Etmfjl 0920 Industry Architecture and Entry of Entrepreneurial Startups Case of IT Sector

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 1

    Industry Architecture and Entry of Entrepreneurial Startups:

    The Case of the IT Sector

    by

    Jeffrey L. Funk

    Associate Professor

    National University of Singapore

    7 Engineering Drive 1

    Block E3A, 4th Floor

    Singapore 129793

    [email protected]

  • 2

    Industry Architecture and Entry of Entrepreneurial Startups:

    The Case of the IT Sector

    Abstract

    This paper uses the literature on industry architecture to examine the tradeoffs involved

    with the entry timing of vertically disintegrated entrepreneurial startups. While the

    conventional wisdom on entry timing focuses on capabilities and dominant designs, the

    literature on industry architecture focuses on capabilities and transaction costs. Falling

    transaction costs, through for example the emergence of open standards, can reduce the cost

    of entry for vertically disintegrated startups while economies of scale in capabilities can

    increase the cost of entry over time. Focusing primarily on transaction costs, this papers

    analysis shows that more entrepreneurial startups were founded (and thus entered) after a

    relevant open interface standard had been released than were founded before the release.

    These results suggest that large numbers of entrepreneurial opportunities still exist after open

    interface standards are released, even when these open interface standards are defined as

    dominant designs, and that the emergence of these open standards may be an open important

    signal for entry by entrepreneurial startups.

  • 3

    1. Introduction

    Understanding where entrepreneurs should look for opportunities remains an important

    issue for practitioners and academics. The popular press focuses on final products such as

    MP3 players (e.g., i-pod), mobile phones (e., i-phone, Google phone), Internet search (e.g.,

    Google), tablet computers (e.g., i-pad) and personal digital assistants. The literature on

    entrepreneurship has found that entrepreneurs do better in software than hardware (Audretsch,

    1991) or in industries with rapid growth, low capital intensity, small scale, and low

    concentration (Bygrave and Zacharakis, 2003; Shane, 2004; Baron and Shane 2005). The

    literature on technological management and innovation has found that technological

    discontinuities, particularly those that destroy competencies, provide opportunities for new

    entrants (Tushman and Anderson, 1986; Anderson and Tushman, 1990; Henderson and Clark,

    1990; Christensen, 1997) particularly when firms enter before a dominant design emerges

    and defines the necessary capabilities for firms (Utterback, 1994; Suarez and Utterback,

    1995).

    On the other hand, a growing body of research has concluded that the emergence of

    vertical disintegration has challenged incumbents and thus this research implies that vertical

    disintegration has led to opportunities for new entrants in a variety of industries (Langlois,

    1992; 2003, 2007; Baldwin and Clark, 2000; Arora et al, 2001; Chesbrough, 2003).

    Furthermore, these results have led to an increasing interest in so-called industry

    architectures, which are an abstract description of the economic agents within an economic

    system and represent the degree of vertical (dis)integration in an industry (Jacobides,

    Knudsen and Augier, 2006). Changes in industry architecture can come from technological,

    institutional, or social changes that impact on the way in which economic agents divide up

    work. In particular, reductions in transaction cost can reduce both the costs of having work

    done by multiple agents and the importance of integrative capabilities and thus facilitate the

    emergence of vertical disintegration (Brusoni and Prencipe, 2001; Jacobides, 2005; Jacobides

  • 4

    and Winter, 2005). These reductions in transaction costs can come from the emergence of

    open standards, modular designs (Langlois, 2003, 2007), and other events such as

    governments (or legal systems) requiring the un-bundling of products, restricting a firms

    ownership/market share in a market, or approving open standards (Arora et al, 2001;

    Kenney, 2003; Steinmueller, 2003) where these events can emerge in either a bottom-up or

    top-down process (Jacobides, 2005; Jacobides and Winter, 2005).

    In spite of this wide agreement that vertical disintegration is occurring and is somehow

    related to entrepreneurial opportunities, however, empirical research has not addressed the

    relationship between the emergence of vertical disintegration and entrepreneurial

    opportunities nor has it challenged the conventional wisdom on dominant designs. More

    specifically: 1) what are the mechanisms by which vertical disintegration emerges and creates

    entrepreneurial opportunities; 2) what are the tradeoffs between early and late entry for

    vertically disintegrated startups; and 3) under what conditions can firms enter after a

    so-called dominant design emerges?

    The information technology (IT) sector is an appropriate one to consider these issues.

    Vertical disintegration has emerged in almost every type of computer system, open standards

    have played a role in the emergence of this vertical disintegration (Langlois, 1992; Ceruzzi,

    1998; Baldwin and Clark, 2000), there has been a decline in the number of firms (i.e.,

    shakeout) in most of these vertically disintegrated layers (Flamm, 1988; Langlois, 1992;

    Steffens, 1994; Hatfield et al, 1999; Campbell-Kelly, 2003), and the number of de novo

    entrepreneurial startups has steadily grown.

    2. Theoretical Discussion

    The most widely used models of technological change in the management and economic

    literature are the product life cycle (PLC) and cyclical model of technological change. Both

    characterize the evolution of an industry in terms of technological discontinuities, dominant

  • 5

    designs, and incremental change (Anderson and Tushman, 1990; Tushman and Rosenkopf,

    1992). Technological discontinuities can replace existing products and technologies or they

    can create entire new product categories (Tushman and Anderson, 1986; Utterback, 1994;

    Christensen, 1997). For example, it is generally agreed by the management (Anderson and

    Tushman, 1990; Langlois, 1992; Baldwin and Clark, 2001) and other literatures that

    mainframe, mini, and personal computers, client server computing, and the Internet represent

    technological discontinuities within the IT sector.

    The emergence of such a discontinuity is generally defined as the beginning of a

    products life cycle. Research on the product life cycle has found that there is typically a large

    decline (i.e., a shakeout) in the total number of firms through mergers, acquisitions, and exits

    where these shakeouts occur even when the total market for these products continues to grow

    rapidly (Gort and Klepper, 1982; Klepper and Grady, 1990; Agarwal and Gort, 1996; Klepper,

    1997; Klepper & Simons, 1997). For example, there were large shakeouts in the number of

    automobile and television (Klepper and Simons, 1997) and personal computer (Hatfield,

    1999) manufacturers in the 1910s, 1950s, and 1980s respectively even though the markets for

    these products continued to grow long after the shakeouts had occurred. The conventional

    wisdom in the technology management (Teece, 1986; Utterback, 1994; Suarez and Utterback,

    1995) and entrepreneurship (Bygrave and Zacharakis, 2003; Shane, 2004; Baron and Shane,

    2005) literatures is that the emergence of a dominant design has been a trigger for these

    shakeouts because they define a set of necessary capabilities that firms must have in order to

    effectively compete,

    On the other hand, the literatures on modular design, interface standards, other research

    on the product life cycle, and industry architecture imply that the emergence of dominant

    designs may not lead to a shakeout in the number of firms and that certain kinds of open

    dominant designs may lead to increases in the number of firms and thus the number of

    entrepreneurial opportunities. Modular designs are those in which the interfaces that

  • 6

    determine how the functional components or modules in a product or process design will

    interact are specified to enable the substitution of component variations within the design.

