29
www.cerp.org.uk Copyright © 2011 AQA and its licensors. All rights reserved. The Assessment and Qualifications Alliance (AQA) is a company limited by guarantee registered in England and Wales (company number 3644723). Registered address: AQA, Devas Street, Manchester M15 6EX Centre for Education Research and Policy REGULATION AND THE QUALIFICATIONS MARKET 1INTRODUCTION The Apprenticeship, Skills, Children and Learning (ASCL) Act 2009 established Ofqual as the regulator of qualifications, examinations and tests in England. It commenced work as a fully independent non-ministerial government department on 1 April 2010, having operated in interim form as a distinct part of QCA for two years before that. This Act marked the latest in a long, but increasingly active, history of regulatory activity in the public examinations and qualifications industry in England. (Similar, largely parallel, activity had been going on in Wales and Northern Ireland, under their devolved jurisdictions. Although this paper will focus on England only, most of what is described is equally applicable to those parts of the United Kingdom. Scotland has a separate education system altogether. In addition, only regulation that applies to general qualifications will be the focus of this paper, although all qualifications, general, applied and vocational, are within Ofqual’s remit.) The purpose of this paper is to consider the implications of this latest regulatory activity from a theoretical perspective based on market economics, allied to an historical survey of regulatory practice over the past 150 years. The paper is in four main sections. After this introduction, Section 2 (“A theoretical framework from economics”) introduces the conceptual framework of economics, in which the qualifications industry is seen as an operational market. Part 1 of this section describes the metaphors used to describe qualifications and their uses, and how these metaphors form, as well as reflect, how educational qualifications are perceived, understood and managed. Part 2 then summarises four typical market models as a background to understanding the market context of the qualifications industry. Part 3 defines this context more closely, drawing particular attention to the external influences and constraints on it, from both the supply and demand sides. In that light, Section 3 (“Where have we been?”) is a survey of general qualifications provision in England since the mid 19 th century, indicating how the industry has evolved through different types of market context, and, latterly, how statutory intervention and regulation has increased. Part 1 describes the early years of public examining in England, rooted in the universities. Part 2 describes the post-war years as education provision and entitlement expanded rapidly as a result of the 1944 Education Act (Butler), and Part 3 describes the last twenty years since the reforming 1988 Education Act (Baker) which, inter alia, introduced the national curriculum. Section 4 (“Where are we now?”) describes the 2009 Education Act and its implications and aftermath, particularly the significant changes to regulatory powers it introduced and how, via various subsequent consultation exercises, it appears these are intended to be applied. Drawing on some of the information and issues raised explicitly or implicitly in the previous sections, Section 5 (“Where are we going? Regulation in a Market Context”) considers the issues facing Ofqual following the 2009 Act, and looks to the possible direction, nature and implications of future regulatory practice.

Download the full paper (660.04 KB)

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

www.cerp.org.uk Copyright © 2011 AQA and its licensors. All rights reserved.

The Assessment and Qualifications Alliance (AQA) is a company limited by guarantee registered in England and Wales (company number 3644723). Registered address: AQA, Devas Street, Manchester M15 6EX

Centre for Education Research and Policy

REGULATION AND THE QUALIFICATIONS MARKET

1 INTRODUCTION

The Apprenticeship, Skills, Children and Learning (ASCL) Act 2009 established Ofqual as theregulator of qualifications, examinations and tests in England. It commenced work as a fullyindependent non-ministerial government department on 1 April 2010, having operated in interimform as a distinct part of QCA for two years before that. This Act marked the latest in a long, butincreasingly active, history of regulatory activity in the public examinations and qualificationsindustry in England. (Similar, largely parallel, activity had been going on in Wales and NorthernIreland, under their devolved jurisdictions. Although this paper will focus on England only, mostof what is described is equally applicable to those parts of the United Kingdom. Scotland has aseparate education system altogether. In addition, only regulation that applies to generalqualifications will be the focus of this paper, although all qualifications, general, applied andvocational, are within Ofqual’s remit.) The purpose of this paper is to consider the implicationsof this latest regulatory activity from a theoretical perspective based on market economics, alliedto an historical survey of regulatory practice over the past 150 years.

The paper is in four main sections. After this introduction, Section 2 (“A theoretical frameworkfrom economics”) introduces the conceptual framework of economics, in which thequalifications industry is seen as an operational market. Part 1 of this section describes themetaphors used to describe qualifications and their uses, and how these metaphors form, aswell as reflect, how educational qualifications are perceived, understood and managed. Part 2then summarises four typical market models as a background to understanding the marketcontext of the qualifications industry. Part 3 defines this context more closely, drawing particularattention to the external influences and constraints on it, from both the supply and demandsides.

In that light, Section 3 (“Where have we been?”) is a survey of general qualifications provisionin England since the mid 19th century, indicating how the industry has evolved through differenttypes of market context, and, latterly, how statutory intervention and regulation has increased.Part 1 describes the early years of public examining in England, rooted in the universities. Part2 describes the post-war years as education provision and entitlement expanded rapidly as aresult of the 1944 Education Act (Butler), and Part 3 describes the last twenty years since thereforming 1988 Education Act (Baker) which, inter alia, introduced the national curriculum.

Section 4 (“Where are we now?”) describes the 2009 Education Act and its implications andaftermath, particularly the significant changes to regulatory powers it introduced and how, viavarious subsequent consultation exercises, it appears these are intended to be applied.

Drawing on some of the information and issues raised explicitly or implicitly in the previoussections, Section 5 (“Where are we going? Regulation in a Market Context”) considers theissues facing Ofqual following the 2009 Act, and looks to the possible direction, nature andimplications of future regulatory practice.

anagle
Typewritten Text
Ben Jones
anagle
Typewritten Text
anagle
Typewritten Text
anagle
Typewritten Text

Centre for Education Research and Policy

Finally, Section 6 comprises a conclusion, which particularly addresses the role andresponsibility of the regulator in guaranteeing standards – the economic currency – in what is anincreasingly free qualifications market.

2 A THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK FROM ECONOMICS

A) METAPHORS

In their book, “Metaphors We Live by”, Lakoff and Johnson (1980) argue that, rather than beingsimply a device of the poetic imagination, a characteristic of language alone, metaphors arepervasive in everyday life, in thought and action as well as in language. Thus:

“Our ordinary conceptual system, in terms of what we both think and act, is

fundamentally metaphorical in nature … If we are right in suggesting that our

conceptual system is largely metaphorical, then the way we think, what we experience,

and what we do every day is very much a matter of metaphor.” (p3, Lakoff andJohnson, 1980.).

In the same vein, Foucault (1981) argues:

“We must conceive of discourse as a violence which we do to things, or in any case as

a practice which we impose on them; and it is in this practice that the events of

discourse find the principle of their regularity.” (p67, emphasis added).

In short, metaphors not only describe our reality, but – via our conceptual framework – also formit. As an example of what it could mean for a concept to be metaphorical and to structure aneveryday activity they suggest the idea of “argument”, and the metaphor of “argument as war”,suggesting that this metaphor is reflected in our everyday language by a variety of expressions:

Your claims are indefensible. He attacked every weak point in my argument. His criticisms were right on target. I demolished his argument. If you use that strategy, he’ll wipe you out.

He shot down all of my arguments.

They then point out that we don’t just talk about arguments in terms of war; many of the thingswe do when arguing are partially structured by the concept of war. Thus we actually win or losearguments, we see the person with whom we are arguing as an opponent, there is a verbalbattle. “It is in this sense that the “argument as war” metaphor is one that we live by in this

culture” (p4, ibid). They go on to suggest that arguments could be seen in terms of othermetaphors, offering dancing as an example. In such a culture, arguments would be viewed,experienced and carried out differently: “Perhaps the most neutral way of describing this

difference … would be to say that we have a discourse form structured in terms of battle and

they have one structured in terms of dance” (p5, ibid).

By a similar token, the conceptual framework, of educational assessment and qualifications inthis country is now one of a market economy. Thus, as with the example of “argument as war”,the language of educational assessment is replete with various expressions which indicate a

2 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

“conceptual framework and dominant discourse form” structured in terms of “qualifications aseconomy”.

For example:

The GCE A level “gold standard”; The market for qualifications; currency of qualification grades; grade inflation; competition between awarding organisations; exchange rates between qualifications.

It could be informative to consider what alternative metaphors might be applied to the Englishqualifications system, and what an education culture that adopted this perspective wouldresemble.

The term “qualification” implies that the holder is in some sense qualified for something, or atleast has achieved a certain level or standard of attainment in a subject area. In this sense, thequalification has intrinsic worth. As will be seen, in the early days of public educationalqualifications, this view of qualifications prevailed: the assessment industry grew out ofcandidates’ meeting a particular university’s required matriculation standard - even though,paradoxically, the awarding mechanisms tended to be statistically referenced. Despite – orperhaps because of – failed attempts to define qualification outcomes in terms of gradeattainment criteria1, nowadays, the prevailing conceptual framework has made more debatablethe notion of a qualification outcome indicating a certain level or standard of attainment in asubject area, and thus having intrinsic worth. Rather, a qualification is seen more as a unit ofcurrency, whose value is determined in terms of exchange, and supply and demand factors ona free and open (or often not so free and open, see later) market, as by intrinsic worth. As in thereal economy, the qualifications market no longer operates according to a “gold standard”, if itever did.

