2008). Attempts to consolidate these agreements

into a single institution have been unsuccessful with states preferring to preserve their autonomy in

negotiating with individual investment partners2. While BITs are concluded between governments,

they primarily govern the conduct of governments towards their treaty partners’ private investors

engaged in economic activity within their territory.

In terms of issues covered, BITs are remarkably similar with the vast majority outlining gov-

ernment obligations to foreign investors in the following areas (UNCTAD 2007):

1. Promotion of Investment

2. Absolute Standards of Treatment

3. Relative Standards of Treatment (e.g. Most-Favored Nation Obligations)

4. Transfers of Capital

5. Compensation for Losses Due to War and Civil Unrest

6. Conditions and Compensation for Acts of Expropriation

7. Pledge to Honor All Other Obligations to Foreign Investors2The abortive attempt led by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) to develop

a Multilateral Agreement on Investment, abandoned in 1997, is the most prominent example of this (Kobrin 1998).

8

8. State-State Dispute Settlement

9. Investor-State Dispute Settlement

The first seven of these areas serve the institutional function of establishing acceptable standards

of conduct. They generally aim to afford investors fair and equitable treatment, protect investor’s

property rights and promote an environment in which MNEs are free from discriminatory and

predatory behavior by host governments. The pledge to honor other obligations is particularly

important because it brings private contracts concluded between investors and governments under

the protective umbrella of the treaty. The last provision listed, investor-state dispute settlement, is

the primary source of increased costs for violating these standards of conduct. Most BITs’ dispute

settlement clauses grant private investors the right to take host governments to arbitration directly

(i.e. without the approval or assistance of their home governments) if they feel they have violated

provisions of the BIT or, in some cases, if they have any investment related grievance. If the

arbitrators find in favor of the investors, they have the power to order offending governments to

pay compensation to the investors.

The costs of arbitration to governments are real. Legal costs alone are tens of millions of dollars

which is substantial for developing countries with small economies. Arbitration awards can also

be substantial. For example, in 2003, a Stockholm based tribunal awarded the Dutch-American

firm, Central European Media (CME), 350 million dollars in compensation for what it judged was

violation of a BIT between the Netherlands and the Czech Republic (Peterson 2003a, Peterson

2003b). This effectively doubled the Czech governments already record budget deficit for that year

and led Czech leaders to consider raising the nation’s value added tax (Peterson 2003b). Thus

the ability for BITs to generate material costs for commitment violating governments is genuine.

Furthermore, such large awards and the actions governments need to take to pay them can also have

the effect of triggering audience costs as the media is likely to publicize the outcome and constituents

are forced to foot the bill. Thus, the costliness and more public nature of arbitration, as provided

for in BITs, help to make violation of investment commitments salient to domestic audiences. A

final manner in which BITs may raise the costs of breaking commitments to foreign investors is

through reputation costs. Todd Allee and Clint Peinhardt (2008a) have argued that arbitration

9

of investment disputes, as provided for in BITs, sends negative signals to foreign investors about

the investment environment in states that appear before arbitration which results in reduced FDI

flows to that state. This dimension of commitment enhancement may be particularly relevant for

autocratic governments because, as highlighted above, the effect of audience costs in autocratic

regimes is attenuated.

The argument that BITs increase the costs of reneging and therefore make commitments to fair

and equitable treatment of foreign investors more credible has been made before as has the argument

that states sign BITs with a view to attracting foreign investment by credibly guaranteeing to

provide a secure investment environment (Buthe & Milner 2005, Guzman 1998, Elkins, Guzman &

Simmons 2006). Simmons et al. (2006) go further to argue that the competition to attract FDI

between governments has spilled over into the negotiation of BITs such that there is a competitive

diffusion of BITs across host states. This suggests that governments, host and home alike, believe

that BITs can substitute for imperfect domestic institutions and lock in government promises of

favorable treatment towards foreign investors.

Institutions, Commitment and BIT design

BITs are typically signed by states that have asymmetric FDI flows. Usually one BIT partner

is a developed and/or large economy that exports a significant amount of FDI while the other is

a developing economy that exports little FDI but rather seeks foreign capital. Thus, based on

economic size, development and FDI activity one can often identify the likely exporter of FDI (the

home state) and the likely importer of FDI (the host state) in a BIT relationship. Although BIT

provisions are largely reciprocal, applying equally to both treaty partners, the asymmetric nature

of FDI flows between BIT partners mean that when designing and concluding a BIT the host and

home state seek, in practice, to constrain the host state’s policy flexibility. This is done by using the

provisions in the BIT to make policy shifts, in a wide range of areas that can adversely investment,

more costly. The host state seeks this constraint to attract foreign investment while the home state

seeks to protect the interests of its investors.

The preceding discussion of the commitment virtues of democratic institutions suggests that the

10

need to enhance governments’ capacities to credibly commit are greatest for states with autocratic

institutions. Thus autocratic leaders in host states who seek to make credible commitments to

foreign investors would seek highly constraining BITs given that their existing policy constraints are

limited. Similarly, home governments concluding BITs with autocrats’ would seek treaty provisions

that more tightly constrain policy in order to more effectively limit policies that can negatively

affect the profitability of their firms’ and citizens’ enterprises. From this argument we can derive

the following expectation:

H1: BITs in which the host government faces fewer domestic institutional constraints (i.e. auto-cratic regimes) are more likely to contain provisions that place greater constraints on governmentpolicy.

Domestic Institutions and the Political Economy of FDI

The previous section outlined how the commitment capacities inherent in different domestic political

institutions can affect leaders’ preferences with respect to BIT design. However, the need and ability

to establish credible commitments is not the only manner in which domestic institutions can shape

preferences over international institutional design in general, and BITs in particular, with respect

to policy constraint and flexibility. In this section I present an alternative perspective that focuses

on the political economy of inward FDI and leaders’ desires for political survival.