    Design rules (Baldwin and Clark, 2000) define the interaction between these modules (Ulrich,

    1995; Sanchez and Mahoney, 1996; Brusoni and Prencipe, 2001). The term standard or

    interface standard (Farrell and Saloner, 1985; Katz and Shapiro, 1985, 1994; Shapiro and

    Varian, 1999) is often used to define the way in which these different modules interact when

    products from different firms are compatible with the same interface design rules. The greater

    the extent to which design rules or interface standards are open, the greater the extent to

    which new entrants may challenge vertically integrated incumbents (Langlois, 1992; Langlois

    and Robertson, 1992; Baldwin and Clark, 2000; Langlois, 2003, 2007).

    Other research on the product life cycle also supports the notion that the emergence of

    dominant designs may not lead to a shakeout in the number of firms. Klepper (1996, 1997)

    explains a shakeout in the number of product manufacturers in terms of economies of scale in

    R&D where R&D can be linked to capabilities and where economies of scale in these

    capabilities cause small firms to be acquired or to exit the industry. He also concluded that

    the emergence of independent equipment and process technology suppliers reduce the need

    for scale in R&D by product manufacturers, creates entrepreneurial opportunities for these

    product manufacturers, and thus prevents a shakeout in the number of them. Although his

    analysis focused on final manufacturers, as do most analyses of the product life cycle, his

    argument is consistent with the notion that vertical disintegration enables new firm entry, in

    this case in the final product1.

    The framework of industry architectures can probably better address these issues than the

    product life cycle model can (Jacobides, Knudsen and Augier, 2006), particularly if some

    1 Klepper (1997) also concluded that the existence of sub-markets prevents a shakeout in the number of these final manufacturers since

    their existence reduces the advantages of scale in R&D. a more comprehensive analysis could address the number of sub-markets and their

    impact on economies of scale in R&D.

  • 7

    concepts from the product life cycle model (shakeouts and economies of scale in capabilities)

    are imported into the framework of industry architectures. According to the literature on

    industry architecture, falling transaction costs, through for example the emergence of open

    standards, can reduce both the costs of having work done by multiple agents and the

    importance of integrative capabilities and thus facilitate the emergence of vertical

    disintegration (Brusoni and Prencipe, 2001; Jacobides, 2005; Jacobides and Winter, 2005).

    Since previous research implies that incumbents have trouble adapting to these changes in

    industry architecture (Storper and Christopherson, 1987; Langlois, 1992; Baldwin and Clark,

    2000; Arora et al, 2001; Christensen et al, 2002; Chesbrough, 2003), it is expected that the

    emergence of open standards will enable some de novo entrepreneurial startups to become

    successful providers of these modules. Thus, de novo startups will be more successful in

    providing modules that involve open standards than in providing modules that do not involve

    open standards. This leads to Hypothesis 1:

    Hypothesis 1: de novo entrepreneurial startups are more represented among suppliers of

    modules that involve open interface standards than in those that do not,

    But when should these firms enter a market (i.e., become suppliers of a specific module)

    and what are the relative tradeoffs between entering early or late? Kleppers (1996, 1997)

    theory of economies of scale in R&D for product and process capabilities recommends early

    entry. Early entrants can begin doing R&D, selling products, and developing the relevant

    capabilities. Later entrants will be at a disadvantage in terms of these economies of scale in

    capabilities and thus may incur higher R&D costs as a percent of sales than do an earlier

    entrant. On the other hand, the literature on industry architecture suggests that reductions in

    transaction costs, through for example the emergence of open design rules and open standards,

    can facilitate the entry of vertically disintegrated suppliers. Assuming these open standards do

  • 8

    eventually emerge, early entrants may incur higher entry costs than do later entrants because

    initially few system suppliers have set open design rules, because open standards have not yet

    been defined for these design rules, and because when these open standards do emerge the

    early entrants may not notice, they may be unable to adapt, or they may incur high costs in

    their attempts to adapt to the open standards and the capabilities that are associated with them.

    Furthermore, if these open standards are defined by designs that can be classified as dominant

    designs, firm that enter after a dominant design emerges may incur lower entry costs than

    firms that enter before a dominant design emerges.

    Figure 1 summarizes these tradeoffs for a case when an open standard does eventually

    emerge for a specific module. As systems providers set open design rules for interfaces and as

    standards emerge for these design rules, the transaction costs associated with different firms

    supplying different modules and thus the entry costs for a supplier of a specific module

    declines. On the other hand, economies of scale for capabilities in a specific module increase

    over time thus increasing the cost of entry over time. It should be noted that if open standards

    are later replaced by closed ones, this may raise transaction costs and in combination with

    economies of scale may raise the costs of new entry (which is not shown in Figure 1).

    Assuming that economies of scale in R&D increases as characterized by Klepper (1996),

    this paper focuses on the falling transaction costs from the emergence of open design rules

    and interface standards and whether these falling transaction costs enable new firms to enter

    even after an open standard is defined. In particular, since existing firms are often slow to

    adapt to the emergence of open standards and to the changes in industry and inter-firm

    architecture that are brought about by these open standards (Storper and Christopherson,

    1987; Langlois, 1992; Baldwin and Clark, 2000; Arora et al, 2001; Christensen et al, 2002;

    Chesbrough, 2003, the emergence of open standards may enable some de novo

    entrepreneurial startups to enter (and perhaps be founded) and succeed even after an open

    standard has emerged. This leads to the following hypothesis:

  • 9

    Hypothesis 2: more de novo entrepreneurial startups are founded after open standards

    emerge than before they emerge

    3. Methodology

    This paper uses the literature on the IT sector to define the technological discontinuities,

    the modules for each discontinuity, the emergence of design rules, interface standards, and

    other factors that impacted on falling transaction costs, the classification of the design rules

    and standards as either open or closed, and the dates of release for open standards. The

    relevant literature includes academic papers and books from the management, economic, and

    historical fields, practitioner-oriented accounts, and encyclopedic histories. The emergence of

    open standards for a specific interface refers to the year in which the open interface standard

    is released (e.g., the release of the IBM PC in 1981). Although the emergence of an interface

    standard typically follows the emergence of the discontinuity, in some cases the emergence of

    standards may precede the emergence of the discontinuity (e.g., UNIX emerged before the

    first workstation was introduced in 1980) particularly when the standards and vertical

    disintegration emerged in a bottom-up process (Jacobides, 2005).

    The sample of firms was taken from Datamation magazine and includes those that were

    ranked at least once in the Datamation 50 or Datamation 100. Datamation magazine used

    sales data from annual reports to annually (in a June issue) rank the top 50 IT firms in the

    North American market in terms of IT revenues between 1975 and 1996, the top 100 IT firms

    between 1979 to 1994, and for most years broke down each firms revenues into multiple IT

    categories (e.g., mainframe versus mini-computers, peripherals and software) and

    summarized the firms annual activities in a half page description. Focusing on the most

    successful firms in an industry can be problematic due to so-called sampling on the

    dependent variable. One reason why this is not a major problem with this papers database is

  • 10

    that this database is large enough to represent the entire set of firms in the IT sector. Second,

    the representativeness of this sample was checked by testing Hypothesis 2 for the most

    successful firms in the IT sector; these are defined as those firms that were ranked by

    Datamation in the top 25 IT firms at least twice. Third, the paper is testing whether a majority

    of successful firms were founded after open standards emerged, and not whether firms should

    enter after an open standard has emerged. This last point is addressed in the discussion

    section.