A consequence of this conceptual framework is that the focus of those employed in the variousbranches of education tends to be on educational qualifications (as currency), and less oneducational attainment in general, and education - in a broader sense - in particular. This issimilar to the focus on the financial markets which, of themselves, do not produce any wealth,although their operations purportedly ensure the efficient working of the markets in the “realeconomy”. Education has come to be seen as a commodity whose value is measured in thecurrency of qualifications. Thus people talk of “getting a good education” (note the acquisitiveverb), meaning being awarded qualifications which carry value in the education/employmentmarket place. Again, whether those qualifications describe anything of intrinsic educationalvalue may be a secondary concern to what they are worth in the market place. As we shall see,it is not only candidates who, to some extent at least, act as “economic men/women” in thequalifications market place; schools and colleges too – in the light of performance tables – also“play the market” to their advantage, regardless of wider educational concerns.

1 For example, in the early stages of the national curriculum, a primary school teacher could have beenrequired to judge pupils against a total of 1,000 national curriculum “statements of attainment” in a singleyear.

3 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

It is not the purpose of this paper to undertake a wider debate about the beneficial ordetrimental effects on education of the “qualifications as currency” conceptual framework, muchless what education is for. Many have done this, for example, Postman (1996) in his deliberatelyambiguously entitled, The End of Education: Redefining the Value of School. In it, he states:“But what [these questions] have in common is that they evade the issue of what schools are

for. It is as if we are a nation of technicians, consumed by our expertise in how something

should be done, afraid or incapable of thinking about why” (p.x). To a large extent that issuehinges on how education is perceived and what values underpin that perception. For example,is education primarily the fuel to run the engine of the real (knowledge?) economy efficiently andproduce growth, or does it have some other, less utilitarian purpose? The former approach isserved by the use of targets, performance tables etc., and in this respect the words of RobertMcNamara, the US Secretary of Defence in the 1960s, are salutary. Drawing on his successfulintroduction of production targets as CEO of the Ford Motor company, he applied a similarapproach to the bombing campaigns in the Vietnam war, with disastrous consequences. Laterin life, he famously confessed: “We set out to measure what was important, but ended up

making important what was measureable”. (The Fog of War: Eleven Lessons from the Life ofRobert S. McNamara. 2003 Film.).

B) MARKET TYPES

To sharpen the focus of this economic framework it would be helpful to consider some marketconcepts and models which underpin classical economic theory; the extent to which aspects ofeach model apply (or do not apply) to the current qualifications market should be apparent.When considering markets, economists are primarily interested in issues of the price andquantity of production of a good/service (via the operation of the price mechanism), and howthese are affected by - and come to a position of equilibrium in - particular market conditionsand structures. Although these are pertinent to suppliers in a qualifications market, other,secondary issues, which will also be identified, are also important.

Economists define a market as anywhere “where buyers and sellers are brought together and

negotiate the exchange of a well-defined commodity” (via the operation of the pricemechanism). (p69, Lipsey, 2). A market is said to be “free” to the extent to which there is nointervention and regulation by the state, except to enforce private contracts and the ownershipof property. To the extent to which a market is “controlled”, on the other hand, the state directlyregulates the use, prices, resources or distribution of goods and services. A free market hassome important features and underpinning assumptions associated with it which allow the pricemechanism to function:

private ownership of property; the market is responsive to the collective decisions of buyers/sellers, such that prices,

resource allocation and the distribution of goods/services are not consciously coordinatedby anyone;

sellers are free to enter and leave the market, and aim to maximize profits and produceaccordingly.

Within this broad context of a free market, economists typically identify four “ideal types” ofmarket (or “market forms”): Perfect Competition; Monopolistic Competition; Oligopoly andMonopoly. The characteristics of each are described in more detail in Appendix A, but aresummarised in Table 1; each model assumes many buyers, but not always many sellers.

4 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

TABLE 1. SUMMARY OF TYPES OF MARKET

Marketcompetition type

Number ofsellers

Ease ofmarket

entry/exit

Homo/heterogeneity ofsellers’ goods

Seller’s controlover price

Examples

Perfect Many Easy Homogeneous None Internet

Monopolistic Few to many Quitedifficult

Seemingly hetero, but maybe quite homogeneous

Some Fast-foodrestaurant

Oligopoly Very few Difficult Either Some Car companies

Monopoly No directcompetition

Difficult No directly competingproducts

Considerable(but little

if regulated)

Powercompany

The features of the market in which the general qualifications awarding bodies operate are thusvarious, but are generally a mixture of monopolistic (i.e. very similar products, potentiallydifferentiated by non-price considerations) and particularly oligopolistic (few, large suppliers,high barriers to entry with the product being homo- or heterogeneous). Of course, these modelsdo not so much describe in detail the actual operations of the qualifications market in thiscountry, but they do provide a theoretical framework in which to consider the role and purposeof the regulator.

When an imperfection arises in a market or industry, classical economists tend to identify thesolution as being found in a freer market (i.e. aiding a movement towards the features of perfectcompetition, often by encouraging more sellers) - i.e. de-regulation - rather than seeking asolution via increased regulatory intervention.2 They point to the advantages of perfectcompetition in ensuring an optimal allocation of resources, efficiency of industry, low prices andconsumer sovereignty, i.e. a change in demand leading to a change in supply, often using theterm “the invisible hand”, to describe the beneficial self-regulating nature of the marketplace.The term was first coined by the economist Adam Smith in The Theory of Moral Sentiments(1759) to describe the conjunction of the forces of self-interest,3 competition, and supply anddemand, which he noted as being capable of allocating resources in society. It is the foundingjustification for the laissez-faire economic philosophy.

The perfect market does, however, also embody disadvantages even in its pure, theoreticalform. Thus it can produce insufficient profits for investment and a lack of product variety. Not alleconomists agree that all market problems are best solved by a deregulated market. In themiddle of last century, for example, one eminent economist, Joseph Schumpeter (1950) arguedthat the beneficial effects of innovations and lower costs of production resulting from animperfect (monopolistic or oligopolistic) market have a larger effect on output per head andeconomic growth than any detrimental effects of misallocated resources. Empirical evidencecollected since his writings have tended to support his theory. He also argued that innovation isfunctionally related to market forms such that more innovation is likely under a monopoly and

2 A recent, significant example is the Independent Commission on Banking’s Interim Report (April 2011)on the recent banking crisis, a dominant theme of which is the need rapidly to increase competition in thissector.3 “It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer or the baker, that we expect our dinner, butfrom their regard to their own self interest. We address ourselves, not to their humanity but to theirself-love, and never talk to them of our own necessities but of their advantages.” Smith, A. (1776) AnInquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.

5 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

oligopoly than under perfect or even monopolistic competition, as they provided a moreconducive climate for the (necessary) risks of innovation to be taken.

Finally, some would argue that some sectors of the economy (e.g. public utilities) are notconducive to competition because it would leave potential economies of scale unexploited.Lipsey describes this scenario as follows:

“Such industries are regarded as “natural monopolies” since competition among many

suppliers would be unstable and quickly give way to oligopoly or monopoly. The

advantage of having one or a few large firms producing at a lower cost than could be

achieved by many small firms is evident but, in order to prevent monopolistic

exploitation, the policy advice was that the central authorities should regulate prices in

such a way that the industry would only earn the normal rate of return on its capital.

Thus costs would be lowered by the monopolization, but the price would be held to its

competitive level by the State’s intervention. … Many countries exercise a great deal of

this sort of regulation of naturally monopolistic industries particularly in the case of

public utilities such as gas, electricity, transportation and communications.” (p300,Lipsey, 1963).

This brief analysis suggests a continuum of viewpoints of how markets should operate. At oneextreme is the laissez faire position which argues that markets tend to self-regulate, produce theoptimum allocation of scarce resources and drive down prices, and that any external regulationor intervention is counter-productive. At the other extreme is what might be called theinterventionist position, which views a free market as inherently unstable, and thus risky, andfavours external regulation and intervention to control it, and plan and manage the desiredoutcomes. Few people are found at either extreme; most harbour a mixture of each viewpoint,an issue which will be revisited later.

C) THE QUALIFICATIONS MARKETS

Although reference is often made of “the qualifications market place”, there are, in fact, twodistinct, albeit closely linked, markets in the qualifications industry (each with several sub-markets or segments according to, for example, subject or qualification type).

In the first market the sellers are awarding organisations and the buyers are students, althoughschools and colleges typically act as buyers on behalf of their candidates. The amount ofconsumer influence exerted by individual students depends on the level of examination – atGCE, for example, they tend to have greater influence on subject choice than they do at GCSE.The currency in this market is the legal tender: pounds sterling. But what is it that awardingorganisations are selling when candidates (via their centres) submit their fees? Formally, it isneither a good nor a service but the opportunity or entitlement to be assessed and consideredfor a grade award in a given qualification. It is not - presumably! - a market in certificates orgrades per se, but in the right to be awarded one.4 In one sense, it is analogous to buying araffle ticket; the ticket does not give you a right to a given prize but it does give you the right tobe considered for a prize of some sort. The analogy is not complete, of course, in that one’sreward in a raffle is determined purely by chance, whereas in this qualification market it is (or

4 A parallel situation obtains in the inspection and testing services industry, run by companies such asSGS, Intertek Plc, and Bureau Veritas, which compete to issue certificates of compliance with ISOstandards. They also have had to resolve the contradiction between selling (where the buyer is supposedto have the power) and being an authority (where the provider grants, or does not grant, certification).

