81
Unclassified ECO/WKP(2006)5 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development ___________________________________________________________________________________________ English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT PROJECTING OECD HEALTH AND LONG-TERM CARE EXPENDITURES: WHAT ARE THE MAIN DRIVERS? ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPERS No. 477 All Economics Department Working Papers are available through OECD's Internet Web site at www.oecd.org/eco Document complet disponible sur OLIS dans son format d'origine Complete document available on OLIS in its original format ECO/WKP(2006)5 Unclassified English - Or. English Cancels & replaces the same document of 03 February 2006

English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    1

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

Unclassified ECO/WKP(2006)5 Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Economiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development ___________________________________________________________________________________________

English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT

PROJECTING OECD HEALTH AND LONG-TERM CARE EXPENDITURES: WHAT ARE THE MAIN DRIVERS? ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT WORKING PAPERS No. 477

All Economics Department Working Papers are available through OECD's Internet Web site at www.oecd.org/eco

Document complet disponible sur OLIS dans son format d'origine Complete document available on OLIS in its original format

EC

O/W

KP(2006)5

Unclassified

English - O

r. English

Cancels & replaces the same document of 03 February 2006

Page 2: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

2

ABSTRACT/RESUMÉ

Projecting OECD health and long-term care expenditures: What are the main drivers?

This paper proposes a comprehensive framework for projecting public heath and long-term care expenditures. Notably, it considers the impact of demographic and non-demographic effects for both health and long-term care. Compared with other studies, the paper extends the demographic drivers by incorporating death-related costs and the health status of the population. Concerning non-demographic drivers of health care, the projection method accounts for income elasticity and a residual effect of technology and relative prices. For long-term care, the effects of increased labour participation, reducing informal care, and wage inflation are taken into account. Using this integrated approach, public health and long-term care expenditure are projected for all OECD countries for the years 2025 and 2050. Alternative scenarios are simulated, in particular a 'cost-pressure' and 'cost-containment' scenario, together with sensitivity analysis. Depending on the scenarios, the total health and long-term care spending is projected to increase on average across OECD countries in the range of 3.5 to 6 percentage points of GDP for the period 2005-2050.

JEL Classification: H51, I12, J11, J14

Key words: Public health expenditures, long-term care expenditures, ageing populations, longevity, demographic and non-demographic effects, projection methods.

******

Cette étude propose un cadre assez complet pour effectuer des projections de dépenses de soins de santé et de soins de long terme. Notamment, à la fois pour les dépenses de santé et les soins de long terme, les effets des facteurs démographiques et non démographiques sont considérés dans l'analyse. En comparaison avec d'autres études, les effets démographiques ont été élargis pour incorporer les coûts liés à la mortalité et à l'état de santé de la population. Pour ce qui concerne les facteurs non démographiques des dépenses de santé, la méthode de projection incorpore un effet d'élasticité-revenu et l'effet résiduel de la technologie et des prix relatifs. Pour les soins de long terme, l'effet d'une participation accrue dans le marché du travail diminuant l'offre de soins informels, et de l'inflation des salaires ont été pris en compte. Sur la base de cette approche intégrée, les dépenses publiques de santé et des soins de long terme sont projetées pour tous les pays de l'OCDE et pour les années 2025 et 2050. Des scénarios alternatifs ont été simulés, en particulier un "scénario de pression sur les coûts" et un "scénario de contention des coûts", ainsi qu’une analyse de sensitivité. En fonction des scénarios, le total des dépenses de santé et des soins de long terme est projeté d'augmenter pour la moyenne de l’OCDE entre 3.5 et 6 points de PIB pour la période 2005-2050.

Classification JEL: H51, I12, J11, J14

Mots clefs: dépenses publiques de santé, dépenses publiques de soins à long terme, vieillissement de la population, longévité, effets démographiques et non démographiques, méthodes de projection.

Copyright OECD, 2006 Applications for permission to reproduce or translate all, or part of, this material should be made to: Head of Publications Service, OECD, 2 rue André-Pascal, 75775 Paris Cedex 16, France.

Page 3: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

3

TABLE OF CONTENTS

FOREWORD .................................................................................................................................................. 5 1. Summary and main findings............................................................................................................. 6 2. Health care...................................................................................................................................... 10

Projecting demographic drivers of expenditure..................................................................................... 10 Projecting non-demographic drivers of expenditure.............................................................................. 12 Combining demographic and non-demographic drivers........................................................................ 14 Alternative scenarios for OECD countries ............................................................................................ 15

Demographic effects .......................................................................................................................... 15 A cost pressure scenario..................................................................................................................... 16 A cost-containment scenario .............................................................................................................. 16

Sensitivity analysis ................................................................................................................................ 17 Residuals, income elasticity and different health scenarios ............................................................... 17 Alternative population projections..................................................................................................... 18

3. Long-term care ............................................................................................................................... 18 Projecting demographic drivers of expenditure..................................................................................... 19 Projecting non-demographic drivers of expenditure.............................................................................. 20 Combining demographic and non-demographic drivers........................................................................ 21 Alternative scenarios for OECD countries ............................................................................................ 22

Demographic effects .......................................................................................................................... 22 A cost-pressure scenario .................................................................................................................... 23 A cost-containment scenario .............................................................................................................. 23

Sensitivity analysis ................................................................................................................................ 23 REFERENCES ............................................................................................................................................. 25 ANNEX 1. LIST OF TABLES AND FIGURES.......................................................................................... 30 ANNEX 2A. DATA SOURCES AND METHODS..................................................................................... 50

Macro data ............................................................................................................................................. 50 Health care ............................................................................................................................................. 50

Estimating the death-related costs...................................................................................................... 50 Estimating the survivors' expenditure curves..................................................................................... 51 Calibration of the cost curves on the OECD Health database............................................................ 51 Projecting the demographic effects under a ‘healthy ageing’ scenario.............................................. 51

Long-term care (LTC) ........................................................................................................................... 52 Expenditure curves............................................................................................................................. 52

The starting point of the projections ...................................................................................................... 53 Detailed results for the projection scenarios.......................................................................................... 53

ANNEX 2B. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON THE HEALTH CARE INCOME ELASTICITIES .............. 73 A brief survey of the literature............................................................................................................... 73 Econometric estimates ........................................................................................................................... 74

ANNEX 2C. OBESITY TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES ....................................................................... 77

Page 4: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

4

Boxes

Box 1. Glossary of technical terms ............................................................................................................. 9 Box 2. Longevity and health status scenarios ........................................................................................... 11 Box 3. Cost-containment policies in OECD countries: an overview1 ....................................................... 13 Box 4. Exogenous variables and assumptions underlying the projections................................................ 15 Box 5. Has disability fallen over time? ..................................................................................................... 20

Page 5: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

5

FOREWORD

Rising expenditure on health and long-term care is putting pressure on government budgets in most OECD countries. Going forward, these pressures will add to those arising from insufficiently reformed retirement schemes. The question is how much health and long-term care spending could increase in the future and what policy can do about it. This paper presents a framework for thinking about that question and provides some quantitative illustrations. Both changing demography and non-demographic drivers of spending are taken into account.

The paper shows that spending on health and long-term care is a first-order policy issue. Between now and 2050, public spending on health and long-term care could almost double as a share of GDP in the average OECD country in the absence of policy action to break with past trends in this area. And that estimate takes into account that as people live longer, they also remain in good health for longer. Even with containment measures, public spending on health and long-term care could rise from the current average level of 6-7 % of GDP to around 10% by 2050. In some countries, the increase could be dramatic. Despite the orders of magnitudes involved, policy discussion in many countries has focused less on health and long-term care spending than on pension and transfer spending. There can be many reasons for that. One is possibly that pension spending is analytically more easily tractable than is the case for health and long-term care. Another is that the policy instruments to address pension spending are more readily identifiable. A third is that it is easier in the case of pensions to identify benchmarks for assessing what constitutes reasonable spending levels and sensible incentives to private sector actors. Whatever the reasons, the results in this paper illustrate that the policy environment for health and long-term care spending is of primordial importance.

The work behind this report was undertaken by a team led by Joaquim Oliveira Martins and comprising also Christine de la Maisonneuve and Simen Bjørnerud. As usual in our work, a preliminary version of the report was discussed by OECD government representatives. They provided many helpful comments, but the responsibility for the final product of course lies with the OECD Secretariat.

Jean-Philippe Cotis Chief Economist

Page 6: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

6

PROJECTING OECD HEALTH AND LONG-TERM CARE EXPENDITURES: WHAT ARE THE MAIN DRIVERS?

1. Summary and main findings

1. Public spending on health and long-term care is a major source of fiscal pressures in most OECD countries, amounting to, on average, some 7% of GDP in 2005. Evolution has been uneven over time: following rapid growth during the 1970s, public spending slowed down for several decades. However, a recent acceleration (Figure 1.1) has raised concern about likely future trends.

[Figure 1.1 Evolution of public and private OECD health spending]

2. This paper attempts to respond to these concerns by considering a number of factors likely to drive public spending on health and long-term care over the period to 2050.1 In projecting drivers of this spending, two important distinctions are made:

• Expenditures on long-term care and on health care (both preventive and acute) are examined separately,

• For both health and long-term care, the impacts of ageing and non-demographic factors are brought separately into the analysis.

3. The projections rely on a uniform cross-country framework, in contrast with an earlier OECD exercise.2 The latter essentially gathered country-specific projections, provided by national authorities, produced on the basis of an agreed set of macroeconomic and demographic assumptions. The current projections are more homogeneous, but at the cost of simplifying the description of national health and long-term care arrangements. The main purpose is to bring out in a stylised and tractable way the key mechanisms at work. The inherent uncertainties surrounding this approach are addressed by analysing the sensitivity of the projection results to changes in the assumptions concerning the main drivers of expenditure.

4. In broad terms, the principal forces driving these projections are (see main text for detail):

• Health care, demographic factors: a rising share of older age groups in the population will put upward pressure on costs because health costs rise with age. However, the average cost per individual in older age groups should fall over time for two reasons:

− Longevity gains are assumed to translate into additional years of good health (“healthy ageing); and

1. This paper only deals with public spending. Private spending added another 2% of GDP on average to

expenditure on health and long-term care in 2005. While it could be argued that private and public expenditures are not separable, it is implicitly assumed here that private health spending arises from individual choices and, therefore, could be treated like any other consumption item.

2. For details on this earlier project see Dang et al. (2001).

Page 7: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

7

− Major health costs come at the end of life. Insofar as increasing longevity means that more individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the group in question will fall.

• Health care, non-demographic factors: health care costs have typically grown faster than income (even as incomes have increased). This is generally held to be due to the effect of technology and relative-price movements in the supply of health services. Disentangling these factors is beyond the scope of current analysis and indeed is dealt with only modestly in the literature. Hence, two scenarios are assumed in the projections here:

− A “cost pressures” scenario in which it is assumed that, for given demography, expenditures grow 1% per annum faster than income. This corresponds to observed trends over the past two decades.

− A “cost-containment” scenario in which (unspecified) policy action is assumed to curb this “extra” expenditure growth such that it is eliminated by the end of the projection period (2050).

• Long-term care, demographic factors: dependency on long-term care will tend to rise as the share of old people in the population increase. This effect is mitigated somewhat by the likelihood that the share of dependents per older age group will fall as longevity increases due to “healthy ageing”.

• Long-term care, non demographic factors: expenditures are likely to be pushed up by a possible “cost disease” effect, i.e. the relative price of long-term care increasing in line with average productivity growth in the economy because the scope for productivity gains in long-term care is more limited.3 This effect is assumed to be fully operative in the “cost pressure” scenario but to be partially mitigated4 by (unspecified) policy action in the “cost containment” scenario.

5. As noted, two main sets of scenarios were simulated, one in which no policy action is assumed, the “cost pressures” scenario, and a “cost-containment scenario” that embodies the assumed effects of policies curbing expenditure growth. As mentioned above, these policies are not modelled explicitly. Finally, sensitivity tests were carried out to assess the robustness of the results to key assumptions.

6. The projections for health and long-term care expenditures yield the following stylised results (Table 1.1):

• In the “cost-pressure” scenario average health and long-term care spending across OECD countries is projected to almost double from close to 7% of GDP in 2005 to some 13% by 2050.

• In the “cost-containment” scenario, average expenditures would still reach around 10% of GDP by 2050, 5 or an increase of 3½ percentage points of GDP.

3. Note that empirical evidence on the income elasticity of long-term care spending simply does not exist, and

in most scenarios it is assumed to be zero.

4. It is arbitrarily assumed that the relative price changes by only half of productivity growth elsewhere in the economy.

5. As a comparison, on the basis of pure demographic effects, Dang et al. (2001) concluded that the expenditure on health and long-term care for a group of OECD countries would increase from 6% of GDP in 2000 to 9 to 9½ per cent of GDP in 2050. A similar study by the EC-Economic Policy

Page 8: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

8

• Non-demographic factors (including effects from technology and relative prices) play a significant role in upwards pressure on long-term care expenditures, and indeed are the most important driver of the increase in health-care expenditure.

[Table 1.1 Public health and long-term care spending]

7. These average results hide striking differences across countries (Figure 1.2). In the cost-containment scenario, a group of countries stands out with increases of health and long-term care spending at or above four percentage points of GDP, over the period 2005-50. It includes rapidly ageing countries (Italy, Japan, Spain), countries that will experience a dramatic change in their population structure (Korea, Mexico, Slovak Republic), and countries with currently low labour participation, which may face a substantial increase in the demand for formal long-term care (Italy, Ireland, Spain). In contrast, Sweden is in the lowest range with an increase below two percentage points of GDP. This country is in a mature phase of its ageing process and already spends a relatively high share of GDP on health and long-term care.

[Figure 1.2 Total increase in health and long-term care spending, 2005-2050]

8. Despite the uncertainties, sensitivity analysis suggests the results are fairly robust in key respects. For example, under the assumption of “healthy ageing” changes in longevity will have only a modest effect on spending. However, the projections for spending on long-term care are sensitive to the future development of participation rates for the working-age population because higher participation reduces the capacity for “informal” care. An alternative scenario, where participation rates in countries where they are currently low converge towards levels in high-participation countries, has spending on long-term care rising by an additional 1-2% of GDP on average, but much more in some countries.6

9. The paper follows the structure displayed in Figure 1.3. It begins with health care expenditure, decomposing demographic and non-demographic expenditure drivers, discusses the main mechanisms at work in each case, and describes the projection framework. Alternative projection scenarios are then presented, followed by a discussion of the sensitivity of the results to key assumptions. The same sequence applies to long-term care expenditures. A glossary of technical terms is provided in Box 1.

[Figure 1.3 Drivers of total health and long-term care spending: key components]

Committee (2001), focusing on the EU15 area, calculated that the expenditure on health and long-term care would increase from 6½ per cent in 2000 to 8½ to 9% in 2050. Calculated in the same way, the ageing effect was estimated to be of comparable size also in Canada (Health Canada, 2001). These orders of magnitude are comparable with the results of the present study, but the underlying drivers are rather different. For an update of the assumptions and projection methodologies see EC-Economic Policy Committee (2005).

6. However, higher participation rates are likely to have positive effects on public budgets which, depending on how they come about, may more than offset the effect via long-term care spending.

Page 9: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

9

Box 1. Glossary of technical terms Activities of daily living (ADLs) Self-care activities that a person must perform every day, such as bathing, dressing,

eating, getting in and out of bed, moving around, using the toilet, and controlling bladder and bowel.

(Acute) health care Is distinguished from long-term care in the sense that acute health care aims at changing the medical condition of a person (e.g. surgery) while long-term care only compensates for lasting ability.

Baumol effect or 'cost-disease' Tendency for relative prices of some services, such as long-term care, to increase vis-à-vis other goods and services in the economy, reflecting a negative productivity differential and the equalisation of wages across sectors.

Compression of morbidity The hypothesis that increases in longevity translate into a shorter share of life lived in relatively bad health.

Death-related costs Health expenditures incurring at the end of life. One hypothesis proclaims that the apparent rise in health expenditures with age reflects the fact that death is more frequent at higher ages, not merely the fact that people are old and frail. Following this line of thought, the projected fall in mortality will damp the future impact of ageing.

Disability/dependency Inability to perform one or more ADLs without help. Specific definitions, i.e. how many ADLs, differ across countries making comparisons difficult.

Dynamic equilibrium (“healthy ageing”) The hypothesis that the number of years of life lived in bad health remains constant in the wake of increased longevity (or increased life expectancy is translated into additional years in good health).

Expansion of morbidity The hypothesis that increases in longevity translate into a higher share of life lived in relatively bad health.

Formal long-term care Long-term care services supplied by the employees of any organisation, in either the public or private sector, including care provided in institutions like nursing homes, as well as care provided to persons living at home by either professionally trained care assistants, such as nurses, or untrained care assistants. Divided into home care and institutional care.

Informal care Long-term care provided by spouses/partners, other members of the household and other relatives, friends and neighbours. Informal care is usually provided at the home and is typically unpaid.

Long-term care A range of (often basic) services needed for persons who are dependent on help for carrying out basic ADLs. Divided into formal and informal long-term care where, on average across OECD countries, the latter currently makes up the bigger part.

Morbidity/chronic conditions A wider concept than disability. Higher levels of disability are generally accompanied by more chronic conditions, but the opposite does not necessarily follow; intensive medical treatment can reduce disability by soothing chronic diseases. This implies that a decline in disability does not necessarily means curtailment in costs. Still, analyses usually focus on disability due to lack of reliable and objective measures of morbidity.

Prevalence of disability/morbidity/ dependency

Number of cases of disability/disease/dependency for a given population for a given time period. Prevalence of disability/morbidity/dependency tends to be more frequent at higher ages.

Page 10: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

10

2. Health care

10. Looking at the recent past, expenditures on health care have increased in terms of their share in GDP. Given that pure demographic factors have so far been weak, this upward trend in spending is probably due to the increased diffusion of technology and relative price changes. Two important questions are then: how will these typically non-demographic drivers behave in the future and will the projected change in demographic trends create additional expenditure pressures?

Projecting demographic drivers of expenditure

11. While the effect of ageing on public health expenditures per capita has been weak in the past,7 it is commonly expected that it will increase in the future. This assessment is based on the combined effect of the projected increase in the share of old people and the tendency for health expenditures per capita to increase with age.8

12. In this study expenditure profiles are a central piece of the projection framework (Figure 2.1). Average health expenditures by age group are relatively high for young children; they decrease and remain stable for most of the prime-age period, and then start to increase rapidly at older ages.9

[Figure 2.1 Public health care expenditure by age groups]

13. For any given year, the population can be divided into two segments: the survivors and the non-survivors. Each of these segments of the population has a specific cost curve. The non-survivors' cost curve can be estimated by multiplying the estimated costs of death by age group by the number of deaths per age group. In line with evidence that health costs are concentrated in the proximity to death (i.e., they are “death-related”; Seshamani and Gray, 2004; Batljan and Lagergren, 2004), the cost of death was proxied by the health expenditure per capita for the oldest age group (95+) multiplied by a factor (equal to 4 for an individual between 0 to 59 years old and declining linearly to 1 afterwards). The survivors' cost curve can then be derived from the difference between the total cost curve and the non-survivor curve (see Annex 2A). An example of this split is given for one country, Finland, in Figure 2.2. Using this framework, health expenditures for survivors and non-survivors can be projected separately in a more meaningful way.

[Figure 2.2 Breakdown of the health care cost curve]

7. See Culyer (1990), Gerdtham et al., (1992), Hitiris and Posnett (1992), Zewifel et al. (1999), Richardson

and Roberston (1999), Moise and Jacobzone (2003) and Jönsson and Eckerlund (2003).

8. Across all health expenditure types, expenditure on those aged over 65 is around four times higher than on those under 65. The ratio rises to between six to nine times higher for the older groups (Productivity Commission, 2005; OECD Health Database, 2005).

9. The data is based on the EU-AGIR Project; see Westerhout and Pellikaan (2005). The complete expenditure profiles were only available for a subset of OECD countries. A number of different adjustments and estimations were made in order to derive these curves for other OECD countries. Moreover, for some countries only total costs were available and thus health care had to be separated from long-term care. For 12 countries, the data were simply not available. In this case, the expenditure curves were estimated by adjusting expenditures as a spline function of age, based on available data, and were calibrated on the basis of total health expenditures derived from OECD (2005a). These estimation procedures are described in detail in Annex 2A.

Page 11: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

11

14. The shape of the aggregate cost curves can be explained by movements across age groups in health care expenditures for these two segments of the population. Indeed, the upward shape of the average cost curve reflects the fact that mortality rates are higher for older age groups. At the same time, the fact that the cost curves tend to peak and then decline at very old ages can be explained by considerations related to the cost of death. While the probability of dying increases with age, the costs of death tend to decline steadily after young and prime ages (Aprile, 2004). Finally, the little spike in health expenditures at the youngest age is related in part to infant mortality being higher than prime-age mortality.

15. Noteworthy, the death-related costs hypothesis has logical implications for the health status of survivors. In the extreme case where health costs are only death-related, there are only two outcomes: an individual either dies or survives in good health. To be consistent over time the projected increase in life expectancy must be accompanied by an equivalent gain in the numbers of years spent in good health. Otherwise, an increasing share of the population living in “bad health” would emerge. Average health care costs would then cease to be mainly driven by the costs of death, as initially assumed.

16. Thus, the death-related costs hypothesis implies that longevity gains are translated into years in good health. Under this “healthy ageing” scenario, the cost curve for survivors is allowed to shift rightwards, progressively postponing the age-related increases in expenditure.10 This development tends to reduce costs compared with a situation in which life expectancy would not increase. Other health status scenarios have been envisaged in previous research (see Box 2) and the projections in this paper test the sensitivity of the results to these alternative assumptions.

17. As regards non-survivors, two different demographic effects are at play. On the one hand, the number of deaths is set to rise due to the transitory effect of the post-war baby-boom. On the other hand, if mortality falls over time, due to a permanent increase in longevity, fewer will be at the very end of life in each given year, mitigating health care costs.11 The total effect on public health care expenditures will depend on the relative size of these effects.

Box 2. Longevity and health status scenarios

Different health status scenarios have been envisaged in the literature. In an “expansion of morbidity” scenario (Grunenberg, 1977), the share of life spent in bad health would increase as life expectancy increases, while a ”compression of morbidity” scenario (Fries, 1980) would mean the opposite. Currently, equilibrium between longevity and morbidity is observed in many OECD countries. Accordingly, and striking a compromise between the expansion and compression scenarios, Manton (1982) put forward the ”dynamic equilibrium” hypothesis where longevity gains are translated one-to-one into years in good health (hereafter, referred as ”healthy ageing”).

In this context, Michel and Robine (2004) proposed a general approach to explain why countries may shift from an expansion to a contraction of morbidity regime, or achieve a balanced equilibrium between longevity gains and the reduction of morbidity. They identified several factors at work: i) an increase in the survival rates of sick persons which would explain the expansion in morbidity; ii) a control of the progression of chronic diseases which would explain a subtle equilibrium between the fall in mortality and the increase in disability; iii) an improvement in the health status and health behaviour of the new cohorts of old people which would explain the compression of morbidity, and eventually; iv) the emergence of very old and frail populations which would explain a new expansion in morbidity. Depending on the relative size of each of these factors, countries could evolve from one morbidity regime to another.

10. In contrast, in a “pure demographic” approach to health care expenditures, the cost curves would not shift

rightwards with ageing, reflecting the implicit assumption of unchanged health status at any given age. When the cost curves stay put in presence of longevity gains, the share of life lived in ‘bad health’ increases when life expectancy increases.

11. See for example Fuchs (1984), Zwiefel et al. (1999), Jacobzone (2003) and Gray (2004).

Page 12: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

12

Projecting non-demographic drivers of expenditure

18. Income growth is certainly the main non-demographic driver of expenditures, although the vast literature on this topic is still somewhat inconclusive on the precise value of the income elasticity (see Annex 2B). Two insights can, nevertheless, be drawn. First, income elasticity tends to increase with the level of aggregation, implying that health care is both “an individual necessity and a national luxury” (Getzen, 2000). Second, without reliable price data for health-related goods and services, the high income elasticities (above unity) often found in macro studies may result from the failure to control for true price effects. In this context, the most reasonable approach seems to assume unitary income elasticity and, subsequently, to test the sensitivity of the projections to this assumption.

19. After controlling for demographic and income effects, a residual expenditure growth can be derived. Between 1981 and 2002 (Table 2.1), public health spending grew on average by 3.6% per year for OECD countries,12 of which 0.3 percentage point was accounted by pure demographic effects13 and 2.3 percentage points by income effects (assuming unitary income elasticity). Thus, the residual growth can be estimated at around 1% per year. Over an extended sample, 1970-2002, the residual growth would much higher to reach 1.5% per annum (Table 2.2). This difference reflects the implementation of cost-containment policies over part of the 1980s and the 1990s that curbed the strong residual growth of the 1970s (Box 3).

[Table 2.1 Decomposing growth in public health spending, 1981-2002] [Table 2.2 Decomposing growth in public health spending, 1970-2002]

20. What are the factors underlying this residual expenditure growth? The main culprits seem to be technology and relative prices.14 Indeed, the gains in health status discussed above do not only arise from improvements in lifestyle (Sheehan, 2002; Cutler, 2001), but also from advances in medical treatment/technology. The latter, however, do not come free of economic cost. Technical progress can be cost-saving and reduce the relative price of health products and services, but its impact on expenditure will depend on the price elasticity of the demand for health care. If it is high, a fall in prices will induce a more than proportionate rise in demand, increasing expenditures.15 Even if prices do not fall, new technologies may increase demand by increasing the variety and quality of products.16,17

12. This estimate was carried out for total health spending given that the split between health care and long-

term care expenditures is not available in time series for historical data. Given the low share of public long-term care expenditure to GDP in 2000 (typically below 1% of GDP; OECD, 2005b), this approximation of the residual growth seems reasonable.

13. To simplify calculations, the effect of past ageing does not incorporate “healthy longevity” and “death-related cost” as is done in the projections. In any event, the ageing effect was small and would have even been even smaller if a more sophisticated method had been applied. If anything, ceteris paribus, ignoring these past factors is likely to have lead to a downward bias in the estimated residual.

14. See Fuchs (1972) and Mushkin and Landefeld (1979). More recently, there has been a renewal of interest in this approach, see Newhouse (1992), KPMG Consulting (2001), Wanless (2001), Productivity Commission (2005a-b).

15. For example, Dormont and Huber (2005) found that in France the unit price of certain surgical treatments, such as cataract, decreased whereas the frequency of the treatments increased significantly. Such effects can explain much of the recent upward shift in the health care cost curves in France.

16. This is equivalent to say that the “true” relative price of health care vis-à-vis all other goods in the economy decreases. Consider for example the case of a demand for variety model with a CES utility function:

∑ −=

iixU σσ )1(

, where σ>1 is the elasticity of substitution among products.

Page 13: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

13

21. In projecting public health care expenditures, two alternative scenarios were envisaged for the future: one in which the residual effect of technology and prices continues to rise at the historical rate and another in which this rate declines over time due to cost containment policies. Should the country-specific historical growth rates in the residual be used to project expenditures? There are least two reasons for questioning this choice. First, in countries where cost-containment policies have resulted in a low or negative residual (e.g., Austria, Denmark, Ireland, Italy, Sweden) there could be a trend reversal, e.g. because new personnel has to be attracted or run-down facilities renewed. Second, in countries where the residual growth was very high (e.g., Portugal, Turkey, United States) it may seem likely that cost-containment policies will be implemented in the future. These effects would lead to a certain cross-country convergence of the expenditure residual over time. Therefore, in most of the projection scenarios, an OECD average residual was preferred to project expenditures.

Box 3. Cost-containment policies in OECD countries: an overview1

Faced with unsustainable growth in health care spending over the 1960s and 1970s, governments initially aimed at containing it through various kinds of macroeconomic restrictions. These policies often created allocative problems of their own. Wage and price controls had negative consequences on the supply of health while top-down spending constraints also discouraged providers to increase output or to enhance productivity.

More recently the focus turned to more efficient provision of care. Nonetheless, while spending growth has slowed considerably over the past two decades, studies using statistical tests of the impact of budgetary caps or other policies to limit spending provide little evidence of a strong impact. In some cases, the reduction of health care costs has been achieved by transferring spending to other areas, such as long-term care. Supporting this view is the fact that countries that have been most effective at controlling health care spending are also the ones where long-term care expenditures have increased most rapidly.

Macroeconomic cost-containment initiatives

Wage controls have been used in public integrated systems in both the hospital and the ambulatory sector where health care personnel are paid on a salary basis (Denmark (hospitals), Finland, Ireland (hospitals), Spain, Sweden and the United Kingdom (hospitals)). Such policies were part of a broader public sector restraint rather than specific to the health sector.

Price controls have been widely used, particularly in areas where governments set prices administratively or have oversight on prices agreed between health care purchasers and providers. A number of countries have set fees directly (e.g., Australia, Belgium, France, Japan, Luxembourg and Canada). In others, prices have been automatically adjusted to offset volume overrun so as not to exceed a fixed budget ceiling (e.g., Germany (ambulatory care), Austria (hospital care), Hungary (outpatient care), and recent Belgium reforms). Administrative price setting has probably been most widespread for pharmaceutical drugs.

Limits in most countries on entry to medical schools are an important factor affecting the growth of the number of medical professionals. The number of new doctors per capita has slowed as a result. There have also been reductions in support staff (Canada, Sweden). Policies to restrain supply have actually led to supply shortages in, for example, Canada, the United Kingdom and Denmark and waiting lists are a common feature across OECD countries. In countries like Finland, France and Korea an upward pressure on wages has unfolded.

Hospital supply policies have encouraged a reduction in the number of beds per capita and concentrated acute care in larger hospital units so as to achieve economies of scale and scope. Nonetheless, the level of acute-care beds per capita remains relatively high in some countries (such as Austria, the Czech Republic, Germany, Hungary and the Slovak Republic).

Budgetary caps or controls have been a widely used instrument for controlling expenditure. In general, policies to control and reshape supply and to cap spending in the hospital sector appear to have been more successful than for ambulatory care or pharmaceutical drugs. Spending control through budgetary caps also appears to have been most successful in countries such as Denmark, Ireland, New Zealand and the United Kingdom where integrated models of health-care financing and supply are (or were)

To simplify, let us assume price symmetry ( ippi ∀= , ). The true composite price index is then equal to

pnP ⋅= − )1(* σ. With two types of composite goods, say health (H) and all other goods (O), the true

relative price would be: )()( )1(**OHOHOH ppnnPP ⋅= −σ

. Thus, even if the usual price ratio ( OH pp / )

remains constant, the “true” relative price ** / OH PP would decrease when the pace of product creation in the health sector is much faster than in the rest of the economy.