    This paper used the Datamations firm descriptions, breakdowns in firm revenues, and

    other sources (see footnote #2) to classify each firm for each year in terms of one

    technological discontinuity and its associated system (e.g., mainframe, mini-, and personal

    computers and client-server systems) and one vertically disintegrated layer (e.g., computer

    design, peripherals, software) within these technological discontinuities/systems. More than

    80% of the de novo firms in the Datamation 100 were classified each year in the same layer

    and system/discontinuity2. The same sources (in particular the Internet) were also used to

    classify each firm as either de novo or de alio and to identify the firms founding date. This

    paper focuses on de novo firms and their founding date because this data was easier to obtain

    than was data on entry date into the relevant vertically disintegrated layers by de novo or de

    alio firms. Since firms have to be founded before they can release products, this analysis will

    underestimate the extent to which successful firms have entered a market after the emergence

    of open interface standards.

    Firms were classified as de novo firms if they were founded to enter the IT sector and as

    de alio firms if they entered the IT sector from another sector. Partly to prevent double

    2 For those few firms whose classifications did change at least once, short historical descriptions were constructed from the firm

    descriptions in the Datamation magazines and other sources such as the Computer Industry Almanac (Juliussen et al, 1987), the Internet, and

    historical accounts of software (Steinmueller, 1996; Campbell-Kelly, 2003), local area networks (von Burg, 2001), hard disks (Christensen,

    1993), and printers (Dorfman, 1987) in order to more accurately classify them.

  • 11

    counting within a specific vertically disintegrated layer, for the small number of mergers and

    acquisitions (

  • 12

    Table 2 also summarizes the relevant standards for these discontinuities and Figure 2

    roughly summarizes the changes in vertical disintegration that were brought about by the

    emergence of these standards. As discussed in the subsequent sub-sections, open standards

    emerged for the interfaces between computers and peripherals, operating systems (OSs) and

    application software, and computers and some services (e.g., remote services). Key events

    related to the emergence of these open interface standards include the release of IBMs

    System/360 in 1964, of 16-bit mini-computers in 1970, of TCP/IP (transmission control

    protocol/ internet protocol) specifications for the Internet in the late 1970s, of the IBM PC in

    1981, and of the Ethernet for local area networks (LAN) in the early 1980s, plus IBMs

    announcement of software unbundling in 1969 and partial agreements on UNIX in the mid-

    to late-1970s On the other hand, open standards did not emerge for the interfaces between the

    OS (operating system) and CPU (central processing unit) for mainframe and mini computers

    and only initially for personal computers (PCs). Furthermore, they did not emerge between

    application software from different systems/discontinuities and instead experience in dealing

    with these non-standard interfaces became a barrier to entry for new suppliers of system

    integration services (discussed in more detail in sub-section 4.4).

    Hypothesis 1 can be tested by looking at the ratio of de novo to total number of firms in

    Table 3 or the total number of de novo firms in the vertically disintegrated layers. Comparing

    the different software layers shown in Table 3, the proportion of de novo to total number of

    firms is greater in those layers for which open standards did emerge than for layers for which

    they did not emerge (systems integration in column labeled application software). Hypothesis

    1 was tested using hypothesis testing for the difference between two binomial proportions

    (Mitra, 1993, p. 119). The smaller proportion of de novo to total number of firms in systems

    integration software (10 of 24) than in other software (35 of 39 is significant at the 0.001

    level.

    Furthermore, a lack of open standards for the interfaces between the OS and CPU for

  • 13

    computers made it difficult for independent providers of OSs and CPUs, much less de novo

    ones, to emerge. For OSs, only one firm (Microsoft) had any level of success before 2000.

    For CPUs, although the Datamation rankings do not include semiconductor suppliers, the

    literature on the computer industry primarily emphasizes one firm, Intel (Flamm, 1988,

    Langlois, 1992; Ceruzzi, 1998). A much smaller number of de novo firms in these layers than

    in the other layers shown in Table 3 provide further confirmation of Hypothesis 1.

    Excluding those layers (i.e., systems integration) for which open standards did not emerge,

    Table 4 shows the number of de novo firms that were ranked at least once in the Datamation

    100 and that were founded before and after open standards emerged for specific vertically

    disintegrated layers. Although a small number of firms are represented twice in Table 4

    because a few of them are classified into different layers/discontinuities in different years, the

    total number of firms shown in Table 4 (150) is less than the total number of firms in Table 1

    (170) since firms classified as systems integrators or classified as other are eliminated from

    Table 4.

    Hypothesis 2 is addressed using Table 4. Sixty five percent (97 of 150) of the de novo

    firms were founded after an open standard was released. Hypothesis 2 was first tested using

    hypothesis testing for the difference between two binomial proportions (Mitra, 1993, p.

    119). The larger proportion of de novo to total number of firms founded before (97 of 150)

    than after (523 of 150) open standards emerged is significant at the 0.001 level. Furthermore,

    a similar proportion (13 of 21) of the of the most successful firms (those spending more than

    two years in the top 25 IT firms) were established after these open standards were released

    (See Table 4). These results suggest that large numbers of entrepreneurial opportunities still

    exist after open interface standards are released, even when these open interface standards are

    defined as dominant designs, and that the emergence of these open standards may be an open

    important signal for entry by entrepreneurial startups.

  • 14

    4.1 Mainframe computers

    Open standards emerged for some modules and their interfaces but not for others in

    mainframe computers. The first key event was the release of IBMs System/360 in 1964. In

    order to reduce the rising software costs of computers, IBM designed the System/360 to be a

    modular system in which software and also peripherals (such as storage devices and printers)

    could be mixed and matched with any computer in the family of System/360 computers

    (Fisher et al, 1983; Flamm, 1988; Pugh, 1995; Ceruzzi, 1998). Although IBM did not intend

    for its customers to purchase peripherals from other manufacturers, the release of the IBM

    System/360 inadvertently made this possible as the design rules that defined the interface

    between computers and peripherals became open to the public thus reducing the transaction

    costs associated with other firms selling peripherals to users of IBMs System/360.

    Furthermore, although other computer manufacturers had already opened their design

    rules in order to facilitate their use of externally available peripherals, IBMs large share of

    the mainframe computer market caused its design rules to become industry standards and the

    IBM System/360 to become a so-called dominant design for mainframe computers (Fisher et

    al, 1983; Dorfman, 1987; Flamm, 1988; Tushman and Rosenkopf, 1992; Baldwin and Clark,

    2000). This increased the potential size of the market for independent suppliers of peripherals

    and in combination with the falling transaction costs associated with the emergence of a

    single standard facilitated the founding of many new firms (Fisher et al, 1983; Flamm, 1988;

    Baldwin and Clark, 2000). As shown in Table 4, four of the 9 de novo mainframe peripheral

    suppliers in the Datamation 100 were founded after the IBM System/360 was released.

    As for application software, IBM opened the interface between its OS and application

    software in 1969 under pressure from the U.S. government. Until then IBM made its large

    library of application software available for free to all customers that leased IBMs

    System/360 computers (Flamm, 1988; Baldwin and Clark, 2000). It was only after the U.S.