6 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

should be) determined on merit, although there is much research (for example Raffe et al

(2006)) that it is heavily influenced by “life chances”: for example birth, health and type ofschooling but not, presumably, the awarding organisation of entry.The second market also deals in opportunity or entitlement, but for entry into a course offurther or higher education or into a contract of employment. It is to this market that themetaphors of the “qualifications market place” generally refer. The sellers in this market are,therefore, colleges/universities and employers, and the buyers are, once again, students. Thecurrency of this market comprises the grades achieved by students, and the market is becomingincreasingly nuanced in its demands of, and sensitive to, grades from particular subjects.

The two markets are clearly intimately connected, not least in that the final outcomes of the firstmarket become the currency of the second. In the interests of both fairness and efficient marketfunctioning, therefore, students need confidence that the value of the currency with which theyhope to be rewarded as a result of their activity in the former market enables them to make theirdesired purchases in the latter.

It is, of course, the former market which is subject to regulation and so will be the main focus ofthis paper, although, as will be argued, regulation - in its broadest sense - has a significantimpact on the second market too. Before proceeding, it is therefore worth briefly applying theclaims of two extreme market models to the former market: a totally deregulated market (perfectcompetition) and a state regulated monopolistic market.

The free marketeer would claim that the current market is too distorted and constrained, and inneed of liberating in many ways and for many reasons, apart from economic efficiency. S/hewould argue that not only is a free market desirable in that it disseminates economic power,spreads risk, welcomes new sellers, improves efficiency, increases competition, drives downprices, promotes innovation, incentivises responsive service and support, but crucially that it is aself-regulatory mechanism. On the basis that “you can’t buck the market”, the free marketeerwill argue that it is always best in the long run to work with the powerful forces of the market,rather than try to combat or overly constrain them5. They will eventually bring the market into anew equilibrium; whilst it is tempting to intervene and to regulate and control matters, this willonly make matters worse in the long run. Thus, for example, if sellers charge too high fees oroffer insufficient support or make awards which are out of line, they will lose custom, in the lattercase either by “pricing” their grades out of the market if they are to severe, or by irreparablydamaging their reputation if they are too lenient such that their grade currency will becomedevalued in the marketplace and potential buyers will steer clear of it. Moreover, in the secondmarket, the value of qualifications and their grades would not be imposed arbitrarily andexternally but be decided by the interaction of impersonal market forces. To some degree thisalready happens with respect to the values assigned to the same grades in different subjects.There is much discussion and analysis about whether 'Your chemistry equals my French'(Wood, 1976), but ultimately the market (buyers) will decide what equals what and compensateaccordingly. As Wolf (2003) argued, “We currently maintain the polite fiction that all A levels are

equivalent (and so a given grade gets the same UCAS points whatever the subject.) No-one

believes this, but it doesn’t matter because offers for most degrees are tied to specific grades in

specific subjects.” Free marketeers would argue that these polite fictions are inimical to the freeand efficient working of the market, and that to the extent that candidates may or do believe

5 The phrase, “You cannot buck the market”, was made famous by Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher whenaddressing the House of Commons in 1989 as Britain, after two years shadowing the Deutsche Mark,prepared for its ill-timed and ill-judged, brief membership of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism(ERM).

7 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

them, they adversely affect candidates’ subject choices. Moreover, they are suspicious ofstatutory intervention to solve these problems. In his commentary on Tattersall’s (2007) chapteron regulation, Kingdon - not necessarily a free marketer - argued, “Readers may assume that

ever-tighter regulation will have produced increasing levels of comparability but this argument

has yet to be demonstrated” (p93).

The monopolist would, on the other hand, argue for a state, or heavily regulated, monopoly inorder to eliminate many of the supply side discrepancies and misalignments, not least byrendering obsolete debates about inter-awarding organisation standards and the allegationsthat awarding organisations compete in a “race to the bottom” in pursuit of more entries. Thisallegation is regularly made, from the notorious Channel 4 Despatches programme in 1995 to,more recently, the claim by Mick Walters (former director of curriculum at the QCA), whoclaimed that “the system is diseased, almost corrupt. We've got a set of awarding bodies who

are in a market place”. In the same book, the author, John Bangs (2010), former head ofeducation at the National Union of teachers, opined that, "I personally think there should just be

a single examination board." In a culture of rising importance of examination grades - forcandidates, their teachers, subject departments, schools, governments – the argument for asingle awarding body on these grounds is increasingly being heard. Additionally, a singleprovider would be able to capitalise on economies of scale, eliminate wasteful duplication,would require less market knowledge by the buyers, and should be able to provide a central,and more streamlined and straightforward, administrative service to candidates and centres.The monopolist would also point to the existence and successful operation of manymonopolistic assessment organisations - state and independent (the closest to home being theScottish Qualifications Authority) – which apply this model with no obvious disadvantages.

Market distortions

The above brief descriptions paint a somewhat simplistic picture of how the markets operate inpractice. Implicitly it has been assumed, for example, that a perfect competition model hasmany sellers (awarding bodies/universities/employers) meeting many buyers (students), theactors on each side freely interacting with those on the other, and making autonomous choicesto pursue their own best personal interests. (This has echoes of Adam Smith’s “invisible hand”,see earlier.)

In reality, however, the actors operate in markets heavily affected by influences and constraints.Some of these are intrinsic to, and some external to, the market; some are explicit, many arecovert; some are statutory, others organisational; some are direct, others less so. Some could,perhaps, be defined as “regulation by stealth”. All, however, arguably inhibit the freedom withwhich the actors operate, and thus – from a free marketeer’s perspective - the efficient workingof the market itself, and are inimical to both buyers’ and sellers’ best interests.

All markets comprise demand and supply sides. As qualifications suppliers in the first market,awarding organisations are primarily interested in supply-side factors and the regulation andconstraints operating there. However, it is important also to recognise the constraints whichoperate on demand side of the market too. Most of these influences are in the form ofequivalences and values assigned to grades by powerful external players (government,regulator, universities) which influence market demand.

8 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

Some examples of these:

The requirements embodied in DfE school and college Performance (“League”) Tables. (Forexample, the IGCSE used not to count in these tables, now it does; this will influencemarket activity6.)

The introduction of the English baccalaureate in 2010 will undoubtedly create more demandfor those subjects included in it.

The external assignation of UCAS points to grades. Perceived, or actual, ease of certification, especially between awarding bodies for the same

qualification. Price and available income; the current economic climate and public sector cuts, for

example, are likely to affect market activity.

Newton (2007) cites some twenty two uses to which qualification outcomes are put, mainly foraccountability purposes which are thus demand-side influences. Each of these, intentionally orunintentionally, imposes value and equivalence by fiat and will, to a lesser or greater degree,influence actors’ behaviour in the market place. Of course, it could be argued that at least someof these “distorting factors” are put in place to correct the implicit values assigned to grades bythe awarding bodies. To the extent that these are awry is largely why constraints on the supplyside of the equation are introduced.

It is thus primarily on the supply side of the market that the new legislation and regulatoryrequirements are focused. Indeed, making the regulator a truly independent body in itselfrepresents a move away from a demand-side player (government) to a more supply-side focus.

The following history of regulation clearly demonstrates an increasing and accelerating,intervention by the regulator into the supply side of the market, determining how and, to someextent, at what price, the product should be produced and sold. For example, as recently as1997 the government, in its consultation document on the structure of awarding bodies,Guaranteeing Standards, toyed with the possibility of having a single awarding body (as existsin so many jurisdictions worldwide) but eschewed the idea. (Interestingly, only 7 per cent ofresponses to the consultation supported the introduction of a single awarding body for theUnited Kingdom.) Nevertheless, the number of awarding bodies (three in England7) is thesmallest ever, and far fewer than even twenty years ago.

Another supply side factor is the National Qualifications Framework (NQF) and theQualifications and Credit Framework (QCF) which respectively provide a structure within whichthe level of a qualification (its difficulty) can be identified, and within which learners’achievements can be represented and recorded. The latter provides for a common approach toidentifying not only levels, as in the NQF, but also volumes of learner achievement, allowing forthe transferability of credit.

6 More famously (or notoriously) was the case of Thomas Telford school in 2002 which topped theGuardian's league table of top comprehensives at GCSE for the third year running, all its pupils beingawarded the equivalent of five Cs or better at GCSE. However, as the Guardian itself somewhat knowinglyacknowledged, “Some have criticised the weighting given to the ICT GNVQ, which is regarded for leaguetable purposes as equivalent to four Cs at GCSE.” The Guardian, 23 August 20027 Strictly speaking there are now more than three with other awarding organisations, e.g. The InternationalCurriculum and Assessment Agency (ICAA), offering GCSEs in specific subjects on a small scale.

9 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

Similarly, the general and subject specific criteria with which GCSE and GCE specificationshave to comply substantially affect the supply side of the market, as does the statutory Code ofPractice which stipulates detailed requirements for all aspects and stages of the examiningprocess, from syllabus design to awarding. Other supply-side factors include production costse.g. small entry subjects, and the quality of administrative and educational service and supportto centres.

Which factors are the proper areas for regulatory intervention, and which should be left to thefree market is the essence of much debate about regulatory powers overseeing educationalassessment. The question facing all regulators is what is the appropriate position to take? Thisquestion will be returned to later, but first a brief survey is made of the history of publicexamination provision in England over the last century and a half, with particular emphasis onhow the market has operated and how the regulatory function has developed.

