294

Eurasian Cities: New Realities along the Silk Road

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

This report responds to pressing questions for policymakers in Eurasian cities and national governments. Faced with changing economic circumstances and a reorientation of trade toward Europe and Asia, will Eurasia’s cities be able to adjust? Will some cities be granted the flexible regulations and supportive policies necessary for growth? And will some be permitted to shrink and their people assisted in finding prosperity elsewhere in the region?

Citation preview

EURASIAN CITIESEURASIAN CITIESNew Realities along the Silk RoadSouleymane CoulibalyUwe DeichmannWilliam R. DillingerMarcel Ionescu-HeroiuIoannis N. KessidesCharles KunakaDaniel Saslavsky 2012 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank1818 H Street NW Washington DC 20433Telephone: 202-473-1000Internet: www.worldbank.orgSome rights reserved1 2 3 415 14 13 12This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. Note that The World Bank does not necessarily own each component of the content included in the work. The World Bank therefore does not warrant that the use of the content contained in the work will not infringe on the rights of third parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringement rests solely with you.The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily reflect the views ofTheWorldBank,itsBoardofExecutiveDirectors,orthegovernmentstheyrepresent.TheWorld Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denom-inations, and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of the privileges and immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved.Rights and PermissionsThis work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 Unported license (CC BY 3.0) http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0. Under the Creative Commons Attribution license, you are free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including for commercial purposes, under the following conditions:AttributionPleasecitetheworkasfollows:Coulibaly,Souleymane,UweDeichmann,WilliamR. Dillinger, Marcel Ionescu-Heroiu, Ioannis N. Kessides, Charles Kunaka, and Daniel Saslavsky. Eurasian Cities: New Realities along the Silk Road. Washington, D.C.: World Bank. DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-9581-3. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC BY 3.0TranslationsIf you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer along with the attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should not be considered an official World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for any content or error in this translation.All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to the Office of the Publisher, The World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2625; e-mail: [email protected] (paper): 978-0-8213-9581-3ISBN (electronic): 978-0-8213-9582-0DOI: 10.1596/978-0-8213-9581-3Cover design: Naylor Design, Inc.Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication DataEurasian cities : new realities along the Silk Road / Souleymane Coulibaly ... [et al.].p. cm.Includes bibliographical references.ISBN 978-0-8213-9581-3 (alk. paper) ISBN 978-0-8213-9582-01.Cities and townsEurasia. 2.City planningEurasia.I. Coulibaly, Souleymane.HT119.E9697 2012307.76095dc232012020577ContentsForewordxiiiAbout the AuthorsxviiAcknowledgmentsxxiAbbreviationsxxiiiOverviewxxvChapter Summariesxxxvii1.Rethinking Cities1The Effect of the Breakup of an Empire onthe Regions Cities5Back to the Market: New Realities for Citiessince the Breakup12Going Forward: Rethinking Eurasian Cities20Notes32References322.Planning Cities35The Soviet Past: The Era of Soviet Planning37The Transitional Present: PlanningsFall from Grace45A Sustainable Future: The Rebirth of Planning60Annex 2A76Notes79References80vviContents3.Connecting Cities83The Soviet Past: Connecting to aPreeminent Center86The Transitional Present: Living in a MultihubWorld90A Sustainable Future: Moving towardBetter Integration105Annex 3A122Notes128References1334.Greening Cities137The Soviet Past: Institutions without Markets140The Transitional Present: Weak Institutions andWeak Markets152A Sustainable Future: Strong Institutions andStrong Markets169Annex 4A183Notes184References185Statistical Websites1865.Financing Cities189Intergovernmental Financing in the Soviet Union 191Intergovernmental Financing during the Transition194Intergovernmental Financing Today 197Conclusion230Annex 5A: Financing Connectivity231Notes238References242Boxes1.1Local Institution Development in Kazan242.1Housing Swap Scheme in Georgia703.1Declining Road Safety944.1What Is the Best Way to Reduce