17. Some governments are attempting to introduce such quality adjustments in the measure of output (and hence prices) of public services. See Grice (2005) for a discussion on this point based on the Atkinson Review, prepared for the UK Office for National Statistics.

Page 14: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

14

the rule and in mainly single-payer countries, such as Canada, where health-care budgets are generally explicitly set through the budget process.

Cost sharing has been an increasingly common feature over the 1980s and, particularly, the 1990s. Greater cost-sharing has mainly affected pharmaceuticals, while patient payments for inpatient and doctors visits have been less widespread (Sweden, Italy, France). This is presumably connected to the higher price elasticity for pharmaceutical drugs than for ambulatory and, particularly, for hospital care.

Improving cost-efficiency at the micro level

Ambulatory care is of key importance to the overall efficiency and effectiveness of health-care systems; it usually is the place where contact between patient and health care personnel is first established and ambulatory care is generally less expensive than hospital care. The gate-keeping role of general practitioners (GPs) has been encouraged in some countries (United Kingdom, New Zealand, Norway, United States and France). In Eastern European countries, the ambulatory sector has been shifted from the public sector to private practitioners in the course of the 1990s and, in some cases, they are now paid on a capitation basis.

Hospital sector reforms concern first and foremost the separation of purchasers and providers within public integrated systems. Purchasers/funders of health care are responsible to the budgetary authorities for cost control and to patients for the quality and accessibility of care. A significant number of countries with integrated systems have now moved in this direction (Australia, United Kingdom, New Zealand, Sweden, Italy, Portugal and, more recently, Greece). More active purchasing has also occurred in countries with public contract models (Germany, Belgium). The role of purchasers has been enhanced in the United States. The contracting out of selected activities has increased, where these can be provided more cheaply externally. Finally, a limited number of countries (the United States, the United Kingdom, Sweden, the Czech Republic and New Zealand) have experimented with greater competition among hospitals as a means of inducing improvement in efficiency, quality, and responsiveness.

____________ 1. This Box is based on and draws extensively on Docteur and Oxley (2003).

Combining demographic and non-demographic drivers

22. To sum up, defining HE, Y and N as real health care expenditures, real income and population, respectively; and, ε the income elasticity of health expenditures, the growth of health expenditures can be decomposed as follows:

( )residualNYfactorageadjusted

NHE loglog)log(log ∆+

∆⋅+∆=

∆ ε (1)

or expressed in share of expenditure to GDP:

( )residualNYfactorageadjusted

YHE loglog)1()log(log ∆+

∆⋅−+∆=

∆ ε (2)

23. The mechanical effect of population ageing on expenditures can be interpreted as first moving up along the cost curve, assuming that the age profile of expenditures remain constant over time (Figure 2.3, Panel 1). This age factor is then adjusted by incorporating the healthy longevity hypothesis, corresponding to a rightward shift of the cost curve (Figure 2.3, Panel 2).18 As mentioned above, this shift implies that older people still cost more than the young, but at progressively older ages. Finally, the cost curve may shift upwards (Figure 2.3, Panel 3) due to non-demographic drivers (income and the residual).

[Figure 2.3 Shifts in expenditure profiles, ageing and non-ageing effects]

18. See Annex 2A for more details.

Page 15: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

15

24. Once the total logarithmic growth rates are estimated for each country, the projection framework computes the changes in expenditure shares to GDP considering a common starting point. The latter is computed as the cross-country average share of public health care spending in GDP in 2005, thus can be viewed as a sort of OECD representative country. The changes in expenditure calculated from this common base are then added to the country-specific initial shares to obtain future projected ratios of expenditure to GDP. This method has two advantages. Over the long run, it makes the projections more comparable across countries, as the effects of the different mechanisms at work during the projection period are isolated from the impact of the initial conditions.19 Moreover, it allows a certain catch-up across countries in the ratios of public health care expenditures to GDP.

25. Additional exogenous assumptions underlying the projections for both health and long term care are listed in Box 4 (more details are also provided in Annex 2B).

Box 4. Exogenous variables and assumptions underlying the projections

The projections require a set of exogenous data, as follows: (1) Population projections (N). The population projections were gathered by the OECD Directorate on

Employment, Labour and Social Affairs, directly from national sources. Given that the underlying assumptions on fertility and life expectancy are not necessarily uniform across countries (see Oliveira Martins et al., 2005 for a discussion), this paper also uses a population maquette (Gonand, 2005) to test the sensitivity of the results to uniform longevity assumptions for a selected group of countries.

(2) Labour force projections (L/N) rely on previous OECD work (Burniaux et al., 2003). These projections are

constructed in the basis of a, so-called, cohort approach. They correspond to a baseline scenario, i.e. the impact of current policies is assumed to influence labour participation over the next decades, but no additional assumptions are made concerning future policy changes.

(3) Labour productivity (Y/L) growth is assumed to converge linearly from the initial rate (1995-2003) to 1.75% per year by 2030 in all countries, except former transition countries and Mexico where it converges only by 2050.

Summary statistics on the exogenous assumptions are provided in Annex 2A. The projected GDP per capita is directly derived from the above exogenous variables (Y/N = Y/L x L/N). This simple framework is not supposed to capture in the best way productivity differentials across countries, but to isolate, as far as possible, the effect of ageing and other demographic factors on the projections.

Alternative scenarios for OECD countries

26. The framework described above was used to project expenditures over the period 2005-50. In the main scenarios, the income elasticity is set to one, thus income effects are not creating additional pressures in terms of expenditure shares to GDP. The main assumptions underlying each projection scenario are listed in Table 2.3.

[Table 2.3 Assumptions underlying the alternative projection scenarios: Health care]

Demographic effects

27. As discussed above, demographic effects on public health care expenditures can be decomposed into the health care costs for survivors, the adjustment for “healthy ageing” and the death-related costs, as shown in Panel A of Figure 2.4. The pure ageing effect can be quite large in some countries, but it tends to

19. Without this specification, spending patterns of countries with equivalent expenditure drivers would

diverge in terms of share of expenditure to GDP merely due to different initial expenditure to GDP ratios.

Page 16: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

16

be compensated by a better health status. The death-related costs account only for a small fraction of the increase in expenditures as a share of GDP. In level terms, they increase from around 5% of total health care spending in 2005 to 7% by 2050.

[Figure 2.4 Demographic effects on health care expenditure]

28. The total effect of demographics on health care expenditures displays a wide cross-country dispersion. It ranges from virtually zero in Sweden to 1.6 percentage points of GDP for Korea. This can be related to differences in evolving population structures, as displayed by the changes in old-age dependency ratios (Panel B of Figure 2.4).

29. However, on average, the demographic effect only accounts for a small increase in expenditure, from 5.7% in 2005 to 6.3% by 2050, or 0.6 percentage points of GDP (Table 2.4). Admittedly, the “healthy ageing” assumption may render the simulation of demographic effects relatively optimistic, but this is in line with observed patterns of health status regimes in many OECD countries. For some countries, such as Australia, the healthy ageing hypothesis may seem less plausible in view of past trends and, therefore, the sensitivity of the results to this assumption was tested below.

[Table 2.4 Projection scenarios for public health care expenditure]

A cost pressure scenario

30. In this scenario it is assumed that, on top of the demographic effects and income effects, the expenditure residual continues to grow at 1% per year over the projection period. This induces a substantial increase in the health expenditures, averaging nearly 4 percentage points of GDP from 2005-2050. In most countries, health care expenditures would then approach or exceed 10% of GDP by the end of the projection period.

31. While these figures may be useful as a benchmark, they do not seem very plausible. It is unlikely that public health care expenditures to GDP could continue to grow at such constant rate, without limit. A long-run convergence (or transversality) condition is therefore considered in the next scenario.

A cost-containment scenario

32. In the “cost-containment” scenario it is assumed that residual expenditure growth converges to zero by 2050,20 implicitly meaning that policies are effective in controlling expenditure growth driven by some of the non-demographic factors. These policies have been already enacted in the past (see Box 3 above) and could progressively rein in the expenditure residual, for example by ensuring that future technology improvements are mainly used in a cost-saving way. In the absence of additional ageing effects, this would imply that public health care expenditure and income would evolve in parallel over the very long-run.21

20. This is roughly equivalent to assuming that the residual grows at a constant rate of ½ per cent per year.

21. This convergence assumption (or transversality condition) may appear controversial in view of past experience. The assumption is justified by the fact that the expenditure growth has to be financed by the public purse. Under perfect health market conditions, a continuing increase in the share of income going to health care spending could reflect individual preferences. But the health care market is not perfect and governments are footing most of the bill. Thus, rapid growth of the share of health care spending in income would have to be compensated by reductions in other public spending items, which may be difficult to achieve, and/or increased health care charges for individuals. Such cost sharing has already been introduced in most countries. Similar transversality conditions have also been imposed in other projection

Page 17: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

17

33. Under this rather optimistic scenario, public health care expenditures in the OECD area would still increase on average by two percentage points between 2005 and 2050, from 5.6% to 7.7% of GDP (Table 2.4). Large increases (above 2.5 percentage points of GDP) by 2050 are found (in descending order) in Korea, Slovak Republic, Mexico and Japan. Most of these countries are experiencing a rapid demographic change induced by the sharp fall in fertility rates.

Sensitivity analysis

34. In the sensitivity analysis, a number of parameters were changed compared with the "cost-containment scenario": the size of the income elasticity, the magnitude of the residual, as well as factors underlying health status scenarios and demographic projections. Overall, the previous results seem relatively robust, as these alternative simulations do not change qualitatively the picture emerging from the comparison of the "cost-pressure" and "cost-containment" scenarios discussed above.

Residuals, income elasticity and different health scenarios

35. Unsurprisingly, applying country-specific growth rates of the residual component22 would significantly affect spending patterns of individual OECD countries (Table 2.4). Korea, Mexico, Portugal, Switzerland, the United States would record significant increases (above two percentage points of GDP) compared with the "cost-containment" scenario.23 If anything, this scenario illustrates the unsustainability of current health expenditure trends in some OECD countries. In contrast, in countries where recent cost-containment policies were successful, the projected expenditure shares would tend to be more moderate than in the cost-containment scenario (e.g., Denmark, Sweden). Other countries would display large decreases in expenditures because the effect of past residual growth resulting from idiosyncratic conditions, such as the scaling back of former welfare systems during economic transition (Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovak Republic), would be prolonged in the future.

36. To assess sensitivity to income elasticity, projections were run with elasticities below and above unity (0.8 and 1.2, respectively), while keeping the residual as in the cost-containment scenario.24 Under these alternative scenarios, average OECD public health care expenditure shares would range from around 7% to 8.7% of GDP. The countries with the largest projected GDP per capita growth (e.g. Ireland, Mexico, Poland, see Table A2.1 in Annex 2A) are obviously the most affected by changes in income elasticity.

37. As discussed above, the residual was derived from trends observed over the two past decades, a period characterised by efforts to contain costs. Assuming that the residual would grow at 1.5% per year (as observed on average over the past three decades), but that it would still decline to zero over the projection period, would induce an average increase of less than one percentage point of GDP compared with the cost-containment scenario.

exercises. For example, Englert (2004) assumes that income elasticity ultimately converges to one. For symmetry, negative residuals are assumed to increase towards zero over the projection period, in the scenario with country-specific residuals.

22. Note that the residual is still assumed to converge towards zero over the projection period.

23. Given the very high historical growth rate of the residual for Turkey, this country was excluded from this simulation as it produced rather implausible shares of health care expenditures to GDP by 2050.

24. Note that when the chosen income elasticity is assumed to be changed both in the past and in the future, applying sub-unity elasticity would increase the residual when explaining past data. This means, when projecting, that the drag on expenditure growth from lower income elasticity would be offset by a higher residual, and vice versa. By construction, such scenarios would not produce very different results.

Page 18: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

18

38. Sensitivity to alternative health regimes was also explored. In a “compression of morbidity” scenario the shift in the cost curves is twice the adjustment applied in the “healthy ageing” regime. Alternatively, a regime of “expansion of morbidity” corresponds to a scenario where longevity gains are not translated into "healthy ageing". Under these scenarios, average health expenditures by 2050 range from 7 to 8.5% of GDP. This shows that alternative health regimes matter for projecting future expenditure trends, but their impact is smaller than non-demographic effects.

Alternative population projections

39. As noted in Box 4, national population projections are not based on harmonised assumptions across countries. In particular, projected longevity gains can differ widely and, on average, are also lower than observed in the past decades. Accordingly, an alternative scenario was tested where longevity is assumed to increase uniformly across countries by two years per decade, in line with past trends. These alternative population projections were derived from a stylised demographic maquette, mimicking national projections (see Gonand, 2005).

40. The simulations were carried out for five large OECD countries (France, Germany, Italy, Japan and United States). Taking again the 'cost-containment' scenario as a benchmark, the implied deviations are relatively modest (on average an increase in expenditures below ½ percentage point of GDP, see Table 2.5). This could be expected in a world of “healthy ageing”. Indeed, a framework were demographic effects are not adjusted to healthy ageing would be much more sensitive to underlying idiosyncrasies in national population projections. Nonetheless, the joint effect of an “expansion of morbidity” assumption and higher longevity gains would generate a sharp increase in expenditures, of around 1½ percentage points, compared with the “cost-containment” scenario. This stresses the important fact that it is not longevity or health status per se that could induce expenditure pressures, but rather their interaction.

[Table 2.5 Sensitivity analysis of health care expenditure to population projections]

3. Long-term care

41. Long-term care (hereafter, LTC) differs from health care. While health care services aim at changing a health condition (from unwell to well), long-term care merely aims at making the current condition (unwell) more bearable. Individuals need LTC due to disability, chronic condition, trauma, or illness, which limit their ability to carry out basic self care or personal tasks that must be performed every day. Such activities are defined as activities of daily living, ADLs (eating, dressing, bathing, getting in and out of bed, toileting and continence) or instrumental activities of daily living, IADLs (preparing own meals, cleaning, laundry, taking medication, getting to places beyond walking distance, shopping, managing money affairs and using the telephone/Internet). A person is dependent if he or she has limitations in ADLs and IADLs.

42. At around 1-2% of GDP, the importance of current public long-term care spending is limited compared with health care. Still, as LTC spending is heavily concentrated among the elderly (Wittenberg et al., 2002), the projected demographic change suggests that its share in the economy is likely to increase. As for health care, the expenditure profiles constitute the foundation of the projection framework. In contrast with health care, the cost curves for LTC are basically close to zero up to age 60-65, and then increase sharply and monotonically, with different slopes across countries (Figure 3.1). These

Page 19: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

19

characteristics stem from different features, such as the mix between (expensive) formal and (inexpensive) informal care and the current prevalence of dependency (disability status).25

[Figure 3.1 Public long-term care expenditure by age group]

Projecting demographic drivers of expenditure

43. Whereas health care projections distinguished between survivors and non-survivors, the LTC projections split each age group into dependants and non-dependants.26 Deriving the cost of LTC per dependant requires an estimate of the prevalence of dependency by age group. Unfortunately, one of the most comprehensive study in this area (Comas-Herrera et al., 2003) provides dependency figures only for Germany, Italy, Spain, and the United Kingdom. Nonetheless, it can be observed that the shape of the dependency ratios by age is similar in these four countries (Figure 3.2). This suggests that, as a first approximation, dependency ratios could be assumed to be broadly uniform across countries. For the purpose of projecting expenditure, this has also the advantage of eliminating current differences in prevalence of dependency across age groups as a possible cause for future different increases in LTC expenditures. Put differently, the projections become less sensitive to initial conditions. Along these lines, the original expenditure profiles were divided by the average cross-country dependency ratio in order to derive the LTC expenditures per dependant person (Figure 3.3).

[Figure 3.2 Prevalence of dependency per age group] [Figure 3.3 Adjusted long-term care expenditure per dependant]

44. There is a great deal of uncertainty about the extent to which disability has changed over time or could change for future generations (see Box 5). Internationally-comparable data in this area is also limited (Lagergren and Batljan, 2000; Jacobzone et al., 2000; Wittenberg et al., 2001). Moreover, disability is not necessarily translated into dependency, as the technical progress could help a disable person to work and take part in everyday life. Despite hard evidence on these phenomena, this paper assumes that the prevalence of dependency improves as life expectancy increases. However, while for health care “healthy ageing” implied that every year gained in longevity is one in good health, the assumption for dependency is not as sanguine. One could argue that for the oldest old, where dependency is most prevalent, the potential for experiencing complete healthy longevity gains is decreasing. Accordingly, the “healthy ageing” hypothesis for long-term care was (arbitrarily) assumed to be that only half of the longevity gains are translated into a reduction in dependency. Alternative scenarios allow testing the sensitivity of the results to this assumption.

25. For comprehensive discussions of long-term care, see for example OECD (2005b), Lundsgaard (2005),

Karlsson et al., (2004), Comas-Herrera et al. (2003), Norton (2000) and Wittenberg et al. (1998). Interesting UK case studies are Davies et al., (1990) and Evandrou et a,,. (1998). As an indication of the potential spending pressures, the average cost per year of institutional long-term care for old persons in France is currently at 35,000 € per dependant, and in the range of 40,000-75,000 US$ per dependant for the United States (Taleyson, 2003).

26. Indeed, even if the unit costs of long-term care per dependant are equal in, say, countries A and B, the cost curves by age group would still differ if the share of dependants in each age group is different in each country.

Page 20: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

20

Box 5. Has disability fallen over time?

Answering this question is not easy because consistent cross-country data on disability rates simply do not exist. Disability is usually measured through the inability of performing one or more Activities of Daily Living (ADL). Evidence for some OECD countries suggests that the share of the severely disabled has fallen over time, while no conclusion could be reached concerning the evolution of moderate disability. Studies on the United States, for which more data are available, show that disability rates may have declined somewhat among the oldest but have increased among younger age groups, a phenomenon that is often linked to obesity trends (cf. Rand Research Bulletin, 2004).

Nonetheless, downward trends in disability may not be accompanied by a lower pressure on expenditures. On the contrary, increased spending on health care is rather the precondition for lower disability (Lichtenberg and Virabhak, 2002; Lichtenberg, 2003; Jacobzone, 2003). Indeed, helping a chronically-ill person to be autonomous may require access to the high-cost technical frontier in bio-tech/drugs.

Projecting non-demographic drivers of expenditure

45. The main non-demographic driver of LTC expenditure is related to the relative shares of informal27 and formal care and their evolution over time.28 While the bulk of LTC is provided informally throughout the OECD area, it is relatively more important in southern European or lower income countries. As labour force participation is projected to increase in the future, concerns are expressed that informal care will have to be substituted by more expensive formal care, adding to the fiscal burden alongside the projected greying of the population (OECD, 2005b; Comas-Herrera et al., 2005).29

46. Wage trends among staff providing LTC would also be a significant driver of costs. Data from a UK study shows that staff costs in public sector homes accounted for 85% of total unit costs (Netten et al., 1998). Similarly, a study in Germany found that staff costs accounted for between 70% and 90% of total unit cost of nursing homes (Reinhold, 2001).

47. LTC is highly labour intensive, but the room for productivity gains is probably limited. Therefore, it could be exposed to a “cost disease” or Baumol (1967, 1993)'s effect. In short, this implies 27. Most informal care is provided by partners or children. To be considered informal, the provision of care

cannot be paid for as if purchasing a service. However, an informal care giver may receive income transfers conditioned on his/her provision of informal care and possibly, in practice, some informal payment from the person receiving care. On the other hand, formal care is provided by care assistants who are paid for providing care under some form of employment contract. It includes care provided in institutions as well as care provided at home. The difference between formal and informal care is first of all not about the type of care, but who provides it (Lundsgaard, 2005).

28. Due to lack of sufficiently comparable information across countries, this paper does not incorporate another important distinction, which is the subdivision of formal care into institutional care and care delivered to the patient’s home. There are indeed fundamental differences between countries in the way they organise their formal LTC. Institutional LTC is particularly widespread in the Nordic countries. Norway and Sweden stand out with substantially higher LTC spending than any other country due to generous services (single rooms and well-equipped housing infrastructure) provided for residents in nursing homes (OECD, 2005b). Whether this organisation is adopted by other countries or a (cheaper) ambulatory help-at-home strategy is pursued could have important consequences for public expenditures.

29. There are indications that the proportion of older people living alone increased up to the early 1990s, although trends appear to have changed since (Tomassini et al., 2004 and Borsch-Suppan, 2005).

Page 21: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

21

that relative prices of LTC vis-à-vis other goods and services in the economy tend to rise, reflecting the negative productivity differential and equalisation of wages across sectors. With a price-inelastic demand, the share of LTC expenditure in GDP would tend to increase over time. A possible way to capture this effect is to assume that unit costs rise in line with average earnings of care staff or a measure of wage inflation in the economy (Comas-Herrera et al., 2003).

48. It is plausible that income growth could push up LTC expenditure, although empirical evidence on the income elasticity of LTC expenditure is just not available. Considering that LTC can be characterised as a necessity, the income elasticity could be probably small or close to zero, though it could be expected that with the development of long-term care services a demand for higher quality services could also develop.

49. In order to assess the impact of these different drivers on the observed differences of LTC costs per dependant across countries, a simple econometric model was specified:30

uWZAgeNDLTCLog +⋅+⋅+⋅+=

321 βββα (3)

where LTC is total long-term care expenditure, ND, the number of dependants, Age is the central point in each age bracket (2, 7, 12,…, 97), Z a proxy capturing the provision of informal care and W a proxy for the other effects (relative prices and/or income). The model was estimated using a panel of eleven EU countries by twenty age groups. Following several alternative specification tests (not reported here), the availability of informal care appeared to be best proxied by the participation ratio of the population aged 50-64. The level of GDP per capita was included but it did not appear significant, suggesting that the income elasticity could indeed be small. Given the reduced size of the country cross-section and collinearity problems, it was not possible to test for relative price effects. The equation was first estimated with country-fixed effects (Table 3.1). In the final specification, the fixed-effects were replaced by the participation ratio of people aged 50-64. The estimates of the age and old-age participation coefficients are robust across different specifications and display the expected sign.

[Table 3.1 Econometric estimates of long-term care costs per dependant]

Combining demographic and non-demographic drivers

50. Combining the different drivers, the logarithmic growth of long-term care expenditures to GDP can be decomposed as follows:

( ) ( )ionparticipatofeffecteffectBaumolNYfactorageadjusted

YLTC

loglog

log)1()log(log

∆+∆⋅

+

∆⋅−+∆=

γ

ϕ (4)

where Y and N are income and population, as defined previously; φ is the income elasticity of LTC expenditures and γ the elasticity characterising the "Baumol effect", i.e. the extent to which an increase of average labour productivity in the economy (a proxy for wage growth) is translated into an increase of LTC costs per dependant.

30. Given that the shape of the expenditure curves by age is close to an exponential function, a log-level

specification was used.

Page 22: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

22

51. Using this framework, the drivers are allowed to operate in several ways (see Annex 2A for further details). On demographics, it was assumed that half of the projected longevity gains translated into years with lower dependency. This is accomplished by shifting the dependency curve rightwards accordingly.31

52. On non-demographics, the cost curve per dependant is assumed to shift upwards due to the increase of the average labour productivity in the economy, thus embodying an implicit “cost-disease”. In most scenarios, the elasticity of this "Baumol effect" (γ) was assumed to be 0.5, probably a mild view on the extent to which the productivity of LTC services could under-perform relatively to the rest of the economy. The income elasticity was assumed in general to be zero, implying that income growth tends to drive down LTC expenditures as a share of GDP. This set of assumptions could be viewed as a relatively optimistic.

53. The second non-demographic effect is related to the participation rate of people aged 50-64, proxying the supply of informal care. Using the econometric model (3), increasing labour market participation trends induce an additional upward shift in the LTC cost curve. The baseline projections on participation rates were derived from Burniaux et al.(2003). These projections rely on a cohort-based approach; however, the last cohort used to project participation is the one entering the labour market in year 2000. The behaviour of subsequent cohorts remains unchanged thereafter. The latter could lead to a somewhat subdued projection of future increases in participation rates, especially in countries where these rates were well below average for cohorts entering the labour market in year 2000.

Alternative scenarios for OECD countries

54. The framework described above was used to project expenditures over the period 2005-50, under a range of scenarios similar to the approach followed for the health care projections. The main assumptions underlying each scenario are listed in Table 3.2.

[Table 3.2 Assumptions underlying the alternative projection scenarios: Long-term care]

Demographic effects

55. The first simulation corresponds to demographic effects (Table 3.3). On average, LTC expenditures reach 2.3% of GDP by 2050 or an increase of 1.2 percentage points of GDP compared with 2005. Due to the sharp increase in dependency ratios with age, demographic effects contribute to a relatively much larger increase in LTC expenditures than the one observed for health care. Very large impacts of demographics on LTC expenditures (with increases from 2 to above 4 percentage points of GDP) are found in fast-ageing countries, such as Korea, Slovak Republic, Poland, Czech Republic, Poland, Turkey and Japan. As it can be seen from the detailed projection results provided in Annex 2A (Tables A2.4), the income and the Baumol effects tend to compensate for each other, their joint impact being on average neutral in terms of expenditure shares to GDP.

[Table 3.3 Projection scenarios for public long-term care expenditure]

31. Note that this method differs somewhat from what was presented earlier for health care expenditures,

where the cost profile for survivors was shifted directly in line with projected longevity gains. Here the cost profile is shifted indirectly through the shift in dependency rates.

Page 23: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

23

A cost-pressure scenario

56. This scenario assumes a 'full Baumol' effect, implying that LTC costs per dependant increase in line with overall labour productivity. Due to the steady increase in relative prices, LTC expenditures would reach 3.3% of GDP by 2050, or an increase of 2.2 percentage points of GDP compared to 2005.

A cost-containment scenario

57. In this case it is assumed that policies are able to 'contain' the cost pressures associated with the Baumol effect. It is difficult to give a clear interpretation for this policy lever, but in practical terms it means that governments would deploy a continuous effort to generate productivity gains and/or contain upward pressures on wages of staff providing long-term care. In this scenario, the supply of informal care would also continue to be relatively abundant because mild increases in the participation ratios are combined with an increase of the population in the group of 50-64 years old due to the ageing trends. Despite these optimistic assumptions, average LTC expenditures would still more than double from the current base to reach 2.4% of GDP by 2050. Much larger effects are found in countries, such as Greece, Italy, Ireland and Spain where the participation ratios of those aged 50-64 are projected to increase significantly or in countries facing strong demographic pressures, as noted previously.

Sensitivity analysis

58. Given the data uncertainties, sensitivity analysis is particularly important concerning LTC projections. A first scenario captures the possibility of higher income effects. Arbitrarily, it was assumed that the income elasticity is unitary. This would add around ½ percentage points of expenditure to GDP by 2050 compared to the cost-containment scenario.

59. As noted above, future developments in the prevalence of dependency are hard to predict. A “compression of disability” scenario was tested, where the dependency curve is shifted to the right twice as fast as longevity gains. This would reduce LTC expenditures by around ½ percentage point of GDP for the OECD group compared with "cost-containment" scenario. In an “expansion of disability” scenario, the dependency rates remain constant as life expectancy increases and the effect would be symmetrically opposite.

60. Another alternative scenario captures a possible autonomous increase in the dependency rate by 0.5% per year. This could be interpreted as a conservative estimate of the impact of the worrying obesity trends on dependency.32 On average LTC expenditures would reach 3.5% of GDP by 2050, or a significant shift of more than 1 percentage point of GDP compared to the cost-containment case.

61. In an 'increased participation' scenario, the availability of informal care is dramatically reduced by assuming that all countries converge towards an old-age participation ratio of at least 70% by 2050 (countries having already a participation ratio above that level were supposed to follow their country-specific pattern). This is well above the baseline labour participation projections and would lead to average LTC costs roughly at 4% of GDP by 2050, or an additional expenditure of 1.5 percentage points of GDP compared to the cost-containment scenario. The most significant increases would occur in countries where old-age participation ratios are currently particularly low (e.g., Austria, France, Italy, Turkey and former transition countries).

32. Sturm et al. (2004) argue that if current trends in obesity continue, disability rates will increase by 1% a

year more in the 50-59 age group than if there were no further weight gains. See also Olshansky et al. (2005) for a discussion on the effect of obesity trends on life expectancy.

Page 24: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

24

62. The comparison between this scenario and the cost-containment one gives a sense of the trade-offs involved with policies aiming at increasing participation rates, on the one hand, and the objective of containing future LTC expenditures, on the other hand. In this context, competing demands on the age group 50-64 could be particularly strong.

63. Finally, the sensitivity to alternative population projections was also tested for five OECD countries (France, Germany, Italy, Japan and the United States). Under the “healthy ageing” assumption (i.e. the dependency curves are shifted by half of the increase in life expectancy), higher longevity gains (two years per decade) per se do not have a strong impact on expenditures. Average expenditure for the five OECD countries is projected to be around 2.8% of GDP by 2050. In contrast, a scenario where higher longevity gains are coupled with an “expansion of disability” would push average LTC expenditures to above 4% of GDP by 2050.

[Table 3.4 Sensitivity analysis of long-term care expenditure to population projections]

64. To sum-up, the sensitivity analysis showed that the long-term care projections presented here seem relatively robust to alternative specifications of the income elasticity, health status and longevity assumptions. In contrast, increased dependency associated with obesity trends or lower provision of informal care could have a much stronger impact on expenditures. A combination of these negative factors would obviously generate a rather gloomy perspective for public budgets.

Page 25: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

25

REFERENCES

Aprile, R. (2004), “How to Take Account of Death-Related Costs in Projecting Health Care Expenditure – Updated Version”, Ragioneria Generale Dello Stato.

Batljan, I. and M. Lagergren 2004), “Inpatient/Outpatient Health Care Costs and Remaining Years of Life – Effect of Decreasing Mortality on Future Acute Health Care Demand”, Social Science & Medicine 59: 2459-2466.

Baumol, W.J. 1967), “Macroeconomics of Unbalanced Growth: The Anatomy of Urban Crisis”, American Economic Review 57: 415-426.

Baumol, W.J. (1993), “Health Care, Education and the Cost of Disease: A Looming Crisis for Public Choice,” Public Choice 77:17-28.

Borsch-Suppan, A. (2005), Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe, Manheim Research Institute for the Economics of Ageing, Manheim.

Burniaux, J.-M., R. Duval and F. Jaumotte (2003), “Coping with Ageing: a Dynamic Approach to Quantify the Impact of Alternative Policy Options on Future Labour Supply in OECD Countries”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 371.

Comas-Herrera and R. Wittenberg, eds., (2003), European study of Long-Term Care Expenditure: Investigating the Sensitivity of Projections of Future Long-Term Care Expenditure in Germany, Spain, Italy and the United Kingdom to Changes in Assumptions About Demography, Dependency, Informal Care, Formal Care and Unit Costs, PSSRU, LSE Health and Social Care, London School of Economics.