3. WHERE HAVE WE BEEN?

The history of the past 150 years of public examinations, and their regulation, has generallybeen characterised as a progressive march towards increased external, state regulation, asexemplified in the following diagram:

from … to …decentralisation centralisationopen entry into the market restrictions to market entryfreedom of provision tight criterialack of external regulation heavy external, state regulationseveral suppliers few suppliersbreadth of choice uniformity; fewer distinct specifications

Charting this progression is both interesting and instructive. Viewed from a contemporaryperspective, this history can, perhaps, provide some useful pointers about the best wayforward.8

A) EARLY DAYS

Public examining has its roots in the mid 19th century with individual universities setting theirown matriculation examinations and conditions of entry – initially London (1838), closelyfollowed by Oxford, Cambridge and Durham, and later the newer universities, for example,Manchester, Leeds, Liverpool and Bristol. A consequence of this independent provision wasthat candidates needed to take several examinations depending on which university(ies) theyapplied for.

Although the 1868 Schools Inquiry (Taunton) Commission had recommended a centralexaminations authority - regionally administered - to govern the embryonic examination system,and prevent such duplication, its proposal was ignored and, by the time the Bryce Commission(1894) had successfully recommended the establishment of a Board of Education (1899), theolder universities had become too well established as examination boards to be replaced.

8 I am indebted to several excellent histories of the examining of general qualifications, notably those of

Steinberg (2002) and Tattersall (2000, 2003), which are drawn on particularly.

10 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

However, the effect of this duplication on students, the comparability of standards, and the(limited) currency of the certificates concerned head teachers, causing them in 1904 to lobby fora codification of examinations and a system in which certificates would have widespreadacceptance.

As an example of unnecessary duplication, in its 1911 report on its investigation intoexaminations, the Board of Education’s Consultative Committee on Examinations noted that …

“… of the twenty-nine candidates who entered for Bedford College scholarships in

1909, eight had already taken three public examinations, eight had taken four, three

had taken five, two had taken six and one had taken seven examinations” (p65, Petch,1953)

… and recommended the establishment of a two tier system of school examinations. So it wasthat, in 1917, the School Certificate (SC) and Higher School Certificate (HSC) were launched bythe Board of Education as measures of general attainment. Certification was subject todemonstrating attainment across a group of subjects (see Appendix B) – the SC bearing a fairlyclose resemblance to the new English GCSE baccalaureate. Although intended to replace theuniversities’ customised entrance examinations, in reality the HSC was accepted only as abasic standard for matriculation, with universities continuing to specify their own entryrequirements.

The eight university examination boards were invited by the Board of Education to become‘approved’ providers who would set, mark and certificate this new examination, under thecentral coordinating authority of the Board’s newly formed (1917) Secondary SchoolsExamination Council (SSEC). The Board had intended that the SSEC would “… lay down

regulations as to the scope, time, method [of examinations] ... control their organisation, fix the

fees to be charged for admission to them, and approve the examiners ... No external

examinations would be permitted except those held under [its] authority … and [the SSEC]

would bring order to the present confusion. It would replace a multiplicity of standards by unity

of control.” (p46, Steinberg, 2002).

Although this appears to be an early example of the statutory accreditation and regulation ofawarding bodies, the SSEC’s role was merely to oversee the examinations (not syllabuscontent), ensuring there was ‘reasonable’ equivalence in the demands of the constituentsubjects of each certificate, and in the examination standards of the examining boards.‘Reasonable’ was not defined, nor did the SSEC have the powers to enforce an interpretationon, or regulate the activities of, the examining boards, which remained under the control of theautonomous universities. By adopting this solution, the Consultative Committee thereforeeffectively reinforced the universities’ oligopoly of provision (which would obtain until 1953,when the AEB became a player) and established general (academic), external examinations asthe main mode of assessment. Nevertheless, even the SSEC’s coordinating function was asmall step towards central regulation and control, although the system was more characterisedby self, as opposed to external, regulation.

A long period of organisational stability during the inter-war years ensued, accompanied by asteady rise in entries resulting from a broadening of access to secondary education. However,although schooling opportunities expanded, a common school leaving age of 14 ensured entriesfor public examinations remained relatively modest. There were, however, severalforward-thinking commissions and committees (e.g. Hadow (1926), Spens (1938)) few of whose

11 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

recommendations were implemented. Hadow, for example, recommended a system of localexamination boards, represented by various stakeholders (universities, schools, LEAs,businesses etc.), but as this was not introduced, universities retained their control over thecurriculum and assessments.

The potentially influential 1943 Norwood Enquiry, appointed by the SSEC to investigatecurriculum and examinations, recommended that assessments at 16 should be subject based(thus allowing freedom of subject choice), largely internally assessed (allowing A level studentsto bypass assessment at that age9) and based on a statutory core curriculum. Such proposalswould, effectively, reduce the influence and independence of the examination boards10.However, despite the many radical changes wrought by the 1944 Education Act, it onlyenshrined the first of Norwood’s above three recommendations, and made no reference tocurriculum matters. These were, therefore, effectively left in the hands of the universities which,both directly (via entrance examinations), and indirectly (via their GCE examination boards)used their freedom to devise syllabuses and examinations relatively unregulated. However, thesubject-based system meant centres and candidates had more autonomy in curriculum matters,which were now freed up.

B) POST WAR

In the immediate post-war period, entries to qualifications continued to remain small, albeitgrowing, despite the major expansion of free educational opportunity which the 1944 Actintroduced. This was partially due to the school leaving age having been set at 15, theEducation Minister discouraging secondary modern schools from offering GCE courses, andtheir lack of resources to do so anyway. Thus, by the early 1950s, LEAs and schools began tointroduce self-regulated, local examinations to provide external accreditation for secondarymodern students. This decade also provided concrete evidence of the GCE examining boardstaking seriously their responsibility for rigorous self-regulation in the form of their conductingmarking reliability research, cross-moderation exercises and inter-board agreement trials.

By the end of the decade, three important reports were published which were to affectsubstantially the provision of secondary education and general qualifications. These were theCrowther (15 to 18, (1959)) and Newsom (Half our Future, (1963)) reports, which paved the wayfor comprehensive education, and the Beloe Report (Secondary School Examinations otherthan GCE (1960)) which led to the introduction of the CSE examination 1965, which wasintended for students in the 40 per cent of the ability range below the top 20 per cent, for whomthe GCE was designed.

The CSE was overseen by the Schools Council, which replaced the SSEC in 1964. Whereasthe SSEC had essentially been a facilitator for a group of self-regulatory boards, the SchoolsCouncil (1964) which replaced it had the remit to be more proactive in coordinating the system.To this end, it formed partnerships with the many education stakeholders (subject associations,LEAs, teacher unions etc.), as seen by the membership of its governing council, and was activein encouraging diversity and innovation, and in sponsoring research.

9 A proposal which has recently been revived; see, for example, the lead story in the Times EducationalSupplement on 18 March 2011: “Ministers’ plan for elite: forget GCSE and go straight to A-level”.10 Controversially, the Norwood report was submitted directly to the President of the Board of Education,by-passing its commissioning body, the SSEC, altogether. When the SSEC did formally discuss the reportin 1943, the university-based examination board representatives raised objections to it, their reward forwhich was to be removed from the SSEC!

12 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

The CSE examination clearly exemplified this collaborative and “light touch” approach. It wasadministered on a decentralised basis: schools entered candidates locally for one of fourteenregional examination boards (which were run by teachers and LEAs), and were granted morefreedom and autonomy in the content and assessment of the syllabuses. Moreover, the BeloeReport had emphasised that the CSE should reflect, not impose on, the developing secondaryschool curriculum, with scope for local variations and experiments, and recognition of the resultsof coursework, special studies and practical work. As Gillan reports:

“The proposals were enthusiastically received in most quarters. … The examination

was to be firmly school and teacher based, with substantial freedom for schools to

develop and examine a curriculum appropriate to their pupils, especially via the Mode 3

assessments. … Thus was released into the secondary sector an unprecedented wave

of imagination and curriculum thinking which was to have far-reaching repercussions

and influence examinations right through to the present day.” (p96, Gillan, 2003)

Despite the popularity of the CSE, the national assessment system at 16+ embodied structuralissues relating to comparability of standards and esteem, both within each qualification andbetween them. Moreover, with the ever greater pressure for a comprehensive secondaryeducation structure, the existing examination system came to be seen as anachronistic. Asearly as 1970, just five years after the inception of the CSE, the Schools Council established aWorking Party (1971) to consider the feasibility of a unified system and this led to pilot Joint 16+exams some of which were retained until 1987, usually overtaking GCE and CSE combinedentries. In 1978, the year that LEAs were required to submit plans for comprehensive education,The Waddell Committee, established to investigate the feasibility of a single examinationsystem, recommended that one should be introduced, administered by groups of existing GCEand CSE boards. Five such groups were established, each being allowed to make its ownconstitutional arrangements. After some delay, in 1984 the GCSE was approved by theSecretary of State, Sir Keith Joseph for first examination in 1988.

At the same time, it had become apparent that localised autonomy of both the curriculum andassessment, as encouraged by the Schools Council in general, and embodied in the design andpractice of the CSE in particular, had become politically unpopular. Thus, in 1984 the SchoolsCouncil was replaced by the Schools Curriculum Development Committee (SCDC) and theSecondary Examinations Council (SEC) which gave government more control over bothaspects. The SEC, in particular, “was given a stronger remit than any of its predecessors to

approve syllabuses and coordinate examination provision.” (p 68, Tattersall, 2007)

This increased centralisation and control was exemplified in the criteria with which the newGCSE syllabuses had to comply: all syllabuses had to meet a set of general criteria, and twentysubjects had to satisfy subject-specific criteria before being approved by the Secretary of State.