    Justice Department started an anti-trust case against IBM that IBM un-bundled its hardware

  • 15

    and application software in 1969 thus making IBMs interface between hardware and

    software an open industry standard in 1969 (Steinmueller, 1996; Campbell-Kelly, 2003). As

    with peripherals, this reduced the transaction costs associated with other firms selling

    application software to users of IBMs System/360 and thus facilitated the founding of many

    new firms (Campbell-Kelly, 2003). As shown in Table 4, seven of the twelve de novo

    mainframe software firms in the Datamation 100 were founded after IBM announced the

    unbundling of its software and hardware.

    Open standards did not emerge for other modules and their interfaces in mainframe

    computers. None of the mainframe computer manufacturers opened the design rules that

    defined the interface between their CPUs and OSs and instead they designed their own CPUs

    and OSs. A lack of open design rules, much less open interface standards, prevented

    reductions in both the transaction costs associated with different firms designing these

    modules and the importance of integrative capabilities from occurring. Mainframe computer

    suppliers competed in these integrative capabilities and both IBMs high share and economies

    of scale in capabilities (Fisher et al, 1983, Flamm, 1988; Ceruzzi, 1998; Klepper, 1997)

    reduced the chances of entry by new computer manufacturers and caused IBM to have the

    highest market value in the IT sector until the 1990s (Baldwin and Clark, 2000). Nevertheless,

    1 of 2 de novo mainframe computer suppliers was founded after the release of IBMs

    System/360.

    From the standpoint of users, not all of them could afford mainframe computers. The

    emergence of other open standards provided opportunities for firms to provide so-called

    remote services to users that could not afford mainframe computers. Through the emergence

    of open standards, users were able access these remote services on dumb terminals that were

    attached to telephone lines through modems. The key event that enabled the emergence of

    open standards for the interfaces modems and telephone lines was the DC Circuit Court of

    Appeals decision for Hush-a-Phone in 1956 (Brock, 1981; Cortada, 2004). The Court ruled

  • 16

    that third parties could attach devices to AT&Ts telephone system. As shown in Table 4, all

    of the de novo firms involved with remote services were formed after the first standards for

    connecting modems to telephone lines were first established in the late 1950s (Cortada,

    2004).

    4.2 Mini-computers

    Open standards also emerged to some extent for mini-computers. A key event for

    mini-computers was DECs release of a 16-bit mini-computer in 1970, which many observers

    (Flamm, 1988; Rifkin and Harrar, 1988; Ceruzzi, 1998) including management scholars

    (Anderson and Tushman, 1990) consider a dominant design for mini-computers. The success

    of IBMs System/360 had defined word lengths with multiplies of 8-bits (now considered one

    byte) as an industry standard. Although many suppliers of peripherals and application

    software were already selling to users or manufacturers of mini-computers, the introduction

    of 16-bit machines increased the compatibility between mini-computers and between them

    and mainframe computers (Ceruzzi, 1998) and thus further reduced the transaction costs

    associated with different firms providing mini-computers, peripherals, and applications

    software, some in the form of so-called value-added resellers (VARs), which combined these

    modules for specific industry applications (Rifkin and Harrar, 1988; Ceruzzi, 1998).

    Furthermore, these reductions in transaction costs also reduced the importance of integrative

    capabilities and enabled vertically disintegrated mini-computer suppliers to dominate the

    market (Flamm, 1988; Rifkin and Harrar, 1988). As shown in Table 4, a little more than half

    (19 of 36) of the de novo suppliers of mini-computer-related products were founded after

    DECs 16-bit mini-computer emerged as a dominant design in 1970 and defined an open

    standard between peripherals, computers, operating systems, and application software.

    4.3 Personal Computers (PCs)

  • 17

    Open standards also emerged to some extent in PCs. As documented in a great deal of

    detail elsewhere, perhaps best by Langlois (1992), the design rules for the IBM PC became

    the standards for these interfaces. IBM intentionally opened the design rules for the interface

    between most of the key components such as the microprocessor, OS, application software,

    and the so-called BIOS software, which was IBMs only proprietary part of the PC, in order

    to attract outside suppliers. Unfortunately for IBM, other firms were able to re-engineer the

    BIOS software and other interface design rules and offer so-called IBM compatible

    computers that relied on many of the exact same components (e.g., microprocessor, OS, and

    peripherals) that were used in the IBM PC. For example, Compaq, and Dell were founded

    after the release of the IBM PC and used the externally available OSs, microprocessors,

    peripherals, and application software to become successful suppliers of PCs. In other words,

    the release of the IBM PC inadvertently reduced both the transaction costs associated with

    different firms supplying different modules and the importance of capabilities in multiple

    modules and of those associated with integrating them.

    However, as shown in Table 4, a smaller proportion of de novo firms were founded after

    the release of the IBM PC (14 of 33) than were founded before its release (19 of 33). One

    reason for this smaller proportion than in the other discontinuities/systems is the increases

    transaction costs that came from the closing of some interface standards. Although the

    interface standards that define the interaction between the CPU, OS, and application software

    were relatively open when IBM first released its PC in 1981 (and thus I define them as open

    for the analysis done for Hypothesis 1 with the data in Table 3), most observers argue that

    Microsoft gradually increased its control over these interface standards in the late 1980s and

    early 1990s and this control increased the transaction costs associated with different firms

    supplying the OS and application software and thus reduced the number of entrepreneurial

    opportunities for application software providers (Ceruzzi, 1998; Campbell-Kelly, 2003). For

    example, initially successful software from WordPerfect (word processing), Lotus

  • 18

    (spreadsheet), and Borland (database) was largely replaced by software from Microsoft in the

    1990s (Campbell-Kelly, 2003) and only two PC application software providers, Adobe and

    Novell, remained in the top 50 software firms by 2002 (Cusumano, 2004).

    4.4 Client-Server Computing

    Unlike the other discontinuities, client-server systems did not emerge through a top-down

    process in which a relatively complete computer system was introduced at a single point of

    time. Instead it emerged through multiple bottom-up processes (Jacobides, 2005) that

    involved the parallel introduction of open standards for workstations (UNIX), the Internet

    (TCP/IP), and LANs (Ethernet) before Microsofts Windows 3.0 marked the official

    beginning of client-server computing in the early 1990s (Ceruzzi, 1998; Moore, 1999; Brock,

    2003; Campbell-Kelly, 2003). UNIX was gradually improved and revised following its

    release by AT&T in 1970 where 1978 is defined as the emergence of the open standard for

    UNIX because variations began to emerge after 1978. The TCP/IP standard for the Internet

    was established in the late 1970s (Abbate, 1999) and the first version of the Ethernet standard

    for LANs was released in 1980 (von Burg, 2001) where the emergence of these open

    standards gradually reduced the transaction costs associated with different firms supplying

    these modules.

    As shown in Table 4, more de novo were founded after the release of these open standards

    than were founded before their release (19 of 33). Seven of the ten LAN/router suppliers from

    the Datamation 100 were founded after the LAN standard was released in 1980 and the

    Internet standards were released in the late 1970s. For workstations, all 12 of these firms

    eventually used UNIX or another externally available OS and also externally available

    microprocessors in their workstations3 and 9 of 12 were founded after the version of UNIX

    3 Although a standard also emerged for workstation microprocessors in the form of Suns SPARC (Scalable Processor Architecture), which

    is a RISC-(Reduced Instruction Set Computing) based microprocessor (Garud and Kumaraswamy, 1993; Khazam and Mowery, 1998;

    Sorensen, 2003), since the literature on the computer industry focuses more on UNIX than RISC or SPARC (Abbate, 1999; Ceruzzi, 1998;

  • 19

    that is common to all subsequent versions was released in 1978.