Comas-Herrera, A. R. Wittenberg and L. Pickard (2005), “Making Projections of Public Expenditure on Long-Term Care for the European Member States: Methodological Proposals for Discussion”, LSE Health and Social Care, London.

Culyer, A.J. (1990), “Cost Containment in Europe”, Health Care Systems in Transition, OECD, Paris.

Cutler, D. (2001), “The Reduction in Disability among the Elderly”, Proceedings of the National Academy of Science, Vol. 98, No. 12, June.

Dang, T.T., P. Antolin and H. Oxley (2001), “Fiscal Implications Ageing: Projections of Age-Related Spending”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers No.305, Paris.

Davies, B., E. Ferlie, M. Hughes and J. Twigg (1990), Resources, Needs and Outcomes in Community-based care: a comparative study of the production of welfare for elderly people in ten local authorities in England and Wales, Avebury, Aldershot.

Docteur, E. and H. Oxley (2003), “Health-care systems: lessons from the reform experience”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 374.

Page 26: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

26

Dormont, B. and H. Huber (2005), “Ageing and Changes in medical practices: reassessing the influence of demography”, mimeo, THEMA University of Paris X, Paris.

Economic Policy Committee (2001), Budgetary Challenges Posed by Ageing Populations: The Impact on Public Spending on Pensions, Health and Long-term Care for the Elderly and Possible Indicators of the Long-term Sustainability of Public Finances, EPC/ECFIN/655/01-EN final, October.

Englert, M. (2004), “Assessing the Budgetary Cost of Ageing and Projecting Health Care (+ Care for Elderly) Expenditure: The Belgian experience”, Federal Planning Bureau, Brussels.

Evandrou, M. and D. Winter (1998), The Distribution of Domiciliary and Primary Health Care in Britain: Preliminary Results on Modelling Resource Allocation in the Welfare State, LSE, Welfare State Programme, WSP/26, London.

EC-Economic Policy Committee (2001), "Budgetary challenges posed by Ageing Populations", EPC/ECFIN/655/01-EN.

EC- Economic Policy Committee (2005), "The 2005 EPC Projection of age-related expenditure: Agreed underlying assumptions and projection methodologies", European Economy, Occasional Papers no. 19.

Fries, J.F. (1980), "Ageing, natural death, and the compression of morbidity", New England Journal of Medicine 303: 130-135.

Fuchs, V. (1972), Essays in the Economics of Health and Medical Care, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York.

Fuchs, V. (1984), “Though Much is Taken Reflections on Ageing, Health and Medical Care”, NBER Working Paper No.1269.

Gerdtham, U., J. ogaard., F. nderson and B. onsson (1992), “An Econometric Analysis of Health Care Expenditure: A Cross-Section Study of the OECD Countries”, Journal of Health Economics, Vol.11, No.1, pp.63-84.

Getzen, T. (2000), “Health Care is an Individual Necessity and a National Luxury: Applying Multilevel Decision Models to the Analysis of Health Care Expenditure”, Journal of Health Economics 19, pp.259-270.

Gonand, F. (2005), "Assessing the Robustness of Demographic Projections in OECD Countries", OECD Economics Department Working Papers no. 464.

Gray, A. (2004), Estimating the impact of ageing populations on future health expenditures, Public lecture to the National Institute of Economics and Business and the National Institute of Health and Human Science, 4 November, Canberra.

Grice, J. (2005), "The Atkinson Review: Measurement of Government Output in National Accounts", in OECD Statistics Newsletter, No. 26, April.

Grunenberg, E.M. (1977), “The failure of success”, Milbank Memorial Fund Q. Health Soc. 55: 3-24.

Health Canada (2001), “Ageing and the financial pressures on the health care system”, Health Policy Research Bulletin, Vol. 1, Issue 1, March.

Page 27: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

27

Hitiris, T. and J. Posnett (1992), “The determinants and effects of health expenditure in developed countries”, Journal of Health Economics, Vol. 11, No. 2, pp.173-81.

Jacobzone, S. (2003), “Ageing and the Challenges of New Technologies: Can OECD Social and Health Care Systems Provide for the Future? “, The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, Vol. 28, No. 2, April, pp.254-74.

Jacobzone, S., E. Cambois and J.M. Robine (2000), “Is the health of older persons in the OECD countries improving fast enough to compensate for population ageing?”, OECD Economic Studies No. 30, Paris.

Jönsson, B. and I. Eckerlund (2003), “Why do different countries spend different amounts on health care?”, A Disease-based Comparison of Health Systems, OECD, Paris.

Karlsson, M., L. Mayhew, R. Plumb, B. Rickayzen (2004), An international Comparison of long-term care arrangements, Cass Business School, City University, London.

KPMG Consulting (2001), Impact of New Technology on Victorian Public Hospital Costs, Report to the Victorian Department of Human Services, September.

Lagergren, M. and I. Batljan (2000), Will Tthere Be a Helping Hand? Macroeconomic Scenarios of Future Needs and Costs of Health and Social Care for the Elderly in Sweden 2000-30, Annex 8 to the Long-term Survey 1999/2000, Stockholm.

Lichtenberg, F.R. (2003), “The Impact of New Drug Launches on Longevity: Evidence From Longitudinal, Disease-Level Data From 52 Countries, 1982-2001”, NBER Working Paper Series No. 9754.

Lichtenberg, F.R. and S. Virabhak (2002), “Pharmaceutical Embodied Technical Progress, Longevity, and Quality of Life: Drugs As “Equipment For Your Health”, NBER Working Paper Series No. 9351.

Lundsgaard, J. (2005), “Consumer Direction and Choice in Long-Term Care for Older Persons, Including Payments for Informal Care: How Can it Help Improve Care Outcomes, Employment and Fiscal Sustainability?”, OECD Health Working Papers No. 20, Paris.

Manton, K.G. (1982), “Changing Concepts of Morbidity and Mortality in the Elderly Population”, Milbank Memorial Fund Q. Health Soc. 60: 183-244.

Michel, J.-P. and J.-M. Robine (2004), “A ‘New’ General Theory of Population Ageing”, The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance Vol. 29 No. 4 (October), pp.667–678.

Moise, P. and S. Jacobzone (2003), “Population Ageing, Health Expenditure and Treatment: an ARD Perspective”, A Disease-based Comparison of Health Systems, OECD, Paris.

Mushkin, E.P. and J.S. Landefeld (1979), Biomedical Research: Costs and Benefits, Ballinger Publishing Company, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

Netten, A., A. Bebbington, R. Darton, J. Forder and K. Miles (1998), 1996 Survey of Care Homes for Elderly People: Final Report, Discussion Paper 1423/2, PSSRU: University of Kent.

Newhouse (1992), “Medical Care Costs: How Much Welfare Loss?”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 6, No. 3, pp.3-21.

Page 28: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

28

Norton, E.C. (2000), “Long-Term Care”, in Culyer, A.J. and J.P. Newhouse (eds.), Handbook of Health Economics, Vol.1B, Elsevier, North-Holland.

OECD (2005a), Health Database, Paris.

OECD (2005b), Long-term Care for Older People, Paris.

Oliveira Martins, J., F. Gonand, P. Antolin, C. de la Maisonneuve and K. Yoo (2005), “The Impact of Ageing in Demand, Factor Markets and Growth”, OECD Economics Department Working Papers No. 420.

Olshansky, J. et al. (2005), "A potential decline in Life Expectancy in the United States in the 21st Century", The New England Journal of Medicine, 352:11.

Productivity Commission (2005a), Economic Implications of an Ageing Australia, Research Report, Canberra.

Productivity Commission (2005b), Impacts of Medical Technology in Australia, Progress Report, Melbourne, April.

Rand Research Bulletin (2004), “Obesity and Disability: The Shape of Things to Come”, RB-9043.

Reinhold, W. (2001), Controlling in Pflegeeinrichtungen: “Operatives Controlling für pflegeleistungen in stationaren pflegeeinrichtungen”, Lage: Jacobs, cited in Comas-Herrera and Wittenberg (2003).

Richardson, J. and I. Robertson (1999), “Ageing and the Cost of Health Services”, in Policy Implications of the Ageing of Australia’s Population, Productivity Commission and Melbourne Institute, Canberra.

Robine, J.M. and J.P. Michel (2004), “A ‘new’ general theory of population ageing”, The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, Vol. 29, No. 4, October, pp.667-678.

Seshamani, M. and A.M. Gray (2004), “A longitudinal study of the effects of age and time to death on hospital costs”, Journal of Health Economics, March, Vol. 23, No. 2, pp.217-35.

Sheehan, P. (2002), “Health Costs, Innovation and Ageing”, Pharmaceutical Industry Working Paper Series No. 9, Centre for Strategic Economic Studies, Victoria University of Technology, Melbourne.

Sturm, R. and D. Lakdawalla (2004), “Swollen Waistlines, Swollen Costs. Obesity Worsens Disabilities and Weighs on Health Budgets”, RAND review, Spring, 2004.

Taleyson, L. (2003),“Private Long-Term Care Insurance- International Comparisons”, Health and Ageing No. 8, Geneva Association Information Newsletter, March.

Tomassini, C., K. Glaser, D.A. Wolf, M. Broese van Groenou and E. Grundy (2004), “Living Arrangements Among Older People: An Overview of Trends in Europe and the USA”, Population Trends 115: 22-34.

Wanless, D. (2001), Securing our Future Health: Taking a Long-Term View, Interim Report, HM Treasury, London.

Page 29: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

29

Westerhout, E. and F. Pellikaan (2005), “Can We Afford to Live Longer in Better Health?”, Netherlands Bureau for Economic Policy Analysis, Document No. 85, June.

Wittenberg, R., B. Sandhu and M. Knapp (2002), “Funding Long-Term Care: The Public and Private Options”, in (eds) Mossialos, E., A. Dixon, J. Figueras and J. Kutzin, Funding Health Care: Options for Europe, Open University Press: Buckingham.

Wittenberg, R., L. Pickard, A. Comas-Herrera, B. Davies and R. Darton (2001), “Demand for Long-Term Care for Elderly People in England to 2031”, Health Statistics Quarterly 12: 5-16.

Wittenberg, R., L. Pickard, A. Comas-Herrera, B. Davies and R. Norton (1998), Demand for Long-Term Care: Projections of Long-Term Care Finance for Elderly People, PSSRU: University of Kent.

Zwiefel, P.S. Felder and M. Meirs (1999), “Ageing of Population and Health Care Expenditure: A Red Herring?”, Health Economics, Vol. 8, pp.485-96.

Page 30: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

30

ANNEX 1. LIST OF TABLES AND FIGURES

Tables

1.1 Public health and long-term care spending 2.1 Decomposing growth in public health spending, 1981-2002 2.2 Decomposing growth in public health spending, 1970-2002 2.3 Assumptions underlying the alternative projection scenarios: health care 2.4 Projection scenarios for public health care expenditure 2.5 Sensitivity analysis of health care expenditure to population projections 3.1 Econometric estimates of long-term care costs per dependant 3.2 Assumptions underlying the alternative projection scenarios: long-term care 3.3 Projection scenarios for public long-term care expenditure 3.4 Sensitivity analysis of long-term care expenditure to population projections

Figures

1.1 Evolution of public and private OECD health spending 1.2 Total increase in health and long-term care spending, 2005-2050 1.3 Drivers of total health and long-term care spending: key components 2.1 Public health care expenditure by age groups 2.2 Breakdown of the health care cost curve 2.3 Shifts in expenditure profiles, ageing and non-ageing effects 2.4 Demographic effects on health care expenditure 3.1 Public long-term care expenditure by age group 3.2 Prevalence of dependency by age group 3.3 Adjusted long-term care expenditure per dependant

Page 31: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

31

Tabl

e 1.

1 Pu

blic

hea

lth a

nd lo

ng-te

rm c

are

spen

ding

In %

of G

DP

Hea

lth c

are

Long

term

car

eTo

tal

2050

2050

2050

2005

Cos

t-pre

ssur

eC

ost-

cont

ainm

ent

2005

Cos

t-pre

ssur

eC

ost-

cont

ainm

ent

2005

Cos

t-pre

ssur

eC

ost-

cont

ainm

ent

Aust

ralia

5.

69.

77.

90.

92.

92.

06.

512

.69.

9Au

stria

3.8

7.6

5.7

1.3

3.3

2.5

5.1

10.9

8.2

Belg

ium

5.

79.

07.

21.

53.

42.

67.

212

.49.

8C

anad

a6.

210

.28.

41.

23.

22.

47.

313

.510

.8C

zech

Rep

ublic

7.

011

.29.

40.

42.

01.

37.

413

.210

.7

Den

mar

k 5.

38.

87.

02.

64.

13.

37.

912

.910

.3Fi

nlan

d3.

47.

05.

22.

95.

24.

26.

212

.29.

3Fr

ance

7.0

10.6

8.7

1.1

2.8

2.0

8.1

13.4

10.8

Ger

man

y7.

811

.49.

61.

02.

92.

28.

814

.311

.8G

reec

e 4.

98.

76.

90.

22.

82.

05.

011

.68.

9

Hun

gary

6.

710

.38.

50.

32.

41.

07.

012

.69.

5Ic

elan

d6.

810

.78.

92.

94.

43.

49.

615

.212

.3Ire

land

5.9

10.0

8.2

0.7

4.6

3.2

6.7

14.5

11.3

Italy

6.0

9.7

7.9

0.6

3.5

2.8

6.6

13.2

10.7

Japa

n 6.

010

.38.

50.

93.

12.

46.

913

.410

.9

Kore

a 3.

07.

86.

00.

34.

13.

13.

311

.99.

1Lu

xem

bour

g6.

19.

98.

00.

73.

82.

66.

813

.710

.6M

exic

o 3.

07.

55.

70.

14.

23.

03.

111

.78.

7N

ethe

rland

s5.

18.

97.

01.

73.

72.

96.

812

.59.

9N

ew Z

eala

nd6.

010

.18.

30.

52.

41.

76.

412

.610

.0

Nor

way

7.3

10.7

8.9

2.6

4.3

3.5

9.9

15.0

12.4

Pola

nd4.

48.

56.

70.

53.

71.

84.

912

.28.

5Po

rtuga

l6.

710

.99.

10.

22.

21.

36.

913

.110

.4Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

5.1

9.7

7.9

0.3

2.6

1.5

5.4

12.3

9.4

Spai

n5.

59.

67.

80.

22.

61.

95.

612

.19.

6

Swed

en5.

38.

56.

73.

34.

33.

48.

612

.910

.1Sw

itzer

land

6.

29.

67.

81.

22.

61.

97.

412

.39.

7Tu

rkey

5.

99.

98.

10.

11.

80.

86.

011

.78.

9U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m6.

19.

77.

91.

13.

02.

17.

212

.710

.0U

nite

d St

ates

6.

39.

77.

90.

92.

71.

87.

212

.49.

7

Ave

rage

5.7

9.6

7.7

1.1

3.3

2.4

6.7

12.8

10.1

Sour

ce: S

ecre

taria

t cal

cula

tions

.

Page 32: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

32

Table 2.1 Decomposing growth in public health spending 1 , 1981-2002 2

Health spending Age effect Income effect 3 Residual

Australia (1981-2001) 3.6 0.4 1.8 1.4Austria 2.2 0.1 2.1 0.0Belgium (1995-2002) 2.9 0.4 1.7 0.6Canada 2.6 0.4 1.7 0.6Czech Republic (1993-2002) 2.7 0.4 2.8 -0.4

Denmark 1.3 0.1 1.7 -0.5Finland 2.6 0.3 2.1 0.2France 2.8 0.2 1.6 1.0Germany 2.2 0.2 1.2 1.0Greece (1987-2002) 3.4 0.4 1.3 0.8

Hungary (1991-2002) 1.5 0.3 2.8 -1.5Iceland 3.5 0.1 1.5 1.9Ireland 3.9 0.1 4.9 -1.0Italy (1988-2002) 2.1 0.7 1.7 -0.1Japan (1981-2001) 3.8 0.4 2.2 1.1

Korea (1982-2002) 10.1 1.4 6.1 2.4Luxembourg (1981-2002) 3.8 0.0 3.9 -0.1Mexico (1990-2002) 4.5 0.7 0.5 2.4Netherlands (1981-2002) 2.6 0.3 1.9 0.3New Zealand 2.7 0.2 1.5 1.0

Norway 4.0 0.1 2.5 1.5Poland (1990-2002) 3.1 0.5 3.2 -0.6Portugal 5.9 0.4 2.6 2.8Slovak Republic (1997-2002) 2.1 0.5 4.2 -1.5Spain 3.4 0.3 2.3 0.8

Sweden 1.5 0.1 1.7 -0.4Switzerland (1985-2002) 3.8 0.2 0.8 2.9Turkey (1984-2002) 11.0 0.3 2.3 8.3United Kingdom 3.4 0.2 2.3 1.0United States 4.7 0.1 2.0 2.6

Average 3.6 0.3 2.3 1.0

1. Total public health spending per capita.2. Or the longest overlapping period available.3. Assuming an income elasticity of health expenditure equal to 1.Source : OECD Health Database (2004), ENPRI-AGIR and Secretariat calculations.

Page 33: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

33

Table 2.2 Decomposing growth in public health spending 1, 1970-2002 2

Health spending Age effect Income effect 3 Residual

Australia (1971-2001) 4.0 0.5 1.7 1.7Austria 4.2 0.2 2.5 1.5Belgium (1995-2002) 2.9 0.4 2.2 0.6Canada 3.1 0.6 2.1 0.4Czech Republic (1993-2002) 2.7 0.4 2.8 -0.4

Denmark (1971-2002) 1.9 0.2 1.6 0.1Finland 3.4 0.6 2.4 0.5France 3.9 0.3 1.9 1.6Germany 3.7 0.3 1.6 1.9Greece (1987-2002) 3.4 0.4 2.1 0.8

Hungary (1991-2002) 1.5 0.3 2.8 -1.5Iceland 6.1 0.1 2.7 3.2Ireland 5.3 0.0 4.4 0.9Italy (1988-2002) 2.1 0.7 2.2 -0.1Japan (1970-2001) 4.9 0.6 2.6 1.8

Korea (1982-2002) 10.1 1.4 6.0 2.4Luxembourg (1975-2002) 4.2 0.0 3.3 0.7Mexico (1990-2002) 4.5 0.7 1.7 2.4Netherlands (1972-2002) 3.3 0.4 2.0 0.9New Zealand 2.9 0.2 1.2 1.4

Norway 5.4 0.1 3.0 2.2Poland (1990-2002) 3.1 0.5 3.2 -0.6Portugal 8.0 0.5 2.9 4.4Slovak Republic (1997-2002) 2.1 0.5 4.2 -1.5Spain 5.4 0.4 2.4 2.5

Sweden 2.5 0.3 1.6 0.7Switzerland (1985-2002) 3.8 0.2 0.9 2.9Turkey (1984-2002) 11.6 0.3 2.1 8.3United Kingdom 3.8 0.1 2.1 1.5United States 5.1 0.3 2.1 2.7

Average 4.3 0.4 2.5 1.5

1. Total public health spending per capita.2. Or the longest overlapping period available.3. Assuming an income elasticity of health expenditure equal to 1.Source : OECD Health Database (2004), ENPRI-AGIR and Secretariat calculations.

Page 34: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

34

Tabl

e 2.

3 As

sum

ptio

ns u

nder

lyin

g th

e al

tern

ativ

e pr

ojec

tion

scen

ario

s: H

ealth

car

e

Scen

ario

s H

ealth

Sta

tus

Inco

me

elas

ticity

Ex

pend

iture

resi

dual

Dem

ogra

phic

effe

ct

Hea

lthy

agei

ng: l

onge

vity

gai

ns a

re tr

ansl

ated

into

eq

uiva

lent

add

ition

al y

ears

in g

ood

heal

th

Inco

me

elas

ticity

is e

qual

to 1

n.a.

Cos

t-pre

ssur

e sc

enar

io

Hea

lthy

agei

ng: l

onge

vity

gai

ns a

re tr

ansl

ated

into

eq

uiva

lent

add

ition

al y

ears

in g

ood

heal

th

Inco

me

elas

ticity

is e

qual

to 1

The

expe

nditu

re re

sidu

al g

row

s at

1%

per

ye

ar o

ver t

he p

roje

ctio

n pe

riod

Cos

t-con

tain

men

t sce

nario

H

ealth

y ag

eing

: lon

gevi

ty g

ains

are

tran

slat

ed in

to

equi

vale

nt a

dditi

onal

yea

rs in

goo

d he

alth

Inco

me

elas

ticity

is e

qual

to 1

Res

idua

l gro

wth

is e

qual

to 1

% in

200

5 an

d co

nver

ges

to 0

by

2050

(tra

nsve

rsal

ity c

ondi

tion)

Cou

ntry

-spe

cific

resi

dual

s H

ealth

y ag

eing

: lon

gevi

ty g

ains

are

tran

slat

ed in

to

equi

vale

nt a

dditi

onal

yea

rs in

goo

d he

alth

Inco

me

elas

ticity

is e

qual

to 1

Res

idua

l gro

wth

is c

ount

ry-s

peci

fic a

nd

conv

erge

s to

0 b

y 20

50 (t

rans

vers

ality

co

nditi

on)

Inco

me

elas

ticity

= 0

.8

Hea

lthy

agei

ng: l

onge

vity

gai

ns a

re tr

ansl

ated

into

eq

uiva

lent

add

ition

al y

ears

in g

ood

heal

th

Inco

me

elas

ticity

is e

qual

to 0

.8

R

esid

ual g

row

th is

equ

al to

1%

in 2

005

and

conv

erge

s to

0 b

y 20

50 (t

rans

vers

ality

con

ditio

n)

Inco

me

elas

ticity

= 1

.2

Hea

lthy

agei

ng: l

onge

vity

gai

ns a

re tr

ansl

ated

into

eq

uiva

lent

add

ition

al y

ears

in g

ood

heal

th

Inco

me

elas

ticity

is e

qual

to 1

.2

R

esid

ual g

row

th is

equ

al to

1%

in 2

005

and

conv

erge

s to

0 b

y 20

50 (t

rans

vers

ality

con

ditio

n)

Res

idua

ls a

t 1.5

%

Hea

lthy

agei

ng: l

onge

vity

gai

ns a

re tr

ansl

ated

into

eq

uiva

lent

add

ition

al y

ears

in g

ood

heal

th

Inco

me

elas

ticity

is e

qual

to 1

Res

idua

l gro

wth

is e

qual

to 1

.5%

in 2

005

and

conv

erge

s to

0 b

y 20

50 (t

rans

vers

ality

co

nditi

on)

Com

pres

sion

of m

orbi

dity

Lo

ngev

ity g

ains

are

dou

bled

into

add

ition

al y

ears

in

good

hea

lth

Inco

me

elas

ticity

is e

qual

to 1

Res

idua

l gro

wth

is e

qual

to 1

% in

200

5 an

d co

nver

ges

to 0

by

2050

(tra

nsve

rsal

ity c

ondi

tion)

Expa

nsio

n of

mor

bidi

ty

No

heal

thy

agei

ng a

djus

tmen

t, i.e

. lon

gevi

ty g

ains

do

not t

rans

late

into

add

ition

al y

ears

in g

ood

heal

th

Inco

me

elas

ticity

is e

qual

to 1

Res

idua

l gro

wth

is e

qual

to 1

% in

200

5 an

d co

nver

ges

to 0

by

2050

(tra

nsve

rsal

ity c

ondi

tion)

NB

: The

key

ass

umpt

ion

chan

ged

in e

ach

scen

ario

is in

bol

d.

Page 35: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

35

Tabl

e 2.

4. P

roje

ctio

n sc

enar

ios

for p

ublic

hea

lth c

are

expe

nditu

re 1

In %

of G

DP

Sens

itivi

ty a

nalys

is

Dem

ogra

phic

ef

fect

Cos

t-pr

essu

reC

ost-

cont

ainm

ent

Cou

ntry

-sp

ecifi

c re

sidu

als

Inco

me

elas

ticity

=0.8

Inco

me

elas

ticity

=1.2

Res

idua

ls a

t 1.

5%C

ompr

essi

on o

f m

orbi

dity

Expa

nsio

n of

m

orbi

dity

2005

220

50

Aust

ralia

5.6

6.5

9.7

7.9

8.5

7.1

8.9

8.7

7.1

8.7

Aust

ria3.

84.

47.

65.

74.

45.

06.

66.

65.

06.

7Be

lgiu

m5.

75.

89.

07.

26.

76.

48.

18.

06.

48.

2C

anad

a6.

27.

010

.28.

47.

87.

69.

39.

27.

99.

1C

zech

Rep

ublic

7.0

8.0

11.2

9.4

7.5

8.9

9.9

10.2

8.5

10.3

Den

mar

k5.

35.

68.

87.

05.

16.

27.

97.

86.

47.

6Fi

nlan

d3.

43.

87.

05.

24.

14.

36.

36.

04.

46.

1Fr

ance

7.0

7.3

10.6

8.7

8.7

8.1

9.5

9.6

7.8

9.8

Ger

man

y7.

88.

211

.49.

69.

68.

910

.310

.49.

010

.4G

reec

e4.

95.

58.

76.

96.

66.

17.

97.

76.

47.

5

Hun

gary

6.7

7.1

10.3

8.5

5.4

7.5

9.6

9.3

7.6

9.6

Icel

and

6.8

7.5

10.7

8.9

10.5

7.9

10.1

9.7

8.5

9.3

Irela

nd5.

96.

810

.08.

25.

66.

99.

89.

07.

78.

8Ita

ly6.

06.

59.

77.

96.

47.

38.

68.

76.

89.

2Ja

pan

6.0

7.1

10.3

8.5

8.7

7.9

9.1

9.3

7.9

9.0

Kore

a3.

04.

67.

86.

08.

65.

36.

96.

84.

87.

3Lu

xem

bour

g6.

16.

69.

98.

06.

66.

99.

48.

97.

58.

6M

exic

o3.

04.

37.

55.

78.

34.

47.

36.

54.

96.

5N

ethe

rland

s5.

15.

78.

97.

06.

16.

38.

07.

96.

87.

4N

ew Z

eala

nd6.

06.

910

.18.

38.

47.

69.

19.

17.

79.

1

Nor

way

7.3

7.5

10.7

8.9

9.6

8.1

9.8

9.7

8.1

9.7

Pola

nd4.

45.

38.

56.

74.

65.

58.

27.

55.

58.

2Po

rtuga

l6.

77.

710

.99.

112

.68.

310

.19.

98.

49.

9Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

5.1

6.5

9.7

7.9

4.9

7.2

8.6

8.7

6.8

9.0

Spai

n5.

56.

49.

67.

87.

57.

18.

58.

67.

28.

3

Swed

en5.

35.

38.

56.

74.

95.

97.

77.

56.

37.

3Sw

itzer

land

6.2

6.4

9.6

7.8

11.4

7.1

8.6

8.6

7.4

8.4

Turk

ey5.

96.

79.

98.

1n.

a7.

39.

18.

97.

39.

2U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m6.

16.

59.

77.

97.

97.

18.

88.

77.

18.

7U

nite

d St

ates

6.3

6.5

9.7

7.9

10.8

7.1

8.9

8.7

7.3

8.6

Ave

rage

5.7

6.3

9.6

7.7

7.5

6.9

8.7

8.5

7.0

8.5

1. F

or th

e de

finiti

on o

f the

diff

eren

t sce

nario

s se

e ta

ble

2.3.

2. E

stim

ates

, tak

ing

into

acc

ount

the

obse

rved

exp

endi

ture

gro

wth

bet

wee

n 20

00 a

nd 2

003

(or 2

002

if no

t ava

ilabl

e).

Sour

ce: S

ecre

taria

t cal

cula

tions

.

Page 36: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

36

Table 2.5 Sensitivity analysis of health care expenditure to population projectionsAssuming longevity gains of 2 years per decade

(In % of GDP)

Healthy ageing Expansion of morbidity

2005 1 2050

France 7.0 8.8 9.8Germany 7.8 9.6 10.7Italy 6.0 8.1 9.2Japan 6.0 8.4 9.5United States 6.3 7.7 8.6

Average 6.6 8.5 9.6

1. Estimates, taking into account the observed expenditure growth between 2000 and 2003 (or 2002 if not available).Source: Secretariat calculations.

Page 37: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

37

Table 3.1. Econometric estimates of long-term care costs per dependant

Log of long-term care cost per dependant

Fixed effects

Robust OLS with age-invariant explanatory variables

Age

0.0335*** (0.0014)

0.0348*** (0.0025)

0.0345*** (0.0023)

Participation ratio of people aged 50-64

0.0394*** (0.0054)

0.0378*** (0.0066)

GDP per capita

0.0748

(0.0509)

Constant

6.433*** (0.079)

4.217*** (0.380)

2.356* (1.317)

Number of countries

Number of age groups

Number of Obs.

11

20

185

R-squared

0.77

(within)

0.62

0.62

Note: *** significant at 1% and * significant at 10 %. Standard errors in parentheses

Page 38: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

38

Tabl

e 3.

2 As

sum

ptio

ns u

nder

lyin

g th

e al

tern

ativ

e pr

ojec

tion

scen

ario

s: L

ong-

term

car

e

Sc

enar

ios

H

ealth

Sta

tus

Part

icip

atio

n ra

tes

(pro

xy fo

r ava

ilabi

lity

of in

form

al c

are)

Inco

me

and

'cos

t dis

ease

' effe

cts

Dem

ogra

phic

effe

ct

Hea

lthy

agei

ng: t

he p

reva

lenc

e of

dep

ende

ncy

per

age

is s

hifte

d by

½ y

ear e

very

10

year

s (a

ppro

xim

atel

y ha

lf of

the

proj

ecte

d lo

ngev

ity g

ains

)

n.a.