One of the central arguments to emerge from Bueno de Mesquita and colleagues’ (2003) The

Logic of Political Survival (and related works) is that the size of the winning coalition (W) required

for an incumbent to stay in power affects the type of goods that it is most efficient for a leader to

supply in order to maintain support. Leaders can choose to use their resources to provide public or

private goods with the former benefitting all members of society and the latter benefitting only the

winning coalition. When W is small, the incumbent leader can maintain its support most effectively

by providing supporters with private goods. On the other hand, when W is large, it is more efficient

to provide public goods and effective public policy. If we adopt Bueno de Mesquita et al.’s plausible

assumption that incumbents wish, above all, to stay in power, then they will care about preserving

their flexibility and freedom to use policy levers that allow them to generate the appropriate stream

11

of goods to their winning coalition. Thus, with respect to international institutions such as BITs

that seek to curtail policy freedom, we should expect the following:

• Leaders of autocratic regimes will prefer to build greater flexibility into institutions for policies

that are conducive to the provision of private goods.

• Leaders of democratic regimes will prefer to build greater flexibility into institutions for

policies that are conducive to the provision of public goods.

For an institution such as a BIT to be significant, it needs to effectively constrain government

behavior. However, as Rosendorff and Milner (2001) argue with respect to the World Trade Orga-

nization, office-seeking politicians will seek to balance constraint with flexibility to allow them to

attend to the needs of their supporters without rupturing the entire institutional framework. What

I suggest here is that the areas of flexibility that leaders seek may, at least in some cases, reflect

the kind of policy levers that they find most effective in ensuring political support. I acknowledge

that policies often have both private and public components (McGillivray & Smith 2004) and that

leaders, regardless of the size of W, will often provide some mix of public and private goods (see

Grossman & Helpman 1994). Nevertheless, the relative importance of public and private goods to

leaders will vary according to the size of the winning coalition.

Public Goods, Private Goods and FDI

What type of good is FDI? As noted earlier, inward FDI is often greatly desired by governments,

particularly those in capital scarce states in the developing world, because FDI can be a source of

employment, technology, foreign exchange and tax revenue. However, much of the literature on the

consequences of FDI for the host state, particularly in the short-run, indicates that benefits and

costs of inward FDI are typically concentrated in certain sectors of the economy and regions of the

host country (Li & Resnick 2003).

For example, the net nationwide impact of FDI on employment in a host country can be very

small, but if FDI chooses to concentrate in a particular region, employment in that region may rise

12

at the expense of other regions3 (Graham & Krugman 1991). On the other hand, if foreign MNEs

displace local firms in a particular part of the host state, and are more efficient than their local

predecessors, they not only put local capital owners out of business but can also reduce the demand

for labor in that sector and in that region of the host country (Hanson 2001). In addition, it has

been argued that efficient foreign MNEs can drive locally owned competitors in the same sector

to become more efficient (Li & Resnick 2003)e.g., however, they can also force local competitors

to produce at below optimum capacity by reducing their market share and cause them to become

more inefficient and to suffer profit losses (Aitken & Harrison 1999). However, while displacing local

firms in the same sector, foreign firms may increase employment and productivity in upstream and

downstream sectors if they use domestic firms to source intermediate goods and distribute finished

products (Gorg & Greenaway 2003, Markusen & Venables 1999). Finally, some have argued that

beneficial productivity spillovers from MNEs tend to concentrate in those local firms and industries

that have a high quality of physical and human capital and thus are capable of absorbing such

spillovers effectively (Gorg & Greenaway 2003, Li & Resnick 2003).

This concentration of gains and losses from FDI in sectors and regions causes FDI to take on the

character of a private good. The benefits of FDI in terms of employment and technology transfer

are concentrated in small groups of firms, individuals and regions. Thus, government policy that

eases investment provides a private good to these groups. Likewise, any government policy that

seeks to protect or support those firms and workers that are challenged or displaced by FDI provides

a private good to these groups.

One might reasonably question whether or not there is no public good to be found in FDI, as

there is in trade, in the form of a consumer dividend. The existence of such a dividend depends

on the nature of inward FDI. If FDI seeks to service local markets, then the greater efficiency of

MNEs potentially results in a greater variety of better made products at lower prices for consumers

in the host country. In this case, the benefits of FDI are widespread but the costs to local firms

that compete unsuccessfully with MNEs are still narrow. Not all FDI is market seeking, however,

and much investment into the developing world seeks primarily to extract natural resources or

3The development of export processing zones in developing countries may encourage such regional concentration.

13

use relatively cheaper inputs in manufacturing for export back to the home state and/or other

countries4. In both of these cases, the costs and benefits of FDI are narrowly concentrated.

Host State Preferences Over BIT Provisions

What are the policy implications of the “private” nature of FDI? Firstly, democratic governments

gain little directly from FDI in terms of public goods creation beyond some limited increases in

consumer welfare from market-seeking MNE operations. Therefore, they seek to redistribute and

spread some of the gains from FDI that accrue to MNEs and to domestic winners from FDI. They

do this through using FDI to generate tax revenue. Recall that governments seek to attract FDI

to generate employment, technology transfers and tax revenue. For democratic leaders seeking

to provide public goods, tax revenue is the most important of these three benefits of FDI. By

taxing foreign enterprises the government channels a share of the profits gained by the firm and its

employees, and domestic commercial partners, towards the provision of public goods. Moreover,

these public goods can include social welfare programs and labor market intervention that help to

compensate domestic losers from FDI. Thus, we should expect the following:

H2: BITs in Which the Host State is More Democratic are More Likely to Contain Greater Flex-ibility for Policies that Facilitate Public Goods Provision and Redistribution (i.e. Tax and FiscalPolicy)

Autocratic governments on the other hand, care less for redistribution of the gains from FDI

and instead focus on promoting the interests of the small group that makes up their core supporters.