    For system software, all of the firms classified as suppliers of system software started as

    suppliers of software for mainframe, mini-, and personal computers and merely upgraded

    their software for client-server systems after Microsoft successfully introduced Windows 3.0

    in the early 1990s. They were able to do this because the users of client-server systems

    already used mainframe, mini-, and personal computers and thus demanded backward

    compatibility with these computers as they upgraded their systems to client-server systems

    (Flamm, 1988, Ceruzzi, 1998). Therefore, the relevant dates for when open standards

    emerged for system software suppliers are when open standards were established for

    mainframe, mini-, and personal computer software. Eight of the system software suppliers

    were initially suppliers for mainframes including Oracle, SAS, and JD Edwards and all eight

    of them were founded after IBM announced unbundling in 1969. SAP and System Software

    Associates were initially suppliers for mini-computers and Sybase was initially a supplier for

    PCs. Both SAP and System Software Associates were founded after the release of 16-bit

    mini-computers and Sybase was founded three years after the release of the IBM PC.

    An alternative way to analyze system software would be to consider the interface for which

    the emergence of an open standard would have reduced the transaction costs associated with

    new entrants providing system software. Since users demanded backward compatibility with

    their existing systems, the relevant interface is between the software for previous (i.e.,

    mainframe, mini-, and PC software) and client-server systems (i.e., system software).

    However, open standards for these interfaces have never emerged (Besen and Farrell, 1994;

    Shapiro and Varian, 1999; van Everdingen et al, 2000) partly since incumbent suppliers of

    software did not want such an open standard to emerge and instead used control over their

    Campbell-Kelly, 2003), this paper uses the release of the first version of UNIX as the date for the release of the open standard (i.e., dominant

    design) for workstations.

  • 20

    proprietary design rules to upgrade customers from existing software (for mainframe, mini, or

    personal computers) to the system software for client-server systems (Moore, 1999; Shapiro

    and Varian, 1999).

    The last vertically disintegrated layer to consider is system integration, for which open

    standards have never emerged. Although this layer is included in this sub-section on

    client-server systems, it is probably more accurate to include this layer as a separate

    sub-section since it has existed since the early days of main- frame computers. Firms in this

    layer initially provided contract software for sophisticated users such as the military and other

    government agencies and this contract software gradually became more complex and

    proprietary as the complexity of computer systems has increased. Now called systems

    integrators, the early providers of these services successfully resisted the emergence of open

    standards between different computer systems and between software for these different

    computer systems (cited in the previous paragraphs) and have used their proprietary systems

    to increase the switching costs for users (Shapiro and Varian, 1999; van Everdingen et al,

    2000). These switching costs have increased the transactions costs associated with new

    entrants providing systems integration services. The result is that de novo firms are

    represented less among systems integrators than other providers of software (see earlier

    discussion of Hypothesis 1) and none of the firms defined as a systems integrator in the

    Datamation 100 (either de alio or de novo) were founded after 1982 and more than half of

    these firms were founded before 1970. Many of the de alio system integrators in the

    Datamation lists came from the accounting or general consulting industries. They used their

    relationships with IT users in their accounting and general consulting work to build a large

    installed base of customers for system integration services and create switching costs to

    maintain this installed base.

    5. Discussion

  • 21

    This paper uses the literature on industry architecture to challenge the conventional

    wisdom on entry timing and re-examine the tradeoffs for vertically disintegrated

    entrepreneurial startups. The conventional wisdom is that the emergence of a dominant

    design defines a set of necessary capabilities that firms must have in order to effectively

    compete, leads to the exit or acquisition of firms that are deficient in these capabilities, and

    thus causes a decline, i.e., a shakeout, in the total number of firms, where these shakeouts

    occur even when the size of the market continues to grow. This suggests that firms must enter

    and be founded before a dominant design emerges.

    The literature on industry architecture suggests there is a tradeoff between early entry to

    develop capabilities and later entry to benefit from lower transaction costs. For each module

    or so-called vertically disintegrated layer, early entrants can begin doing R&D and

    developing capabilities. Later entrants will be at a disadvantage in terms of these economies

    of scale in capabilities and thus may incur higher R&D costs as a percent of sales than do

    earlier entrants. On the other hand, the emergence of open design rules and open standards

    can reduce the transaction costs associated with different firms providing these different

    modules. The emergence of these externally available modules also reduces the importance

    of integrative capabilities and thus increases the advantages of vertically disintegrated firms

    vis--vis vertically integrated firms. Furthermore, if the relevant open standards are defined

    by designs that can be classified as dominant designs, the emergence of such a dominant

    design would also reduce transaction costs and thus facilitate the entry of new firms.

    Assuming that economies of scale in R&D increases in the same way for all modules as

    characterized by Klepper (1996), this paper focuses on declining transaction costs from the

    emergence of open design rules and interface standards and whether these declining

    transaction costs enable new firms to enter. Hypothesis 1 addressed whether de novo

    entrepreneurial startups are more represented among modules that involve open interface

    standards than in those that do not. It was found that the proportion of de novo to total

  • 22

    number of firms, or the number of de novo firms was much larger for those vertically

    disintegrated layers in which open standards emerged than for those layers in which they did

    not. A lack of open standards for the interfaces between application software from different

    systems/discontinuities and for the interfaces between a computers OS and CPU reduced the

    number of opportunities for de novo startups in systems integration and in OSs, and CPUs

    respectively. The former was tested by comparing the proportion of de novo to total number

    of firms in systems integration software (10 of 24) than in other software (36 of 40); the

    difference in these proportions is significant at the 0.001 level. The latter was tested by

    comparing the small number of independent suppliers of OSs and CPUs with the much larger

    numbers of firms in other layers.

    After excluding those layers for which open standards did not emerge, the analysis

    focused on founding date for new entrants. Since market entry must occur after a firm is

    founded, a comparison of when firms were founded and when open standards emerged will

    underestimate the extent to which the emergence of open standards reduces transaction costs

    and facilitates market entry. This papers analysis found that more de novo firms were

    founded after open standards were released (97 of 150) than before they were released (53 of

    150) and this is significant at the 0.001 level. These results suggest that entrepreneurial

    opportunities still exist after an open interface standard has been established and to some

    extent the entrepreneurial opportunities are created by the emergence of the open interface

    standards since their emergence reduces transaction and thus entry costs. Furthermore, since

    these open standards are often defined by designs that are classified as dominant designs by

    the literature on technology management, these results suggest that entrepreneurial

    opportunities still exist after a dominant design containing open standards has been

    established and to some extent the entrepreneurial opportunities are created by the release of

    an open dominant design that reduces the transaction costs associated different firms

    supplying different modules.