As Tattersall states:

“The introduction of GCSE criteria thus opened the door to greater control of the system

from the centre, including the rationalisation of syllabuses (and later of providers), a

dominant theme of the last years of the century. GCSE proved to be the Trojan Horse

which brought Government squarely into both the curriculum and assessment

arenas…” (p16-17, Tattersall, 2003).

13 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

Elsewhere, Tattersall described these developments as the government entering “the secret

garden of the curriculum” and the accompanying regulatory framework as a “seismic shift from

… one of loose coordination to tight regulation”. (p70, 72, Tattersall, 2007)

C) MODERN TIMES

It was, however, the 1988 Education Reform Act (Baker) which more radically realigned therelationships between the government and education stakeholders, including the examinationboards. In prescribing, for the first time, a statutory, national curriculum and assessment systemat four key stages, state control of education took a large step forward. The agencies foroverseeing and administering these newly accrued powers were the National CurriculumCouncil (NCC) and the Schools Examination and Assessment Council (SEAC), replacing theSEDC and SEC respectively.

The impact on examination boards was direct. As the assessment vehicle for Key Stage 4 of thenational curriculum, GCSE syllabuses were required by SEAC, under the powers granted to it,to embody, inter alia, detailed and specific learning outcomes and strict limits on the amount ofcoursework. It was indicative of these changes that, by the time of the GCE Curriculum 2000reforms, the term “syllabuses” had been replaced by “specifications”.

In 1993 the SEAC and NCC were replaced by the School Curriculum and Assessment Authority(SCAA) which was merged with the National Council for Vocational Qualifications (NCVQ) in1997 to become the Qualifications and Curriculum Authority (QCA), covering both general andvocational qualifications, in an attempt to promote parity of esteem. In addition to maintainingand developing the national curriculum and its associated assessments, QCA was grantedfurther powers and duties under Section 24 of the 1997 Education Act (which established it), toregulate all external qualifications in England. (In 1992 Ofsted, with enhanced powers, replacedHMI to inspect the operation of the education system.) In 2007, however, it was announced thatresponsibility for regulating examinations and qualifications would move from the QCA to a newindependent regulator, the Office of Qualifications and Examinations Regulation (Ofqual), andboth bodies would become statutorily independent and report to Parliament rather than toministers.The increased powers of the regulator were no more clearly illustrated than by the introductionof the Code of Practice. Following an HMI report on the quality and standards of A/AS levelexaminations in 1993, a voluntary code for the GCE was drafted in 1994, complementing the1993 mandatory code for GCSE with which it was merged in 1997. The codes stipulated strictprocedures for all stages of the examining process, from syllabus design to awarding, and theGCE Code limited the contribution of coursework to 20 per cent in most A level subjects. Thiswas a consequence of a speech by Prime Minster John Major in 1991, in which he hadsignalled the same limit to most GCSE subjects. The intervention of a Prime Minister in thedetails of the assessment structure gave a significant indication of how centralised andregulatory the administration of the system had become.

As increasing numbers of post-16 students began to remain in full-time education, thegovernment’s attention began to focus on provision at 18+ in general, and on GCE A level inparticular. In his 1996 report, “A Review of Qualifications for 16-19 year olds”,11 Sir Ron Dearingcovered many areas, four of which in particular signalled increased central control. First, a

11 Other reports by Capey (1996) on GNVQs, and by Beaumont (1996) on NVQs/SVQs, were published atthe same time.

14 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

national framework for qualifications at three clearly defined levels and three pathways: general(GCSE and A level), applied, and vocational. Second, a substantial rationalisation of GCEsyllabus provision and the specification of the content of the subject cores which, together witha new Advanced Subsidiary examination, paved the way for the GCE Curriculum 2000 reforms.Third, a rationalisation of awarding bodies12 and new joint arrangements for awarding theGCSE, A level and GNVQ in order to tighten comparability of standards, not least across thegeneral/applied divide, and to eliminate wasteful duplication. (It also called for a rationalisationof NVQ – vocational – awarding bodies.) Fourth, a single, statutory body to be responsible forthe school curriculum from 4-19.

Thus Dearing signalled what had been increasingly clear, that the awarding bodies were nowlargely agencies of government and that its control of curriculum and assessment had movedinto the post-statutory school leaving age. The government’s response to Dearing, significantlyentitled “Guaranteeing Standards” (1997), eschewed the possibility of a single awarding body inEngland, instead opting for three unitary (across the general/applied divide) awarding bodies.

After a delay of one year to allow more preparation time, the new-style GCE specifications wereapproved for courses starting in 2000, such that the first AS awards were made in 2001 and thefirst new, modularised A levels were awarded in 2002. As per Dearing’s recommendations, andas an example of tighter central control of GCE, far fewer specifications had been approvedthan had previously been available. Despite their delayed introduction, the new GCE reformsproved problematic to implement, and led to problems in the awarding of the new GCE A levelsin 2002. The phased, two-report Tomlinson Enquiry (2002) into these problems argued forgreater commonality of administrative procedures, standards of service and, not least, awardingstandards. Historically, voluntary self-regulation of this type had been undertaken by the JointCouncil for General Qualifications (JCGQ)13, but the problems of 2002 adversely affected publicconfidence in the system and strengthened the case of those arguing for greater centralregulation and control of the assessment system.

However, commenting on the events of 2002, Tattersall seems to suggest that the regulatorytightening which had preceded them may, partially at least, have been one of their causes:

“However, I would be alarmed if the chapter were to be read as support for a further

tightening of the regulation noose. Indeed, I would hope that the juxtaposition of tighter

regulation and the 2002 crisis of public confidence in A levels would raise questions

about the role and purpose of regulation.” (p95, Tattersall, 2007)

It was suggested earlier than the awarding organisations had, in effect, become agents ofgovernment, partially via the regulator’s activities. The provision, content, assessment structure,recognition and accreditation requirements, fees, etc. are all directly imposed by the regulator,not to mention the huge indirect influences on the market via imposed equivalences inPerformance Tables. Apart from these concrete indicators which can be identified, a lesstangible mentality has developed in awarding organisations in recent years, which might bedescribed as one of “corporate compliance”. The grading of recent GCSE Science awards is a

12 As Tattersall (2003) perceptively indicates , “the term awarding body” reflects the separation ofcurriculum responsibility from the assessment process” (p28)13 The JCGQ, comprising the main general qualifications awarding bodies in the UK, had been establishedin 1998 as a voluntary, self-regulatory and administrative body. It was superceded in 2004 by the JointCouncil for Qualifications (JCQ).

15 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

small but poignant example of this mentality in action: how the focus on compliance with theprocesses and requirements of the Code of Practice arguably deflected awarding bodies fromthe more important issue of maintaining standards. The former was not a sufficient, norarguably a necessary, condition for the latter.

An obvious area which is indicative of the influence of increased regulation is that of innovation.Before the expansion of regulatory activity, innovative syllabuses and assessment schemesflourished. Although some of these were supported and facilitated by the then regulator, e.g. theSchools’ Council, the characteristic of them all is that they were “bottom-up” developments,demand led and implemented by groups who were enthusiastic about, and knew the curriculumrequirements of, their subject areas. In addition to the locally-developed CSE syllabuses,examples of such successful innovations range from the JMB’s GCE General Studies syllabusto the Nuffield and Salters’ science suites, the SMP mathematics developments, NEAB’shundred per cent GCSE English coursework syllabus, and OCR’s successful Computer Literacyand Information Technology (CLAIT) qualification. Doubtless there were failures too, but in thedecades when these, and other innovative, qualifications were developed, a spirit of creativityprevailed. It is hard to think of similar schemes in recent years. Indeed, such developmentswhich do come to mind are “top-down”, supply-led and implemented by political will, as opposedto local knowledge and enthusiasm. The Diploma would appear to be a classic case in point;one cannot imagine an awarding organisation, on its own volition, designing such aqualification.

4. WHERE ARE WE NOW?

The latest development in the story of examinations regulation begins with the Apprenticeship,Skills, Children and Learning (ASCL) Act 2009 that established Ofqual as the regulator ofqualifications, examinations and tests in England. It commenced work as a fully independentnon-ministerial government department on 1 April 2010 (having operated in interim form as adistinct part of QCA for two years before that), the same date that the Act had provided for thedissolution of the QCA, its responsibilities for the handling of qualifications and recognitionbeing transferred to Ofqual, in addition to its regulatory functions. (Thus, in a short time Ofqualat least partially subsumed its progenitor, QCA). The remaining work of the QCA - to promotequality and coherence in education and training, review curriculum and assessmentarrangements, and assist Ofqual in setting assessment criteria - was transferred to theQualifications and Curriculum Development Agency (QCDA), which was to be abolished in the2011 Education Bill.The first indications of how Ofqual would interpret and utilise the substantial new powersgranted to it have been in the form of three main consultations: Regulating for Confidence inStandards (RCS) (2009), From Transition to Transformation (FTT) (2010) and Consultation onEconomic Regulation and the Fee-capping Process (2010).

The new regime

It is in Part 7 of the 2009 Apprenticeships, Skills, Children and Learning Act that the statutoryduties and requirements of Ofqual are laid out. It has been given five overall objectives,described in RCS (p9):

16 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

The first two are directly focused on maintaining standards:

1. The qualifications standards objective is to secure that regulatedqualifications:

a) give a reliable indication of knowledge, skills and understanding,and

b) indicate a consistent level of attainment (including over time)between comparable regulated qualifications.