Most host states that sign BITs are developing countries and in autocratic developing countries the

selectorate from which the winning coalition is chosen frequently “consists of the richest individuals,

and hence those who own the most capital” (Milner & Kubota 2005). Thus, given the propensity

of FDI to displace and crowd out domestic capital, there is a high probability that members of

the winning coalition will be potentially harmed by competition from highly competitive MNEs.

In order to maintain the support of such capital owners, autocrats prefer to have sufficient policy

autonomy to grant them special privileges and supports such as subsidies or exemptions from

4Recall that in most cases cases the host state in BITs are developing economies.

14

certain regulations, that will allow their firms to survive and compete. Such protection is clearly a

private good and is only effective if granted to local producers and not foreign MNEs. This leads

to the following hypothesis:

H3: BITs in Which the Host State is More Autocratic are More Likely to Contain Greater Flex-ibility for Policies that Facilitate Private Goods Provision and the Protection of Narrow Interests(i.e. Policies Privileging Domestic Firms and Producers)

In terms of BIT design, such privileging of domestic firms is done by denying foreign firms national

treatment (i.e. treatment that is no less favorable than that accorded to domestic enterprises).

One might question the need to preserve flexibility over national treatment as governments

can simply deny entry to foreign firms that can displace capital owned by important political

supporters. This is indeed a possible solution but it may not always be optimal. Firstly, capital

owners in upstream and downstream industries as well as those participating in joint ventures with

inward FDI may benefit from FDI. Thus, autocratic leaders seeking to provide capital owners in

the winning coalition with private goods may not want to deny entry to MNEs as some supporters

benefit, but they may also want to protect those domestic firms that are vulnerable, especially if

that vulnerability is expected to be short-lived or temporary, as in the case of infant industries.

Testing the Arguments: Data and Methodology

Dependent Variable: The Degree of Policy Flexibility/Constraint in BIT Provisions

The growing literature on BITs has tended to treat them as homogenous in all meaningful respects5

(e.g. Buthe & Milner 2005, Neumayer & Spess 2005, Elkins, Guzman & Simmons 2006). Moreover,

even studies that acknowledge some degree of variation across BITs assert that they are essentially

the same apart from provisions that relate to the states’ pre-consent to investor-state dispute

settlement (Yackee 2007).

One argument that has been forwarded to justify this approach is that as most treaties contain

most-favored nation provisions guaranteeing investors the best treatment a state offers to investors

from any other country, the most favorable treaty a state signs applies to all of its BIT partners

5For a noteworthy exception to the trend of treating all BITs alike see Allee and Peinhardt (2008b).

15

(Yackee 2007). This argument is misleading in several respects. Firstly, most-favored nation

provisions in treaties only require that the signatories grant investors from their treaty partner

treatment no less favorable than they grant to investors from any third state. This does not preclude

variation in the level of treatment different states choose to promise foreign investors. Secondly,

most-favored nation provisions can include exceptions that are particular to certain BITs. Thus,

the promise of most-favored nation may not always be comprehensive. Finally, there often needs to

be some degree of situational congruence for most-favored nation provisions to apply. Situational

congruence is unlikely to always be present, especially when one considers that firms from different

countries will invest in different industries under different contractual terms making straightforward

comparisons of the treatment of firms form different countries difficult, and possibly inappropriate.

While bilateral investment treaties share the same purpose of creating a secure environment

for investment and are undoubtedly similar in structure, they do vary in subtle but important

ways. The theoretical discussion above has focused on the relative degree of policy flexibility and

constraint in BITs. I argue that these variations in BITs are substantive and have significant impli-

cations for the policy flexibility and autonomy that governments have towards foreign investors. In

short, governments can and build into treaties policy flexibility along several dimensions and this

often takes the form of exceptions to general principles, such as the principle of national treatment.

In some cases common provisions may be omitted entirely from the text of a treaty.

Measuring Policy Flexibility in BITs

I developed an original coding scheme to measure the relative level of flexibility and constraint in

several BIT provisions. Development of the coding scheme was guided by the United Nations Con-

ference on Trade and Development’s (UNCTAD) (2007) Bilateral Investment Treaties 1995-2006:

Trends in Investment Rulemaking, an impressively detailed clause by clause review of trends in BIT

drafting and their implications for states and investors. The subset of provisions chosen to be coded

relate to the following: 1) Admission of Investment; 2) Most Favored Nation Treatment; 3) National

Treatment; 4) Tax/Fiscal Policy. The coding scheme for each of these provisions is presented in

tables 1-4, with larger numbers indicating greater policy flexibility for host governments.

16

Table 1: Admission of FDICode Content of Treaty Provision

0 Investors are guaranteed some form of most favored nation and/or national treatment

1 No requirements to admit investment orAdmission is contingent on domestic legislation and policy

Table 2: Most Favored Nation Treatment of FDICode Content of Treaty Provision

0 Most-Favored Nation Without Exceptions

1 Most-Favored Nation With Exceptions or No MFN Commitment

Table 3: National Treatment of FDICode Content of Treaty Provision

1 National Treatment Without Exceptions

2 Most-Favored Nation With Exceptions or Contingent on Domestic Legislation

3 No National Treatment Commitments

Table 4: Tax/Fiscal PolicyCode Content of Treaty Provision

0 No mention of tax or fiscal policyin the context of treaty exemptions for double taxation agreements

1 Tax/fiscal policy exempt from most-favored nation and/or nationaltreatment provisions OR exempt from all parts of the treaty

17

Figure 1: Differences in National Treatment and Tax Provisions in a Sample of 324 BITs