  • 23

    This papers analysis of multiple modules and interface standards also suggests that

    reductions in transaction costs may lead to new firm entry in different ways for different

    situations. For example, open standards are needed before some services can be

    technologically provided and thus the emergence of open standards may dramatically (as

    opposed to gradually) reduce the transaction costs associated with different firms providing

    different modules in a very short time. This was probably the case with remote services that

    could not be provided before an open interface between computers and telecommunication

    systems was defined and a standard for this interface in the form of a modem was released.

    Thus, all of the firms that are classified as providers of remote services in Table 4 were

    founded after the initial standards for modems were established. More recent examples of

    services that could not be provided before open standards were defined are (PC) Internet

    content and applications (Abbate, 1999) and mobile Internet content and applications (Funk,

    2007).

    Second, the emergence of some open standards probably increased the size of the market

    for many types of computer peripherals and software and reduced the number of interface

    design rules that had to be addressed by suppliers of peripherals and software. For example,

    although some firms supplied peripherals to computer manufacturers other than IBM before

    the System/360 was released, the release of the System/360 opened up a large new market for

    these peripherals and defined a single standard for the interface. To some extent similar things

    occurred following IBMs decision to unbundle hardware and software in its mainframe

    computer and the release of the 16-bit mini-computers and the IBM PC. Third, the emergence

    of open standards makes it easier for firms to supply the final product, computers, using

    externally available peripherals, application software, OSs, and CPUs. This was the case with

    16-bit mini-computers, the IBM PC, and workstations in that the emergence of externally

    available modules reduced the transaction costs associated with new entrants combining these

    externally available modules into computers.

  • 24

    The case of Apples i-Phone will hopefully illustrate some of these issues and the problems

    with the management literatures characterization of entrepreneurial opportunities and

    dominant designs. The conventional wisdom about dominant designs would focus ones

    attention on phones and the potential reduction in the number of opportunities for new phone

    entrants that the i-Phone might bring. However, this papers analysis would focus ones

    attention on how the greater use of open standards in the i-Phone than in other phones has

    already enabled thousands of firms to enter the mobile phone industry and become providers

    of application software. Furthermore, the emergence externally available modules that the

    open standards is bringing might enable other firms to use these same modules to supply

    mobile phones in much the same way that the release of the IBM PC inadvertently facilitated

    the entry of personal computer manufacturers.

    One thing that this paper is not arguing, however, is that firms should be founded after an

    open standard has emerged. The real issue is not timing, it is how firms can recognize the

    emergence of open design rules and open standards in for example the i-Phone. Economies of

    scale in R&D and other functions means that early entry is better than late entry as long as

    firms can adapt to changes in interface design rules and standards. However, the large

    proportion of de novo firms that were founded after open standards were released suggests

    that adapting to changes in design rules and standards is a very large challenge. Future

    research should attempt to better understand how early entrants failed (and other firms

    succeeded). Did they fail because they did not notice the changes in design rules or the

    emergence of standards or because they were unable to adapt to their emergence and to the

    new capabilities that were associated with the emergence of these standards?

    Future research should also address several limitations in this study. First, a larger sample

    of firms would provide a better test of the two hypotheses. Second, testing the hypothesis

    with entry date rather than founding data could provide more detailed insights into the impact

    of falling transaction costs on entry timing. Third, similar arguments could also be made for

  • 25

    better quantifying the degree of agreements on standards (e.g., there were more versions of

    UNIX than in other standards). Fourth, data on economies of scale in for example, R&D

    would enable one to further analyze the tradeoffs between economies of scale in R&D and

    falling transaction costs. Fifth, data on economies of scale in R&D could be combined with

    data on the total number of firms in each module to analyze the impact of economies of scale

    in R&D on the total number of firms and thus the number of entrepreneurial opportunities in

    each layer.

    6. Conclusions

    This paper re-characterizes the issue of entry timing using the literature on industry

    architecture. Focusing on a specific module, early entrants can benefit from economies of

    scale in capabilities while later entrants can benefit from the reductions in entry costs that

    occur as open design rules and open standards emerge and that reduce the transaction costs

    associated with different firms supplying different modules. Focusing on transaction costs,

    this papers analysis found that a larger number of successful de novo firms were founded

    after the release of open standards than were founded before their release. These results

    suggest that the emergence of open standards can facilitate the entry of new firms and if the

    relevant open standards are defined by designs that can be classified as dominant designs the

    emergence of such a dominant design would also reduce transaction costs and thus facilitate

    the entry of new firms.

  • 26

    6. References

    Abbate J 1999. Inventing the Internet, Cambridge: MIT Press.

    Agarwal R, Gort M 1996. The evolution of markets and entry, exit, and survival of firms The

    Review of Economics and Statistics 78(3): 489-498.

    Anderson P, Tushman M 1990. Technological discontinuities and dominant designs: A

    cyclical model of technological change. Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 604-633.

    Arora A, Fosuri A, Gambardella A 2001. Markets and Technology: The Economics of

    Innovation and Corporate Strategy. Boston: MIT Press.

    Audretsch D 1991. New Firm Survival and the Technological Regime, Review of Economics

    and Statistics 441-450.

    Baldwin C, Clark K 2000. Design Rules, Volume 1: The Power of Modularity, Cambridge,

    MA: MIT Press.

    Baldwin C 2008. Where do transactions come from? Modularity, transactions, and the

    boundaries of firms, Industrial & Corporate Change 17(1), 155-195.

    Baron R and Shane S 2005. Entrepreneurship: a process prospective. NJ: South-Western

    Besen S, Farrell J 1994. Choosing How to Compete: Strategies and Tactics in Standardization,

    The Journal of Economic Perspectives 8(2): 117-131

    Brock G. 2003. The Second Information Revolution, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Brock G 1981. The Telecommunications Industry: The Dynamics of Market Structure,

    Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Brusoni S, Prencipe A 2001. Unpacking the Black Box of Modularity: Technologies, Products

    and Organizations, Industrial and Corporate Change 10(1): 179-205.

    Bygrave W, Zacharakis A 2003. The Portable MBA in Entrepreneurship, NY: John Wiley &

    Sons, 3rd edition.

    Campbell-Kelly M 2003. From airline reservations to sonic the hedgehog: A history of the

    software Industry. Boston: MIT Press.

  • 27

    Ceruzzi P 1998. A History of Modern Computing, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Chandler A 1977. The Visible Hand, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press

    Chesbrough H 2003. Open innovation: The new imperative for creating and profiting from

    technology. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Christensen C 1993. The Rigid Disk Drive Industry: A History of Commercial and

    Technological Turbulence, Business History Review 67: 531-588.

    Christensen C 1997. The innovators dilemma, Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Christensen C, Verlinden M, Westerman G 2002. Disruption, disintegration, and the

    dissipation of differentiability, Industrial and Corporate Change 11(5): 955-993.

    Cortada J 2006. The Digital Hand: How Computers Changed the Work of American

    Financial, Telecommunications, Media, and Entertainment Industries. NY: Oxford

    University Press.

    Cusumano M 2004. The Business of Software. NY: The Free Press.

    Dorfman N 1987. Innovation and Market Structure: Lessons from the computer structure.

    NY: Ballinger.

    Farrell J, Saloner G 1985. Standardization, Compatibility, and Innovation, RAND

    Journal of Economics 16(1): 70-83.

    Fisher F, McKie J, Mancke R 1983. IBM and the U.S. data processing industry, NY: Praeger.

    Flamm K 1988. Creating the computer: government, industry, and high technology,

    Washington DC: Brookings Institution.