Emissionsfrom a Taxi Fleet?1725.1The Communist Party and the Soviet Political Structure 1935.2Territorial Reform in Georgia2005.3Norms, Inefficiencies, and UnfundedMandates in Ukraine208Contentsvii5.4Choosing among Local Benefit Taxes2165.5Subnational Finance in China2225.6Resistance to Homeowner Associations inthe Former Soviet Union2245.7Technical Constraints on Water Metering2275A.1Financing Highways with Toll Roads2355A.2Is Earmarking Road Taxes a Good Idea?235ExhibitsO.1Size Distribution of Cities in the SovietUnion, 1939, 1959, 1974, and 1989xxviO.2Population Trends in Eurasian Cities,19922011xxx1.1Population Trends in EurasianCities, 1992201141.2Mean Surface Temperature in theSoviet Union, January 199081.3Size Distribution of Cities in the Soviet Union,1939, 1959, 1974, and 1989101.4Development of Baku, 1918, 1940, 1960,and 1980221.5Pollution in Former Soviet Union Cities,1992 and 2004252.1Floor Area of Food and Consumer GoodsStores in Moscow, 1989452.2Industrial and Similar Uses in SelectedCities in the Former Soviet Union, 2009502.3Distribution of Males in the SovietUnion, 1989603.1The Trans-AsiaEurope Optical FiberCable Network1184.1Air Pollution from Transport in the SovietUnion, 19881484.2Moscow Green Areas1524.3Air Pollution from Stationary Sources in Citiesin the Russian Federation, 1992 and 20091584.4Developments in Public Transport inSelected Eurasian Cities161FiguresO.1Population Shares Living in Cities of 1 MillionPeople or More, 19902010xxixviiiContents1.1Destination of Nonnatural ResourceIntensiveExports from the Central Asian Countries, 2003and 2008182.1GDP per Capita in Selected Countries,19902008 462.2Density in Selected Cities and TheirPeripheries, 1990482.3Industrial Area as Percentage of Built-UpArea in Selected Cities, 2010492.4New Construction in Armenia andGeorgia and Their Capitals512.5Young and Old People, by Country,1991 and 2008603.1Railway Traffic Volumes in the Soviet Unionand Successor Countries, 19852007933.2Time, Cost, and Distance of Transport alongthe Almaty-Berlin Trade Route, circa 20031093.3Internet Penetration Rates in SelectedCountries, 20101133.4Share of Broadband Subscribers perCapita in Selected Countries, 20091133.5Number of Fixed Broadband Connections in the Former Soviet Union and theWorld, 200008 1144.1Electricity Production in Western Europeand the Soviet Union, 1950801454.2Production of Primary Energy in theSoviet Union and Elsewhere, 1950s80s 1464.3Carbon Dioxide Emissions in SelectedCountries, 198920071544.4Carbon Dioxide Emissions in SelectedCountries, 1990 and 20071554.5Electric Power Consumption in SelectedCountries, 199020071564.6Composition of Energy Sources inSelected Countries, 1990 and 20071574.7Motor Gasoline Consumption inSelected Countries, 2000 and 20081604.8Household Consumption per Capita inthe Former Soviet Union, by Country,199120081644.9Water Use in Selected Countries, bySector and Year167Contentsix4.10Municipal Water Withdrawal inSelected Countries, 2002 1674.11Respiratory Diseases per 1,000People in Selected Countries, 20041694.12Indexes of Exposure to Climate Changeand Adaptive Capacity to Climate Changein the Former Soviet Union, by Country1704.13Net Energy Imports in the Former SovietUnion, by Country, 2007 1754.14Real Prices of Coal, Gas, and Oil onWorld Market, 199120081754.15Proposed Clean Energy Mix for California1774.16Retail Prices for Gasoline in SelectedCountries, 20081785.1GDP in the Russian Federation, 198920092025.2Revenue Composition in St. Petersburg,2005092115.3Expenditure Composition inSt. Petersburg, 20102115.4Revenue Composition in Kiev, 2007092125.5Municipal Expenditure Compositionin Kiev, 20092135.6Municipal Expenditure Compositionin Tbilisi, 20092145.7Aggregate Tax Burden in the FormerSoviet Union, by Country, 20092155.8Personal Income Tax as Percentage ofGDP in Selected Countries, 2009 or MostRecent Available2195.9Property Tax as Percentage of GDP inSelected Countries, 2009 or MostRecent Available2205.10Household Payments for Communal Servicesin the Russian Federation, 199420052255.11Cost-Recovery Levels in Public Transit in theRussian Federation, by Mode, 199520032285A.1Number of Telephones per 100 People inSelected Countries, 2009238TablesO.1Issues That Cities Face in the Former SovietUnion and Ways ForwardxxxiiixContents1.1Industrial Production in the FormerSoviet Union, by Ownership Type, 1928,1937, 1950, and 196061.2Ethnic Composition of Net Migrationfrom Eurasia (Excluding the RussianFederation) and the Baltics to the RussianFederation, 199094151.3Percentage of Total Exports, UnlessOtherwise Indicated191.4Issues That Cities Face in the FormerSoviet Union and Ways Forward292.1Housing Conditions in Selected Cities inthe Former Soviet Union, 1988422.2Homeownership