These four areas were selected for several reasons. Firstly, they all have a direct influence on

the freedom host governments have to implement and adjust policies towards foreign and domestic

investors and manipulate the allocation of costs and benefits of foreign investment activity. Sec-

ondly, they are less open to variations in legal interpretation and stylistic variations than other

BIT provisions making attempts at cross-treaty comparison more reliable. The third reason is that

there is genuine variation across BITs in these areas, whereas in some others there is little mean-

ingful variation worth investigating. For instance, there is almost universal consensus regarding the

acceptable conditions for expropriation are and how investors should be compensated (UNCTAD

2007). Furthermore, the coding scheme is relatively simple and treaty provisions are broken up into

easily differentiable categories. Again this facilitates reliable and easy comparisons across treaties

written in multiple different languages. A random sample of 324 BITs were coded and figure 1 illus-

trates the variation in content in two areas: national treatment and tax/fiscal policy. Information

on the universe of BITs, the dates of BIT signings and BIT texts were obtained from UNCTAD’s

online treaty database and the Kluwer Arbitration Online’s investment treaty database6.

6Kluwer Arbitration’s source for the BIT texts is the Penn State Institute of Arbitration Law and Practice.

18

The measures for each BIT provision are tested in two ways. Firstly, a combined index of all four

measures are examined as a general measure of BIT policy constraint. The index is constructed by

normalizing each measure and then summing across all four measures. This general measure is used

primarily to test the first hypothesis that links the need to enhancement commitment credibility

to BIT design. The second approach uses the national treatment and tax/fiscal policy measures

individually as originally coded. These individual measures are employed to test hypotheses two

and three regarding public and private goods provision. As indicated above, tax and fiscal policy

facilitates public goods provision whilst exceptions to national treatment promotes the provision of

private goods

Independent Variables

In addition to the main independent variable of regime type, several control variables that are

common in the literature on BITs and FDI are also included in the statistical tests. Furthermore,

variables that attempt to capture and control for the bargaining power and dynamics between the

home and host state are also included. While the arguments presented above have focused on the

preferences of the host state and, to a lesser degree, the home state, a BIT’s design is the outcome

of a bargain between the two parties. Thus, it is important to control for factors than can influ-

ence the bargaining aspect of the treaty design. The monadic independent variables are those in

the model that measure characteristics of the individual members of each dyad. For the monadic

variables a distinction is drawn between host and home states. The host state is the member of the

dyad with the lower GDP per capita7. All time varying independent variables are lagged one year.

Monadic Independent Variables

The host state’s regime type is the main independent variable in the model. The home state’s

regime type is also included. Both are measured using the Polity IV Autocracy-Democracy Score

from -10 to 10 (Marshall & Jaggers 2006). Polity’s measure of regime durability is also included

for the host state. It is the number of years since a significant shift in the host state’s regime

7This practice mimics the approach employed by Simmons et al. (2006)

19

type (defined by a 3 point or greater change in the polity scale). Regime durability may effect

the design of BITs as states with long-lasting regimes may have well-known institutions on which

rest established reputations for the treatment of FDI that therefore reduce the challenge of making

credible commitments, and the need for highly constraining BITs. Thus a positive relationship

between durability and policy flexibility is expected.

Several monadic economic variables are employed in the model including the logarithmic trans-

formation of the host and the home country’s GDP per capita. The log of the host country’s GDP

is used as a proxy for the level of economic development. This is included as a control variable

because the level of development can potentially effect the contents of BIT provisions, although

the direction of the effect is not clear. For example, a more economically developed host may be

less willing to push for a less constraining BIT as they believe that domestic firms are capable

of competing with foreign investors and as human and physical capital is developed enough for

local firms to derive substantial gains from technology and productivity spillovers. On the other

hand, developed economies are desirable investment locations and so home states may be more

willing to concede greater flexibility to a more developed BIT partner to ensure that an agreement

is concluded that offers some protection to investors. The home country’s level of development is

also included as a more developed home country may have bargaining leverage because it has a

greater degree of technological sophistication and know-how that its firms can potentially transfer

to the host state and this may result in more constraining BIT provisions. GDP data is obtained

from the Gleditsch (2002) Expanded Trade and GDP Data v5.0 the years 1960-2004 and from the

World Bank’s World Development Indicators for the years 2005-06. A further economic variable is

included in the model, FDI outflows as a share of GDP for the home state. This is another mea-

sure of bargaining leverage as home states that export larger amounts of FDI should have greater

bargaining power with host states that are keen to attract that investment. Thus a negative rela-

tionship with policy flexibility is expected. FDI flow data is obtained from the World Bank’s World

Development Indicators .

A variable which is the count of the number of BITs signed in the same region as the host state

in the past five years is also included in the analysis. Simmons et al. (2006) find strong evidence of

20

the diffusion of BIT signing through processes of competition and learning. This measure attempts

to control for the possible affect that such processes may have on the design of BITs. The assump-

tion is that learning and, in particular, competition will be strongest with one’s regional neighbors

and that as the number of BITs signed in the region grows, this creates greater pressure on states

to conclude more BITs. If this has any effect on BIT design, it should be to make BIT provisions

more constraining as host states are more willing to concede policy flexibility in order to sign the

BIT sooner rather than later. Data on regional membership is taken from Hadenius and Teorell

(2005).

Dyadic Independent Variables

A further indicator of bargaining power is included at the dyadic level. Following measures used

in the literature on material capabilities, a variable called wealth ratio is constructed by taking the

home state’s GDP (corrected for inflation) and dividing it by the sum of the home and the host

state’s GDP. The larger the ratio of home state GDP to dyadic combined GDP, the greater economic

power and leverage the home state has over the host state and the more likely that BIT provisions

will be more constraining.