Lo

ng-te

rm c

are

cost

s pe

r dep

ende

nt in

crea

se b

y ha

lf o

f ave

rage

labo

ur p

rodu

ctiv

ity

(par

tial B

aum

ol e

ffect

) In

com

e el

astic

ity e

qual

to z

ero

Cos

t-pre

ssur

e sc

enar

io

Hea

lthy

agei

ng: t

he p

reva

lenc

e of

dep

ende

ncy

per

age

is s

hifte

d by

½ y

ear e

very

10

year

s

Parti

cipa

tion

rate

s of

peo

ple

aged

50-

64 in

crea

se

in li

ne w

ith b

asel

ine

labo

ur fo

rce

proj

ectio

ns

Long

-term

car

e co

sts

per d

epen

dent

incr

ease

in

line

with

ave

rage

labo

ur p

rodu

ctiv

ity

(full

Bau

mol

effe

ct)

Inco

me

elas

ticity

equ

al to

zer

o

Cos

t-con

tain

men

t sce

nario

H

ealth

y ag

eing

: the

pre

vale

nce

of d

epen

denc

y pe

r ag

e is

shi

fted

by ½

yea

r eve

ry 1

0 ye

ars

Parti

cipa

tion

rate

s of

peo

ple

aged

50-

64 in

crea

se

in li

ne w

ith b

asel

ine

labo

ur fo

rce

proj

ectio

ns

Long

-term

car

e co

sts

per d

epen

dent

incr

ease

by

half

of a

vera

ge la

bour

pro

duct

ivity

(p

artia

l Bau

mol

effe

ct)

Inco

me

elas

ticity

equ

al to

zer

o

Uni

tary

inco

me

elas

ticity

H

ealth

y ag

eing

: the

pre

vale

nce

of d

epen

denc

y pe

r ag

e is

shi

fted

by ½

yea

r eve

ry 1

0 ye

ars

Parti

cipa

tion

rate

s of

peo

ple

aged

50-

64 in

crea

se

in li

ne w

ith b

asel

ine

labo

ur fo

rce

proj

ectio

ns

Long

-term

car

e co

sts

per d

epen

dent

incr

ease

by

half

of a

vera

ge la

bour

pro

duct

ivity

(p

artia

l Bau

mol

effe

ct)

Inco

me

elas

ticity

equ

al to

one

Com

pres

sion

of d

isab

ility

Th

e pr

eval

ence

of d

epen

denc

y pe

r age

is s

hifte

d by

1 y

ear e

very

10

year

s

Parti

cipa

tion

rate

s of

peo

ple

aged

50-

64 in

crea

se

in li

ne w

ith b

asel

ine

labo

ur fo

rce

proj

ectio

ns

Long

-term

car

e co

sts

per d

epen

dent

incr

ease

by

half

of a

vera

ge la

bour

pro

duct

ivity

(p

artia

l Bau

mol

effe

ct)

Inco

me

elas

ticity

equ

al to

zer

o

Expa

nsio

n of

dis

abili

ty

No

heal

thy

agei

ng a

djus

tmen

t, i.e

. the

pr

eval

ence

of d

epen

denc

y re

mai

ns c

onst

ant

over

tim

e

Parti

cipa

tion

rate

s of

peo

ple

aged

50-

64 in

crea

se

in li

ne w

ith b

asel

ine

labo

ur fo

rce

proj

ectio

ns

Long

-term

car

e co

sts

per d

epen

dent

incr

ease

by

half

of a

vera

ge la

bour

pro

duct

ivity

(p

artia

l Bau

mol

effe

ct)

Inco

me

elas

ticity

equ

al to

zer

o

Incr

ease

in d

epen

denc

y H

ealth

y ag

eing

: the

pre

vale

nce

of d

epen

denc

y pe

r ag

e is

shi

fted

by ½

yea

r eve

ry 1

0 ye

ars,

but

de

pend

ency

rate

s ar

e as

sum

ed to

incr

ease

by

0.5%

per

yea

r

Parti

cipa

tion

rate

s of

peo

ple

aged

50-

64 in

crea

se

in li

ne w

ith b

asel

ine

labo

ur fo

rce

proj

ectio

ns

Long

-term

car

e co

sts

per d

epen

dent

incr

ease

by

half

of a

vera

ge la

bour

pro

duct

ivity

(p

artia

l Bau

mol

effe

ct)

Inco

me

elas

ticity

equ

al to

zer

o

Incr

ease

d pa

rtic

ipat

ion

Hea

lthy

agei

ng: t

he p

reva

lenc

e of

dep

ende

ncy

per

age

is s

hifte

d by

½ y

ear e

very

10

year

s

Part

icip

atio

n ra

tes

of p

eopl

e ag

ed 5

0-64

co

nver

ge to

at l

east

70%

by

2050

in a

ll co

untr

ies

Long

-term

car

e co

sts

per d

epen

dent

incr

ease

by

half

of a

vera

ge la

bour

pro

duct

ivity

(p

artia

l Bau

mol

effe

ct)

Inco

me

elas

ticity

equ

al to

zer

o

NB

: The

key

ass

umpt

ion

chan

ged

in e

ach

scen

ario

is in

bol

d.

Page 39: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

39

Tabl

e 3.

3 P

roje

ctio

n sc

enar

ios

for p

ublic

long

-term

car

e ex

pend

iture

1

In %

of G

DP

Sens

itivi

ty a

nalys

is

Dem

ogra

phic

ef

fect

Cos

t-pre

ssur

eC

ost-c

onta

inm

ent

Uni

tary

inco

me

elas

ticit y

Com

pres

sion

of

disa

bilit

yEx

pans

ion

of

disa

bilit

yIn

crea

se in

de

pend

ency

Incr

ease

d pa

rtici

patio

n20

05 2

2050

Aust

ralia

0.9

2.2

2.9

2.0

2.6

1.5

2.4

3.1

3.2

Aust

ria1.

32.

53.

32.

53.

02.

02.

93.

65.

4Be

lgiu

m1.

52.

43.

42.

63.

22.

23.

13.

75.

9C

anad

a1.

22.

33.

22.

43.

01.

92.

93.

62.

9C

zech

Rep

ublic

0.4

2.0

2.0

1.3

1.7

0.9

1.8

2.4

3.2

Den

mar

k2.

63.

34.

13.

33.

92.

93.

74.

23.

5Fi

nlan

d2.

94.

35.

24.

24.

83.

74.

65.

44.

9Fr

ance

1.1

2.3

2.8

2.0

2.5

1.6

2.4

3.0

3.7

Ger

man

y1.

01.

92.

92.

22.

71.

72.

73.

43.

2G

reec

e0.

21.

02.

82.

02.

61.

42.

63.

53.

0

Hun

gary

0.3

1.5

2.4

1.0

1.6

0.6

1.3

1.8

5.4

Icel

and

2.9

3.5

4.4

3.4

4.1

3.1

3.8

4.3

3.5

Irela

nd0.

71.

74.

63.

23.

92.

53.

94.

93.

7Ita

ly0.

62.

03.

52.

83.

32.

23.

54.

56.

3Ja

pan

0.9

2.3

3.1

2.4

2.8

1.9

2.9

3.7

2.3

Kore

a0.

34.

14.

13.

13.

72.

33.

95.

15.

1Lu

xem

bour

g0.

71.

63.

82.

63.

32.

03.

14.

04.

9M

exic

o0.

12.

04.

23.

03.

82.

23.

95.

13.

7N

ethe

rland

s1.

72.

43.

72.

93.

52.

43.

44.

13.

9N

ew Z

eala

nd0.

52.

02.

41.

72.

21.

22.

12.

82.

1

Nor

way

2.6

3.3

4.3

3.5

4.1

3.1

3.9

4.5

3.6

Pola

nd0.

52.

63.

71.

82.

51.

32.

22.

86.

2Po

rtuga

l0.

21.

32.

21.

31.

90.

81.

82.

42.

1Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

0.3

2.6

2.6

1.5

2.0

1.1

2.0

2.6

6.6

Spai

n0.

21.

02.

61.

92.

31.

32.

43.

33.

0

Swed

en3.

33.

64.

33.

44.

03.

23.

64.

03.

6Sw

itzer

land

1.2

1.7

2.6

1.9

2.4

1.5

2.3

2.8

1.9

Turk

ey0.

11.

81.

80.

81.

40.

51.

21.

76.

8U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m1.

12.

13.

02.

12.

71.

72.

63.

22.

6U

nite

d St

ates

0.9

1.8

2.7

1.8

2.4

1.4

2.2

2.8

1.9

Ave

rage

1.1

2.3

3.3

2.4

2.9

1.9

2.8

3.5

3.9

1. F

or th

e de

finiti

on o

f the

diff

eren

t sce

nario

s se

e ta

ble

3.2.

2. E

stim

ates

, tak

ing

into

acc

ount

the

obse

rved

exp

endi

ture

gro

wth

bet

wee

n 20

00 a

nd 2

003

(or 2

002

if no

t ava

ilabl

e).

Sour

ce: S

ecre

taria

t cal

cula

tions

.

Page 40: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

40

Table 3.4 Sensitivity analysis of long-term care expenditure to population projectionsAssuming longevity gains of 2 years per decade

(In % of GDP)

Healthy ageing Expansion of disability

2005 1 2050

France 1.1 2.2 3.1Germany 1.0 3.0 4.4Italy 0.6 3.5 5.3Japan 0.9 3.6 5.2United States 0.9 1.7 2.6

Average 0.9 2.8 4.1

1. Estimates, taking into account the observed expenditure growth between 2000 and 2003 (or 2002 if not available).Source: Secretariat calculations.

Page 41: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

41

Figure 1.1 Evolution of public and private OECD health spending 1Index 1970 = 100

1. Unweighted average of available OECD countries. As a % of GDP.Source : OECD Health Database (2005).

90.0

100.0

110.0

120.0

130.0

140.0

150.0

160.0

170.0

180.0

1970

1971

1972

1973

1974

1975

1976

1977

1978

1979

1980

1981

1982

1983

1984

1985

1986

1987

1988

1989

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1996

1997

1998

1999

2000

2001

2002

2003

Public expenditurePrivate expenditure

Page 42: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

42

Figure 1.2 Total increase in health and long-term care spending, 2005-2050 1In percentage points of GDP

1. The vertical bars correspond to the range of the alternative scenarios, including sensitivity analysis. Countriesare ranked by the increase of expenditures between 2005 and 2050 in the cost-containment scenario. Turkey was not included because it was not possible to calculate one of the scenarios.2. Excluding Turkey.Source : Secretariat calculations.

-2.0

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8.0

10.0

12.0

Kore

a M

exico

Ire

land

Italy

Japa

n Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

Spain

Gree

ce

Luxe

mbo

urg

Polan

dNe

w Ze

aland

Portu

gal

Cana

daAu

strali

a

OECD

ave

rage

(2)

Czec

h Re

publi

c Ne

ther

lands

Finla

ndAu

stria

Germ

any

Unite

d Ki

ngdo

mIce

land

Fran

ceBe

lgium

No

rway

Unite

d St

ates

Hu

ngar

y De

nmar

k Sw

itzer

land

Swed

en

Cost-pressure scenarioCost-containment scenario

Page 43: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

43

Figu

re 1

.3 D

river

s of

tota

l hea

lth a

nd lo

ng-te

rm c

are

spen

ding

: key

com

pone

nts

Not

e: F

or a

def

initi

on a

nd d

escr

iptio

n of

the

diffe

rent

tech

nica

l ter

ms,

see

the

Glo

ssar

y in

Box

1.

TOTA

L S

PEN

DIN

G

HEA

LTH

CAR

ELO

NG

-TER

M C

ARE

Dem

ogra

phic

driv

ers

Non

-dem

ogra

phic

driv

ers

Dem

ogra

phic

driv

ers

Non

-dem

ogra

phic

driv

ers

Cha

nge

in th

e po

pula

tion

stru

ctur

e

Cos

t of n

on-s

urvi

vors

(Dea

th-

rela

ted

cost

s)

Inco

me

effe

ct

The

resi

dual

: tec

hnol

ogy,

re

lativ

e pr

ices

, pol

icie

s

Cha

nge

in th

e po

pula

tion

stru

ctur

e

Dep

ende

ncy

rate

s an

d he

alth

st

atus

Part

icip

atio

n ra

tes

and

prov

isio

n of

LTC

Wag

e in

flatio

n cu

m in

com

e ef

fect

s

Hea

lth s

tatu

s of

sur

vivo

rs

Page 44: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

44

Figure 2.1 Public health care expenditure by age groups 1

1. Expenditure per capita in each age group divided GDP per capita.Source : ENPRI-AGIR, national authorities and Secretariat calculations.

0.0

5.0

10.0

15.0

20.0

25.0

0-4 5-910

-1415

-1920

-2425

-2930

-3435

-3940

-4445

-4950

-5455

-5960

-6465

-6970

-7475

-7980

-8485

-8990

-94 95+

% o

f GD

P pe

r cap

ita

AustriaBelgiumDenmarkFinlandFranceGermanyGreeceIrelandItalyLuxembourgNetherlandsPortugalSpainSwedenUKAustraliaUnited States

Page 45: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

45

Figure 2.2 Breakdown of the health care cost curve 1(Finland)

1. Expenditure per capita in each age group.Source : ENPRI-AGIR and Secretariat calculations.

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

4000

4500

5000

0-4 5-910

-1415

-1920

-2425

-2930

-3435

-3940

-4445

-4950

-5455

-5960

-6465

-6970

-7475

-7980

-8485

-8990

-94 95+

$ pe

r cap

ita

TotalDeath related costsSurvivor costs

Page 46: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

46

Figure 2.3 Shifts in expenditure profiles, ageing and non-ageing effects

(1) Pure ageing effectHealth expenditure per capita

Young OldAge groups

(2) Ageing effect adjusted for death-related costs and healthy longevityHealth expenditure per capita

Young OldAge groups

(3) Non-ageing driversHealth expenditure per capita

Young OldAge groups

Average in 2050

Average in 2000Pure demographic effect

Non-demographic effects

Page 47: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

47

Figure 2.4 Demographic effects on health care expenditure

A. Public health care expenditureIncrease in % points of GDP 2005-2050

B. Increase in the old-age dependency ratio between 2005 and 2050 1(In percentage points of working age population)

1. Ratio of population aged 65 and over to population aged 15-64.Source : Secretariat calculations.

-2.0

-1.5

-1.0

-0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

Kore

aSl

ovak

Rep

ublic

Mex

icoJa

pan

Portu

gal

Austr

alia

New

Zeal

and

Czec

h Re

publi

cPo

land

Spain

Turk

eyCa

nada

Irelan

dIce

land

Gree

ceNe

ther

lands

Austr

iaIta

lyLu

xem

bour

gFi

nland

Germ

any

Hung

ary

Unite

d Ki

ngdo

mDe

nmar

kFr

ance

Switz

erlan

dNo

rway

Unite

d St

ates

Belgi

umSw

eden

Adjustment for healthy ageing Pure age effect (survivors)Death related costsTotal

0.0

10.0

20.0

30.0

40.0

50.0

60.0

Kore

a Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

Polan

dIta

ly Ja

pan

Portu

gal

Czec

h Re

publi

c Hu

ngar

y Sp

ainAu

stral

ia Fi

nland

Austr

iaFr

ance

Gree

ce

New

Zeala

ndIre

land

Cana

daM

exico

Ge

rman

yBe

lgium

Un

ited

King

dom

Luxe

mbo

urg

Turk

ey

Norw

ayIce

land

Denm

ark

Neth

erlan

dsUn

ited

Stat

es

Switz

erlan

d Sw

eden

Page 48: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

48

Figure 3.1. Public long-term care expenditure by age group 1

1. Expenditure per capita in each age group divided by GDP per capita.Source : ENPRI-AGIR and Secretariat calculations.

0.0

10.0

20.0

30.0

40.0

50.0

60.0

70.0

80.0

0-4 5-910

-1415

-1920

-2425

-2930

-3435

-3940

-4445

-4950

-5455

-5960

-6465

-6970

-7475

-7980

-8485

-8990

-94 95+

% o

f GD

P pe

r cap

ita

AustriaBelgiumDenmarkFinlandFranceGermanyIrelandItalyNetherlandsSwedenUnited Kingdom

Page 49: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

49

Figure 3.2 Prevalence of dependency by age group 1

Age1. Dependency is defined as the inability to accomplish one or several Activities of Daily Living (see text).Source : Comas-Herrera et al. (2003) and Secretariat calculations.

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0-4 5-910

-1415

-1920

-2425

-2930-3

435

-3940

-4445

-4950

-5455

-5960

-6465-6

970-7

475-7

980

-8485

-8990

-94 95+

GermanyItalySpainUnited Kingdom

Figure 3.3. Adjusted long-term care expenditure per dependant(% of GDP per capita)

AgeSource : ENPRI-AGIR and Secretariat calculations.

0.0

20.0

40.0

60.0

80.0

100.0

120.0

140.0

0-4 5-910

-1415

-1920

-2425

-2930

-3435

-3940

-4445

-4950

-5455

-5960

-6465

-6970

-7475

-7980

-8485

-8990

-94 95+

% AustriaBelgiumDenmarkFinlandFranceGermanyIrelandItalyNetherlandsSwedenUnited kingdom

Page 50: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

50

ANNEX 2A. DATA SOURCES AND METHODS

Macro data

Population ( )N and other demographic assumptions:

Past data: Eurostat + United Nations

Projections are derived from national sources

Projected gains in life expectancy per decade were also derived from national population projections.

Mortality rates were derived from national population projections, using a demographic maquette (see Gonand, 2005). The five-year national projections were transformed into annual projection, by linear interpolation. Using these annual data, a mortality rate by cohort and year was derived.

Participation rates

NL

: Past participation ratios were obtained from OECD Labour Force Statistics

Labour force projections: Burniaux et al., (2003)

Labor productivity

LY

: Productivity growth calculated as the average between 1995-2000, converging to 1.75% per year by 2030, except for former transition countries and Mexico which are assumed to converge by 2050.

GDP per capita

×

=

LY

NL

NY

: Expressed in 2000 $ PPPs.

65. Table A2.1 provides summary statistics on the main exogenous assumptions used in the projections.

[Table A2.1 Exogenous assumptions underlying the projections]

Health care

Estimating the death-related costs

66. The primary data for 18 OECD countries are drawn from the AGIR data set (Westerhout and Pellikaan, 2005, based on EPC, 2001) for EU-15 countries and from national sources for Australia, Canada and United States.

Page 51: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

51

67. The cost of death for the oldest group (95+) is assumed to be the lowest and was proxied by their observed health expenditure per person when available. For France, Germany, Italy, United Kingdom, Spain, Netherlands and Australia for which the expenditure for the oldest group were not available, the cost of people aged 75-79 was taken as a proxy. In fact, when available, expenditure at age 95+ is roughly equal to the level of expenditure at age 75-79. For the countries where no cost expenditures were available, the cost of death for the oldest group was estimated by taking 3 times the average health expenditure per capita.

68. The costs of death for other age groups are then derived by multiplying this estimate by an adjustment factor equal to four between ages 0-4 to 55-59, gradually decreasing to 1 afterwards. Multiplying these costs of death by the estimated number of deaths by age group (using mortality data) gives the death-related cost (DRC) curve.

Estimating the survivors' expenditure curves

69. The cost curve for survivors can be simply derived by subtracting the DRC curve described above from the total expenditure curves, when available (18 OECD countries). Given the uncertainties surrounding these data, it seemed nonetheless preferable to estimate an average expenditure curve for survivors and then use this curve for all countries. In this way, the projections are less sensitive to initial conditions and to country-specific data idiosyncrasies.

70. An average expenditure curve for survivors was estimated econometrically in a panel of 18 countries by 20 age groups, using a spline function, as follows (see Table A2.2):

6.122200002.0004.029.094.98.137Population

Exp.Health 5432 +⋅−⋅+⋅−⋅+⋅−= ageageageageagegroupage

where age is the central point in each age bracket (e.g., 2, 7, 12,…, 97).

[Table A2.2 Econometric estimates of an average health expenditure curve]

Calibration of the cost curves on the OECD Health database

71. The cost curves derived for 2000 were calibrated in order to fit the year 2005, the starting point of the projections. The total health and long-term care expenditures for 2005 being not yet available in the OECD Health Data (2005a), an estimate was made by applying the observed growth rate in expenditures 2000-2003 (or 2002, depending on the countries) for the whole period 2000-2005. A second step was to split the total spending into health and long-term care. The details of this split are provided below and involved an estimate of the shares of long-term care expenditures using OECD (2005b).

72. The costs of death by age group for 2005 were derived by applying the same growth rate as the total health expenditures between 2000 and 2005. The total death-related costs in 2005 were computed as the product of the cost of death by the projected number of deaths by age group in that year. The total survivor expenditures were then derived by subtracting the total death-related costs from the total health spending. Using this information, the survivor cost curve was calibrated proportionally for each age group.

Projecting the demographic effects under a ‘healthy ageing’ scenario

73. Shifting the survivor cost curve according to longevity gains involves two steps:

Page 52: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

52

(1) The survivor expenditure curve by five-year age groups is interpolated in order to derive a profile by individual age. In this way, the cost curve can be shifted smoothly over time in line with life expectancy gains.

(2) An “effective age” is calculated by subtracting the increase in life expectancy at birth according to national projections from current age. For example, a 70-year old person in Germany is projected to have an effective age of 67 by 2025 and 64 by 2050.

74. The death-related cost curve remains constant over time (to isolate the demographic effect) and the costs of death are projected according to the number of deaths.

Long-term care (LTC)

Expenditure curves

75. Expenditure curves for eleven EU-countries were obtained from the AGIR data set (Westerhout and Pellikaan, 2005, based on EPC, 2001). An average dependency ratio (prevalence of dependency by age group) was derived from Comas-Herrera (2003) study for four countries (United Kingdom, Spain, Italy, Germany). As the Comas-Herrera study only provides dependency ratios for old ages, this ratio was assumed to start at 2% for younger ages.

76. More precisely, the LTC expenditures per dependant were derived as follows:

groupagegroupagegroupage ratiodependencypopulationLTC

dependantLTC 1×=

where groupagepopulationtotal

dependantsofnumberratiodependency =

77. An average LTC expenditure curve per dependant and age group was estimated using the following equation (see Table 3.1, in the main text):

)6450(0394.00348.0217.4 −⋅+⋅+=

ofratioionparticipatForceLabouragedependant

LTCLog

78. This equation was used to derive the shit in the LTC cost curve associated with changes in the participation ratios in OECD. With these expenditure curves per dependant, the total LTC costs can be calculated as follows:

⋅=

iigroupage

igroupage

dependantsofnumberdependant

LTCLTCTotal

79. The total LTC expenditure in percentage of GDP in 2000 was calibrated to fit the estimates of the OECD Long-term Care study (OECD, 2005b), when available. Data for the countries not available in this study were obtained by applying the ratios of LTC to GDP observed in ‘similar’ benchmark countries, as indicated in the table below:

Page 53: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

53

Country estimated Benchmark countries

Belgium Netherlands Czech Republic average (Hungary, Poland) Slovak Republic average (Hungary, Poland) Denmark average (Norway, Sweden) Finland average (Norway, Sweden) Iceland average (Norway, Sweden) France Germany Greece Spain Italy average (Germany, Spain) Portugal Spain Switzerland Germany Turkey Mexico

The starting point of the projections

80. The projected changes in spending expressed in percentage of GDP were calculated from a common base applied to all OECD countries. This base was taken as the OECD average of expenditure in 2005. These changes were added to the initial level of expenditures in each country. This approach makes the projected changes (expressed in percent of GDP) less dependent from the base year levels and also allows for a certain catch-up of expenditure ratios across countries. More precisely, the variation of the share of expenditure to GDP in country j between, say, 2005 and 2050, is calculated as:

( )

+∆=

=

=− −

2005

200520052050loglogexp

20052050

yearOECDaverage

yearOECDaveragejcountry

GDPeExpenditur

GDPeExpenditurDrivers

GDPeExpenditur

jcountry

Detailed results for the projection scenarios

81. A detailed breakdown of the projections for each expenditure driver and scenario is provided in Table A2.3 for health care expenditure and in Table A2.4 for long-term care expenditure.

[Table A2.3 Breakdown of the projections of public health expenditure for each driver] [Table A2.4 Breakdown of the projections of long-term care expenditure for each driver]

Page 54: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

54

Tabl

e A2

.1 E

xoge

nous

ass

umpt

ions

und

erly

ing

the

proj

ectio

ns

Gai

ns in

life

ex

pect

ancy

at b

irth

Labo

ur fo

rce

Prod

uctiv

ityG

DP

per c

apita

1Pa

rtici

patio

n ra

te o

f peo

ple

aged

50-

64

In n

umbe

r of y

ears

pe

r dec

ade

Aver

age

annu

al g

row

thAv

erag

e an

nual

gro

wth

Aver

age

annu

al g

row

thPe

rcen

tage

s

2000

-205

020

05-2

025

2025

-205

020

05-2

025

2025

-205

020

05-2

025

2025

-205

020

0520

50

Aust

ralia

1.

20.

60.

02.

21.

82.

21.

460

.557

.8Au

stria

1.4

-0.3

-0.5

2.0

1.8

1.7

1.4

46.7

46.7

Belg

ium

1.

60.

0-0

.21.

91.

81.

71.

545

.148

.0C

anad

a0.

90.

3-0

.12.

01.

81.

81.

664

.265

.6C

zech

Rep

ublic

1.

3-0

.4-1

.11.

51.

71.

10.

956

.449

.4

Den

mar

k 1.

1-0

.4-0

.32.

01.

81.

71.

666

.465

.7Fi

nlan

d1.

5-0

.5-0

.42.

61.

82.

31.

763

.862

.8Fr

ance

1.8

-0.2

-0.2

1.8

1.8

1.3

1.5

58.0

54.6

Ger

man

y1.

2-0

.3-0

.61.

51.

81.

21.

559

.663

.3G

reec

e 0.

80.

1-0

.92.

01.

82.

41.

354

.465

.1

Hun

gary

1.

6-0

.7-1

.12.

92.

12.

51.

641

.434

.1Ic

elan

d0.

60.

60.

12.

51.

82.

81.

688

.687

.8Ire

land

0.9

0.9

0.0

3.5

1.8

4.4

1.7

62.4

76.5

Italy

1.

8-0

.2-1

.01.

51.

81.

31.

244

.652

.5Ja

pan

0.8

-0.6

-1.0

1.5

1.8

1.0

1.4

72.2

72.7

Kore

a 1.

7-0

.5-1

.12.

41.

82.

01.

462

.957

.2Lu

xem

bour

g1.

11.

00.

53.

21.

83.

61.

648

.357

.8M

exic

o 1.

21.

80.

32.

62.

03.

62.

260

.467

.7N

ethe

rland

s0.

50.

10.

01.

81.

81.

61.

756

.963

.0N

ew Z

eala

nd1.

20.

3-0

.11.

81.

81.

51.

470

.566

.8

Nor

way

1.5

0.4

0.2

1.9

1.8

1.8

1.6

77.2

80.3

Pola

nd2.

0-0

.5-1

.63.

72.

43.

71.

946

.738

.4Po

rtuga

l1.

1-0

.1-0

.92.

21.

82.

31.

364

.464

.6Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

1.5

-0.5

-1.4

2.4

1.9

1.9

1.0

48.7

38.6

Spai

n0.

80.

1-0

.71.

61.

81.

41.

354

.163

.2

Swed

en0.

9-0

.10.

22.

31.

81.

91.

873

.268

.9Sw

itzer

land

0.

90.

0-0

.31.

71.

81.

51.

672

.775

.1Tu

rkey

1.

60.

6-0

.12.

41.

82.

31.

435

.323

.6U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m1.

60.

0-0

.12.

11.

81.

91.

662

.863

.3U

nite

d St

ates

1.

40.

50.

72.

11.

81.

91.

768

.869

.0

1. D

eriv

ed G

DP

per c

apita

usi

ng th

e la

bour

forc

e an

d pr

oduc

tivity

ass

umpt

ions

and

dem

ogra

phic

pro

ject

ions

for t

otal

pop

ulat

ion.

Sour

ce: N

atio

nal p

opul

atio

n pr

ojec

tions

, Bur

niau

x et

al.

(200

3) a

nd S

ecre

taria

t's c

alcu

latio

ns.

Page 55: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

55

Table A2.2. Econometric estimates of an average health expenditure curve

Dependant variable: Health expenditure per capita in each age group

Coefficients

t-statistic

age

-137.8

-3.60

age**2 9.94 4.12

age**3 -.29 -4.71

age**4 .004 5.53

age**5 -.00002 -6.32

Constant 1222.6 6.69

Number of observations: 360 R. squared: 0.78

Page 56: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

56

Tabl

e A2

.3 B

reak

dow

n of

the

proj

ectio

ns o

f pub

lic h

ealth

car

e ex

pend

iture

for e

ach

driv

erD

emog

raph

ic e

ffect

Hea

lth e

xpen

ditu

re a

s a

% o

f GD

P

Dea

th-

rela

ted

cost

s

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lD

eath

-re

late

d co

sts

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lH

ealth

ex

pend

iture

as

a %

of G

DP

2000

2005

Incr

ease

in %

poi

nts

of G

DP

2005

-202

5In

crea

se in

% p

oint

s of

GD

P 20

05-2

050

2050

Aust

ralia

5.3

5.6

0.1

0.8

-0.4

0.0

0.0

0.5

0.3

1.5

-0.8

0.0

0.0

1.0

6.5

Aust

ria3.

83.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

00.

30.

21.

3-0

.90.

00.

00.

64.

4Be

lgiu

m4.

95.

70.

10.

5-0

.50.

00.

00.

00.

10.

9-1

.00.

00.

00.

15.

8C

anad

a5.

36.

20.

10.

8-0

.30.

00.

00.

70.

21.

3-0

.70.

00.

00.

87.

0C

zech

Rep

ublic

5.7

7.0

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.0

0.0

0.4

0.2

1.6

-0.9

0.0

0.0

0.9

8.0

Den

mar

k4.

65.

30.

10.

5-0

.40.

00.

00.

20.

10.

8-0

.60.

00.

00.

35.

6Fi

nlan

d2.

73.

40.

10.

8-0

.40.

00.

00.

50.

21.

1-0

.90.

00.

00.

43.

8Fr

ance

6.2

7.0

0.1

0.6

-0.5

0.0

0.0

0.2

0.2

1.2

-1.1

0.0

0.0

0.3

7.3

Ger

man

y7.

47.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

00.

20.

21.

0-0

.80.

00.

00.

48.

2G

reec

e5.

04.

90.

10.

5-0

.30.

00.

00.

30.

21.

0-0

.60.

00.

00.

65.

5

Hun

gary

4.8

6.7

0.1

0.7

-0.6

0.0

0.0

0.3

0.2

1.4

-1.2

0.0

0.0

0.4

7.1

Icel

and

5.4

6.8

0.1

0.6

-0.3

0.0

0.0

0.4

0.2

1.0

-0.4

0.0

0.0

0.8

7.5

Irela

nd4.

25.

90.

10.

5-0

.20.

00.

00.

40.

21.

3-0

.70.

00.

00.

86.

8Ita

ly5.

36.

00.

10.

7-0

.50.

00.

00.

30.

21.

6-1

.30.

00.

00.

56.

5Ja

pan

5.3

6.0

0.1

0.8

-0.3

0.0

0.0

0.7

0.2

1.4

-0.5

0.0

0.0

1.1

7.1

Kore

a2.

03.

00.

21.

3-0

.60.

00.

00.

90.

32.

6-1

.30.

00.

01.

64.

6Lu

xem

bour

g4.

96.

10.

10.

4-0

.40.

00.

00.

10.

20.

9-0

.60.

00.

00.

56.

6M

exic

o2.

53.

00.

10.

7-0

.30.