Regulated qualifications will be subject to the following principles: validity;reliability; comparability; manageability; minimising bias.

2. The assessment standards objective is to promote the development andimplementation of regulated assessment arrangements which:

a) give a reliable indication of achievement, andb) indicate a consistent level of attainment (including over time)

between comparable assessments.

(N.B. This objective relates only to statutory national curriculum, excludingGCSE, and Early Years Foundation Stage (EYFS) assessments.)

A next two objectives are directed towards public confidence in regulated qualifications andassessments and public understanding of the benefits of regulated qualifications:

3. The public confidence objective is to promote public confidence in regulatedqualifications and regulated assessment arrangements.

4. The awareness objective is to promote awareness and understanding of:

a) the range of regulated qualifications,b) the benefits of regulated qualifications to learners, employers and

institutions within the higher education sector, andc) the benefits of recognition to bodies awarding or authenticating

qualifications.

The final objective is concerned with economic regulation:

5. The efficiency objective is to ensure that regulated qualifications are providedefficiently, and in particular that any relevant sums payable to a body awardingor authenticating a qualification in respect of which the body is recognisedrepresent value for money.

Ofqual is committed to realising these objectives by utilising the government’s principles of goodregulation.14

14 These are: proportionality: policy solutions should be appropriate for the perceived problem or risk accountability: regulators and policy officials must be able to justify the decisions they make and

should expect to be open to public scrutiny

17 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

Whilst this broad range of objectives and duties appears unexceptionable, how they are to berealised and applied signals a potentially significant change of direction for regulatory activity.As the RCS itself states:

The new legislation marks a step-change in the way that qualifications and

assessments are regulated. It sets out a structure within which Ofqual, as theindependent regulator, will maintain standards and public confidence largely by making

sure that the organisations which award regulated qualifications have the right systems

in place to control the quality of their qualifications. Ofqual will have specific powers tointervene, where necessary, but such interventions will need to be justified by risk. (p8,emphases added.).

However, it is how these broad objectives are realised, and how the new powers are applied,that will determine the extent of the step-change, and how different the qualifications industry ingeneral, and those parts pertaining to the regulator in particular, will appear. The aboveconsultation documents, RCS (2009) in particular, give a good indication of how the regulationis to be applied. It is not easy to summarise a 140 page document but the following are some ofits key features:

The regulatory focus will shift from the accreditation of the individual qualifications towardsthe recognition of awarding organisation. Prior to the 2009 ASCL Act the regulator wasrequired to accredit each individual qualification separately; this is no longer necessary.

Thus an awarding organisation intending to enter the qualifications market must becomerecognised by demonstrating to Ofqual that it satisfies certain “recognition requirements”and can be trusted to control the quality and standards of its qualifications. To this end,Ofqual will develop a risk profile of each awarding organisation and monitor compliance withthe recognition conditions. A corollary of this is that, previously, if something was amiss orproblematic, Ofqual’s focus was on solving the problem with the qualification. Henceforth insuch situations, the focus will be on the awarding organisation as a whole, and will includespecifically the systemic source of the problem, e.g. the quality assurance and controlprocesses, development design procedures or assessment arrangements.

However, Ofqual retains the right to use its discretion to apply “accreditation requirements”to individual qualifications. This discretion will be used for qualifications embodyingparticularly high levels of risk, for example because the awarding organisation is new, hasexperienced a problem in the previous series, has a very large number of subject entriesand/or is a high profile subject.

Whereas previously, regulation was limited to qualifications awarded by an ‘external’organisation, qualifications offered by teaching and training organisations can now beregulated;

consistency: rules and standards must be joined up and implemented fairly and consistently transparency: regulations should be open, simple and user friendly. Policy objectives, including

the need for regulation, should be clearly defined and effectively communicated to allstakeholders

targeted: regulation should be focused on the problem. Regulators should aim to minimiseside-effects and ensure that no unintended consequences will result from the regulation beingimplemented. (RCS, p.39)

18 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

The qualifications market will be reviewed to secure efficiency and value for money, withOfqual having the power to cap the fees to that end. Although the former provisions arenew, the ability to cap fees has existed previously, but has not been used.

These changes are designed with the expressed intentions that Ofqual will become a morestrategic and risk-based regulator by:

focusing more on product, rather than process; protecting the interests of learners; securing standards and promote confidence in those standards; diverting scarce regulatory resources to areas of highest risk and in the interests of

learners; making a wider range of regulated qualifications available to learners; enabling awarding organisations to be more responsive to learners’ and employers’ needs

and to encourage opportunities for innovation; facilitating greater transparency about the operation of the market.

5. WHERE ARE WE GOING? REGULATION IN A MARKET CONTEXT

The recent changes in regulatory arrangements purport to effect some significant changes tothe way regulation will occur. However, do they in reality simply comprise a bureaucratic re-arrangement and tidying up or do they signal a fundamental change to the way qualificationswill be administered and in the way the market operates, and in what direction should futureregulatory arrangements be aimed?

Ofqual is placed somewhere on the continuum between the two extremes of a monopoly and aperfect market, presumably trying to apply the best of both models as it sees them. Thereappears to be something of a paradox, or at least a tension, in recent developments and theway they are being implemented. On the one hand, more powers have been centralised, yetdevolved to the independent regulator, than ever before. On the other hand these powers arebeing used with a less interventionist, light-touch, approach, and in the interests of expandingand liberating the market to make it more competitive. (It is, perhaps, illustrative of this changeof approach that in the 140 pages of RCS, “monitor” (or its derivatives) appears 112 times,whereas “enforce” appears a mere 29 times.)

Initial movements in this direction can already be seen. The forthcoming, new style Code ofPractice for 2012 will, for instance, be based on principles, rather than detailed rules andprocedures as has been the case hitherto, signalling a shift of focus from process to product(outcomes). The experience of GCSE Science awards in recent years has been a salutaryreminder of the deficiencies of the process-focussed approach: although none of the awardingorganisations could have been accused of non-compliance with the Code of Practice, therewere, at the initial, provisional stages of each series at least, significant discrepancies instandard between awarding organisations, leading to, arguably, a corresponding drift in nationalstandards over time.

The encouragement of more sellers to enter the market for qualifications is also becomingapparent. The International Curriculum and Assessment Agency (ICAA) already offers a suite ofGCSE Business, D&T and ICT qualifications, and McDonalds, Flybe and National Rail were thefirst companies to be granted awarding body status by QCA in 2008 allowing them to developtheir own in-house qualifications equivalent to GCSEs and GCEs. This marks a clear change in

19 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

policy from the government’s Guaranteeing Standards (1997) report (made in the light of theDearing Review (1996)) which reduced the number of English awarding bodies.

Whilst the above examples signal a less interventionist approach, indications relating to theefficiency and value for money objective hint at increased intervention in awardingorganisations’ arrangements. Although it is too early to see any specific intervention by Ofqualin pursuit of this objective, its intentions are laid out in its consultation on Economic Regulationand the Fee-capping Process (2010). Ofqual has traditionally monitored fee levels and marketefficiency, for example via its annual Ofqual Annual Qualification market reports (2008, 2009,2010) and its Report on Awarding Body Fees for the revised GCE A levels (2008). It has alsohad the power to intervene and cap fees since before the 2009 ASCL Act, but this has not yetbeen used. However, it is interesting to note that - probably independent of changes inregulatory design and practice - recent years have seen an increase in differential pricing policyfor GCSE and GCE qualifications. Thus the Report on Awarding Body Fees for the revised GCEA levels could report:

The largest fee differentials between awarding bodies are seen in design andtechnology, music, and art and design with differences of 121 per cent, 84 per cent and80 per cent respectively between the highest and lowest fee. The fees charged for an Alevel range from £67.20 for the lowest to £148.40 for the highest. Awarding bodies differin the services and specifications they provide for the fee charged and this should betaken into consideration when making comparisons. (p.4)

Moreover, a range of fees exists between awarding bodies’ for the same subject. In 2008/9, forexample, AQA’s fee for a GCE A level modern language was £67, whereas Edexcel’s was£102. The rationales for each awarding body’s pricing of this subject are unknown, but it ispossible that the converse occurred in other subjects. In an attempt to increase the fluidity of themarket, the report concludes:

However, a comparison of fees for the same subjects across awarding bodies revealsconsiderable differences. Centres should consider these fee differentials as well as thespecifications and services when deciding which awarding bodies to use. (p.4)

Anecdotal and AQA market survey evidence suggests, however, that the market is priceinsensitive and (because?) those who decide which specification/awarding body to choose areheads of subject departments who are often ignorant of the fees. In a period of severe financialconstraint, this pattern may soon change.

The more recent consultation on Economic Regulation and the Fee-capping Process (2010)has, however, caused some concern about potentially inappropriate interventions in awardingbodies’ business. The full introductory comments of AQA’s response to this consultation (2010)are included as Appendix C, but a few brief extracts are as follows:

AQA would argue that economic regulation as outlined by Ofqual is not appropriatebecause the market is complex with normal competitive functioning hugely distorted bypublic funding activity and with many of the awarding organisations operating asregistered charities or not for profit businesses. Additionally, we consider that thisstatutory objective of Ofqual’s will not prove to be cost effective … there is littleevidence of a level of inefficiency that, if driven out, could lead to a reduction in fees.

20 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

AQA questions the approach being taken by Ofqual to the objectives, duties andpowers it has under the ASCL Act of 2009. Although Ofqual may be described as aneconomic regulator as regards the efficiency objective, it appears to be taking an overlyprescriptive approach as to how it discharges that function.