Neumayer (2006) has found support that political links between states affects the probability

they will sign a BIT. It is possible that such links will spillover and influence BIT design. Therefore

two dummy variables for whether or not the home and host state share an alliance and whether or

not they have a shared colonial heritage are included in the analysis. Data on alliance membership

and colonial heritage are taken from Leeds (2005) and Hadenius and Teorell (2005) respectively.

The density of economic links between home and host state may also influence BIT design.

Ideally, one would be able to control for the level of bilateral FDI flows. However, the availability

of bilateral FDI data is inconsistent at best and there is very little data for dyads involving non-

OECD states. Therefore, to measure economic ties, the level of dyadic trade between the home and

host country is included using data obtained from Barbieri, Keshk and Pollins (2008). Furthermore,

economic interactions typically decline with the distance between actors. Therefore, as more cross-

border direct investment is to be expected between members in close proximity (i.e. within the

21

same region), there is a possibility that this expectation of dense economic ties will affect BIT

design. Therefore, I include a dummy variable which equals one when both home and host state

are located in the same region. At this stage, I am agnostic about the nature and direction of any

such effect. Again, data on regional membership is taken from Hadenius and Teorell (2005).

Method

Multiple estimation approaches are adopted as the nature of the dependent variable varies. The

combined general index of flexibility in investment treatment provisions is a continuous variable

and therefore is evaluated using standard OLS estimation. The individual measure of national

treatment is a three point ordinal scale and is analyzed using a generalized ordered logit/partial

proportional odds estimation technique (Fu 1998, Williams 2006). The generalized ordered logit

is preferred because in this instance, as is often the case, the model violates the parallel lines, or

proportional odds, assumption that is necessary when using ordered logit estimation. However,

not all variables in the model, including the primary independent variable of interest, regime type,

violate this assumption. Therefore, a partial proportional odds model is fitted that employs a

parallel lines constraint on those variables that do not violate the assumption but does not do so on

those variables that do. For the variables that do not violate the assumption, the model estimates

a single coefficient for comparisons between all outcomes. Finally, the dummy tax policy constraint

measure is analyzed using a standard logit estimator.

In all cases, standard errors are corrected for clustering on the home state. There are two reasons

to cluster on the home state. Firstly, there are approximately one third as many home states as

there are host states in the sample suggesting a greater potential for correlation of standard errors.

Secondly, the most active BIT signing home states often have a model BIT on which they endeavor

to base their investment treaties. By working from the same model, there is an increased likelihood

of correlation of errors for BITs concluded by the same home state.

22

Results

Table 5 presents the results for the general index of policy flexibility/constraint which pools together

measures for all four types of treaty provision. The results do not offer support for the first

hypothesis as while the relationship between host state regime type and the general index of policy

flexibility is statistically significant at the 0.05 level, higher levels of host state democracy are

positively correlated with policy flexibility. This suggests that bits in which the host state is more

democratic, are more likely to have a higher general level of policy constraints. Such a result may

be cause for pessimism because it is precisely those governments which are already constrained

domestically that submit to tighter BIT constraints. Thus, BITs most constrain host governments

when such constraints are least needed.

A more positive conclusion regarding the effect of BITs can be drawn if one considers the

marginal effect of BITs on states’ capacities to credibly commit. The commitment challenge is

greater for unconstrained autocrats and thus BITs, even though they establish moderately weaker

constraints on policy for autocratic leaders, still represent a marked increase in policy constraint

for autocrats. Viewed in this light, it is not surprising that democratic governments sign more

constraining BITs as they are already more constrained and better equipped to make credible

commitments to foreign investors. Thus democratic host states, and home states seeking enhanced

commitment from democratic hosts, would design more constraining BIT provisions. Otherwise

the marginal effect of the BIT on the host state’s commitment capacity would be minimal, and the

purpose of the BIT unclear.

With respect to other variables in the model, host state regime durability is statistically signif-

icant in the direction that we would expect (i.e. older host state regimes negotiate more flexibility

into their treaties). Meanwhile, the home state’s FDI outflows, which is one indicator of home state

bargaining leverage is statistically significant at the 0.1 level and, as expected, a higher level of FDI

outflows is correlated with a higher degree of policy constraint.

The result for host state regime type presented in the model of the general index of flexibility

is mirrored in the model of national treatment (table 6). Once again as the level of host state

autocracy decreases and the level of democracy increases, the probability that a BIT will contain

23

Table 5: OLS Model of Combined General Measure of Policy Flexibility/ConstraintCovariate Estimate p-valuePolity (Host State) -0.035 0.045

(0.017)Polity (Home State) 0.014 0.795

(0.055)Regime Durability (Host) 0.019 0.004

(0.006)Wealth Ratio -0.011 0.986

(0.610)LG(GDPpc) (Host) 0.138 0.508

(0.206)LG(GDPpc) (Home) 0.616 0.353

(0.657)FDI Outflows/GDP (Home State) -0.084 0.071

(0.045)Alliance -0.130 0.640

(0.276)Colony -0.360 0.541

(0.585)Dyadic Trade -0.000 0.233

(0.000)Regional BITs (5 yrs.) (Host) -0.002 0.102

(0.001)

R2 0.146N 241Standard errors are robust to clustering on the home state

24

more constraining national treatment provisions increases. Figure 2 illustrates this relationship

very clearly. The blue line illustrates the positive relationship between host state democracy and

the predicted probability that a BIT will contain national treatment provisions with no exceptions,

which is the lowest level of policy flexibility on the coding scale (see table 3). On the other hand the

predicted probability of a BIT allowing greater policy flexibility in the form of national treatment

provisions with exceptions or no national treatment guarantees at all is a decreasing function of

the level of democracy and an increasing function of the level of autocracy (see the red and green

lines in figure 2). This relationship is statistically significant at the 0.01 level and provides support

for the argument that autocratic regimes will seek to preserve flexibility of policies that facilitate

the provision of private goods to important supporters (H3) as exceptions to, and the absence

of, national treatment provide host states with an opening to privilege domestic firms and capital

vis-a-vis foreign investors.