00.

00.

50.

22.

0-0

.90.

00.

01.

34.

3N

ethe

rland

s3.

95.

10.

10.

6-0

.30.

00.

00.

40.

10.

8-0

.40.

00.

00.

65.

7N

ew Z

eala

nd5.

76.

00.

10.

8-0

.40.

00.

00.

50.

21.

5-0

.80.

00.

00.

96.

9

Nor

way

5.2

7.3

0.1

0.5

-0.4

0.0

0.0

0.2

0.2

0.9

-0.8

0.0

0.0

0.2

7.5

Pola

nd3.

64.

40.

11.

0-0

.60.

00.

00.

60.

22.

1-1

.50.

00.

00.

95.

3Po

rtuga

l6.

26.

70.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

00.

30.

21.

5-0

.80.

00.

01.

07.

7Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

4.6

5.1

0.1

1.0

-0.6

0.0

0.0

0.6

0.3

2.2

-1.1

0.0

0.0

1.4

6.5

Spai

n5.

15.

50.

10.

5-0

.30.

00.

00.

30.

21.

3-0

.60.

00.

00.

96.

4

Swed

en4.

55.

30.

10.

4-0

.30.

00.

00.

20.

10.

5-0

.60.

00.

00.

05.

3Sw

itzer

land

4.9

6.2

0.1

0.5

-0.3

0.0

0.0

0.3

0.1

0.8

-0.6

0.0

0.0

0.3

6.4

Turk

ey4.

15.

90.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

00.

30.

31.

7-1

.10.

00.

00.

96.

7U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m5.

06.

10.

10.

6-0

.50.

00.

00.

20.

21.

0-0

.80.

00.

00.

36.

5U

nite

d St

ates

5.1

6.3

0.1

0.6

-0.4

0.0

0.0

0.3

0.1

0.8

-0.7

0.0

0.0

0.2

6.5

Aver

age

4.8

5.7

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.0

0.0

0.4

0.2

1.3

-0.8

0.0

0.0

0.7

6.3

NB:

Ass

umpt

ions

use

d in

this

sce

nario

:H

ealth

y ag

eing

: dy

nam

ic e

quilib

rium

(1 y

ear g

ains

in li

fe e

xpec

tanc

y =

1 ye

ar in

goo

d he

alth

)So

urce

: Sec

reta

riat c

alcu

latio

ns.

Page 57: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

EC

O/W

KP(

2006

)5

57

Tabl

e A2

.3 (c

ont.)

Bre

akdo

wn

of th

e pr

ojec

tions

of p

ublic

hea

lth c

are

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Cos

t-pre

ssur

e sc

enar

io

Hea

lth e

xpen

ditu

re a

s a

% o

f GD

P

Dea

th-

rela

ted

cost

s

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lD

eath

-re

late

d co

sts

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lH

ealth

ex

pend

iture

as

a %

of G

DP

2000

2005

Incr

ease

in %

poi

nts

of G

DP

2005

-202

5In

crea

se in

% p

oint

s of

GD

P 20

05-2

050

2050

Aust

ralia

5.3

5.6

0.1

0.8

-0.4

0.0

1.3

1.8

0.3

1.5

-0.8

0.0

3.2

4.2

9.7

Aust

ria3.

83.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

01.

31.

50.

21.

3-0

.90.

03.

23.

87.

6Be

lgiu

m4.

95.

70.

10.

5-0

.50.

01.

31.

30.

10.

9-1

.00.

03.

23.

39.

0C

anad

a5.

36.

20.

10.

8-0

.30.

01.

31.

90.

21.

3-0

.70.

03.

24.

110

.2C

zech

Rep

ublic

5.7

7.0

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.0

1.3

1.7

0.2

1.6

-0.9

0.0

3.2

4.1

11.2

Den

mar

k4.

65.

30.

10.

5-0

.40.

01.

31.

50.

10.

8-0

.60.

03.

23.

58.

8Fi

nlan

d2.

73.

40.

10.

8-0

.40.

01.

31.

80.

21.

1-0

.90.

03.

23.

67.

0Fr

ance

6.2

7.0

0.1

0.6

-0.5

0.0

1.3

1.5

0.2

1.2

-1.1

0.0

3.2

3.5

10.6

Ger

man

y7.

47.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

01.

31.

50.

21.

0-0

.80.

03.

23.

611

.4G

reec

e5.

04.

90.

10.

5-0

.30.

01.

31.

60.

21.

0-0

.60.

03.

23.

98.

7

Hun

gary

4.8

6.7

0.1

0.7

-0.6

0.0

1.3

1.5

0.2

1.4

-1.2

0.0

3.2

3.6

10.3

Icel

and

5.4

6.8

0.1

0.6

-0.3

0.0

1.3

1.7

0.2

1.0

-0.4

0.0

3.2

4.0

10.7

Irela

nd4.

25.

90.

10.

5-0

.20.

01.

31.

60.

21.

3-0

.70.

03.

24.

010

.0Ita

ly5.

36.

00.

10.

7-0

.50.

01.

31.

60.

21.

6-1

.30.

03.

23.

89.

7Ja

pan

5.3

6.0

0.1

0.8

-0.3

0.0

1.3

1.9

0.2

1.4

-0.5

0.0

3.2

4.3

10.3

Kore

a2.

03.

00.

21.

3-0

.60.

01.

32.

10.

32.

6-1

.30.

03.

24.

97.

8Lu

xem

bour

g4.

96.

10.

10.

4-0

.40.

01.

31.

40.

20.

9-0

.60.

03.

23.

79.

9M

exic

o2.

53.

00.

10.

7-0

.30.

01.

31.

70.

22.

0-0

.90.

03.

24.

57.

5N

ethe

rland

s3.

95.

10.

10.

6-0

.30.

01.

31.

70.

10.

8-0

.40.

03.

23.

88.

9N

ew Z

eala

nd5.

76.

00.

10.

8-0

.40.

01.

31.

80.

21.

5-0

.80.

03.

24.

210

.1

Nor

way

5.2

7.3

0.1

0.5

-0.4

0.0

1.3

1.4

0.2

0.9

-0.8

0.0

3.2

3.4

10.7

Pola

nd3.

64.

40.

11.

0-0

.60.

01.

31.

80.

22.

1-1

.50.

03.

24.

18.

5Po

rtuga

l6.

26.

70.

10.

6-0

.40.

01.

31.

60.

21.

5-0

.80.

03.

24.

210

.9Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

4.6

5.1

0.1

1.0

-0.6

0.0

1.3

1.9

0.3

2.2

-1.1

0.0

3.2

4.6

9.7

Spai

n5.

15.

50.

10.

5-0

.30.

01.

31.

60.

21.

3-0

.60.

03.

24.

19.

6

Swed

en4.

55.

30.

10.

4-0

.30.

01.

31.

40.

10.

5-0

.60.

03.

23.

28.

5Sw

itzer

land

4.9

6.2

0.1

0.5

-0.3

0.0

1.3

1.6

0.1

0.8

-0.6

0.0

3.2

3.5

9.6

Turk

ey4.

15.

90.

10.

6-0

.40.

01.

31.

60.

31.

7-1

.10.

03.

24.

19.

9U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m5.

06.

10.

10.

6-0

.50.

01.

31.

40.

21.

0-0

.80.

03.

23.

69.

7U

nite

d St

ates

5.1

6.3

0.1

0.6

-0.4

0.0

1.3

1.5

0.1

0.8

-0.7

0.0

3.2

3.4

9.7

Aver

age

4.8

5.7

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.0

1.3

1.6

0.2

1.3

-0.8

0.0

3.2

3.9

9.6

NB:

Ass

umpt

ions

use

d in

this

sce

nario

:H

ealth

y ag

eing

: dy

nam

ic e

quilib

rium

(1 y

ear g

ains

in li

fe e

xpec

tanc

y =

1 ye

ar in

goo

d he

alth

)In

com

e el

astic

ity =

1R

esid

uals

= 1

NO

tran

sver

salit

y co

nditi

onSo

urce

: Sec

reta

riat c

alcu

latio

ns.

Page 58: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

58

Tabl

e A2

.3 (c

ont.)

Bre

akdo

wn

of th

e pr

ojec

tions

of p

ublic

hea

lth c

are

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Cos

t-con

tain

men

t sce

nario

Hea

lth e

xpen

ditu

re a

s a

% o

f GD

P

Dea

th-

rela

ted

cost

s

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lD

eath

-re

late

d co

sts

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lH

ealth

ex

pend

iture

as

a %

of G

DP

2000

2005

Incr

ease

in %

poi

nts

of G

DP

2005

-202

5In

crea

se in

% p

oint

s of

GD

P 20

05-2

050

2050

Aust

ralia

5.3

5.6

0.1

0.8

-0.4

0.0

0.9

1.5

0.3

1.5

-0.8

0.0

1.4

2.3

7.9

Aust

ria3.

83.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

91.

20.

21.

3-0

.90.

01.

42.

05.

7Be

lgiu

m4.

95.

70.

10.

5-0

.50.

00.

91.

00.

10.

9-1

.00.

01.

41.

57.

2C

anad

a5.

36.

20.

10.

8-0

.30.

00.

91.

60.

21.

3-0

.70.

01.

42.

28.

4C

zech

Rep

ublic

5.7

7.0

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.0

0.9

1.3

0.2

1.6

-0.9

0.0

1.4

2.3

9.4

Den

mar

k4.

65.

30.

10.

5-0

.40.

00.

91.

10.

10.

8-0

.60.

01.

41.

77.

0Fi

nlan

d2.

73.

40.

10.

8-0

.40.

00.

91.

50.

21.

1-0

.90.

01.

41.

85.

2Fr

ance

6.2

7.0

0.1

0.6

-0.5

0.0

0.9

1.1

0.2

1.2

-1.1

0.0

1.4

1.7

8.7

Ger

man

y7.

47.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

91.

20.

21.

0-0

.80.

01.

41.

89.

6G

reec

e5.

04.

90.

10.

5-0

.30.

00.

91.

30.

21.

0-0

.60.

01.

42.

06.

9

Hun

gary

4.8

6.7

0.1

0.7

-0.6

0.0

0.9

1.2

0.2

1.4

-1.2

0.0

1.4

1.8

8.5

Icel

and

5.4

6.8

0.1

0.6

-0.3

0.0

0.9

1.3

0.2

1.0

-0.4

0.0

1.4

2.1

8.9

Irela

nd4.

25.

90.

10.

5-0

.20.

00.

91.

30.

21.

3-0

.70.

01.

42.

28.

2Ita

ly5.

36.

00.

10.

7-0

.50.

00.

91.

20.

21.

6-1

.30.

01.

41.

97.

9Ja

pan

5.3

6.0

0.1

0.8

-0.3

0.0

0.9

1.6

0.2

1.4

-0.5

0.0

1.4

2.5

8.5

Kore

a2.

03.

00.

21.

3-0

.60.

00.

91.

80.

32.

6-1

.30.

01.

43.

06.

0Lu

xem

bour

g4.

96.

10.

10.

4-0

.40.

00.

91.

00.

20.

9-0

.60.

01.

41.

98.

0M

exic

o2.

53.

00.

10.

7-0

.30.

00.

91.

40.

22.

0-0

.90.

01.

42.

75.

7N

ethe

rland

s3.

95.

10.

10.

6-0

.30.

00.

91.

40.

10.

8-0

.40.

01.

42.

07.

0N

ew Z

eala

nd5.

76.

00.

10.

8-0

.40.

00.

91.

50.

21.

5-0

.80.

01.

42.

38.

3

Nor

way

5.2

7.3

0.1

0.5

-0.4

0.0

0.9

1.1

0.2

0.9

-0.8

0.0

1.4

1.6

8.9

Pola

nd3.

64.

40.

11.

0-0

.60.

00.

91.

50.

22.

1-1

.50.

01.

42.

36.

7Po

rtuga

l6.

26.

70.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

91.

30.

21.

5-0

.80.

01.

42.

49.

1Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

4.6

5.1

0.1

1.0

-0.6

0.0

0.9

1.5

0.3

2.2

-1.1

0.0

1.4

2.8

7.9

Spai

n5.

15.

50.

10.

5-0

.30.

00.

91.

30.

21.

3-0

.60.

01.

42.

37.

8

Swed

en4.

55.

30.

10.

4-0

.30.

00.

91.

10.

10.

5-0

.60.

01.

41.

46.

7Sw

itzer

land

4.9

6.2

0.1

0.5

-0.3

0.0

0.9

1.3

0.1

0.8

-0.6

0.0

1.4

1.6

7.8

Turk

ey4.

15.

90.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

91.

30.

31.

7-1

.10.

01.

42.

38.

1U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m5.

06.

10.

10.

6-0

.50.

00.

91.

10.

21.

0-0

.80.

01.

41.

77.

9U

nite

d St

ates

5.1

6.3

0.1

0.6

-0.4

0.0

0.9

1.2

0.1

0.8

-0.7

0.0

1.4

1.6

7.9

Aver

age

4.8

5.7

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.0

0.9

1.3

0.2

1.3

-0.8

0.0

1.4

2.1

7.7

NB:

Ass

umpt

ions

use

d in

this

sce

nario

:H

ealth

y ag

eing

: dy

nam

ic e

quilib

rium

(1 y

ear g

ains

in li

fe e

xpec

tanc

y =

1 ye

ar in

goo

d he

alth

)In

com

e el

astic

ity =

1R

esid

uals

= 1

with

a tr

ansv

ersa

lity

cond

ition

Sour

ce: S

ecre

taria

t cal

cula

tions

.

Page 59: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

EC

O/W

KP(

2006

)5

59

Tabl

e A2

.3 (c

ont.)

Bre

akdo

wn

of th

e pr

ojec

tions

of p

ublic

hea

lth c

are

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Scen

ario

: co

untry

-spe

cific

resi

dual

s

Hea

lth e

xpen

ditu

re a

s a

% o

f GD

P

Dea

th-

rela

ted

cost

s

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lD

eath

-re

late

d co

sts

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lH

ealth

ex

pend

iture

as

a %

of G

DP

2000

2005

Incr

ease

in %

poi

nts

of G

DP

2005

-202

5In

crea

se in

% p

oint

s of

GD

P 20

05-2

050

2050

Aust

ralia

5.3

5.6

0.1

0.8

-0.4

0.0

1.3

1.9

0.3

1.5

-0.8

0.0

2.0

3.0

8.5

Aust

ria3.

83.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

00.

30.

21.

3-0

.90.

00.

00.

64.

4Be

lgiu

m4.

95.

70.

10.

5-0

.50.

00.

60.

60.

10.

9-1

.00.

00.

90.

96.

7C

anad

a5.

36.

20.

10.

8-0

.30.

00.

61.

20.

21.

3-0

.70.

00.

81.

77.

8C

zech

Rep

ublic

5.7

7.0

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.0

-0.4

0.1

0.2

1.6

-0.9

0.0

-0.5

0.4

7.5

Den

mar

k4.

65.

30.

10.

5-0

.40.

0-0

.4-0

.20.

10.

8-0

.60.

0-0

.5-0

.25.

1Fi

nlan

d2.

73.

40.

10.

8-0

.40.

00.

20.

70.

21.

1-0

.90.

00.

30.

74.

1Fr

ance

6.2

7.0

0.1

0.6

-0.5

0.0

0.9

1.1

0.2

1.2

-1.1

0.0

1.4

1.7

8.7

Ger

man

y7.

47.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

91.

20.

21.

0-0

.80.

01.

41.

89.

6G

reec

e5.

04.

90.

10.

5-0

.30.

00.

71.

00.

21.

0-0

.60.

01.

11.

76.

6

Hun

gary

4.8

6.7

0.1

0.7

-0.6

0.0

-1.2

-0.9

0.2

1.4

-1.2

0.0

-1.6

-1.3

5.4

Icel

and

5.4

6.8

0.1

0.6

-0.3

0.0

2.0

2.4

0.2

1.0

-0.4

0.0

3.0

3.8

10.5

Irela

nd4.

25.

90.

10.

5-0

.20.

0-0

.8-0

.40.

21.

3-0

.70.

0-1

.1-0

.35.

6Ita

ly5.

36.

00.

10.

7-0

.50.

0-0

.10.

30.

21.

6-1

.30.

0-0

.10.

56.

4Ja

pan

5.3

6.0

0.1

0.8

-0.3

0.0

1.1

1.8

0.2

1.4

-0.5

0.0

1.6

2.7

8.7

Kore

a2.

03.

00.

21.

3-0

.60.

02.

63.

40.

32.

6-1

.30.

04.

05.

68.

6Lu

xem

bour

g4.

96.

10.

10.

4-0

.40.

0-0

.10.

00.

20.

9-0

.60.

0-0

.10.

46.

6M

exic

o2.

53.

00.

10.

7-0

.30.

02.

63.

00.

22.

0-0

.90.

04.

05.

38.

3N

ethe

rland

s3.

95.

10.

10.

6-0

.30.

00.

30.

70.

10.

8-0

.40.

00.

41.

06.

1N

ew Z

eala

nd5.

76.

00.

10.

8-0

.40.

01.

01.

50.

21.

5-0

.80.

01.

52.

48.

4

Nor

way

5.2

7.3

0.1

0.5

-0.4

0.0

1.4

1.6

0.2

0.9

-0.8

0.0

2.1

2.4

9.6

Pola

nd3.

64.

40.

11.

0-0

.60.

0-0

.50.

10.

22.

1-1

.50.

0-0

.70.

24.

6Po

rtuga

l6.

26.

70.

10.

6-0

.40.

03.

03.

40.

21.

5-0

.80.

04.

85.

812

.6Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

4.6

5.1

0.1

1.0

-0.6

0.0

-1.2

-0.6

0.3

2.2

-1.1

0.0

-1.6

-0.2

4.9

Spai

n5.

15.

50.

10.

5-0

.30.

00.

71.

10.

21.

3-0

.60.

01.

12.

07.

5

Swed

en4.

55.

30.

10.

4-0

.30.

0-0

.3-0

.20.

10.

5-0

.60.

0-0

.5-0

.44.

9Sw

itzer

land

4.9

6.2

0.1

0.5

-0.3

0.0

3.1

3.4

0.1

0.8

-0.6

0.0

4.9

5.2

11.4

Turk

ey4.

15.

90.

10.

6-0

.40.

014

.414

.70.

31.

7-1

.10.

029

.130

.035

.8U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m5.

06.

10.

10.

6-0

.50.

00.

91.

10.

21.

0-0

.80.

01.

41.

77.

9U

nite

d St

ates

5.1

6.3

0.1

0.6

-0.4

0.0

2.7

3.0

0.1

0.8

-0.7

0.0

4.3

4.5

10.8

Aver

age

14.

85.

70.

10.

7-0

.40.

00.

81.

10.

21.

3-0

.80.

01.

21.

87.

5

NB:

Ass

umpt

ions

use

d in

this

sce

nario

:H

ealth

y ag

eing

: dy

nam

ic e

quilib

rium

(1 y

ear g

ains

in li

fe e

xpec

tanc

y =

1 ye

ar in

goo

d he

alth

)In

com

e el

astic

ity =

1C

ount

ry s

peci

fic re

sidu

als

with

a tr

ansv

ersa

lity

cond

ition

1. E

xclu

ding

Tur

key.

Sour

ce: S

ecre

taria

t cal

cula

tions

.

Page 60: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

60

Tabl

e A2

.3 (c

ont.)

Bre

akdo

wn

of th

e pr

ojec

tions

of p

ublic

hea

lth c

are

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Sens

itivi

ty a

naly

sis:

inco

me

elas

ticity

at 0

.8

Hea

lth e

xpen

ditu

re a

s a

% o

f GD

P

Dea

th-

rela

ted

cost

s

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lD

eath

-re

late

d co

sts

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lH

ealth

ex

pend

iture

as

a %

of G

DP

2000

2005

Incr

ease

in %

poi

nts

of G

DP

2005

-202

5In

crea

se in

% p

oint

s of

GD

P 20

05-2

050

2050

Aust

ralia

5.3

5.6

0.1

0.8

-0.4

-0.5

0.9

1.0

0.3

1.5

-0.8

-0.8

1.4

1.5

7.1

Aust

ria3.

83.

80.

10.

6-0

.4-0

.40.

90.

90.

21.

3-0

.9-0

.71.

41.

25.

0Be

lgiu

m4.

95.

70.

10.

5-0

.5-0

.40.

90.

60.

10.

9-1

.0-0

.81.

40.

76.

4C

anad

a5.

36.

20.

10.

8-0

.3-0

.40.

91.

20.

21.

3-0

.7-0

.81.

41.

47.

6C

zech

Rep

ublic

5.7

7.0

0.1

0.7

-0.4

-0.2

0.9

1.1

0.2

1.6

-0.9

-0.5

1.4

1.8

8.9

Den

mar

k4.

65.

30.

10.

5-0

.4-0

.40.

90.

80.

10.

8-0

.6-0

.81.

40.

96.

2Fi

nlan

d2.

73.

40.

10.

8-0

.4-0

.50.

91.

00.

21.

1-0

.9-0

.91.

40.

94.

3Fr

ance

6.2

7.0

0.1

0.6

-0.5

-0.3

0.9

0.9

0.2

1.2

-1.1

-0.7

1.4

1.0

8.1

Ger

man

y7.

47.

80.

10.

6-0

.4-0

.30.

90.

90.

21.

0-0

.8-0

.61.

41.

18.

9G

reec

e5.

04.

90.

10.

5-0

.3-0

.50.

90.

80.

21.

0-0

.6-0

.81.

41.

26.

1

Hun

gary

4.8

6.7

0.1

0.7

-0.6

-0.5

0.9

0.7

0.2

1.4

-1.2

-0.9

1.4

0.8

7.5

Icel

and

5.4

6.8

0.1

0.6

-0.3

-0.6

0.9

0.8

0.2

1.0

-0.4

-1.0

1.4

1.2

7.9

Irela

nd4.

25.

90.

10.

5-0

.2-0

.90.

90.

40.

21.

3-0

.7-1

.31.

41.

06.

9Ita

ly5.

36.

00.

10.

7-0

.5-0

.30.

91.

00.

21.

6-1

.3-0

.61.

41.

37.

3Ja

pan

5.3

6.0

0.1

0.8

-0.3

-0.2

0.9

1.4

0.2

1.4

-0.5

-0.6

1.4

1.9

7.9

Kore

a2.

03.

00.

21.

3-0

.6-0

.40.

91.

40.

32.

6-1

.3-0

.81.

42.

35.

3Lu

xem

bour

g4.

96.

10.

10.

4-0

.4-0

.70.

90.

30.

20.

9-0

.6-1

.11.

40.

86.

9M

exic

o2.

53.

00.

10.

7-0

.3-0

.70.

90.

70.

22.

0-0

.9-1

.31.

41.

44.

4N

ethe

rland

s3.

95.

10.

10.

6-0

.3-0

.40.

91.

00.

10.

8-0

.4-0

.81.

41.

26.

3N

ew Z

eala

nd5.

76.

00.

10.

8-0

.4-0

.30.

91.

20.

21.

5-0

.8-0

.71.

41.

67.

6

Nor

way

5.2

7.3

0.1

0.5

-0.4

-0.4

0.9

0.7

0.2

0.9

-0.8

-0.8

1.4

0.8

8.1

Pola

nd3.

64.

40.

11.

0-0

.6-0

.80.

90.

80.

22.

1-1

.5-1

.21.

41.

15.

5Po

rtuga

l6.

26.

70.

10.

6-0

.4-0

.50.

90.

80.

21.

5-0

.8-0

.81.

41.

68.

3Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

4.6

5.1

0.1

1.0

-0.6

-0.4

0.9

1.1

0.3

2.2

-1.1

-0.7

1.4

2.1

7.2

Spai

n5.

15.

50.

10.

5-0

.3-0

.30.

91.

00.

21.

3-0

.6-0

.61.

41.

77.

1

Swed

en4.

55.

30.

10.

4-0

.3-0

.40.

90.

70.

10.

5-0

.6-0

.91.

40.

55.

9Sw

itzer

land

4.9

6.2

0.1

0.5

-0.3

-0.3

0.9

0.9

0.1

0.8

-0.6

-0.7

1.4

0.9

7.1

Turk

ey4.

15.

90.

10.

6-0

.4-0

.50.

90.

80.

31.

7-1

.1-0

.81.

41.

47.

3U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m5.

06.

10.

10.

6-0

.5-0

.40.

90.

70.

21.

0-0

.8-0

.81.

40.

97.

1U

nite

d St

ates

5.1

6.3

0.1

0.6

-0.4

-0.4

0.9

0.8

0.1

0.8

-0.7

-0.8

1.4

0.8

7.1

Aver

age

4.8

5.7

0.1

0.7

-0.4

-0.4

0.9

0.9

0.2

1.3

-0.8

-0.8

1.4

1.2

6.9

NB:

Ass

umpt

ions

use

d in

this

sce

nario

:H

ealth

y ag

eing

: dy

nam

ic e

quilib

rium

(1 y

ear g

ains

in li

fe e

xpec

tanc

y =

1 ye

ar in

goo

d he

alth

)In

com

e el

astic

ity =

0.8

Res

idua

ls =

1 w

ith a

tran

sver

salit

y co

nditi

onSo

urce

: Sec

reta

riat c

alcu

latio

ns.

Page 61: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

EC

O/W

KP(

2006

)5

61

Tabl

e A2

.3 (c

ont.)

Bre

akdo

wn

of th

e pr

ojec

tions

of p

ublic

hea

lth c

are

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Sens

itivi

ty a

naly

sis:

inco

me

elas

ticity

1.2

Hea

lth e

xpen

ditu

re a

s a

% o

f GD

P

Dea

th-

rela

ted

cost

s

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lD

eath

-re

late

d co

sts

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lH

ealth

ex

pend

iture

as

a %

of G

DP

2000

2005

Incr

ease

in %

poi

nts

of G

DP

2005

-202

5In

crea

se in

% p

oint

s of

GD

P 20

05-2

050

2050

Aust

ralia

5.3

5.6

0.1

0.8

-0.4

0.5

0.9

2.0

0.3

1.5

-0.8

1.0

1.4

3.3

8.9

Aust

ria3.

83.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

40.

91.

60.

21.

3-0

.90.

81.

42.

86.

6Be

lgiu

m4.

95.

70.

10.

5-0

.50.

40.

91.

40.

10.

9-1

.00.

91.

42.

48.

1C

anad

a5.

36.

20.

10.

8-0

.30.

40.

92.

00.

21.

3-0

.70.

91.

43.

29.

3C

zech

Rep

ublic

5.7

7.0

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.3

0.9

1.6

0.2

1.6

-0.9

0.5

1.4

2.8

9.9

Den

mar

k4.

65.

30.

10.

5-0

.40.

40.

91.

50.

10.

8-0

.60.

91.

42.

67.

9Fi

nlan

d2.

73.

40.

10.

8-0

.40.

50.

92.

00.

21.

1-0

.91.

11.

42.

96.

3Fr

ance

6.2

7.0

0.1

0.6

-0.5

0.3

0.9

1.4

0.2

1.2

-1.1

0.7

1.4

2.4

9.5

Ger

man

y7.

47.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

30.

91.

50.

21.

0-0

.80.

71.

42.

510

.3G

reec

e5.

04.

90.

10.

5-0

.30.

60.

91.

80.

21.

0-0

.61.

01.

43.

07.

9

Hun

gary

4.8

6.7

0.1

0.7

-0.6

0.6

0.9

1.8

0.2

1.4

-1.2

1.1

1.4

2.9

9.6

Icel

and

5.4

6.8

0.1

0.6

-0.3

0.7

0.9

2.0

0.2

1.0

-0.4

1.2

1.4

3.3

10.1

Irela

nd4.

25.

90.

10.

5-0

.21.

10.

92.

40.

21.

3-0

.71.

61.

43.

99.

8Ita

ly5.

36.

00.

10.

7-0

.50.

30.

91.

60.

21.

6-1

.30.

71.

42.

68.

6Ja

pan

5.3

6.0

0.1

0.8

-0.3

0.2

0.9

1.9

0.2

1.4

-0.5

0.7

1.4

3.1

9.1

Kore

a2.

03.

00.

21.

3-0

.60.

50.

92.

30.

32.

6-1

.30.

91.

43.

96.

9Lu

xem

bour

g4.

96.

10.

10.

4-0

.40.

90.

91.

90.

20.

9-0

.61.

41.

43.

39.

4M

exic

o2.

53.

00.

10.

7-0

.30.

90.

92.

30.

22.

0-0

.91.

61.

44.

37.

3N

ethe

rland

s3.

95.

10.

10.

6-0

.30.

40.

91.

80.

10.

8-0

.40.

91.

42.

98.

0N

ew Z

eala

nd5.

76.

00.

10.

8-0

.40.

30.

91.

80.

21.

5-0

.80.

81.

43.

19.

1

Nor

way

5.2

7.3

0.1

0.5

-0.4

0.4

0.9

1.5

0.2

0.9

-0.8

0.9

1.4

2.6

9.8

Pola

nd3.

64.

40.

11.

0-0

.60.

90.

92.

40.

22.

1-1

.51.

51.

43.

88.

2Po

rtuga

l6.

26.

70.

10.

6-0

.40.

50.

91.

80.

21.

5-0

.80.

91.

43.

310

.1Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

4.6

5.1

0.1

1.0

-0.6

0.4

0.9

2.0

0.3

2.2

-1.1

0.7

1.4

3.5

8.6

Spai

n5.

15.

50.

10.

5-0

.30.

30.

91.

60.

21.

3-0

.60.

71.

43.

08.

5

Swed

en4.

55.

30.

10.

4-0

.30.

50.

91.

60.

10.

5-0

.61.

01.

42.

47.

7Sw

itzer

land

4.9

6.2

0.1

0.5

-0.3

0.3

0.9

1.6

0.1

0.8

-0.6

0.8

1.4

2.5

8.6

Turk

ey4.

15.

90.

10.

6-0

.40.

50.

91.

80.

31.

7-1

.11.

01.

43.

29.

1U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m5.

06.

10.

10.

6-0

.50.

40.

91.

60.

21.

0-0

.81.

01.

42.

78.

8U

nite

d St

ates

5.1

6.3

0.1

0.6

-0.4

0.4

0.9

1.7

0.1

0.8

-0.7

1.0

1.4

2.6

8.9

Aver

age

4.8

5.7

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.5

0.9

1.8

0.2

1.3

-0.8

1.0

1.4

3.0

8.7

NB:

Ass

umpt

ions

use

d in

this

sce

nario

:H

ealth

y ag

eing

: dy

nam

ic e

quilib

rium

(1 y

ear g

ains

in li

fe e

xpec

tanc

y =

1 ye

ar in

goo

d he

alth

)In

com

e el

astic

ity =

1.2

Res

idua

ls =

1 w

ith a

tran

sver

salit

y co

nditi

onSo

urce

: Sec

reta

riat c

alcu

latio

ns.