    Fransman, M, 2002, Telecoms in the Internet Age: From Boom to Bust To...? Oxford

    University Press, NY.

    Funk J 2007. Solving the Startup Problem in Western Mobile Internet Markets.

    Telecommunications Policy 31(1): 14-30.

    Garud R, Kumaraswamy A 1993. Changing Competitive Dynamics in Network Industries:

    An Exploration of Sun Microsystems Open Systems Strategy, Strategic Management

  • 28

    Journal 14(5): 351-369

    Gort M, Klepper S 1982. Time Paths in the Diffusion of Product Innovations, Economic

    Journal 92: 630-653.

    Hatfield, D, Echols, A, and Tegarden, L. 1999. Doomed from the start: what is the value of

    selecting a future dominant design? Strategic Management Journal 20: 495518.

    Henderson R, Clark K 1990. Architectural innovation: The reconfiguration of existing

    product technologies and the failure of established Firms, Administrative Science

    Quarterly 35: 9-30.

    Jacobides M 2005. Industry Change through Vertical Disintegration: How and why markets

    emerged in mortgage banking, Academy of Management Journal 48 (3): 465 498.

    Jacobides M 2006. Designing the Boundaries of the Firm: From Make, Buy, or Ally to the

    Dynamic Benefits of Vertical Architecture, Organization Science 17(2): 249261

    Jacobides M, Knudsen T, Augier M, 2006. Benefiting from innovation: Value creation, value

    appropriation, Research Policy 35: 12001221

    Juliussen E, Isaacson P, Kruse L 1987. Computer Industry Almanac. NY: Prentice-Hall.

    Katz M, Shapiro C 1985. Network Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility, American

    Economic Review 75(3): 424-440.

    Katz M, Shapiro C 1994. Systems Competition and Network Effects, The Journal of

    Economic Perspectives 8(2): 93-115.

    Kenney M 2003. The Growth and Development of the Internet in the United States, In The

    Global Internet Economy, Kogut, B (Ed.) Cambridge: MIT Press: 69-108.

    Khazam J, Mowery D 1994. The Commercialization of RISC: Strategies for the Creation of

    Dominant Designs, Research Policy 23: 89-102.

    Klepper S 1997. Industry Life Cycles. Industrial and Corporate Change 6(2): 145-181.

    Klepper S 1996. Entry, exit and growth over the product life cycle, American Economic

    Review, 86: 562-583.

  • 29

    Klepper S, Simons K 1997. Technological Extinctions of Industrial Firms: An Inquiry into

    their Nature and Causes. Industrial and Corporate Change 6(2): 379-460.

    Klepper S, Graddy E 1990. The Evolution of New Industries and the Determinants of Market

    Structure, Rand Journal of Economics 21: 27-44.

    Langlois R 1992. External Economics and Economic Progress: the case of the

    Microcomputer Industry, Business History Review 66: 1- 50.

    Langlois R 2003. The vanishing hand: the changing dynamics of industrial capitalism,

    Industrial and Corporate Change 12(2): 351-385.

    Langlois R 2007. The dynamics of industrial capitalism: Schumpeter, Chandler, and the

    New Economy, NY: Taylor and Francis Group.

    Langlois R, Robertson P 1992. Networks and innovation in a modular system: lessons from

    the microcomputer and stereo component industries, Research Policy 21: 297-313.

    Mitra A 1993. Fundamentals of Quality Control and Improvement, NY: MacMillan.

    Moore G 1999. Crossing the Chasm: Marketing and Selling High-Tech Products to

    Mainstream Customers, NY: HarperBusiness.

    Murmann P, Frenken K 2006. Toward a Systematic Framework for Research on Dominant

    Designs, Technological Innovations, and Industrial Change, Research Policy 35(7):

    25-952.

    Pugh E 1995. Building IBM: Shaping an industry and its technology. MIT Press.

    Rifkin G, Harrar G 1983. The ultimate entrepreneur: the story of Ken Olsen and Digital

    Equipment Corporation, NY: Contemporary Books.

    Sanchez R, Mahoney J 1996. Modularity, flexibility, and knowledge management in product

    and organization design, Strategic Management Journal 17: 63-76.

    Shane S.= 2004. Finding Fertile Ground: Identifying Extraordinary Opportunities for New

    Ventures, Philadelphia: Wharton Publishers.

    Shapiro S, Varian H 1999. Information Rules, Harvard Business School Press.

  • 30

    Sorensen O 2003. Interdependence and Adaptability: Organizational Learning and the

    Long-Term Effect of Integration, Management Science 49(4): 446-463.

    Steinmueller W 1996. The U.S. Software Industry: An Analysis and Interpretive History. In

    Mowery, David C. (Ed), The International Computer Software Industry. NY: Oxford

    University Press.

    Storper M, Christopherson S 1987. Flexible Specialization and Regional Industrial

    Agglomeration: the case of the US Motion Picture Industry, Annals of the Association of

    American Geographers. 77: 104-117.

    Suarez F, Utterback J 1995. Dominant Designs and the Survival of Firms, Strategic

    Management Journal 16: 415-430.

    Teece D 1986. Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration,

    collaboration, licensing and public policy, Research Policy 15(6): 285-305.

    Tushman M, Anderson P 1986. Technological discontinuities and organizational environment,

    Administrative Science Quarterly 31: 439-456.

    Tushman M, Rosenkopf L 1992. Organizational Determinants of Technological Change:

    Toward a Sociology of Technological Evolution, in Cummings, L. and B. Staw (eds),

    Research in Organizational Behavior 14: 311-347, Greenwich, CT:

    Ulrich K 1995. The role of product architecture in the manufacturing firm, Research Policy

    24: 419-440.

    Utterback J 1994. Mastering the dynamics of innovation, Boston: Harvard Business Press.

    van Everdingen Y, van Hillegersberg J, Waarts E 2000. Enterprise resource planning: ERP

    adoption by European midsize companies. Communications of ACM archive 4(4): 2731.

    von Burg U 2001. The Triumph of Ethernet, Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Wikipedia 2009. History of UNIX: //en.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Unix_history-simple.en.svg

  • 31

    Table 1. Number of De Novo and De Alio Firms in the Datamation Rankings and the Number of New Firms Entering these Rankings (either top 50 or top 100) Each Year

    All firms in top 50 All firms in 51-100 Firms New to List Year De Novo De Alio De Novo De Alio De Novo De Alio Total (1)

    1975 22 28 NA NA 22 28 50 (2) 1976 21 29 NA NA 3 2 5 1977 22 27 NA NA 0 1 2 1978 21 28 NA NA 1 2 3 1979 19 30 30 19 30 20 51 (2) 1980 17 33 25 23 8 14 22 1981 19 31 26 22 3 4 8 1982 19 31 26 23 6 2 10 1983 20 30 24 24 3 6 10 1984 21 29 30 18 12 3 16 1985 21 29 33 16 9 3 12 1986 23 27 33 17 11 4 15 1987 23 27 36 14 9 4 13 1988 24 26 34 16 5 2 7 1989 25 25 38 12 10 1 11 1990 26 24 34 16 3 2 5 1991 29 21 34 16 11 3 14 1992 28 22 34 15 4 1 5 1993 29 21 37 12 6 0 6 1994 31 19 39 10 13 4 18 1995 31 18 NA NA 1 2 4 1996 31 19 NA NA 0 1 1 Total NA NA NA NA 170 109 288 Notes: (1) Some of the numbers for the de novo and de alio firms to not add up to 50 or to 100 because of a lack of information on some firms. Thus, the differences between the number 50 and the sums of columns 2 and 3 and the sums of columns 4 and 5 are the number of unknown/unclassifiable firms. The same reason accounts for the differences between the total number of new firms to the list in column 8 and the sum of columns 6 and 7. (2) The numbers 50 and 51 reflect the first year of the Datamation 50 and 100 lists respectively and thus there were by definition a large number of firms new to the list in those two years. NA: Not applicable