The estimates presented in table 6 also show that the relationship between FDI outflows from

the home state and host state regime durability, and policy flexibility identified in the general index

model, holds in the national treatment model as the does the relationship between the number of

bits signed in the host state’s region in the past five years. As the number of bits signed in the

recent past in a host state’s region increases, the probability that a BIT to which that state is a

party, as a host state, will contain promises of national treatment without exceptions increases.

This suggests that host states do face diffusion pressures to sign BITs and are therefore potentially

more willing to accept greater constraints.

The results of the logit model of tax are quite different. All variables except the host state’s

regime type are insignificant (it is significant at the 0.1 level) but in this model the coefficient is

positive. This suggests that in matters relating to tax and fiscal policy, BITs in which the host

state is more democratic are more likely to exhibit a higher degree of policy flexibility (i.e. taxation

matters do not apply to one or more integral parts of the treaty). This relationship is represented

graphically in figure 3 and supports the argument that links democratic governments’ needs to

provide public goods to their preferences to build-in to BITs greater discretion and flexibility in

their use of tax and fiscal policy levers (H2).

25

Table 6: Generalized Ordinal Logit Model of National Treatment Policy ConstraintsComparison: NT Without Exceptions & All Others

Covariate Estimate p-value

Polity (Host State) -0.085 0.000(0.018)

Polity (Home State) 0.068 0.227(0.056)

Regime Durability (Host) 0.018 0.005(0.006)

Wealth Ratio -0.301 0.645(0.653)

LG(GDPpc) (Host) 0.136 0.568(0.238)

LG(GDPpc) (Home) 0.246 0.586(0.451)

FDI Outflows/GDP (Home State) -0.178 0.020(0.077)

Alliance 0.554 0.086(0.322)

Colony -0.056 0.917(0.541)

Dyadic Trade 0.000 0.305(0.000)

EU Candidate 0.421 0.701(1.095)

Regional BITs (5 yrs.) (Host) -0.004 0.001(0.001)

N 241Comparison: (NT With and Without Exceptions) & All OthersCovariate Estimate p-value

Polity (Host State) -0.085 0.000(0.018)

Polity (Home State) -0.043 0.181(0.064)

Regime Durability (Host) 0.018 0.005(0.006)

Wealth Ratio -1.403 0.018(0.594)

LG(GDPpc) (Host) 0.136 0.568(0.238)

LG(GDPpc) (Home) 0.246 0.586(0.451)

FDI Outflows/GDP (Home State) -0.098 0.254(0.086)

Alliance 0.554 0.086(0.322)

Colony -0.056 0.917(0.541)

Dyadic Trade -0.001 0.917(0.001)

EU Candidate 1.176 0.220(0.959)

Regional BITs (5 yrs.) (Host) -0.004 0.001(0.001)

N 241

26

Figure 2: Predicted Probability of a BIT Containing Greater Flexibility/Constraint in NationalTreatment Obligations

Figure 3: Predicted Probability of a BIT Containing Greater Flexibility for Tax/Fiscal Policy

27

Table 7: Logit Model of Tax/Fiscal Policy ConstraintsCovariate Estimate p-value

Polity (Host State) 0.036 0.064(0.020)

Polity (Home State) 0.061 0.284(0.057)

Regime Durability (Host) 0.010 0.298(0.010)

Wealth Ratio 1.452 0.063(0.780)

LG(GDPpc) (Host) 0.074 0.753(0.236)

LG(GDPpc) (Home) 0.797 0.219(0.657)

FDI Outflows/GDP (Home State) -0.150 0.118(0.096)

Alliance -0.303 0.421(0.376)

Colony -1.012 0.236(0.854)

Dyadic Trade -0.000 0.108(0.000)

EU Candidate -0.875 0.410(1.063)

Regional BITs (5 yrs.) (Host) 0.000 0.102(0.001)

N 241Standard errors are robust to clustering on the home state

28

Conclusion and Extensions

This paper presents a first cut at explaining important variations in the design of functionally similar

institutions. Several arguments linking domestic political institutions and leaders’ preferences over

the level of policy flexibility in international institutions are used to explain why the level of policy

flexibility and constraint that BITs establish differs across treaties. These arguments were then

tested using an original data set of hand coded BIT provisions from a sample of over 300 BITs.

The empirical results suggest that BITs are commitment enhancing devices rather than anti-

dotes to commitment challenges. BITs in which the host state is autocratic are less likely to highly

constrain the host states policy autonomy. Thus, while BITs represent a marginal increase on a

host state’s ability to keep commitments (as indicated by the propensity for dyads with democratic

host states to sign more constraining BITs), they are not a perfect remedy to governments whose

domestic institutions make credible commitments difficult. As home states seek to maximize the

level of constraint in BITs, this greater flexibility found in BITs with autocratic host states must

be a product of the preferences of the host state.

Indeed, one line of argument presented in this paper is that host states do seek some degree

of policy flexibility. However, when we disaggregate our pooled measure of policy flexibility, we

find that domestic institutions determine which pockets of government policy governments prefer

to remain flexible in BITs. Autocratic states seek to preserve flexibility in policies (i.e. national

treatment) that allow them to furnish their supporters with private goods while democratic leaders

seek flexibility in policies that promote public goods provision (i.e. taxation).

There are several future directions in which the analysis presented here may be extended. The

first is to evaluate how the decision to sign a BIT and the design of a BIT relate. Methodologically,

this means looking at selection effects and modeling both BIT signing and BIT design together.

The second is two delve deeper into the role of regime type. The distinction between autocracy

and democracy masks an array of institutionally different systems of government (e.g. Wright 2008)

that may shape leaders’ international institutional design preferences in different ways.