Page 62: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

62

Tabl

e A2

.3 (c

ont.)

Bre

akdo

wn

of th

e pr

ojec

tions

of p

ublic

hea

lth c

are

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Sens

itivi

ty a

naly

sis:

resi

dual

at 1

.5%

per

yea

r

Hea

lth e

xpen

ditu

re a

s a

% o

f GD

P

Dea

th-

rela

ted

cost

s

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lD

eath

-re

late

d co

sts

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lH

ealth

ex

pend

iture

as

a %

of G

DP

2000

2005

Incr

ease

in %

poi

nts

of G

DP

2005

-202

5In

crea

se in

% p

oint

s of

GD

P 20

05-2

050

2050

Aust

ralia

5.3

5.6

0.1

0.8

-0.4

0.0

1.5

2.0

0.3

1.5

-0.8

0.0

2.2

3.2

8.7

Aust

ria3.

83.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

01.

51.

80.

21.

3-0

.90.

02.

22.

86.

6Be

lgiu

m4.

95.

70.

10.

5-0

.50.

01.

51.

50.

10.

9-1

.00.

02.

22.

38.

0C

anad

a5.

36.

20.

10.

8-0

.30.

01.

52.

10.

21.

3-0

.70.

02.

23.

19.

2C

zech

Rep

ublic

5.7

7.0

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.0

1.5

1.9

0.2

1.6

-0.9

0.0

2.2

3.1

10.2

Den

mar

k4.

65.

30.

10.

5-0

.40.

01.

51.

70.

10.

8-0

.60.

02.

22.

57.

8Fi

nlan

d2.

73.

40.

10.

8-0

.40.

01.

52.

00.

21.

1-0

.90.

02.

22.

66.

0Fr

ance

6.2

7.0

0.1

0.6

-0.5

0.0

1.5

1.7

0.2

1.2

-1.1

0.0

2.2

2.5

9.6

Ger

man

y7.

47.

80.

10.

6-0

.40.

01.

51.

70.

21.

0-0

.80.

02.

22.

610

.4G

reec

e5.

04.

90.

10.

5-0

.30.

01.

51.

80.

21.

0-0

.60.

02.

22.

97.

7

Hun

gary

4.8

6.7

0.1

0.7

-0.6

0.0

1.5

1.8

0.2

1.4

-1.2

0.0

2.2

2.6

9.3

Icel

and

5.4

6.8

0.1

0.6

-0.3

0.0

1.5

1.9

0.2

1.0

-0.4

0.0

2.2

3.0

9.7

Irela

nd4.

25.

90.

10.

5-0

.20.

01.

51.

80.

21.

3-0

.70.

02.

23.

09.

0Ita

ly5.

36.

00.

10.

7-0

.50.

01.

51.

80.

21.

6-1

.30.

02.

22.

78.

7Ja

pan

5.3

6.0

0.1

0.8

-0.3

0.0

1.5

2.2

0.2

1.4

-0.5

0.0

2.2

3.3

9.3

Kore

a2.

03.

00.

21.

3-0

.60.

01.

52.

30.

32.

6-1

.30.

02.

23.

86.

8Lu

xem

bour

g4.

96.

10.

10.

4-0

.40.

01.

51.

60.

20.

9-0

.60.

02.

22.

78.

9M

exic

o2.

53.

00.

10.

7-0

.30.

01.

51.

90.

22.

0-0

.90.

02.

23.

56.

5N

ethe

rland

s3.

95.

10.

10.

6-0

.30.

01.

51.

90.

10.

8-0

.40.

02.

22.

87.

9N

ew Z

eala

nd5.

76.

00.

10.

8-0

.40.

01.

52.

00.

21.

5-0

.80.

02.

23.

29.

1

Nor

way

5.2

7.3

0.1

0.5

-0.4

0.0

1.5

1.6

0.2

0.9

-0.8

0.0

2.2

2.4

9.7

Pola

nd3.

64.

40.

11.

0-0

.60.

01.

52.

10.

22.

1-1

.50.

02.

23.

17.

5Po

rtuga

l6.

26.

70.

10.

6-0

.40.

01.

51.

80.

21.

5-0

.80.

02.

23.

29.

9Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

4.6

5.1

0.1

1.0

-0.6

0.0

1.5

2.1

0.3

2.2

-1.1

0.0

2.2

3.6

8.7

Spai

n5.

15.

50.

10.

5-0

.30.

01.

51.

80.

21.

3-0

.60.

02.

23.

18.

6

Swed

en4.

55.

30.

10.

4-0

.30.

01.

51.

60.

10.

5-0

.60.

02.

22.

27.

5Sw

itzer

land

4.9

6.2

0.1

0.5

-0.3

0.0

1.5

1.8

0.1

0.8

-0.6

0.0

2.2

2.5

8.6

Turk

ey4.

15.

90.

10.

6-0

.40.

01.

51.

80.

31.

7-1

.10.

02.

23.

18.

9U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m5.

06.

10.

10.

6-0

.50.

01.

51.

60.

21.

0-0

.80.

02.

22.

68.

7U

nite

d St

ates

5.1

6.3

0.1

0.6

-0.4

0.0

1.5

1.8

0.1

0.8

-0.7

0.0

2.2

2.4

8.7

Aver

age

4.8

5.7

0.1

0.7

-0.4

0.0

1.5

1.8

0.2

1.3

-0.8

0.0

2.2

2.9

8.5

NB:

Ass

umpt

ions

use

d in

this

sce

nario

:H

ealth

y ag

eing

: dy

nam

ic e

quilib

rium

(1 y

ear g

ains

in li

fe e

xpec

tanc

y =

1 ye

ar in

goo

d he

alth

)In

com

e el

astic

ity =

1R

esid

uals

= 1

.5 w

ith a

tran

sver

salit

y co

nditi

onSo

urce

: Sec

reta

riat c

alcu

latio

ns.

Page 63: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

EC

O/W

KP(

2006

)5

63

Tabl

e A2

.3 (c

ont.)

Bre

akdo

wn

of th

e pr

ojec

tions

of p

ublic

hea

lth c

are

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Sens

itivi

ty a

naly

sis:

Com

pres

sion

of m

orbi

dity

sce

nario

Hea

lth e

xpen

ditu

re a

s a

% o

f GD

P

Dea

th-

rela

ted

cost

s

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lD

eath

-re

late

d co

sts

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lH

ealth

ex

pend

iture

as

a %

of G

DP

2000

2005

Incr

ease

in %

poi

nts

of G

DP

2005

-202

5In

crea

se in

% p

oint

s of

GD

P 20

05-2

050

2050

Aust

ralia

5.3

5.6

0.1

0.8

-0.6

0.0

0.9

1.2

0.3

1.5

-1.6

0.0

1.4

1.6

7.1

Aust

ria3.

83.

80.

10.

6-0

.80.

00.

90.

90.

21.

3-1

.70.

01.

41.

25.

0Be

lgiu

m4.

95.

70.

10.

5-0

.80.

00.

90.

60.

10.

9-1

.70.

01.

40.

76.

4C

anad

a5.

36.

20.

10.

8-0

.50.

00.

91.

30.

21.

3-1

.20.

01.

41.

77.

9C

zech

Rep

ublic

5.7

7.0

0.1

0.7

-0.8

0.0

0.9

1.0

0.2

1.6

-1.7

0.0

1.4

1.5

8.5

Den

mar

k4.

65.

30.

10.

5-0

.60.

00.

90.

90.

10.

8-1

.10.

01.

41.

26.

4Fi

nlan

d2.

73.

40.

10.

8-0

.80.

00.

91.

10.

21.

1-1

.70.

01.

41.

04.

4Fr

ance

6.2

7.0

0.1

0.6

-1.0

0.0

0.9

0.7

0.2

1.2

-2.0

0.0

1.4

0.8

7.8

Ger

man

y7.

47.

80.

10.

6-0

.60.

00.

90.

90.

21.

0-1

.40.

01.

41.

29.

0G

reec

e5.

04.

90.

10.

5-0

.50.

00.

91.

00.

21.

0-1

.10.

01.

41.

56.

4

Hun

gary

4.8

6.7

0.1

0.7

-0.9

0.0

0.9

0.9

0.2

1.4

-2.0

0.0

1.4

0.9

7.6

Icel

and

5.4

6.8

0.1

0.6

-0.4

0.0

0.9

1.2

0.2

1.0

-0.7

0.0

1.4

1.8

8.5

Irela

nd4.

25.

90.

10.

5-0

.50.

00.

91.

10.

21.

3-1

.20.

01.

41.

77.

7Ita

ly5.

36.

00.

10.

7-1

.00.

00.

90.

80.

21.

6-2

.30.

01.

40.

96.

8Ja

pan

5.3

6.0

0.1

0.8

-0.5

0.0

0.9

1.4

0.2

1.4

-1.0

0.0

1.4

1.9

7.9

Kore

a2.

03.

00.

21.

3-1

.00.

00.

91.

40.

32.

6-2

.50.

01.

41.

84.

8Lu

xem

bour

g4.

96.

10.

10.

4-0

.60.

00.

90.

80.

20.

9-1

.20.

01.

41.

37.

5M

exic

o2.

53.

00.

10.

7-0

.50.

00.

91.

20.

22.

0-1

.60.

01.

41.

94.

9N

ethe

rland

s3.

95.

10.

10.

6-0

.40.

00.

91.

30.

10.

8-0

.60.

01.

41.

76.

8N

ew Z

eala

nd5.

76.

00.

10.

8-0

.60.

00.

91.

20.

21.

5-1

.40.

01.

41.

77.

7

Nor

way

5.2

7.3

0.1

0.5

-0.7

0.0

0.9

0.8

0.2

0.9

-1.6

0.0

1.4

0.9

8.1

Pola

nd3.

64.

40.

11.

0-1

.10.

00.

91.

00.

22.

1-2

.70.

01.

41.

15.

5Po

rtuga

l6.

26.

70.

10.

6-0

.70.

00.

91.

00.

21.

5-1

.50.

01.

41.

78.

4Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

4.6

5.1

0.1

1.0

-1.0

0.0

0.9

1.2

0.3

2.2

-2.2

0.0

1.4

1.7

6.8

Spai

n5.

15.

50.

10.

5-0

.50.

00.

91.

00.

21.

3-1

.10.

01.

41.

87.

2

Swed

en4.

55.

30.

10.

4-0

.50.

00.

90.

90.

10.

5-1

.00.

01.

41.

06.

3Sw

itzer

land

4.9

6.2

0.1

0.5

-0.5

0.0

0.9

1.0

0.1

0.8

-1.1

0.0

1.4

1.2

7.4

Turk

ey4.

15.

90.

10.

6-0

.70.

00.

91.

00.

31.

7-1

.90.

01.

41.

57.

3U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m5.

06.

10.

10.

6-0

.80.

00.

90.

80.

21.

0-1

.60.

01.

41.

07.

1U

nite

d St

ates

5.1

6.3

0.1

0.6

-0.7

0.0

0.9

0.9

0.1

0.8

-1.3

0.0

1.4

1.0

7.3

Aver

age

4.8

5.7

0.1

0.7

-0.7

0.0

0.9

1.0

0.2

1.3

-1.5

0.0

1.4

1.4

7.0

NB:

Ass

umpt

ions

use

d in

this

sce

nario

:H

ealth

y ag

eing

: 1

year

gai

ns in

life

exp

ecta

ncy

= 2

year

s in

goo

d he

alth

Inco

me

elas

ticity

= 1

Res

idua

ls =

1 w

ith a

tran

sver

salit

y co

nditi

onSo

urce

: Sec

reta

riat c

alcu

latio

ns.

Page 64: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

64

Tabl

e A2

.3 (c

ont.)

Bre

akdo

wn

of th

e pr

ojec

tions

of p

ublic

hea

lth c

are

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Sens

itivi

ty a

naly

sis:

Exp

ansi

on o

f mor

bidi

ty s

cena

rio

Hea

lth e

xpen

ditu

re a

s a

% o

f GD

P

Dea

th-

rela

ted

cost

s

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lD

eath

-re

late

d co

sts

Pure

age

ef

fect

(s

urvi

vors

)

Adju

stm

ent

for h

ealth

y ag

eing

Inco

me

effe

ct

Non

-ag

eing

re

sidu

al

effe

ct

Tota

lH

ealth

ex

pend

iture

as

a %

of G

DP

2000

2005

Incr

ease

in %

poi

nts

of G

DP

2005

-202

5In

crea

se in

% p

oint

s of

GD

P 20

05-2

050

2050

Aust

ralia

5.3

5.6

0.1

0.8

0.0

0.0

0.9

1.9

0.3

1.5

0.0

0.0

1.4

3.1

8.7

Aust

ria3.

83.

80.

10.

60.

00.

00.

91.

60.

21.

30.

00.

01.

42.

96.

7Be

lgiu

m4.

95.

70.

10.

50.

00.

00.

91.

50.

10.

90.

00.

01.

42.

48.

2C

anad

a5.

36.

20.

10.

80.

00.

00.

91.

90.

21.

30.

00.

01.

42.

99.

1C

zech

Rep

ublic

5.7

7.0

0.1

0.7

0.0

0.0

0.9

1.8

0.2

1.6

0.0

0.0

1.4

3.2

10.3

Den

mar

k4.

65.

30.

10.

50.

00.

00.

91.

50.

10.

80.

00.

01.

42.

37.

6Fi

nlan

d2.

73.

40.

10.

80.

00.

00.

91.

90.

21.

10.

00.

01.

42.

76.

1Fr

ance

6.2

7.0

0.1

0.6

0.0

0.0

0.9

1.6

0.2

1.2

0.0

0.0

1.4

2.8

9.8

Ger

man

y7.

47.

80.

10.

60.

00.

00.

91.

60.

21.

00.

00.

01.

42.

610

.4G

reec

e5.

04.

90.

10.

50.

00.

00.

91.

50.

21.

00.

00.

01.

42.

67.

5

Hun

gary

4.8

6.7

0.1

0.7

0.0

0.0

0.9

1.8

0.2

1.4

0.0

0.0

1.4

2.9

9.6

Icel

and

5.4

6.8

0.1

0.6

0.0

0.0

0.9

1.6

0.2

1.0

0.0

0.0

1.4

2.5

9.3

Irela

nd4.

25.

90.

10.

50.

00.

00.

91.

60.

21.

30.

00.

01.

42.

98.

8Ita

ly5.

36.

00.

10.

70.

00.

00.

91.

80.

21.

60.

00.

01.

43.

29.

2Ja

pan

5.3

6.0

0.1

0.8

0.0

0.0

0.9

1.9

0.2

1.4

0.0

0.0

1.4

3.0

9.0

Kore

a2.

03.

00.

21.

30.

00.

00.

92.

40.

32.

60.

00.

01.

44.

37.

3Lu

xem

bour

g4.

96.

10.

10.

40.

00.

00.

91.

40.

20.

90.

00.

01.

42.

58.

6M

exic

o2.

53.

00.

10.

70.

00.

00.

91.

70.

22.

00.

00.

01.

43.

56.

5N

ethe

rland

s3.

95.

10.

10.

60.

00.

00.

91.

70.

10.

80.

00.

01.

42.

47.

4N

ew Z

eala

nd5.

76.

00.

10.

80.

00.

00.

91.

90.

21.

50.

00.

01.

43.

19.

1

Nor

way

5.2

7.3

0.1

0.5

0.0

0.0

0.9

1.5

0.2

0.9

0.0

0.0

1.4

2.4

9.7

Pola

nd3.

64.

40.

11.

00.

00.

00.

92.

10.

22.

10.

00.

01.

43.

88.

2Po

rtuga

l6.

26.

70.

10.

60.

00.

00.

91.

70.

21.

50.

00.

01.

43.

29.

9Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

4.6

5.1

0.1

1.0

0.0

0.0

0.9

2.1

0.3

2.2

0.0

0.0

1.4

3.9

9.0

Spai

n5.

15.

50.

10.

50.

00.

00.

91.

60.

21.

30.

00.

01.

42.

98.

3

Swed

en4.

55.

30.

10.

40.

00.

00.

91.

40.

10.

50.

00.

01.

42.

07.

3Sw

itzer

land

4.9

6.2

0.1

0.5

0.0

0.0

0.9

1.5

0.1

0.8

0.0

0.0

1.4

2.3

8.4

Turk

ey4.

15.

90.

10.

60.

00.

00.

91.

70.

31.

70.

00.

01.

43.

49.

2U

nite

d Ki

ngdo

m5.

06.

10.

10.

60.

00.

00.

91.

60.

21.

00.

00.

01.

42.

68.

7U

nite

d St

ates

5.1

6.3

0.1

0.6

0.0

0.0

0.9

1.6

0.1

0.8

0.0

0.0

1.4

2.3

8.6

Aver

age

4.8

5.7

0.1

0.7

0.0

0.0

0.9

1.7

0.2

1.3

0.0

0.0

1.4

2.9

8.5

NB:

Ass

umpt

ions

use

d in

this

sce

nario

:Ex

pans

ion

of m

orbi

dity

: ga

ins

in li

fe e

xpec

tanc

y do

not

tran

slat

e in

to y

ears

in g

ood

heal

thIn

com

e el

astic

ity =

1R

esid

uals

= 1

with

a tr

ansv

ersa

lity

cond

ition

Sour

ce: S

ecre

taria

t cal

cula

tions

.

Page 65: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

EC

O/W

KP(

2006

)5

65

Tabl

e A2.4

Bre

akdo

wn o

f the

pro

jectio

ns o

f lon

g-te

rm ca

re ex

pend

iture

for e

ach

drive

rDe

mog

raph

ic ef

fect

Long

-term

care

expe

nditu

re as

a %

of G

DPPu

re a

geing

ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

agein

gInc

ome e

ffect

Cost

disea

se

effe

ct

Effe

ct of

the

partic

ipatio

n rat

e of

peop

le ag

ed

50-6

4

Tota

l incr

ease

Pure

age

ing

effe

ctAd

justm

ent f

or

healt

hy a

geing

Inco

me

effe

ctCo

st dis

ease

ef

fect

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipat

ion ra

te of

peo

ple a

ged

50-6

4

Tota

l incr

ease

Leve

l as a

% o

f GD

P

(0)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)=

Sum

(1) t

o (5)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

(11)

(12)

=Sum

(7) t

o (11

)(1

3)=(

0)+(

12)

2000

120

05 e

Incr

ease

in %

poin

ts of

GDP

2005

-202

5Inc

reas

e in

% po

ints o

f GDP

200

5-20

5020

50

Austr

alia

0.9

0.90.6

-0.1

-0.4

0.30.

00.4

1.8

-0.5

-0.6

0.6

0.01.3

2.2Au

stria

1.3

1.30.5

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.

00.3

1.6

-0.5

-0.5

0.6

0.01.2

2.5Be

lgium

1.

31.5

0.4-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.0

0.21.

3-0

.4-0

.50.

50.0

0.92.4

Cana

da1.

01.2

0.6-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.0

0.41.

6-0

.4-0

.60.

60.0

1.12.3

Czec

h Re

publi

c 0.

30.4

0.6-0

.1-0

.20.2

0.0

0.52.

1-0

.5-0

.40.

50.0

1.62.0

Denm

ark

2.3

2.60.3

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.

00.1

1.1

-0.4

-0.6

0.5

0.00.7

3.3Fin

land

2.3

2.90.8

-0.1

-0.4

0.30.

00.6

1.9

-0.5

-0.6

0.6

0.01.4

4.3Fr

ance

1.0

1.10.5

-0.1

-0.2

0.20.

00.4

1.7

-0.5

-0.5

0.5

0.01.2

2.3Ge

rman

y1.

01.0

0.6-0

.1-0

.20.2

0.0

0.41.

3-0

.4-0

.50.

50.0

0.91.9

Gree

ce

0.2

0.20.6

-0.1

-0.4

0.20.

00.3

1.3

-0.4

-0.6

0.5

0.00.8

1.0

Hung

ary

0.2

0.30.7

-0.1

-0.4

0.40.

00.5

1.6

-0.5

-0.6

0.8

0.01.3

1.5Ice

land

2.3

2.90.3

-0.1

-0.4

0.30.

00.0

1.0

-0.3

-0.7

0.6

0.00.6

3.5Ire

land

0.5

0.70.3

-0.1

-0.6

0.40.

00.1

1.3

-0.4

-0.8

0.8

0.01.0

1.7Ita

ly 0.

60.6

0.7-0

.1-0

.20.2

0.0

0.51.

8-0

.5-0

.50.

50.0

1.32.0

Japa

n 0.

80.9

1.0-0

.2-0

.20.2

0.0

0.82.

0-0

.5-0

.50.

50.0

1.52.3

Kore

a 0.

20.3

1.4-0

.2-0

.30.3

0.0

1.24.

7-1

.0-0

.50.

60.0

3.84.1

Luxe

mbo

urg

0.5

0.70.4

-0.1

-0.5

0.40.

00.2

1.4

-0.4

-0.7

0.7

0.01.0

1.6Me

xico

0.1

0.10.7

-0.1

-0.5

0.30.

00.3

2.6

-0.6

-0.8

0.7

0.01.9

2.0Ne

ther

lands

1.3

1.70.5

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.

00.3

1.1

-0.4

-0.6

0.5

0.00.7

2.4Ne

w Ze

aland

0.5

0.50.7

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.

00.5

2.1

-0.5

-0.5

0.5

0.01.6

2.0

Norw

ay1.

92.6

0.2-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.0

0.01.

1-0

.4-0

.60.

50.0

0.73.3

Polan

d0.

40.5

0.8-0

.1-0

.50.5

0.0

0.62.

5-0

.6-0

.71.

00.0

2.12.6

Portu

gal

0.2

0.20.6

-0.1

-0.4

0.30.

00.3

1.6

-0.5

-0.6

0.6

0.01.1

1.3Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

0.3

0.30.8

-0.1

-0.3

0.30.

00.6

2.8

-0.7

-0.5

0.7

0.02.3

2.6Sp

ain0.

20.2

0.4-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.0

0.31.

3-0

.4-0

.50.

50.0

0.91.0

Swed

en2.

73.3

0.2-0

.1-0

.30.3

0.0

0.10.

6-0

.3-0

.60.

60.0

0.33.6

Switz

erlan

d 1.

01.2

0.3-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.0

0.10.

9-0

.3-0

.50.

50.0

0.51.7

Turk

ey

0.1

0.10.6

-0.1

-0.4

0.30.

00.4

2.2

-0.6

-0.6

0.6

0.01.7

1.8Un

ited K

ingdo

m0.

91.1

0.5-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.0

0.31.

5-0

.4-0

.60.

60.0

1.02.1

Unite

d Sta

tes

0.7

0.90.4

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.

00.2

1.3

-0.4

-0.6

0.6

0.00.9

1.8

Aver

age

0.91.1

0.6-0

.1-0

.30.3

0.00.4

1.7-0

.5-0

.60.6

0.01.2

2.3

NB: A

ssum

ption

s use

d in t

his sc

enar

io:He

althy

age

ing : d

ynam

ic eq

uilibr

ium (1

year

gain

s in l

ife e

xpec

tanc

y = 1

/2 ye

ar in

goo

d he

alth)

; zer

o inc

ome

elasti

city;

half B

aum

ol ef

fect

1. OE

CD, L

ong-

term

care

for o

lder p

eople

and

Sec

reta

riat e

stim

ates

.e :

Esti

mat

es, ta

king i

nto a

ccou

nt th

e obs

erve

d exp

endit

ure g

rowt

h be

twee

n 20

00 an

d 200

2-03

.So

urce

: Sec

reta

riat c

alcula

tions

.

Page 66: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

66

Tabl

e A2.4

(con

t.) B

reak

down

of t

he p

rojec

tions

of l

ong-

term

care

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Cost-

pres

sure

scen

ario

Long

-term

care

exp

endit

ure

as a

%

of G

DPPu

re a

geing

ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

age

ingIn

com

e ef

fect

Cost

disea

se

effe

ct

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipat

ion ra

te

of pe

ople

aged

50

-64

Total

incr

ease

Pure

agein

g ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

agein

gIn

com

e effe

ctCo

st dis

ease

ef

fect

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipati

on ra

te of

peo

ple ag

ed

50-6

4

Total

incr

ease

Leve

l as a

% o

f GD

P

(0)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)=

Sum

(1) t

o (5

)(7

)(8

)(9

)(1

0)(1

1)(1

2)=S

um (7

) to

(11)

(13)

=(0)

+(12

)

2000

120

05 e

Incr

ease

in %

poin

ts of

GDP

200

5-20

25In

crea

se in

% p

oints

of G

DP 20

05-2

050

2050

Austr

alia

0.9

0.9

0.6-0

.1-0

.40.6

-0.1

0.5

1.8

-0.5

-0.6

1.5

-0.2

2.0

2.9

Austr

ia1.

31.

30.5

-0.1

-0.3

0.50.0

0.6

1.6

-0.5

-0.5

1.4

0.0

2.0

3.3

Belgi

um

1.3

1.5

0.4-0

.1-0

.30.5

0.10.

61.

3-0

.4-0

.51.

30.

21.

93.

4Ca

nada

1.0

1.2

0.6-0

.1-0

.30.5

0.00.

61.

6-0

.4-0

.61.

40.

12.

13.

2Cz

ech R

epub

lic

0.3

0.4

0.6-0

.1-0

.20.4

0.00.

72.

1-0

.5-0

.41.

1-0

.61.

72.

0

Denm

ark

2.3

2.6

0.3-0

.1-0

.30.5

-0.1

0.4

1.1

-0.4

-0.6

1.4

0.0

1.5

4.1

Finlan

d2.

32.

90.8

-0.1

-0.4

0.7-0

.20.

81.

9-0

.5-0

.61.

7-0

.12.

45.

2Fr

ance

1.0

1.1

0.5-0

.1-0

.20.4

-0.2

0.4

1.7

-0.5

-0.5

1.3

-0.3

1.7

2.8

Germ

any

1.0

1.0

0.6-0

.1-0

.20.4

0.20.

81.

3-0

.4-0

.51.

10.

31.

92.

9Gr

eece

0.

20.

20.6

-0.1

-0.4

0.50.7

1.3

1.3

-0.4

-0.6

1.4

1.0

2.7

2.8

Hung

ary

0.2

0.3

0.7-0

.1-0

.40.8

-0.1

0.8

1.6

-0.5

-0.6

2.1

-0.5

2.1

2.4

Icelan

d2.

32.

90.3

-0.1

-0.4

0.7-0

.10.

31.

0-0

.3-0

.71.

6-0

.11.

64.

4Ire

land

0.5

0.7

0.3-0

.1-0

.61.0

0.81.

51.

3-0

.4-0

.82.

21.

53.

84.

6Ita

ly 0.

60.

60.7

-0.1

-0.2

0.40.6

1.3

1.8

-0.5

-0.5

1.1

0.9

2.9

3.5

Japa

n 0.

80.

91.0

-0.2

-0.2

0.40.1

1.1

2.0

-0.5

-0.5

1.1

0.0

2.2

3.1

Kore

a 0.

20.

31.4

-0.2

-0.3

0.6-0

.51.

14.

7-1

.0-0

.51.

6-1

.03.

84.

1Lu

xem

bour

g0.

50.

70.4

-0.1

-0.5

0.90.6

1.3

1.4

-0.4

-0.7

2.0

0.9

3.1

3.8

Mexic

o 0.

10.

10.7

-0.1

-0.5

0.70.5

1.2

2.6

-0.6

-0.8

1.9

1.0

4.1

4.2

Nethe

rland

s1.

31.

70.5

-0.1

-0.3

0.50.2

0.7

1.1

-0.4

-0.6

1.3

0.5

2.0

3.7

New

Zeala

nd0.

50.

50.7

-0.1

-0.3

0.4-0

.10.

62.

1-0

.5-0

.51.

3-0

.42.

02.

4

Norw

ay1.

92.

60.2

-0.1

-0.3

0.50.0

0.3

1.1

-0.4

-0.6

1.3

0.2

1.7

4.3

Polan

d0.

40.

50.8

-0.1

-0.5

1.2-0

.31.

12.

5-0

.6-0

.72.

9-0

.83.

23.

7Po

rtuga

l0.

20.

20.6

-0.1

-0.4

0.60.0

0.6

1.6

-0.5

-0.6

1.5

0.0

2.0

2.2

Slov

ak R

epub

lic0.

30.

30.8

-0.1

-0.3

0.6-0

.30.

72.

8-0

.7-0

.51.

7-1

.02.

32.

6Sp

ain0.

20.

20.4

-0.1

-0.3

0.40.6

1.1

1.3

-0.4

-0.5

1.2

0.8

2.4

2.6

Swed

en2.

73.

30.2

-0.1

-0.3

0.6-0

.10.

30.

6-0

.3-0

.61.

5-0

.21.

14.

3Sw

itzer

land

1.0

1.2

0.3-0

.1-0

.30.4

0.00.

40.

9-0

.3-0

.51.

20.

21.

42.

6Tu

rkey

0.

10.

10.6

-0.1

-0.4

0.6-0

.40.

42.

2-0

.6-0

.61.

6-1

.01.

61.

8Un

ited

King

dom

0.9

1.1

0.5-0

.1-0

.30.6

0.00.

61.

5-0

.4-0

.61.

40.

01.

93.

0Un

ited

Stat

es

0.7

0.9

0.4-0

.1-0

.30.5

-0.1

0.4

1.3

-0.4

-0.6

1.4

0.0

1.7

2.7

Aver

age

0.91.1

0.6-0

.1-0

.30.6

0.10.8

1.7-0

.5-0

.61.5

0.02.2

3.3

NB: A

ssum

ption

s use

d in

this

scen

ario:

Healt

hy ag

eing :

dyn

amic

equil

ibrium

(1 ye

ar ga

ins in

life e

xpec

tancy

= 1

/2 ye

ar in

goo

d hea

lth);

zero

inco

me

elasti

city;

full B

aum

ol ef

fect;

bas

eline

par

ticipa

tion r

atios

1. OE

CD, L

ong-

term

care

for o

lder p

eople

and

Sec

reta

riat e

stim

ates

.e :

Esti

mat

es, ta

king

into

acco

unt t

he ob

serv

ed ex

pend

iture

gro

wth

betw

een

2000

and

200

2-03

.So

urce

: Sec

retar

iat ca

lculat

ions.