6. CONCLUSION: THE REGULATION OF STANDARDS

This paper concludes that, for two, closely related reasons, not only do the recent reforms notappear fundamentally to change the arrangements, but that they do not sufficiently address acentral aspect of regulation, that of standards, thus potentially increasing risk and underminingusers’ confidence in the currency, a vital assumption underpinning any market.

The first reason is simply that the most influential “regulatory” forces in the qualificationsindustry are not at work the first market (see earlier), which is within Ofqual’s sphere of control,but in the second market which is beyond it. Thus the influences of, for example DfE School andCollege Performance (“League”) Tables requirements and UCAS points are far more pervasiveand influential than most factors related to the first market. This is a point also identified by theSykes Review (2010) which was commissioned by the Conservative Party to review “the majorexaminations taken at 16 and 18, with a particular focus on academic qualifications”. Thefollowing extract relates to the second market, and points to the distorting market effects ofarbitrarily-imposed values and argue a reduction in the “equivalence claims” they embody.

We think it is important that the limitations of current equivalence claims be fully

understood, and action taken to reverse their current distorting effects as soon as

possible, for example by disseminating information about the relative difficulty of

qualifications more widely.

The second reason relates to the difficult, but core, issue of standards and their regulation,which has so far not been specifically addressed. Although the powerful players in the secondmarket define and impose the value of qualification grades (currency) in an arbitrary fashion onthat market, it remains incumbent on the regulator and awarding organisations to ensure a fairand stable currency in the first market, although as will be seen, that might be informed bycooperating with those bodies which impose the assigned values of the second market.

All market models are underpinned by certain assumptions which are usually implicit and onlyspecified when, in a particular context, they are relaxed. One of the main ones is that thegood/service which is being traded is homogeneous, that is, competition between sellers is onprice alone. The apparent price insensitivity of this market suggests that this is not the case andthat important factors other than entry fees are at work. Awarding organisations compete, as faras regulatory requirements allow, on quality of specification, teacher support activities etc., but itis extremely controversial to suggest that they should also be allowed to compete on thestandard of the awards provided. The questions are, whether, how much, and how, theregulator should intervene in these areas?

It was argued earlier that the intangible “good” traded in the first market was an opportunity orentitlement, and that the eventual product of that trading - qualification grades - became thecurrency of the second market. Theoretically, the market could be left entirely free, with thesecond market compensating for any differences in perceived value accruing from the workings

21 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

of the first market, as arguably currently exists to some extent (Wolf (2003)), and appears to beat least partially advocated by Sykes (2010):

This means that they (awarding organisations) should be free to offer qualifications at

varying levels of difficulty without interference from Ofqual or any other government

body unless there is specific cause for concern.

Awarding bodies should not be required to have post-16 qualifications accredited,

although they may wish to do so.

Unless there is a clear contrary indication, it should be assumed that qualifications

offered by an accredited awarding organisation are of an acceptable standard.

However, few would think that this approach would work, even in the long term, and it wouldcertainly not in the short term, thus rendering the system not only inefficient but also deeplyunfair, when candidates’ life chances are at stake. Moreover, it would likely be undermining ofconfidence in the system in general, and in candidates’ grades in particular.

It must, perforce, be the regulator’s role to ensure, in the interest of fairness and efficiency, thatbuyers in this market (and its sub-markets), have equal opportunities to be awarded a givengrade, whatever the year, awarding body and specification. Another way of saying this is thatthey must have the same standards applied.

This is what Ofqual currently has to say about standards maintenance in para. 4.2 in FromTransition to Transformation (2010):

“We will secure standards by:

a) requiring that the level of demand required of learners taking different qualifications is

clear

b) requiring each awarding organisation to define clearly the knowledge, skills and

understanding required of the learner for each of its regulated qualifications

c) requiring each awarding organisation to use methodologies that provide assessments

that minimise bias and are valid, reliable, comparable and manageable

d) requiring each awarding organisation to put in place safeguards to make sure the

standards of its qualifications are consistent with other comparable qualifications and

consistent over time

e) undertaking direct checks on the standards an awarding organisation is applying

f) making specified qualifications subject to an accreditation requirement where we judge

it is necessary to do so

g) intervening when standards are at risk.

We currently work in each of these ways. We will continue to develop and strengthen our

approach using our new statutory powers.”

Whilst these are unexceptionable, it is debatable whether they are sufficient to guarantee anddefine standards. This is one area where it is vital that Ofqual not only do not apply a light touchbut be transparent about what are its definitions and expectations of standards. In a sense, it isnot so important how they are defined in each instance, but that they are defined is the mainpriority. In this respect, it is para. d) in the above list which is most important but most of the

22 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

points in the list appear somewhat passive and reactive. Indeed, in risk log parlance, e), f), andg) are, in effect, Ofqual’s counter measures and contingency arrangements in this area. Oneaction which is already being taken in relation to points a) and b) above is that sellers in thesecond market are being encouraged to work closer with those in the first market to ensurefitness for purpose and closer correspondence between the grade values assigned in the twomarkets. Thus universities, in particular, are being encouraged to play a more central part inGCE specification and assessment determination, ironically signalling something of a return tothe early years of this qualification. As Sykes (2010) advocated:

Universities, employers and other relevant bodies should be fully involved in

qualification design and implementation. Awarding bodies, which will have considerably

more freedom, should be fully transparent as to which bodies they work with in

qualification design and implementation.

It is, perhaps, unfair at this stage to anticipate Ofqual’s actions and requirements, but thecurrent wording does not suggest a strong proactive intervention in relation to standards settingand equating is to be expected. The hard lessons of recent years are there to be learnt. This isnot to say that the definition and expectation of standards will always be easy, especially as the(first) market place is opened up to more sellers and a variety of provision. It is not easy definingstandards and many, notably Cresswell (1996), have shown that this can be done in severalways. They could, for example, even be defined by quotas, or be norm, cohort15 orcriterion-based, although AQA has some fairly strong views on preferred methods supportedwith a substantial evidence base. The current expansion of the Functional Skills market(currently thirteen separate awarding organisations16, one of which comprises three separateconsortia, have been accredited to offer (156) Functional Skills qualifications) and the diversenature of their provision and assessment designs is a contemporary and salutary example ofthe challenge to be faced.

In the light of its avowed risk-based approach, permitting the devaluation of, or loss ofconfidence in, the currency of qualification grades represents perhaps the biggest risk of all toOfqual. This specific example of Functional Skills exemplifies the tension that Ofqual faces: howto expand and liberate the market while adopting a robust and transparent approach to ensuringthe value and equivalence of the product of that market.

B E JonesApril 2011

15 There is an analogy between the role of awarding organisations and the private issuing banks inScotland (Bank of Scotland, RBS, Clydesdale Bank) and Northern Ireland (Bank of Ireland, First Trust,Northern Bank and Ulster Bank). Both sets of organisations issue a form of currency whose volume needsto be restrained lest confidence erode. This has been done traditionally by linking the currency to a ‘fixedstock’ of value: gold in the case of banks, and ‘ability’ in the case of awarding organisations. A ‘fixed stockof ability’ model finds its expression in norm- or cohort-referenced awarding. However, the growingmeritocratic instinct eventually manifested itself in a shift towards criterion referencing, the belief being thatachievement should not be defined as relative success against one’s peers. The acceptance of an elementof consequent grade inflation has a parallel with the gradual acceptance of economic inflation: anathemato the pre-1914 era but now accepted as a motive force in the economy.16 1st4Sport, AQA, Ascentis, Bhest (Non-Pilot AO), C&G, EAL (3 consortia), EDI, Edexcel, NCFE, NOCN,OCR, VTCT, WJEC

23 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTSI am indebted to several people for the information and advice they have given me in preparingthis paper, particularly Julie Swan (Ofqual), Neil Stringer, Nigel Smith, Paul Leigh,Jackie Brown, Beth Underdown (all AQA). The views expressed therein are, however, my own.

REFERENCESApprenticeship, Skills, Children and Learning Act. (2009). Retrieved from

http://www.legislation.gov.uk/ukpga/2009/22/bodyBangs, J., MacBeath, J. and Galton, M. (2010) Reinventing Schools, Reforming Teaching.

London: Routledge.Beaumont, G. (1996) Review of 100 NVQs and SVQs. Chesterfield: Department for Education

and Employment.Bill 180: Education Bill (2010). Retrieved from

http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/bills/cbill/2010-2011/0180/cbill_2010-20110180_en_1.htm

Capey, J. (1996) GNVQ Assessment Review. London: NCVQ.Cresswell, M.J. (1996). Defining, setting and maintaining standards in curriculum-embedded

examinations: Judgemental and statistical approaches. In H. Goldstein and A. Heath(Eds.), Assessment: Problems, developments and statistical issues (pp. 57-84).Chichester: John Wiley and Sons.

Dearing, R. (1996). National Committee of Inquiry into Higher Education. London: Departmentfor Education and Employment.

Department for Education and Employment. (1997). Guaranteeing Standards: a consultationpaper on the structure of awarding bodies. London: Department for Education andEmployment.

Department for Education and Skills. (2004.) 14-19: Curriculum and Qualifications Reform: FinalReport of the Working Group on 14-19 Reform. London: Department for Education andSkills.

Foucault, M. (1981). The order of discourse. In R.J. Young (Ed.), Untying the text: apost-structuralist reader (pp.52-64). London: Routledge.