29

References

Abbott, Kenneth W. & Duncan Snidal. 2000. “Hard and Soft Law in International Governance.”International Organization 54(3):421–456.

Aitken, Brian J. & Ann E. Harrison. 1999. “Do Domestic Firms Benefit from Direct ForeignInvestment? Evidence from Venezuela.” American Economic Review 89(3):605–618.

Allee, Todd & Clint Peinhardt. 2008a. “Contingent Credibility: The Reputational Effects of In-vestment Treaty Disputes on Foreign Direct Investment.” Paper Presented at the Annual Con-vention of the American Political Science Association, Boston, August 28-31, 2008 .

Allee, Todd & Clint Peinhardt. 2008b. “Not the Least BIT Rational: An Empirical Test of the”Rational Design” of Investment Treaties.” Paper Presented at the First Conference on thePolitical Economy of International Organizations, Monte Verita, Switzerland, 3 - 8 February2008 .

Barbieri, Katherine, Omar Keshk & Brian Pollins. 2008. “Correlates of War Project Trade DataSet Codebook, Version 2.0.”.

Bernhard, William & David Leblang. 1999. “Democratic Institutions and Exchange-Rate Commit-ments.” International Organization 53(1):71–97.

Buthe, Tim & Helen V. Milner. 2005. “The Politics of Foreign Direct Investment into DevelopingCountries: Increasing FDI through Policy Commitment via Trade Agreements and InvestmentTreaties?” Working Paper.

Cowhey, Peter F. 1993. “Domestic institutions and the credibility of international commitments:Japan and the United States.” International Organization pp. 299–327.

Dai, Xinyuan. 2005. “Why Comply? The Domestic Constituency Mechanism.” International Or-ganization 59(2):363–398.

de Mesquita, Bruce Bueno, Alastair Smith, Randolph Siverson & James D. Morrow. 2003. TheLogic of Political Survival. Cambridge: MIT Press.

Elkins, Zachary, Andrew T. Guzman & Beth A. Simmons. 2006. “Competing for Capital: TheDiffusion of Bilateral Investment Treaties, 1960-2000.” International Organization 60:811–846.

Fearon, James D. 1994. “Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Dis-putes.” American Political Science Review 88(3):577–592.

Fu, Vincent. 1998. “Estimating Generalized Ordinal Logit Models.” Stata Technical Bulletin 44:27–30.

Gartzke, Erik & Kristian Skrede Gleditsch. 2004. “Why Democracies May Actually Be Less ReliableAllies.” American Journal of Political Science 48(4):775–795.

Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede. 2002. “Expanded Trade and GDP data.” Journal of Conflict Resolution46(5):712–724.

30

Gorg, Holger & David Greenaway. 2003. “Much Ado About Nothing? Do Domestic Firms ReallyBenefit from Foreign Direct Investment?” Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA) DiscussionPaper (944).

Gowa, Joanne. 1988. “Public Goods and Political Institutions: Trade and Monetary Policy Pro-cesses in the United States.” International Organization 42(1):15–32.

Graham, Edward M. & Paul R. Krugman. 1991. Foreign Direct Investment in the United States.2nd ed. Washington: Institute for International Economics.

Grossman, Gene M. & Elhanan E. Helpman. 1994. “Protection for Sale.” American EconomicReview 84(4):833–850.

Guzman, Andrew T. 1998. “Why LDCs Sign Treaties That Hurt Them: Explaining the Popularityof Bilateral Investment Treaties.” Virginia Journal of International Law 38:639–688.

Hanson, Gordon H. 2001. “Should Countries Promote Foreign Direct Investment.” G-24 DiscussionPapers (9).

Hasenclever, Andreas, Peter Mayer & Volker Rittberger. 1997. Theories of International Regimes.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Henisz, Witold J. 2000. “The Institutional Environment for Multinational Investment.” Journal ofLaw, Economics and Organization 12(1):1–31.

Jensen, Nathan M. 2003. “Democratic Governance and Multinational Corporations: PoliticalRegimes and Inflows of Foreign Direct Investment.” American Journal of Political Science57:587–616.

Jodice, D.A. 1980. “Sources of Change in Third World Regimes for Foreign Direct Investment1968-1976.” International Organization 34(2):177–206.

Kahler, Miles. 2000. “Conclusion: The Causes and Consequences of Legalization.” InternationalOrganization 54(3):661–683.

Kahler, Miles. 2002. Bretton Woods and Its Competitors: The Political Economy of InstitutionalChoice. In Monetary Institutions, Financial Integration, and Political Authority, ed. David M.Andrews, C. Randall Henning & Louis W. Pauly. Ithaca: Cornell University Press pp. 38–58.

Keohane, Robert O. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Econ-omy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Kobrin, Stephen J. 1984. “Expropriation as an Attempt to Control Foreign Firms in LDCs: Trendsfrom 1960 to 1979.” International Studies Quarterly 28(3):329–348.

Kobrin, Stephen J. 1998. “The MAI and the Clash of Globalizations.” Foreign Policy 112:97–109.

Leeds, Brett Ashley. 1999. “Domestic Political Institutions, Credible Commitments, and Interna-tional Cooperation.” American Journal of Political Science 43(4):979–1002.

Leeds, Brett Ashley. 2005. “Alliance Treaty Obligations and Provisions (ATOP) Codebook.” Ver-sion 3.0.

31

Li, Quan & Adam Resnick. 2003. “Reversal of Fortunes: Democratic Institutions and ForeignDirect Investment Flows in Developing Countries.” International Organization 57:175–211.

Lohmann, Susanne & Sharyn O’Halloran. 1994. “Divided Government and U.S. Trade Policy:Theory and Evidence.” International Organization 48(4):595–632.