Page 67: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

EC

O/W

KP(

2006

)5

67

Tabl

e A2.4

(con

t.) B

reak

down

of t

he p

rojec

tions

of l

ong-

term

care

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Cost-

conta

inmen

t sce

nario

Long

-term

care

exp

endit

ure

as a

%

of G

DPPu

re a

geing

ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

age

ingIn

com

e ef

fect

Cost

disea

se

effe

ct

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipat

ion ra

te

of pe

ople

aged

50

-64

Total

incr

ease

Pure

agein

g ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

agein

gIn

com

e effe

ctCo

st dis

ease

ef

fect

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipati

on ra

te of

peo

ple ag

ed

50-6

4

Total

incr

ease

Leve

l as a

% o

f GD

P

(0)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)=

Sum

(1) t

o (5

)(7

)(8

)(9

)(1

0)(1

1)(1

2)=S

um (7

) to

(11)

(13)

=(0)

+(12

)

2000

120

05 e

Incr

ease

in %

poin

ts of

GDP

200

5-20

25In

crea

se in

% p

oints

of G

DP 20

05-2

050

2050

Austr

alia

0.9

0.9

0.6-0

.1-0

.40.3

-0.1

0.2

1.8

-0.5

-0.6

0.6

-0.2

1.1

2.0

Austr

ia1.

31.

30.5

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.0

0.3

1.6

-0.5

-0.5

0.6

0.0

1.2

2.5

Belgi

um

1.3

1.5

0.4-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.10.

31.

3-0

.4-0

.50.

50.

21.

12.

6Ca

nada

1.0

1.2

0.6-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.00.

41.

6-0

.4-0

.60.

60.

11.

32.

4Cz

ech R

epub

lic

0.3

0.4

0.6-0

.1-0

.20.2

0.00.

52.

1-0

.5-0

.40.

5-0

.61.

01.

3

Denm

ark

2.3

2.6

0.3-0

.1-0

.30.2

-0.1

0.1

1.1

-0.4

-0.6

0.5

0.0

0.7

3.3

Finlan

d2.

32.

90.8

-0.1

-0.4

0.3-0

.20.

41.

9-0

.5-0

.60.

6-0

.11.

34.

2Fr

ance

1.0

1.1

0.5-0

.1-0

.20.2

-0.2

0.2

1.7

-0.5

-0.5

0.5

-0.3

1.0

2.0

Germ

any

1.0

1.0

0.6-0

.1-0

.20.2

0.20.

61.

3-0

.4-0

.50.

50.

31.

22.

2Gr

eece

0.

20.

20.6

-0.1

-0.4

0.20.7

1.0

1.3

-0.4

-0.6

0.5

1.0

1.8

2.0

Hung

ary

0.2

0.3

0.7-0

.1-0

.40.4

-0.1

0.4

1.6

-0.5

-0.6

0.8

-0.5

0.7

1.0

Icelan

d2.

32.

90.3

-0.1

-0.4

0.3-0

.10.

01.

0-0

.3-0

.70.

6-0

.10.

63.

4Ire

land

0.5

0.7

0.3-0

.1-0

.60.4

0.80.

91.

3-0

.4-0

.80.

81.

52.

43.

2Ita

ly 0.

60.

60.7

-0.1

-0.2

0.20.6

1.1

1.8

-0.5

-0.5

0.5

0.9

2.2

2.8

Japa

n 0.

80.

91.0

-0.2

-0.2

0.20.1

0.9

2.0

-0.5

-0.5

0.5

0.0

1.5

2.4

Kore

a 0.

20.

31.4

-0.2

-0.3

0.3-0

.50.

74.

7-1

.0-0

.50.

6-1

.02.

83.

1Lu

xem

bour

g0.

50.

70.4

-0.1

-0.5

0.40.6

0.7

1.4

-0.4

-0.7

0.7

0.9

1.9

2.6

Mexic

o 0.

10.

10.7

-0.1

-0.5

0.30.5

0.8

2.6

-0.6

-0.8

0.7

1.0

2.9

3.0

Nethe

rland

s1.

31.

70.5

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.2

0.4

1.1

-0.4

-0.6

0.5

0.5

1.2

2.9

New

Zeala

nd0.

50.

50.7

-0.1

-0.3

0.2-0

.10.

42.

1-0

.5-0

.50.

5-0

.41.

21.

7

Norw

ay1.

92.

60.2

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.0

0.1

1.1

-0.4

-0.6

0.5

0.2

0.9

3.5

Polan

d0.

40.

50.8

-0.1

-0.5

0.5-0

.30.

42.

5-0

.6-0

.71.

0-0

.81.

31.

8Po

rtuga

l0.

20.

20.6

-0.1

-0.4

0.30.0

0.3

1.6

-0.5

-0.6

0.6

0.0

1.1

1.3

Slov

ak R

epub

lic0.

30.

30.8

-0.1

-0.3

0.3-0

.30.

32.

8-0

.7-0

.50.

7-1

.01.

21.

5Sp

ain0.

20.

20.4

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.6

0.8

1.3

-0.4

-0.5

0.5

0.8

1.7

1.9

Swed

en2.

73.

30.2

-0.1

-0.3

0.3-0

.1-0

.10.

6-0

.3-0

.60.

6-0

.20.

13.

4Sw

itzer

land

1.0

1.2

0.3-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.00.

20.

9-0

.3-0

.50.

50.

20.

71.

9Tu

rkey

0.

10.

10.6

-0.1

-0.4

0.3-0

.40.

02.

2-0

.6-0

.60.

6-1

.00.

70.

8Un

ited

King

dom

0.9

1.1

0.5-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.00.

31.

5-0

.4-0

.60.

60.

01.

12.

1Un

ited

Stat

es

0.7

0.9

0.4-0

.1-0

.30.2

-0.1

0.1

1.3

-0.4

-0.6

0.6

0.0

0.9

1.8

Aver

age

0.91.1

0.6-0

.1-0

.30.3

0.10.4

1.7-0

.5-0

.60.6

0.01.3

2.4

NB: A

ssum

ption

s use

d in

this

scen

ario:

Healt

hy ag

eing :

dyn

amic

equil

ibrium

(1 ye

ar ga

ins in

life e

xpec

tancy

= 1

/2 ye

ar in

goo

d hea

lth);

zero

inco

me

elasti

city;

half B

aum

ol ef

fect;

bas

eline

parti

cipat

ion ra

tios

1. OE

CD, L

ong-

term

care

for o

lder p

eople

and

Sec

reta

riat e

stim

ates

.e :

Esti

mat

es, ta

king

into

acco

unt t

he ob

serv

ed ex

pend

iture

gro

wth

betw

een

2000

and

200

2-03

.So

urce

: Sec

retar

iat ca

lculat

ions.

Page 68: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

68

Tabl

e A2.4

(con

t.) B

reak

down

of t

he p

rojec

tions

of l

ong-

term

care

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Sens

itivity

ana

lysis:

"Unit

ary i

ncom

e ela

sticit

y"

Long

-term

care

exp

endit

ure

as a

%

of G

DPPu

re a

geing

ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

age

ingIn

com

e ef

fect

Cost

disea

se

effe

ct

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipat

ion ra

te

of pe

ople

aged

50

-64

Total

incr

ease

Pure

agein

g ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

agein

gIn

com

e effe

ctCo

st dis

ease

ef

fect

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipati

on ra

te of

peo

ple ag

ed

50-6

4

Total

incr

ease

Leve

l as a

% o

f GD

P

(0)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)=

Sum

(1) t

o (5

)(7

)(8

)(9

)(1

0)(1

1)(1

2)=S

um (7

) to

(11)

(13)

=(0)

+(12

)

2000

120

05 e

Incr

ease

in %

poin

ts of

GDP

200

5-20

25In

crea

se in

% p

oints

of G

DP 20

05-2

050

2050

Austr

alia

0.9

0.9

0.6-0

.10.0

0.3-0

.10.

61.

8-0

.50.

00.

6-0

.21.

72.

6Au

stria

1.3

1.3

0.5-0

.10.0

0.20.0

0.6

1.6

-0.5

0.0

0.6

0.0

1.7

3.0

Belgi

um

1.3

1.5

0.4-0

.10.0

0.20.1

0.6

1.3

-0.4

0.0

0.5

0.2

1.7

3.2

Cana

da1.

01.

20.6

-0.1

0.00.2

0.00.

71.

6-0

.40.

00.

60.

11.

83.

0Cz

ech R

epub

lic

0.3

0.4

0.6-0

.10.0

0.20.0

0.7

2.1

-0.5

0.0

0.5

-0.6

1.4

1.7

Denm

ark

2.3

2.6

0.3-0

.10.0

0.2-0

.10.

41.

1-0

.40.

00.

50.

01.

23.

9Fin

land

2.3

2.9

0.8-0

.10.0

0.3-0

.20.

81.

9-0

.50.

00.

6-0

.11.

94.

8Fr

ance

1.0

1.1

0.5-0

.10.0

0.2-0

.20.

41.

7-0

.50.

00.

5-0

.31.

42.

5Ge

rman

y1.

01.

00.6

-0.1

0.00.2

0.20.

81.

3-0

.40.

00.

50.

31.

72.

7Gr

eece

0.

20.

20.6

-0.1

0.00.2

0.71.

41.

3-0

.40.

00.

51.

02.

42.

6

Hung

ary

0.2

0.3

0.7-0

.10.0

0.4-0

.10.

81.

6-0

.50.

00.

8-0

.51.

31.

6Ice

land

2.3

2.9

0.3-0

.10.0

0.3-0

.10.

41.

0-0

.30.

00.

6-0

.11.

24.

1Ire

land

0.5

0.7

0.3-0

.10.0

0.40.8

1.5

1.3

-0.4

0.0

0.8

1.5

3.2

3.9

Italy

0.6

0.6

0.7-0

.10.0

0.20.6

1.4

1.8

-0.5

0.0

0.5

0.9

2.7

3.3

Japa

n 0.

80.

91.0

-0.2

0.00.2

0.11.

12.

0-0

.50.

00.

50.

02.

02.

8

Kore

a 0.

20.

31.4

-0.2

0.00.3

-0.5

1.1

4.7

-1.0

0.0

0.6

-1.0

3.4

3.7

Luxe

mbo

urg

0.5

0.7

0.4-0

.10.0

0.40.6

1.3

1.4

-0.4

0.0

0.7

0.9

2.6

3.3

Mexic

o 0.

10.

10.7

-0.1

0.00.3

0.51.

42.

6-0

.60.

00.

71.

03.

73.

8Ne

therla

nds

1.3

1.7

0.5-0

.10.0

0.20.2

0.7

1.1

-0.4

0.0

0.5

0.5

1.7

3.5

New

Zeala

nd0.

50.

50.7

-0.1

0.00.2

-0.1

0.7

2.1

-0.5

0.0

0.5

-0.4

1.7

2.2

Norw

ay1.

92.

60.2

-0.1

0.00.2

0.00.

41.

1-0

.40.

00.

50.

21.

54.

1Po

land

0.4

0.5

0.8-0

.10.0

0.5-0

.30.

92.

5-0

.60.

01.

0-0

.82.

12.

5Po

rtuga

l0.

20.

20.6

-0.1

0.00.3

0.00.

71.

6-0

.50.

00.

60.

01.

71.

9Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

0.3

0.3

0.8-0

.10.0

0.3-0

.30.

72.

8-0

.70.

00.

7-1

.01.

72.

0Sp

ain0.

20.

20.4

-0.1

0.00.2

0.61.

11.

3-0

.40.

00.

50.

82.

22.

3

Swed

en2.

73.

30.2

-0.1

0.00.3

-0.1

0.3

0.6

-0.3

0.0

0.6

-0.2

0.7

4.0

Switz

erlan

d 1.

01.

20.3

-0.1

0.00.2

0.00.

40.

9-0

.30.

00.

50.

21.

22.

4Tu

rkey

0.

10.

10.6

-0.1

0.00.3

-0.4

0.4

2.2

-0.6

0.0

0.6

-1.0

1.3

1.4

Unite

d Ki

ngdo

m0.

91.

10.5

-0.1

0.00.2

0.00.

71.

5-0

.40.

00.

60.

01.

62.

7Un

ited

Stat

es

0.7

0.9

0.4-0

.10.0

0.2-0

.10.

41.

3-0

.40.

00.

60.

01.

52.

4

Aver

age

0.91.1

0.6-0

.10.0

0.30.1

0.81.7

-0.5

0.00.6

0.01.9

2.9

NB: A

ssum

ption

s use

d in

this

scen

ario:

Healt

hy ag

eing :

dyn

amic

equil

ibrium

(1 ye

ar ga

ins in

life e

xpec

tancy

= 1

/2 ye

ar in

goo

d hea

lth);

unit i

ncom

e elas

ticity

; half

Bau

mol

effe

ct; ba

selin

e pa

rticipa

tion

ratio

s1.

OECD

, Lon

g-te

rm ca

re fo

r olde

r peo

ple a

nd S

ecre

taria

t esti

mat

es.

e : E

stim

ates

, takin

g int

o ac

coun

t the

obse

rved

expe

nditu

re g

rowt

h be

twee

n 20

00 a

nd 2

002-

03.

Sour

ce: S

ecre

tariat

calcu

lation

s.

Page 69: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

EC

O/W

KP(

2006

)5

69

Tabl

e A2.4

(con

t.) B

reak

down

of t

he p

rojec

tions

of l

ong-

term

care

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Sens

itivity

ana

lysis:

"Com

pres

sion o

f disa

bility

" sce

nario

Long

-term

care

exp

endit

ure

as a

%

of G

DPPu

re a

geing

ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

age

ingIn

com

e ef

fect

Cost

disea

se

effe

ct

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipat

ion ra

te

of pe

ople

aged

50

-64

Total

incr

ease

Pure

agein

g ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

agein

gIn

com

e effe

ctCo

st dis

ease

ef

fect

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipati

on ra

te of

peo

ple ag

ed

50-6

4

Total

incr

ease

Leve

l as a

% o

f GD

P

(0)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)=

Sum

(1) t

o (5

)(7

)(8

)(9

)(1

0)(1

1)(1

2)=S

um (7

) to

(11)

(13)

=(0)

+(12

)

2000

120

05 e

Incr

ease

in %

poin

ts of

GDP

200

5-20

25In

crea

se in

% p

oints

of G

DP 20

05-2

050

2050

Austr

alia

0.9

0.9

0.6-0

.2-0

.40.3

-0.1

0.1

1.8

-1.0

-0.6

0.6

-0.2

0.6

1.5

Austr

ia1.

31.

30.5

-0.2

-0.3

0.20.0

0.2

1.6

-0.9

-0.5

0.6

0.0

0.7

2.0

Belgi

um

1.3

1.5

0.4-0

.2-0

.30.2

0.10.

21.

3-0

.8-0

.50.

50.

20.

72.

2Ca

nada

1.0

1.2

0.6-0

.2-0

.30.2

0.00.

21.

6-0

.9-0

.60.

60.

10.

81.

9Cz

ech R

epub

lic

0.3

0.4

0.6-0

.3-0

.20.2

0.00.

32.

1-1

.1-0

.40.

5-0

.50.

60.

9

Denm

ark

2.3

2.6

0.3-0

.2-0

.30.2

-0.1

0.0

1.1

-0.7

-0.6

0.5

0.0

0.3

2.9

Finlan

d2.

32.

90.8

-0.3

-0.4

0.3-0

.20.

21.

9-1

.0-0

.60.

6-0

.10.

83.

7Fr

ance

1.0

1.1

0.5-0

.2-0

.20.2

-0.2

0.1

1.7

-0.9

-0.5

0.5

-0.2

0.6

1.6

Germ

any

1.0

1.0

0.6-0

.2-0

.20.2

0.20.

51.

3-0

.8-0

.50.

50.

20.

71.

7Gr

eece

0.

20.

20.6

-0.3

-0.4

0.20.6

0.8

1.3

-0.8

-0.6

0.5

0.8

1.2

1.4

Hung

ary

0.2

0.3

0.7-0

.3-0

.40.4

-0.1

0.2

1.6

-0.9

-0.6

0.8

-0.4

0.4

0.6

Icelan

d2.

32.

90.3

-0.2

-0.4

0.3-0

.1-0

.11.

0-0

.7-0

.70.

60.

00.

23.

1Ire

land

0.5

0.7

0.3-0

.2-0

.60.4

0.80.

71.

3-0

.8-0

.80.

81.

21.

72.

5Ita

ly 0.

60.

60.7

-0.3

-0.2

0.20.6

0.9

1.8

-1.0

-0.5

0.5

0.7

1.5

2.2

Japa

n 0.

80.

91.0

-0.3

-0.2

0.20.1

0.8

2.0

-1.0

-0.5

0.5

0.0

1.0

1.9

Kore

a 0.

20.

31.4

-0.4

-0.3

0.3-0

.40.

64.

7-2

.0-0

.50.

6-0

.82.

02.

3Lu

xem

bour

g0.

50.

70.4

-0.2

-0.5

0.40.5

0.6

1.4

-0.8

-0.7

0.7

0.7

1.3

2.0

Mexic

o 0.

10.

10.7

-0.2

-0.5

0.30.4

0.7

2.6

-1.2

-0.8

0.7

0.8

2.1

2.2

Nethe

rland

s1.

31.

70.5

-0.2

-0.3

0.20.2

0.3

1.1

-0.7

-0.6

0.5

0.4

0.7

2.4

New

Zeala

nd0.

50.

50.7

-0.3

-0.3

0.2-0

.10.

32.

1-1

.1-0

.50.

5-0

.30.

71.

2

Norw

ay1.

92.

60.2

-0.2

-0.3

0.20.0

0.0

1.1

-0.7

-0.6

0.5

0.2

0.5

3.1

Polan

d0.

40.

50.8

-0.3

-0.5

0.5-0

.20.

32.

5-1

.2-0

.71.

0-0

.60.

91.

3Po

rtuga

l0.

20.

20.6

-0.2

-0.4

0.30.0

0.2

1.6

-0.9

-0.6

0.6

0.0

0.6

0.8

Slov

ak R

epub

lic0.

30.

30.8

-0.3

-0.3

0.3-0

.30.

22.

8-1

.3-0

.50.

7-0

.80.

81.

1Sp

ain0.

20.

20.4

-0.2

-0.3

0.20.5

0.7

1.3

-0.8

-0.5

0.5

0.6

1.1

1.3

Swed

en2.

73.

30.2

-0.2

-0.3

0.3-0

.1-0

.20.

6-0

.6-0

.60.

6-0

.2-0

.13.

2Sw

itzer

land

1.0

1.2

0.3-0

.2-0

.30.2

0.00.

10.

9-0

.7-0

.50.

50.

10.

31.

5Tu

rkey

0.

10.

10.6

-0.2

-0.4

0.3-0

.4-0

.12.

2-1

.1-0

.60.

6-0

.80.

30.

5Un

ited

King

dom

0.9

1.1

0.5-0

.2-0

.30.2

0.00.

21.

5-0

.8-0

.60.

60.

00.

61.

7Un

ited

Stat

es

0.7

0.9

0.4-0

.2-0

.30.2

-0.1

0.0

1.3

-0.8

-0.6

0.6

0.0

0.5

1.4

Aver

age

0.91.1

0.6-0

.2-0

.30.3

0.10.3

1.7-0

.9-0

.60.6

0.00.8

1.9

NB: A

ssum

ption

s use

d in

this

scen

ario:

Healt

hy ag

eing :

Shif

t of 5

year

s in

the

depe

nden

cy ra

tio; z

ero

incom

e elas

ticity

; half

Bau

mol

effe

ct; ba

selin

e pa

rticipa

tion

ratio

s1.

OECD

, Lon

g-te

rm ca

re fo

r olde

r peo

ple a

nd S

ecre

taria

t esti

mat

es.

e : E

stim

ates

, takin

g int

o ac

coun

t the

obse

rved

expe

nditu

re g

rowt

h be

twee

n 20

00 a

nd 2

002-

03.

Sour

ce: S

ecre

tariat

calcu

lation

s.

Page 70: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

70

Tabl

e A2.4

(con

t.) B

reak

down

of t

he p

rojec

tions

of l

ong-

term

care

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Sens

itivity

analy

sis: "

Expa

nsion

of d

isabil

ity" s

cena

rio

Long

-term

care

exp

endit

ure

as a

%

of G

DPPu

re a

geing

ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

age

ingIn

com

e ef

fect

Cost

disea

se

effe

ct

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipat

ion ra

te

of pe

ople

aged

50

-64

Total

incr

ease

Pure

agein

g ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

agein

gIn

com

e effe

ctCo

st dis

ease

ef

fect

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipati

on ra

te of

peo

ple ag

ed

50-6

4

Total

incr

ease

Leve

l as a

% o

f GD

P

(0)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)=

Sum

(1) t

o (5

)(7

)(8

)(9

)(1

0)(1

1)(1

2)=S

um (7

) to

(11)

(13)

=(0)

+(12

)

2000

120

05 e

Incr

ease

in %

poin

ts of

GDP

200

5-20

25In

crea

se in

% p

oints

of G

DP 20

05-2

050

2050

Austr

alia

0.9

0.9

0.60.0

-0.4

0.3-0

.20.

31.

80.

0-0

.60.

6-0

.31.

52.

4Au

stria

1.3

1.3

0.50.0

-0.3

0.20.0

0.4

1.6

0.0

-0.5

0.6

0.0

1.6

2.9

Belgi

um

1.3

1.5

0.40.0

-0.3

0.20.1

0.4

1.3

0.0

-0.5

0.5

0.3

1.6

3.1

Cana

da1.

01.

20.6

0.0-0

.30.2

0.00.

51.

60.

0-0

.60.

60.

11.

72.

9Cz

ech R

epub

lic

0.3

0.4

0.60.0

-0.2

0.20.0

0.6

2.1

0.0

-0.4

0.5

-0.8

1.4

1.8

Denm

ark

2.3

2.6

0.30.0

-0.3

0.2-0

.10.

21.

10.

0-0

.60.

5-0

.11.

03.

7Fin

land

2.3

2.9

0.80.0

-0.4

0.3-0

.30.

51.

90.

0-0

.60.

6-0

.11.

84.

6Fr

ance

1.0

1.1

0.50.0

-0.2

0.2-0

.20.

31.

70.

0-0

.50.

5-0

.31.

42.

4Ge

rman

y1.

01.

00.6

0.0-0

.20.2

0.20.

71.

30.

0-0

.50.

50.

41.

72.

7Gr

eece

0.

20.

20.6

0.0-0

.40.2

0.81.

21.

30.

0-0

.60.

51.

22.

42.

6

Hung

ary

0.2

0.3

0.70.0

-0.4

0.4-0

.10.

51.

60.

0-0

.60.

8-0

.71.

11.

3Ice

land

2.3

2.9

0.30.0

-0.4

0.3-0

.10.

11.

00.

0-0

.70.

6-0

.10.

93.

8Ire

land

0.5

0.7

0.30.0

-0.6

0.40.9

1.1

1.3

0.0

-0.8

0.8

1.8

3.1

3.9

Italy

0.6

0.6

0.70.0

-0.2

0.20.7

1.3

1.8

0.0

-0.5

0.5

1.1

2.9

3.5

Japa

n 0.

80.

91.0

0.0-0

.20.2

0.11.

12.

00.

0-0

.50.

50.

12.

02.

9

Kore

a 0.

20.

31.4

0.0-0

.30.3

-0.5

0.9

4.7

0.0

-0.5

0.6

-1.2

3.6

3.9

Luxe

mbo

urg

0.5

0.7

0.40.0

-0.5

0.40.6

0.9

1.4

0.0

-0.7

0.7

1.1

2.5

3.1

Mexic

o 0.

10.

10.7

0.0-0

.50.3

0.51.

02.

60.

0-0

.80.

71.

23.

73.

9Ne

therla

nds

1.3

1.7

0.50.0

-0.3

0.20.2

0.6

1.1

0.0

-0.6

0.5

0.6

1.7

3.4

New

Zeala

nd0.

50.

50.7

0.0-0

.30.2

-0.1

0.5

2.1

0.0

-0.5

0.5

-0.4

1.7

2.1

Norw

ay1.

92.

60.2

0.0-0

.30.2

0.00.

21.

10.

0-0

.60.

50.

31.

33.

9Po

land

0.4

0.5

0.80.0

-0.5

0.5-0

.30.

52.

50.

0-0

.71.

0-1

.01.

82.

2Po

rtuga

l0.

20.

20.6

0.0-0

.40.3

0.00.

41.

60.

0-0

.60.

60.

01.

61.

8Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

0.3

0.3

0.80.0

-0.3

0.3-0

.30.

52.

80.

0-0

.50.

7-1

.31.

72.

0Sp

ain0.

20.

20.4

0.0-0

.30.2

0.61.

01.

30.

0-0

.50.

51.

02.

32.

4

Swed

en2.

73.

30.2

0.0-0

.30.3

-0.2

0.0

0.6

0.0

-0.6

0.6

-0.3

0.4

3.6

Switz

erlan

d 1.

01.

20.3

0.0-0

.30.2

0.00.

30.

90.

0-0

.50.

50.

21.

12.

3Tu

rkey

0.

10.

10.6

0.0-0

.40.3

-0.4

0.1

2.2

0.0

-0.6

0.6

-1.2

1.0

1.2

Unite

d Ki

ngdo

m0.

91.

10.5

0.0-0

.30.2

0.00.

41.

50.

0-0

.60.

60.

11.

52.

6Un

ited

Stat

es

0.7

0.9

0.40.0

-0.3

0.2-0

.10.

21.

30.

0-0

.60.

60.

01.

32.

2

Aver

age

0.91.1

0.60.0

-0.3

0.30.1

0.61.7

0.0-0

.60.6

0.11.8

2.8

NB: A

ssum

ption

s use

d in

this

scen

ario:

Healt

hy ag

eing :

No

Healt

h ag

eing

adjus

tmen

t; ze

ro in

com

e ela

sticit

y; ha

lf Bau

mol

effe

ct; b

aseli

ne p

artic

ipatio

n rat

ios1.

OECD

, Lon

g-te

rm ca

re fo

r olde

r peo

ple a

nd S

ecre

taria

t esti

mat

es.

e : E

stim

ates

, takin

g int

o ac

coun

t the

obse

rved

expe

nditu

re g

rowt

h be

twee

n 20

00 a

nd 2

002-

03.

Sour

ce: S

ecre

tariat

calcu

lation

s.

Page 71: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

EC

O/W

KP(

2006

)5

71

Tabl

e A2.4

(con

t.) B

reak

down

of t

he p

rojec

tions

of l

ong-

term

care

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Sens

itivity

analy

sis: "

Incre

ase

in de

pend

ency

" sce

nario

Long

-term

care

exp

endit

ure

as a

%

of G

DPPu

re a

geing

ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

age

ingIn

com

e ef

fect

Cost

disea

se

effe

ct

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipat

ion ra

te

of pe

ople

aged

50

-64

Total

incr

ease

Pure

agein

g ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

agein

gIn

com

e effe

ctCo

st dis

ease

ef

fect

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipati

on ra

te of

peo

ple ag

ed

50-6

4

Total

incr

ease

Leve

l as a

% o

f GD

P

(0)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)=

Sum

(1) t

o (5

)(7

)(8

)(9

)(1

0)(1

1)(1

2)=S

um (7

) to

(11)

(13)

=(0)

+(12

)

2000

120

05 e

Incr

ease

in %

poin

ts of

GDP

200

5-20

25In

crea

se in

% p

oints

of G

DP 20

05-2

050

2050

Austr

alia

0.9

0.9

0.60.2

-0.4

0.3-0

.20.

51.

80.

7-0

.60.

6-0

.42.

23.

1Au

stria

1.3

1.3

0.50.2

-0.3

0.20.0

0.6

1.6

0.7

-0.5

0.6

0.0

2.3

3.6

Belgi

um

1.3

1.5

0.40.2

-0.3

0.20.1

0.6

1.3

0.6

-0.5

0.5

0.4

2.2

3.7

Cana

da1.

01.

20.6

0.2-0

.30.2

0.00.

61.

60.

7-0

.60.

60.

22.

43.

6Cz

ech R

epub

lic

0.3

0.4

0.60.2

-0.2

0.20.0

0.8

2.1

0.8

-0.4

0.5

-0.9

2.0

2.4

Denm

ark

2.3

2.6

0.30.1

-0.3

0.2-0

.10.

31.

10.

5-0

.60.

5-0

.11.

54.

2Fin

land

2.3

2.9

0.80.2

-0.4

0.3-0

.30.

71.

90.

7-0

.60.

6-0

.12.

55.

4Fr

ance

1.0

1.1

0.50.2

-0.2

0.2-0

.20.

41.

70.

7-0

.50.

5-0

.42.

03.

0Ge

rman

y1.

01.

00.6

0.2-0

.20.2

0.30.

91.

30.

6-0

.50.

50.

52.

43.

4Gr

eece

0.

20.

20.6

0.2-0

.40.2

0.81.

51.

30.

6-0

.60.

51.

53.

33.

5

Hung

ary

0.2

0.3

0.70.2

-0.4

0.4-0

.10.

71.

60.

7-0

.60.

8-0

.81.

51.

8Ice

land

2.3

2.9

0.30.1

-0.4

0.3-0

.10.

21.

00.

5-0

.70.

6-0

.11.

44.

3Ire

land

0.5

0.7

0.30.1

-0.6

0.41.0

1.3

1.3

0.6

-0.8

0.8

2.2

4.2

4.9

Italy

0.6

0.6

0.70.2

-0.2

0.20.7

1.6

1.8

0.7

-0.5

0.5

1.3

3.9

4.5

Japa

n 0.

80.

91.0

0.2-0

.20.2

0.11.

32.

00.

8-0

.50.

50.

12.

83.

7

Kore

a 0.

20.

31.4

0.3-0

.30.3

-0.5

1.1

4.7

1.5

-0.5

0.6

-1.5

4.8

5.1

Luxe

mbo

urg

0.5

0.7

0.40.2

-0.5

0.40.7

1.1

1.4

0.6

-0.7

0.7

1.4

3.4

4.0

Mexic

o 0.

10.

10.7

0.2-0

.50.3

0.61.

22.

60.

9-0

.80.

71.

55.

05.

1Ne

therla

nds

1.3

1.7

0.50.2

-0.3

0.20.2

0.8

1.1

0.5

-0.6

0.5

0.7

2.4

4.1

New

Zeala

nd0.

50.

50.7

0.2-0

.30.2

-0.1

0.7

2.1

0.8

-0.5

0.5

-0.5

2.4

2.8

Norw

ay1.

92.

60.2

0.1-0

.30.2

0.00.

31.

10.

5-0

.60.

50.

41.

94.

5Po

land

0.4

0.5

0.80.2

-0.5

0.5-0

.30.

72.

50.

9-0

.71.

0-1

.22.

42.

8Po

rtuga

l0.

20.

20.6

0.2-0

.40.3

0.00.

61.

60.

7-0

.60.

60.

02.

22.

4Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

0.3

0.3

0.80.2

-0.3

0.3-0

.30.

62.

81.

0-0

.50.

7-1

.62.

32.

6Sp

ain0.

20.

20.4

0.2-0

.30.2

0.71.

21.

30.

6-0

.50.

51.

23.

13.

3

Swed

en2.

73.