  • 32

    Table 2. Status of Standards for Discontinuities/Systems in the Information Technology Sector (1950 to 1995)

    System Interface Between Name of Standard or Product Defining Standard

    Year Established/Released

    Open vs. Closed

    Computer and Peripherals IBM System/360 1964 Open OS and Application S/W IBMs unbundling of

    software and hardware 1969 Open

    OS and CPU IBM System/360 1964 Closed

    Mainframe Computer

    Computer and Remote Services

    Various enacted after Hush-a-Phone case

    1956 Open

    Computer and Peripherals Extensive product documentation by computer firms

    1965 Open

    OS and Application S/W Open Computer and Value-Added Reseller

    16-bit word length (multiple of 8-bits)

    1970 Open

    Mini- Computer

    OS and CPU None NA Closed Computer and Peripherals Open OS and Application S/W Initially

    open

    Personal Computer (PC)

    OS and CPU

    IBM PC (later called WINTEL standard)

    1981

    Closed Computers and Internet TCP/IP 1980 Open Computers and LAN Ethernet 1980 Open Computers and Users Windows 1990 Closed Application S/W from Different Systems/ Discontinuities

    None NA Closed

    Client- server system

    Workstation OS UNIX 1978 Open

    Abbreviations: CPU (central processing unit); OS (Operating System); LAN (Local Area Network); S/W (software); NA (Not applicable) Sources: (Rifkin and Harrar, 1983; Flamm, 1988; Langlois, 1992; Steffens, 1994; Pugh and Aspray, 1996; Ceruzzi, 1998; von Burg, 2001; Campbell-Kelly, 2003).

  • 33

    Table 3. Proportion of De Novo to Total Number of Firms

    Computers Peripherals Application Software

    Operating Systems

    Discontinuity

    Proportion

    All Firms

    Proportion

    All Firms

    Proportion

    All Firms

    Proportion

    All Firms

    Mainframe 0.29 7 0.60 15 0.80 15 0 0 Mini 0.67 21 0.50 10 0.83 6 0 0 Personal 0.50 16 0.57 30 1.00 7 1.00 1 Client-Server 1.00

    (4) 12 (4) 0.67 (3) 15 (3) 1.00 (1)

    0.42 (2) 11 (1) 24 (2)

    0 0

    Total 0.62 52 0.59 70 0.71 63 1.00 1 (1) system software (2) system integration services (3) LAN/Routers (4) Workstation-related products and services

  • 34

    Table 4. Number of De Novo Firms Founded before the Discontinuity, after the Discontinuity

    but before an Open Standard is Released, and after the Open Standard is Released Number of Firms that were Founded System/

    Discontinuity

    Module/Vertically Disintegrated Layer

    Number ofDe Novo Firms Before Standard is

    Released After Standard is released

    Computer 2 1 1Peripheral 9 5 4

    Mainframe Computer

    Software 12 5 7Time sharing 3 3Process services 12 12

    Remote Services

    Terminals 10 10Computer 14 8 6Peripherals 5 2 3Software 5 2 3

    Mini- Computer

    Value Added Reseller 12 5 7Computer 8 4 4Peripheral 17 11 6

    Personal Computer

    Software 8 4 4Workstation 12 3 9Local Area Network/Router 10 3

    7Client Server Systems

    System Software

    11 11

    Total Number of Firms 150 53 97

  • 35

    Table 5. The Most Successful De Novo Firms* for each Vertically Disintegrated Layer and their Date of Founding System/ Discontinuity

    Module/ Vertically Disintegrated Layer

    Firm Date of Founding

    Years in the Top 25

    Computer CDC Amdahl

    1957 1970**

    1975-1989 1977-81, 83-92

    Peripheral

    Storage Technology Memorex

    1969** 1961

    1979-84, 91-92 1975-1980

    Software Computer Associates

    1974** 1989-1996

    Mainframe Computer

    Terminals

    Mohawk Data Sciences Datapoint

    1964** 1969**

    1975-1977 1980-1982

    Mini- Computers

    Computer DEC Data General Prime Tandem

    1957 1969 1972** 1974**

    1975-1996 1975-1991 1981, 85-86, 88-91 1986-94

    Computer Apple Compaq Dell

    1977 1982** 1984**

    1981-1996 1987-1996 1992-1996

    Peripheral Seagate Quantum Conner Peripherals

    1978 1980 1986**

    1987-1996 1992-1996 1990-1994

    Personal Computer

    Software Microsoft 1975 1990-1996 Workstaton Sun 1982** 1988-1996 LAN/Router Cisco 1984** 1993-1996

    Client Server Systems System

    Software Oracle 1977** 1994-1996

    *defined as in the top 25 firms in the Datamation ranking for at least two years **established after the relevant standard had been released

  • 36

    Figure 1. Cost Tradeoffs for Timing of Entry/Establishment (1)

    Time

    Costs

    Reductions intransaction costs

    Minimum costs of entry/establishment

    Increasedeconomies ofscale (includingR&D)

    (1) Assumes the eventual emergence of open standards. The emergence of closed standards would increase transaction costs and this case is not shown here.

    Figure 2. Evolution of Industry Architecture for IT Sector

    1950 1960 1970 1980 1990

    MainframeComputers

    Mini-Computers

    PersonalComputers

    (PCs)

    Computer Design

    User (3)Customization

    System360

    Peripherals

    IBMUnbundling

    16-bitword

    length

    IBM PC

    Windows, UNIX, TCP/IP,Ethernet,

    S/W: software; App: application; OS: operating system; CPU: central processing unit; VAR: Value-added reseller. (1): Includes PCs and workstations. (2) Mainframe computers and workstations are also used as servers; (3) Includes contract S/W and services; 4) includesfacility management, computer leasing, and remote services such as processing or time-sharing.

    User Customization (3)

    VARsPeripherals

    App S/WPeripherals

    OSMicroprocessor

    Peripherals Mic

    ropr

    oces

    sor

    Syst

    ems

    Softw

    are

    and

    Syst

    ems I

    nteg

    ratio

    nA

    pp/ S

    /W

    OS

    Net

    -w

    orks

    Mic

    ropr

    oces

    sor

    OS

    App

    S/W

    Clie

    nt (1

    ) Des

    ign

    Serv

    er (2

    ) Des

    ign

    Contract S/W, Services (4)

    Contract S/W, Services (4)

    Peripherals

    Computer Design

    App S/W

    Contract S/W, Services (4)

    Application S/WPeripherals

    Computer Design

    ComputerDesign

    Computer Design Computer Design

    Computer Design

    Client-ServerSystems