Maggi, Giovanni & Andrew Rodriguez-Clare. 1998. “The Value of Trade Agreements in the Presenceof Political Pressures.” Journal of Political Economy 106(3).

Mansfield, Edward D., Helen V. Milner & B. Peter Rosendorff. 2000. “Free to Trade: Democracies,Autocracies, and International Trade.” American Political Science Review 94(2):305–321.

Mansfield, Edward D., Helen V. Milner & B. Peter Rosendorff. 2002. “Why Democracies CooperateMore: Electoral Control and International Trade Agreements.” International Organization56(3):477–513.

Mansfield, Edward D., Helen V. Milner & Jon C. Pevehouse. 2007. “Vetoing Co-operation: The Im-pact of Veto Players on Preferential Trading Agreements.” British Journal of Political Science37:403–432.

Markusen, James R. & Anthony J. Venables. 1999. “Foreign Direct Investment as a Catalyst forIndustrial Development.” European Economic Review 43:335–356.

Marshall, Monte & Keith Jaggers. 2006. Polity IV Project Dataset v.2006. Arlington: GeorgeMason University.

Martin, Lisa L. 1992. Coercive Cooperation: Explaining Multilateral Economic Sanctions. Prince-ton: Princeton University Press.

Martin, Lisa L. & Beth A. Simmons. 1998. “Theories and Empirical Studies of InternationalInstitutions.” International Organization 52(4):729–757.

McGillivray, Fiona. 1997. “Party Discipline as a Determinant of the Endogenous Formation ofTariffs.” American Journal of Political Science 41(2):584–607.

McGillivray, Fiona & Alastair Smith. 2004. “The Impact of Leadership Turnover on TradingRelations Between States.” International Organization 58:567–600.

Milner, Helen V. & Keiko Kubota. 2005. “Why The Move to Free Trade? Democracy and TradePolicy in the Developing Countries.” International Organization 59:107–143.

Moran, Theodore H. 1995. Multinational Corporations and the Developing Countries: An An-alytical Overview. In Multinational Corporations: The Political Economy of Foreign DirectInvestment, ed. Theodore H. Moran. Lexington: Lexington Books pp. 3–24.

Moran, Theodore H. 1999. Foreign Direct Investment and Development. Washington: Institute forInternational Economics.

Neumayer, Eric. 2006. “Self-Interest, Foreign Need and Good Governance: Are Bilateral InvestmentTreaties Similar to Foreign Aid Allocation.” Foreign Policy Analysis 2:245–67.

32

Neumayer, Eric & Laura Spess. 2005. “Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Increase Foreign DirectInvestment to Developing Countries?” World Development 33(10):1567–1585.

North, Douglass C. & Barry R. Weingast. 1989. “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution ofInstitutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England.” Journal of EconomicHistory 49(4):803–832.

Olson, Mancur. 1993. “Dictatorship, Democracy, and Development.” American Political ScienceReview 87(3):567–576.

Oye, Kenneth A. 1986. Explaining Cooperation Under Anarchy: Hypotheses and Strategies. InCooperation Under Anarchy, ed. Kenneth A. Oye. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Persson, Torsten & Guido Tabellini. 2000. Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy.Cambridge: MIT Press.

Peterson, Luke Eric. 2003a. “Czech Broadcasting Dispute Moving Towards Damages Award, Appealin a Swedish Court.” Investment Law and Sustainable Development Weekly News Bulletin, Feb21, 2003 .URL: http://www.investmenttreatynews.org/content/archives.aspx

Peterson, Luke Eric. 2003b. “Czech Republic Hit With Massive Compensation Bill in InvestmentTreaty Dispute.” Investment Law and Policy Weekly News Bulletin, March 21, 2003 .URL: http://www.investmenttreatynews.org/content/archives.aspx

Pevehouse, Jon C. & Renee Buhr. 2005. “Rules of Trade: Democracy and Legalism in Preferen-tial Trade Agreements.” Paper Presented at the 2005 American Political Science AssociationMeetings, Washington DC, September 1-5, 2005. .

Rosendorff, B. Peter & Helen V. Milner. 2001. “The Optimal Design of International Trade Insti-tutions: Uncertainty and Escape.” International Organization 55(4):829–857.

Snidal, Duncan & Alexander Thompson. 2003. International Commitments and Domestic Politics:Institutions and Actors at Two Levels. In Locating the Proper Authorities: The Interactionof Domestic and International Institutions, ed. Daniel Drezner. Ann Arbor: University ofMichigan Press.

Stasavage, David. 2002. “Private Investment and Political Institutions.” Economics and Politics14(1):41–63.

UNCTAD. 2007. Bilateral Investment Treaties 1995-2006: Trends in Investment Rulemaking.Geneva: United Nations.

UNCTAD. 2008. “Recent Development in International Investment Agreements (2007-June 2008).”United Nations International Investment Agreements [IIA] Monitor 2.

Vernon, Raymond. 1971. Sovereignty at Bay: The Multinational Spread of U.S. Enterprises. NewYork: Basic Books.

Williams, Richard. 2006. “Generalized Ordered Logit/Partial Proportional Odds Models for OrdinalDependent Variables.” The Stata Journal 6(1):58–82.

33

Wright, Joseph. 2008. “Do Authoritarian Institutions Constrain? How Legislatures Affect EconomicGrowth and Investment.” American Journal of Political Science 52(2):322–343.

Yackee, Jason Webb. 2007. Sacrificing Sovereignty: Bilateral Investment Treaties, InternationalArbitration and the Quest for Capital PhD thesis University of North Carolina Chapel Hill: .

Yarbrough, Beth & Robert Yarbrough. 1987. “Cooperation in the Liberalization of InternationalTrade: After Hegemony, What?” International Organization 41(1):1–26.

34