30.2

0.1-0

.30.3

-0.2

0.1

0.6

0.4

-0.6

0.6

-0.3

0.7

4.0

Switz

erlan

d 1.

01.

20.3

0.1-0

.30.2

0.00.

40.

90.

5-0

.50.

50.

21.

62.

8Tu

rkey

0.

10.

10.6

0.2-0

.40.3

-0.4

0.2

2.2

0.8

-0.6

0.6

-1.5

1.6

1.7

Unite

d Ki

ngdo

m0.

91.

10.5

0.2-0

.30.2

0.00.

61.

50.

6-0

.60.

60.

12.

13.

2Un

ited

Stat

es

0.7

0.9

0.40.2

-0.3

0.2-0

.10.

31.

30.

6-0

.60.

60.

01.

92.

8

Aver

age

0.91.1

0.60.2

-0.3

0.30.1

0.71.7

0.7-0

.60.6

0.12.5

3.5

NB: A

ssum

ption

s use

d in

this

scen

ario:

Healt

hy ag

eing :

dyn

amic

equil

ibrium

(1 ye

ar ga

ins in

life e

xpec

tancy

= 1

/2 ye

ar in

goo

d hea

lth),

but d

epen

denc

y rat

es in

crea

se b

y 0.5

% p

er ye

ar; z

ero i

ncom

e ela

sticit

y; ha

lf Bau

mol

effe

ct; ba

selin

e par

ticipa

tion

ratio

s1.

OECD

, Lon

g-te

rm ca

re fo

r olde

r peo

ple a

nd S

ecre

taria

t esti

mat

es.

e : E

stim

ates

, takin

g int

o ac

coun

t the

obse

rved

expe

nditu

re g

rowt

h be

twee

n 20

00 a

nd 2

002-

03.

Sour

ce: S

ecre

tariat

calcu

lation

s.

Page 72: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

72

Tabl

e A2.4

(con

t.) B

reak

down

of t

he p

rojec

tions

of l

ong-

term

care

expe

nditu

re fo

r eac

h dr

iver

Sens

itivity

ana

lysis:

"Inc

reas

ed pa

rticipa

tion"

scen

ario

Long

-term

care

exp

endit

ure

as a

%

of G

DPPu

re a

geing

ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

age

ingIn

com

e ef

fect

Cost

disea

se

effe

ct

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipat

ion ra

te

of pe

ople

aged

50

-64

Total

incr

ease

Pure

agein

g ef

fect

Adjus

tmen

t for

he

althy

agein

gIn

com

e effe

ctCo

st dis

ease

ef

fect

Effe

ct of

the

parti

cipati

on ra

te of

peo

ple ag

ed

50-6

4

Total

incr

ease

Leve

l as a

% o

f GD

P

(0)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)=

Sum

(1) t

o (5

)(7

)(8

)(9

)(1

0)(1

1)(1

2)=S

um (7

) to

(11)

(13)

=(0)

+(12

)

2000

120

05 e

Incr

ease

in %

poin

ts of

GDP

200

5-20

25In

crea

se in

% p

oints

of G

DP 20

05-2

050

2050

Austr

alia

0.9

0.9

0.6-0

.1-0

.40.3

0.30.

61.

8-0

.5-0

.60.

61.

02.

33.

2Au

stria

1.3

1.3

0.5-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.60.

91.

6-0

.5-0

.60.

62.

94.

05.

4Be

lgium

1.

31.

50.4

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.8

1.0

1.3

-0.4

-0.6

0.5

3.5

4.3

5.9

Cana

da1.

01.

20.6

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.2

0.6

1.6

-0.4

-0.6

0.6

0.6

1.8

2.9

Czec

h Rep

ublic

0.

30.

40.6

-0.1

-0.2

0.20.3

0.8

2.1

-0.5

-0.4

0.5

1.3

2.9

3.2

Denm

ark

2.3

2.6

0.3-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.00.

21.

1-0

.4-0

.60.

50.

10.

83.

5Fin

land

2.3

2.9

0.8-0

.1-0

.40.3

0.20.

81.

9-0

.5-0

.60.

60.

62.

04.

9Fr

ance

1.0

1.1

0.5-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.30.

71.

7-0

.5-0

.50.

51.

42.

63.

7Ge

rman

y1.

01.

00.6

-0.1

-0.2

0.20.4

0.8

1.3

-0.4

-0.5

0.5

1.3

2.2

3.2

Gree

ce

0.2

0.2

0.6-0

.1-0

.40.2

0.60.

91.

3-0

.4-0

.60.

52.

12.

93.

0

Hung

ary

0.2

0.3

0.7-0

.1-0

.50.4

0.91.

41.

6-0

.5-0

.70.

84.

05.

25.

4Ice

land

2.3

2.9

0.3-0

.1-0

.40.3

0.00.

01.

0-0

.3-0

.70.

60.

00.

63.

5Ire

land

0.5

0.7

0.3-0

.1-0

.60.4

1.21.

21.

3-0

.4-0

.80.

82.

02.

93.

7Ita

ly 0.

60.

60.7

-0.1

-0.3

0.21.0

1.4

1.8

-0.5

-0.5

0.5

4.3

5.6

6.3

Japa

n 0.

80.

91.0

-0.2

-0.2

0.20.1

0.9

2.0

-0.5

-0.5

0.5

0.0

1.5

2.3

Kore

a 0.

20.

31.4

-0.2

-0.4

0.30.2

1.4

4.7

-1.0

-0.6

0.6

1.1

4.8

5.1

Luxe

mbo

urg

0.5

0.7

0.4-0

.1-0

.50.4

0.70.

91.

4-0

.4-0

.70.

73.

24.

24.

9Me

xico

0.1

0.1

0.7-0

.1-0

.50.3

0.40.

72.

6-0

.6-0

.80.

71.

73.

63.

7Ne

therla

nds

1.3

1.7

0.5-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.40.

71.

1-0

.4-0

.60.

51.

52.

13.

9Ne

w Ze

aland

0.5

0.5

0.7-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.00.

52.

1-0

.5-0

.50.

50.

11.

62.

1

Norw

ay1.

92.

60.2

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.1

0.1

1.1

-0.4

-0.6

0.5

0.3

1.0

3.6

Polan

d0.

40.

50.8

-0.1

-0.6

0.50.8

1.4

2.5

-0.6

-0.8

1.0

3.7

5.8

6.2

Portu

gal

0.2

0.2

0.6-0

.1-0

.40.3

0.20.

51.

6-0

.5-0

.60.

60.

91.

92.

1Sl

ovak

Rep

ublic

0.3

0.3

0.8-0

.1-0

.40.3

0.81.

32.

8-0

.7-0

.60.

74.

16.

36.

6Sp

ain0.

20.

20.4

-0.1

-0.2

0.20.5

0.8

1.3

-0.4

-0.5

0.5

2.0

2.9

3.0

Swed

en2.

73.

30.2

-0.1

-0.3

0.30.0

0.1

0.6

-0.3

-0.6

0.6

0.0

0.3

3.6

Switz

erlan

d 1.

01.

20.3

-0.1

-0.3

0.20.0

0.2

0.9

-0.3

-0.5

0.5

0.2

0.7

1.9

Turk

ey

0.1

0.1

0.6-0

.1-0

.50.3

0.91.

32.

2-0

.6-0

.70.

65.

16.

76.

8Un

ited

King

dom

0.9

1.1

0.5-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.20.

51.

5-0

.4-0

.60.

60.

61.

62.

6Un

ited

Stat

es

0.7

0.9

0.4-0

.1-0

.30.2

0.00.

21.

3-0

.4-0

.60.

60.

11.

01.

9

Aver

age

0.91.1

0.6-0

.1-0

.40.3

0.40.8

1.7-0

.5-0

.60.6

1.72.9

3.9

NB: A

ssum

ption

s use

d in

this

scen

ario:

Healt

hy ag

eing :

dyn

amic

equil

ibrium

(1 ye

ar ga

ins in

life e

xpec

tancy

= 1

/2 ye

ar in

goo

d hea

lth);

zero

inco

me

elasti

city;

half B

aum

ol ef

fect;

par

ticipa

tion r

atios

of 5

0-64

conv

erge

to 7

0% b

y 205

0.1.

OECD

, Lon

g-te

rm ca

re fo

r olde

r peo

ple a

nd S

ecre

taria

t esti

mat

es.

e : E

stim

ates

, takin

g int

o ac

coun

t the

obse

rved

expe

nditu

re g

rowt

h be

twee

n 20

00 a

nd 2

002-

03.

Sour

ce: S

ecre

tariat

calcu

lation

s.

Page 73: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

73

ANNEX 2B. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE ON THE HEALTH CARE INCOME ELASTICITIES

A brief survey of the literature

82. There is an extensive economic literature seeking to estimate the elasticity of demand for health care services. Whether health care is a luxury (elasticity above one) or a necessity (elasticity below one) is still an unsettled issue. Nevertheless, it seems to be well established that the measured income elasticity of health care depends on the level of analysis. Getzen (2000) argues that previous empirical work often failed to distinguish between sources of variation between groups and within groups: an individual within an insured group may have little reason or incentive to limit health expenditures, especially if the group is large and the individual’s effect on the group is relatively insignificant, so the individual’s health care spending is insensitive to income. The group’s total expenditure on health care, on the other hand, is limited by group income. Thus, group spending will be more responsive to income than individual spending, and wider groupings (say, nations composed of regions) will be even more responsive.

83. Table A3 provides a summary of a number of studies, arrayed by level of aggregation. In general, the higher the level of aggregation, the higher the estimated income elasticity of health care spending. Studies of individual expenditures show that the majority of the variation of spending (50% to 90%) is associated with individual differences in health status, while income elasticities are small or negative (Newhouse and Phelps, 1976; AMA, 1978; Manning et al., 1987; Sunshine and Dicker, 1987; Wedig, 1988; Wagstaff et al., 1991; AHCPR, 1997). However, analysis of pre-1960 data where insurance is less prevalent and most payment is made out-of-pocket show much larger income elasticity (0.2 to 0.7) (Falk et al., 1933; Anderson et al., 1960; Weeks, 1961). Similarly, consumption of dentistry, plastic surgery, counselling, eyeglasses and other types of care that are still less well-insured show income elasticities that are strongly positive, and sometime substantially exceed 1 (USPHS, 1960; Andersen and Benham, 1970; Silver, 1970; AMA, 1978; Scanlon, 1980; Sunshine and Dicker, 1987; AHCPR, 1997; Parker and Wong, 1997). At the macro level, studies of national expenditures consistently show income elasticities greater than 1, with above 90% of cross-sectional and time-series variation explainable by difference in per capita income, and differences in health status having negligible effects (Abel-Smith, 1967; Kleiman, 1974; Newhouse, 1977, Maxwell, 1981; Leu, 1986; Culyer, 1988; Getzen, 1990; Getzen and Poullier, 1992; Schieber, 1990; Gerdtham et al., 1992).

[Table A3: Survey of income elasticity estimates of health care expenditures (or utilisation) by level of observation]

84. The use of time-series data, individually or pooled in cross-section, inevitably raises the question of whether any observed relationship between health care expenditure and income is spurious, as it is likely that both variables are integrated of the order one, I(1). Using unit root and co-integration tests, Gerdtham and Löthgren (2000, 2002) conclude that health care expenditure and GDP for a panel of OECD countries are characterised by unit roots and are co-integrated. They assert that such co-integration relationship suggests a long-run equilibrium between health care expenditure and GDP in the given sample of OECD countries. Using a dataset of health care expenditures and disposable personal income for the states in the U.S. over the years 1986-1998, Freeman (2003) found that health care expenditures and incomes at state level are non-stationary and co-integrated and estimated income elasticity of health care at 0.817 to 0.844. These findings are close to the estimates of Di Matteo and Di Matteo (1998) for Canadian provincial data.

Page 74: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

74

85. Using panel co-integration techniques, Dreger and Reimers (2005) investigated the link between health care expenditures and GDP for a sample of 21 OECD countries. Their model also incorporates medical progress, proxied by different variables like life expectancy and infant mortality. Their analysis concludes that the income elasticity may not be too different from unity, which implies that health care expenditure is not a luxury good. Furthermore, the main determinants of future health expenditure growth is medical progress. As regards national projections, the more sophisticated evidence points to a coefficient at or below unity rather than above.

86. Despite this empirical evidence suggesting a long-run relationship between health expenditure and income, recent studies have indicated that the observed increasing health care expenditure as a share of GDP is likely due to other factors such as technological change (Hall and Jones, 2004; Okuande and Murthy, 2002; Blomqvist and Carter, 1997; Fuchs, 1987). Time-series (panel data) estimates of health care elasticities that fail to control for the role of technological change would therefore tend to be upward biased. But also cross-sectional analysis could be similarly biased, appreciating that they represent the long-term income elasticity. Together with the aggregation problems cited above, technological advances could also provide an explanation for the high estimates of income elasticities found at the macro level. On the other hand, Di Matteo and Di Matteo (1988) argue that because health care is labour intensive, its cost may increase as a function of average income, so that measured income elasticity is blurred by the price effect. Since the price elasticity is presumably negative, the income coefficient is likely to be biased downward.33

Econometric estimates

87. A simple econometric test illustrates how the estimates of the health spending income elasticity can be sensitive to different specifications (Table A4). The sample corresponds to a panel of the 30 OECD countries for the period 1970-2002. The basic data are from the OECD Health Data Base (2005). The comparison of the different estimates shows that, starting from a value well above one, the income elasticity tends to decrease when additional variables are added in the regression. Not having a good proxy for the effect of technology and/or relative prices, time trends were added in the regression. With such time trends, the income elasticity becomes significantly lower than one, at around 0.9. Allowing for country-specific dynamic effects, a mean-pooled group estimate was also carried out. It produces an estimate of income elasticity around 1.1. The last column of Table A4 shows an estimate where the income elasticity was actually constrained to be unitary. This allows having an alternative estimate of the expenditure residual growth that can be compared with the accounting approach that was used in the main text. It can be seen that the coefficient for the time trend decreases substantially from 2.1% in the 1970s to 1% per year in the 1990s.

[Table A4. Econometric estimates of the income elasticity of health spending]

33 For a comprehensive overview of key studies that explicitly estimate price elasticity for health services,

see Ringel et al.,(2002).

Page 75: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

75

Table A3: Survey of income elasticity estimates of health care expenditures (or utilisation) by level of observation

INDIVIDUALS (micro) Income elasticity General (insured/mixed) Newhouse and Phelps (1976) ≤ 0.1 AMA (1978) ≈ 0 Sunshine and Dicker (1987) ≈ 0 Manning et al. (1987) ≈ 0 Wedig (1988) ≈ 0 Wagstaff et al. (1991) ≤ 0 Hahn and Lefkowitz (1992) ≤ 0 AHCPR (1997) ≤ 0 Special / uninsured Falk et al. (1933) 0.7 Weeks (1961) 0.3 Anderson et al. (1960) (1953 data) 0.4 Anderson et al. (1960) (1958 data) 0.2 Other USPHS (1960) (physician visits) 0.1 USPHS (1960) (dental visits) 0.8 AMA (1978) (dental expenses) 1.0-1.7 Andersen and Benham (1970) (physician expenses) 0.4 Andersen and Benham (1970) (dental expenses) 1.2 Silver (1970) (physician expenses) 0.85 Silver (1970) (dental expenses) 2.4-3.2 Newman and Anderson (1972) (dental expenses) 0.8 Feldstein (1973) (dental expenses) 1.2 Scanlon (1980) (Nursing home expenses) 2.2 Sunshine and Dicker (1987) (dental expenses) 0.7-1.5 Hahn and Lefkowitz (1992) (dental expenses) 1.0 AHCPR (1997) (dental expenses) 1.1 Parker and Wong (1997) (Mexico, total expenses) 0.9-1.6

REGIONS (intermediate) Feldstein (1971) (47 states, 1958-1967, $hospital) 0.5 Fuchs and Kramer (1972) (33 states, 1966, $physician) 0.9 Levit (1982) (50 states, 1966, 1978, $total) 0.9 McLauglin (1987) (25 SMSAs, 1972-1982, $hospital) 0.7 Baker (1997) (3073 US counties, 1986-1990, $Medicare) 0.8 Di Matteo and Di Matteo (1998) (10 Canadian provinces 1965-1991) 0.8

NATIONS (macro) Abel-Smith (1967) (33 countries, 1961) 1.3 Kleiman (1974) (16 countries, 1968) 1.2 Newhouse (1977) (13 countries, 1972) 1.3 Maxwell (1981) (10 countries, 1975) 1.4 Gertler and van der Gaag (1990) (25 countries, 1975) 1.3 Getzen (1990) (US, 1966-1987) 1.6 Schieber (1990) (seven countries, 1960-1987) 1.2 Gerdtham et al. (1992) (19 countries, 1987) 1.2 Getzen and Poulllier (1992) (19 countries, 1965-1986) 1.4 Fogel (1999) (United States, long run) 1.6 Source: Getzen (2000)

Page 76: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO

/WK

P(20

06)5

76

Tabl

e A4

. Eco

nom

etric

est

imat

es o

f the

inco

me

elas

ticity

of h

ealth

spe

ndin

g

Dep

enda

nt

varia

ble:

Log

he

alth

ex

pend

iture

s pe

r ca

pita

Fixe

d-ef

fect

s

Fixe

d-ef

fect

s

Fixe

d-ef

fect

s

Fixe

d-ef

fect

s

Fixe

d ef

fect

s an

d in

com

e el

astic

ity

cons

train

ed =

1

Mea

n-po

oled

gr

oup

estim

ates

Log

GD

P pe

r ca

pita

1.

583*

**

(0.0

28)

0.93

7***

(0

.063

) 0.

893*

**

(0.0

62)

0.86

5***

(0

.062

) ..

1.15

***

(0.0

69)

Log

aver

age

popu

latio

n ag

e ..

.. 1.

561*

* (0

.264

) 1.

63**

(0

.261

) 1.

56**

(0

.259

) 1.

00**

(0

.250

)

Tim

e tre

nd

.. 0.

0168

***

(0.0

01)

0.01

0**

(0.0

01)

.. ..

..

Tim

e tre

nd 7

0s

.. ..

.. 0.

025*

* (0

.003

) 0.

021*

* (0

.003

) ..

Tim

e tre

nd 8

0s

.. ..

.. 0.

015*

* (0

.002

) 0.

013*

* (0

.001

8)

..

Tim

e tre

nd 9

0s

.. ..

.. 0.

012*

* (0

.001

) 0.

010*

* (0

.001

) ..

R2

(with

in)

Nb.

obs

erva

tions

0.

82

756

0.83

75

6 0.

84

756

0.85

75

6 0.

49

756

54

0 N

ote:

Pan

el 3

0 O

ECD

cou

ntrie

s, 1

970-

2002

**

* sig

nific

ant a

t 1%

and

** a

t 5%

. St

anda

rd e

rrors

in b

rack

ets

Sour

ce: S

ecre

taria

t cal

cula

tions

Page 77: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

77

ANNEX 2C. OBESITY TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES

88. Obesity has reached epidemic proportions globally, with more than one billion adults overweight – at least 300 million of those clinically obese – and is a major contributor to the global burden of chronic diseases and disability. Unchecked, obesity may in the near future erode the healthy longevity gains attained by today’s elderly, imposing an additional burden on health care costs.

89. There are three factors appearing to be the main drivers behind these trends:

• How much we eat: Rapid agricultural productivity growth has brought food prices, in real terms, to the lowest level in history. Moreover, the average calorie availability has ballooned. At the beginning of the 1960’s, nearly 40% of the population in developing countries was chronically undernourished, while over-nutrition and obesity were marginal and geographically narrowly defined problems. By the turn of the millennium, the rather homogenous picture of undersupplies and hunger had changed completely. The prevalence of under-nourishment had fallen in all regions except for sub-Saharan Africa and a few countries in South-Asia to levels below 10%. Projections suggest this trend will continue. All in all, average food energy supplies in 43 countries, home of about 3.5 billion people, will be above the 3 200 kcal mark by 2030.34 At these levels of average dietary energy supply, over-nutrition is likely to become a growing problem also in developing countries. And, where income disparities remain high, under-nourishment and over-nutrition are likely to co-exist within the same country (OECD, 2004).

• What we eat: “A calorie is a calorie” is not all true. Increased consumption of more energy-dense, nutrient-poor foods with high levels of sugar and saturated fats have contributed to obese rates rising three-fold or more since 1980 in some areas of North-America, the United Kingdom, Eastern Europe, the Middle East, the Pacific Islands, Australasia and China.35

• How we live: Urbanization and adjustment to a service economy is causing a more sedentary lifestyle, i.e., desk jobs and urban developments that are friendly to cars but hostile to walking and biking. The occasional gym visit does not compensate for the decline in utilitarian physical activity like walking children to school, walking to the corner store, or walking to work (Sturm and Lakdawalla, 2004).

90. Obesity is defined as weight that is dangerously excessive because of its high proportion of body fat relative to lean body mass. A common screener for obesity is the Body Mass Index (BMI). BMI is a person’s weight in kilograms divided by height in meters squared. Because BMI does not distinguish body fat from bone and muscle mass, the index can misclassify some people, such as those with large bones and muscles. The standard BMI categories are as follows: underweight (BMI less than 18.5), normal (18.5 to 24.9), overweight (25 to 29.9) and obese (30 or more). These definitions are based on evidence that suggests health risks are greater at or above a BMI of 25 compared to those below that level. The risk of death, although modest until a BMI of 30 is reached, increases with an increasing Body Mass Index (US 34 The US Department of Agriculture estimates that the average man needs 2 900 calories per day (assuming

light to moderate activity). The average woman needs 2 200 calories. 35 See http://www.who.int/dietphysicalactivity/media/en/gsfs_obesity.pdf

Page 78: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

78

Department of Health and Human Services, 2001). The United States has the highest share of obese people, 30% (Figure A1). Moreover, the fastest growing group of obese Americans are “severely” obese. Between 1986 and 2000, the proportion of moderately obese individuals (those with a BMI of 30-35) merely doubled in the United States. In contrast, the proportion of individuals with a BMI of 40 or greater quadrupled (Sturm and Lakdawalla, 2004).

[Figure A1: Obesity rates in OECD countries]

91. According to WHO, non-fatal, but debilitating health problems associated with obesity include respiratory difficulties, chronic musculoskeletal problems, skin problems and infertility. The more life-threatening problems fall into four main areas: cardio-vascular diseases; conditions associated with insulin resistance such as type-2 diabetes; certain types of cancer, especially the hormonally related and large bowel cancer; and gallbladder disease. The likelihood of developing type-2 diabetes and hypertension rises steeply with increasing body fatness. Confined to older adults for most of the XXth century, this disease now affects obese children even before puberty. About 85% of people with diabetes are type-2, and of these, 90% are obese or overweight. In the analysis carried out for World Health Report 2002, about 58% of diabetes, 21% of ischemic heart disease and 8-42% of certain cancers globally were attributable to a BMI above 21. Looking forward, the increasing incidence of child obesity is of special concern. Overweight children and adolescents are more likely to become overweight or obese adults (US Department of Health and Human Services, 2001).

92. The traditional focus on disability research has been on the elderly, with good reason. Chronic disability is much more prevalent among the elderly, and it has a more direct impact on the demand for medical care. Still, the largest increase in obesity has primarily occurred among younger cohorts (Sturm et al., 2004) sparking the question whether the trend in disability among young may diverge from that of the old. Casting light on these idiosyncrasies requires quite detailed and longitudinal data. Several US studies suggest that while disability among the elderly is falling, the opposite is happening for younger cohorts. These trends could have serious implications for future health care spending because more disability at younger ages almost certainly translates into more disability among tomorrow’s elderly, and disability is one of the key predictors of health care spending. Main suggestions from some of the studies addressing this theme are depicted below.

93. Lakdawalla et al., (2004) use data from the National Health Interview Survey (NHIS) to present a detailed analysis of disability trends in the population ages 18-69. This analysis reveals substantial growth in reported rates of disability in the population younger than age fifty but not among the elderly. These trends do not appear to be the result of changes in the composition of the population or of changes in specific survey procedures. It is suggested that obesity and its attendant disorders are particularly associated with these trends. Sturm et al., (2004) employ data from the Health and Retirement Study (HRS) and the Behavioural Risk Factor Surveillance Survey (BRFSS) and conclude that if current trends in obesity continue, disability rates will increase by one per cent a year more in the 50-59 age group than if there were no further weight gains. Cutler et al., (2004) emphasize that forecasts based on trends in the disability only among the old are misleading. The study combines data from the Medicare Current Beneficiary Survey (MCBS) and the NHIS. The forecasts imply that per capita Medicare costs will decline the next 15-20 years in accordance with recent declines in disability among the elderly.36 By 2020, however, per capita costs begin to rise as a result of growth in disability among younger persons. Andreyeva et al., (2004) use data from the HRS and find that there are large differences in obesity related to health care costs by degree of obesity. Thus, widely cited average effects of obesity on health care costs

36 Assuming that disability trends are the one thing influencing the otherwise constant health care spending,

i.e., no technological advances etc.

Page 79: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

79

obscure major differences across degrees of obesity and will under-predict future health care costs because the prevalence of more severe obesity is growing at a much faster rate than the spread of obesity in general.

94. Recent literature on obesity, disability and health care costs therefore seem uniform. Rising disability rates among the future elderly could wipe out recent reductions in disability among today’s elderly, who have benefited from reduced exposure to disease, better medical care, and reduced smoking. Appreciating that these are studies on American citizens, the trend appears global in nature, and there is no compelling reason why the trend in other western countries should diverge. Admittedly, one could argue that this obesity trend will decrease in speed, if anything because the alternative would lead to greater individual dissatisfaction and a further squeeze on the public purse. Still, quantifying possible future developments on unchanged trends, ceteris paribus, provides important insight and makes the traditional scenario of ever falling disability rates a fairly optimistic one.

Figure A1. Obesity rates in OECD countries

1. Percentage of total population with Body Mass Index (BMI) >30 kg/m2 .2. Percentage of total population with 25<BMI<30 kg/m2 .Source : OECD Health database (2005).

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

Unite

d St

ates

Mex

icoUn

ited

King

dom

Austr

alia

Slov

ak R

epub

licGr

eece

New

Zeal

and

Hung

ary

Luxe

mbo

urg

Czec

h Re

publi

cPo

rtuga

lGe

rman

ySp

ain

Icela

ndIre

land

Cana

daAu

stria

Neth

erlan

dsBe

lgium

Turk

eySw

eden

Norw

ayIta

lyDe

nmar

kFr

ance

Switz

erlan

dKo

rea

Japa

n

Obese population (1)Overweight population (2)

Page 80: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

ECO/WKP(2006)5

80

WORKING PAPERS

The full series of Economics Department Working Papers can be consulted at www.oecd.org/eco/Working_Papers/ 476. Alternative measures of well-being (January 2006) Romina Boarini, Åsa Johansson and Marco Mira D'Ercole 475. Recent house price developments: the role of fundamentals (January 2006) Nathalie Girouard, Mike Kennedy, Paul van den Noord and Christophe André 474. Reforming federal fiscal relations in Austria (January 2006) Andrès Fuentes, Eckhard Wurzel and Andreas Wörgötter 473. Product market competition and economic performance in France Concurrence sur les marchés de produits et performance économique en France (January 2006) Jens Høj and Michael Wise 472. Product market reforms and employment in OECD countries (December 2005) Giuseppe Nicoletti and Stefano Scarpetta 471. Fast-falling barriers and growing concentration: the emergence of a private economy in China (December 2005) Sean Dougherty and Richard Herd 470. Sustaining high growth through innovation: reforming the R&D and education systems in Korea (December 2005) Yongchun Baek and Randall Jones 469. The labour market in Korea: enhancing flexibility and raising participation (December 2005) Randall Jones 468. Getting the most out of public-sector decentralization in Korear (December 2005) Randall Jones and Tadashi Yokoyama 467. Coping with the inevitable adjustment in the US current account (December 2005) Peter Jarrett 466. Is there a case for sophisticated balanced-budget rules? (December 2005) Antonio Fatás 465. Fiscal rules for sub-central governments design and impact (December 2005) Douglas Sutherland, Robert Price and Isabelle Joumard 464. Assessing the robustness of demographic projections in OECD countries (December 2005) Frédéric Gonand 463. The Benefits of Liberalising Product Markets and Reducing Barriers to International Trade and Investment in the OECD (December 2005) 462. Fiscal relations across levels of government in the United States (November 2005) Thomas Laubach 461. Assessing the value of indicators of underlying inflation for monetary policy (November 2005) Pietro Catte and Torsten Sløk.

Page 81: English - Or. English ECONOMICS DEPARTMENT Cancels ... · individuals “exit” an age group by living into an older group (rather than “exit” by dying), average costs of the

81

460. Regulation and economic performance: product market reforms and productivity in the OECD (November 2005) Giuseppe Nicoletti and Stefano Scarpetta. 459. Innovation in the Business Sector (November 2005) Florence Jaumotte and Nigel Pain 458. From Innovation Development to Implementation: Evidence from the Community Innovation Survey (November 2005) Florence Jaumotte and Nigel Pain 457. From Ideas to Development: the Determination of R&D and Patenting (November 2005) Florence Jaumotte and Nigel Pain 456. An Overview of Public Policies to Support Innovation (November 2005) Florence Jaumotte and Nigel Pain 455. Strengthening Regulation in Chile: The Case of Network Industries (November 2005) Alexander Galetovic and Luiz de Mello 454. Fostering Innovation in Chile (November 2005) José-Miguel Benavente, Luiz de Mello and Nanno Mulder 453. Getting the most out of public sector decentralisation in Mexico (October 2005) Isabelle Joumard 452. Raising Greece’s Potential Output Growth (October 2005) Vassiliki Koutsogeorgopoulou and Helmut Ziegelschmidt 451. Product Market Competition and Economic Performance in Australia (October 2005) Helmut Ziegelschmidt, Vassiliki Koutsogeorgopoulou, Simen Bjornerud and Michael Wise 450. House Prices and Inflation in the Euro Area (October 2005) Boris Cournède 449. The EU’s Single Market: At Your Service? (October 2005) Line Vogt 448. Slovakia’s introduction of a flat tax as part of wider economic reforms (October 2005) Anne-Marie Brook and Willi Leibfritz 447. The Education Challenge in Mexico: Delivering Good Quality Education to All (October 2005) Stéphanie Guichard 446. In Search of Efficiency: Improving Health Care in Hungary (October 2005) Alessandro Goglio 445. Hungarian Innovation Policy: What’s the Best Way Forward? (October 2005) Philip Hemmings 444. The Challenges of EMU Accession Faced by Catch-Up Countries: A Slovak Republic Case Study (September 2005) Anne-Marie Brook 443. Getting better value for money from Sweden’s healthcare system (September 2005) David Rae