Gillan, D. (2003). The Northern CSE Boards. In Assessment and Qualifications Alliance, Settingthe Standard: a century of public examining by AQA and its parent boards (pp. 95-112).Manchester: Assessment and Qualifications Alliance.

Lakoff, G., & Johnson, M. (1980) Metaphors We Live By. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Lipsey, R.G. (1963) An Introduction to Positive Economics. London: Weidenfield and Nicolson.Ministry of Education. (1960). Secondary School Examinations other than the GCE. Report of a

committee appointed by the SSEC in July 1958 (Beloe report). London: Her Majesty’sStationery Office.

Morris, E., Williams, M., Ahlberg, J. (Producers), & Morris, E. (Director). (2003). The Fog ofWar: Eleven Lessons from the Life of Robert S. McNamara [Motion picture]. UnitedStates: Sony Pictures Classics.

Newton, P.E. (2007). Evaluating assessment systems. London: Qualifications and CurriculumAuthority.

Ofqual (2009). Regulating for Confidence in Standards: consultation on the regulation ofqualifications, examinations and assessments. Coventry: Office of Qualifications andRegulations.

Ofqual (2010) Consultation on Economic Regulation and the Fee-capping Process. Coventry:Office of Qualifications and Regulations.

Ofqual (2010). From Transition for Transformation: Strategic Regulation of AwardingOrganisations and Qualifications. Coventry: Office of Qualifications and Regulations.

Ofqual (2008). Report on Awarding Body Fees for the revised GCE A levels. Coventry: Office ofQualifications and Regulations

Petch, J.A. (1953). Fifty years of examining: the Joint Matriculation Board, 1903 – 1953.London: Harrap.

Postman, N. (1996). The End of Education: Redefining the value of school. New York: Vintage.QCA. (2008) Annual Qualification Market Report. London: Qualifications and Curriculum

Authority.

24 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

QCA. (2008). Report on Awarding Body Feeds for the Revised GCE A Levels. London:Qualifications and Curriculum Authority. Retrieved fromhttp://www.ofqual.gov.uk/files/Report_on_awarding_body_fees_for_the_revised_GCE_A_levels.pdf

QCA. (2009). Annual Qualification Market Report. London: Qualifications and CurriculumAuthority.

QCA. (2010). Annual Qualification Market Report. London: Qualifications and CurriculumAuthority.

Raffe, D., Croxford, L., Iannelli, C., Shapira, M. & Howieson, C. (2006). Social-class inequalitiesin education in England and Scotland. University of Edinburgh: Centre for EducationalSociology.

Schools Council Bulletin 23. (1971). A common system of examining at 16+. London: Evans.Schumpeter, J. (1950) Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (3rd edition.). New York: Harper.

Smith, A. (1759). The Theory of Moral Sentiments. London: A. Millar.Steinberg, B. (2002). Examination boards: Regulatory overkill or pattern for the future?

Economic Affairs, 22(1), 44-50.Tattersall, K. (2003). Ringing the changes: educational and assessment policies, 1900 to the

present. In Assessment and Qualifications Alliance, Setting the Standard: a century ofpublic examining by AQA and its parent boards (pp.7-28). Manchester: Assessment andQualifications Alliance.

Tattersall, K. (2007). A brief history of policies, practices and issues relating to comparability. InNewton, P., Baird. J., Goldstein, H., Patrick, H., & Tymms, P. (Eds.), Techniques formonitoring the comparability of examination standards (pp. 43-91). London:Qualifications and Curriculum Authority.

The Crowther Report. (1959). 15 to 18: A report of the Central Advisory Council for Education(England). London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.

The Newsom Report. (1963). Half Our Future: A report of the Central Advisory Council forEducation (England). London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.

The Sir Richard Sykes Review (2010). Retrieved fromhttp://www.conservatives.com/news/news_stories/2010/03/~/media/Files/Downloadable%20Files/Sir%20Richard%20Sykes_Review.ashx

The Waddell Report. (1978). School Examinations. London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.Retrieved March 2 2011 fromhttp://www.educationengland.org.uk/documents/waddell/index.html

Tomlinson, M. (2002). Inquiry into A Level Standards – Final Report. London:Department for Education and Skills.

Wolf, A. (2003). An ‘English Baccalaureate’: exactly what do we want it to do? OxfordMagazine, 216, pp.16-17.

Wood, R. (1976). Your Chemistry equals my French, Times Educational Supplement, July 30.

25 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

Appendix A. Four “ideal types” of an Economic Market

Perfect competition

It is often said that, “In a free market the consumer is king”, but this is only really true in the caseof perfect competition, where prices are determined by both demand and supply – sellers andbuyers. The main features of a perfectly competitive market are as follows:

There are many sellers, each of whom produces an insignificant proportion of total marketoutput, and many buyers. As no actor exercises control over the price, market power isdiffused.

Buyers have perfect knowledge about prices and products from competing sellers. The product is homogeneous and perfectly substitutable, leading each seller to be a

passive “price taker” at a lowest equilibrium price. Resources are allocated efficiently and optimally (no waste). There is freedom of entry and exit from the industry.

Monopoly

At the other extreme lies the market model of monopoly (into which, incidentally, mostqualifications systems fall), the main features of which are as follows:

There is a single seller who produces all the output, and thus comprises the industry. The monopolist has market power in being able to affect the terms and conditions of

exchange (e.g. the price can be set by the seller, not impersonally by the market as inperfect competition), but this power is limited as a price increase will result in the loss ofsome sales.

For a market to remain monopolistic, there must be a barrier to other sellers’ entry.

Monopolistic competition

Monopolistically competitive markets have the following characteristics:

There are many sellers and buyers, but buyers perceive product differentiation. In the short term, sellers can behave like a monopolist by setting their price and quantity

without affecting the market as a whole. In the long term more sellers enter the market, which becomes more competitive except

that competition is based on product differentiation, not price. However, because of brandloyalty, sellers can raise prices without losing all of their buyers, thus giving them someinfluence over the market. Sellers thus have a degree of control over price.

There are few barriers to market entry and exit.

Oligopoly

Oligopoly is defined as “competition among the few” and has the following characteristics:

There are few sellers, any of whose actions will affect the market price and competitors’behaviour. The distinctive feature of an oligopoly is thus interdependence; sellers must takecompetitors’ reactions into account (e.g. by not triggering a mutually destructive price war).

Sellers benefit from economies of scale; goods cannot be produced on a small scale.

26 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

Barriers to market entry are high, so oligopolies can retain long run profits. Importantbarriers are economies of scale, patents, access to expensive technology and strategicactions by incumbent firms designed to discourage nascent firms. Sellers have an incentiveto engage in research & development to lower costs and capture a larger market share.

The product may be homogeneous or differentiated.

27 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

Appendix B. School Certificate subject groupings

School Certificate Group Subject 1918-1949

Group Subject

I English Comprehension & Literature, History, Geography,Scripture Knowledge, Greek.

At least one subject

II Greek, Latin, French, German, Spanish. At least one subject

III Mathematics, Mechanics, Physics Chemistry, Biology orBotany, Physics with Chemistry, General Science.

At least one subject

IV Art, Music, Handicraft, Domestic Subjects, CommercialSubjects, Geometrical& Machine Drawing, MechanicalScience.

Not compulsory,only one subjectallowed

Higher School Certificate

Group Subject

I Greek, Latin, Ancient History

IIA English, History, Pure Mathematics, Languages (including Latin)

IIB History, Languages (excluding Latin), Geography, Economics

III Mathematics subjects, Physics, Chemistry, Botany, Zoology*

IV Mathematics subjects

*Biology was added in 1925, Art and Music in 1931, Scripture Knowledge in 1940 and Geologyin 1943.

28 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market

Centre for Education Research and Policy

Appendix C. Introductory Comments to AQA’s response to the Ofqual’s consultation onEconomic Regulation and the Fee-capping Process (2010)

AQA recognises Ofqual’s statutory objective to secure efficiency and value for money in theprovision of regulated qualifications.We have fully contributed to earlier studies commissioned by Ofqual as identified below andhave previously argued against the inclusion of this objective in Ofqual’s remit.The Frontier Economics report – The market for Regulated Qualifications in England, Wales

and Northern Ireland which proposes a starting point for market – wide analysis.The Grant Thornton report – Collection of Economic and Financial Information whichrecommends that Ofqual routinely collects data on fees, revenue, costs and key financial ratiosfrom each awarding organisation for the UK regulated qualifications business only.The Reckon report – Increasing the Transparency of Qualification Fees which looks at differentstandardised methods of comparing prices that could be introduced.AQA would argue that economic regulation as outlined by Ofqual is not appropriate because themarket is complex with normal competitive functioning hugely distorted by public funding activityand with many of the awarding organisations operating as registered charities or not for profitbusinesses. Additionally, we consider that this statutory of objective of Ofqual’s will not prove tobe cost effective. While expenditure on qualifications fees has grown, the many assertionsrelating to the increase have not been back up with any quantitative analysis of the underlyingreasons for this. AQA would suggest that there is little evidence of a level of inefficiency that, ifdriven out, could lead to a reduction in fees.As a general observation, AQA questions the approach being taken by Ofqual to the objectives,duties and powers it has under the ASCL Act of 2009. Although Ofqual may be described as aneconomic regulator as regards the efficiency objective, it appears to be taking an overlyprescriptive approach as to how it discharges that function.Furthermore, we would argue that much of detail relating to economic regulation has still to bedefined and wish to take this opportunity to express concern that awarding organisations arebeing consulted on such an important aspect when so much remains unclear.

29 Ben JonesRegulation and the qualifications market