Rates inSelected Countries, 2005522.3Number of Passenger Cars, by Country,1993 and 2007572.4Average Daily Hours of Operation ofWater Services, by Country592.5Reported Numbers of HomeownerAssociations in the Former Soviet Union,by Country, 2010692.6Water Tariffs and Cross-Subsidy Ratesin Regions Capital Cities, 2010732A.1Car Registration in the FormerSoviet Union, by Country762A.2Length and Capacity of Metro Systems inthe Former Soviet Union, by City, 2010783.1Maritime Port Volumes in the FormerSoviet Union, 2009 963.2Centrality Indicators for Capital Cities inEurasian Aviation Network983.3Number of Weekly Direct Services andIndirect Connections at Main Hubs1013.4Selected Bilateral Agreements withthe Russian Federation1113A.1Air Carriers Networks, 2000111223A.2Peripheralization of Eurasian Cities1243A.3Onward Connectivity: Number ofAvailable Indirectly Connected City Pairs,by Origin City, Hub, and Destination1253A.4Hub Connectivity: Number of ConnectedCity-Pairs via Selected Airports126Contentsxi3A.5Total Turnaround Costs for Selected Cities1274.1Atmospheric Pollution Emissions inSelected Cities, 19871424.2Vehicle Production in the Soviet Unionand Selected Countries, 1960861474.3Generation and Disposal of Toxic Wastein the Soviet Union, by Sector, 19901494.4Performance of Water and WastewaterSector in the Former Soviet Union, 19891504.5Commuter Statistics in Selected Cities, 19981624.6Waste Disposal Methods in SelectedCities, 19981654.7Market, Mixed, and GovernmentSolutions to Increasing Energy Efficiency1734A.1The 25 Coldest Cities in the RussianFederation and North America withabout 500,000 People, 20011835.1Structure of Subnational Government inthe Soviet Union1925.2Distribution of Tax Instruments acrossSubnational Tiers of Government inthe Russian Federation, 20092035.3Distribution of Shared Taxes inTajikistan, 20092065.4Distribution of Shared Taxes inUkraine, 20092075.5Personal Income Tax Rates in the FormerSoviet Union, by Country, 2010218ForewordEurasiancities,uniqueintheglobalspatiallandscape,werepartof the worlds largest experiment in urban development. The challenges they now face because of their history offer valuable lessons to urban plannersandpolicymakersacrosstheworldfromplacesthatare still urbanizing to those already urbanized.Morethanthree-quartersofthebuiltenvironmentinEurasian cities was developed after 1945 in a centralized fashion. Central plan-ners could implement whatever they considered good practice plan-ning solutions, and Eurasias cities became their drawing boards. The central planners got a lot righteasy access to public transportation, districtheatingnetworks,almostuniversalaccesstowatersystems, and socially integrated neighborhoods. At the same time, they failed to acknowledge the importance of markets and individual choice in shaping sustainable and congenial places for people to live in. From a spatial point of view, it became clear that many Eurasian cities were developed in places where they should not have been. To populate sparsely inhabited territory, Soviet planners pushed urban development toward the heart of Siberia. Many of the resulting cities hadnoruralhinterlandtorelyonfordailyfoodneedsandhadto depend on subsidized goods and services.To be viable in a market economy, Eurasias urban structures have toberethought.ThisbookbuildsontheinsightsintheWorld xiiixivForeword Development Report 2009: Reshaping Economic Geography to inform this rethinking. From a planners perspective, land and housing markets were fre-quently mismanaged in the former Soviet Union. Although Eurasian citieswerelargelysparedthenegativesideeffectsoforganicurban growth such as sprawl, central planners were not the best judges of howandwherelandshouldbedeveloped.Indeed,largeindustrial areasstilloccupyprimelandinEurasiancities,evenwhenthey shouldbeusedforotherpurposes.Flat-panelconcreteapartment blocks,builtquicklyandcheaplytoaccommodaterapidurban expansion, often had a short lifesometimes as few as 25 yearsbut continue to be inhabited. In many cases, these apartment blocks have not been upgraded since the end of communism. ThecollapseoftheSovieteconomyweakenedtheconnectivity betweenEurasiancities.Withoutsubsidiesfortransportinggoods and services cheaply from one city to another, the more remote cities are isolated from global markets and increasingly uncompetitive. Rail networks are hard to run efficiently, even with the lowest electricity pricesinEurope.Roadnetworksareexpensivetomaintainand upgrade. And air infrastructure is becoming more and more impor-tant for connecting a landmass that spans nine time zones.ManyEurasiancitiesfaceanoverdevelopedpublicserviceinfra-structure that is hard to maintain and upgrade. Facing an economic downturninthe1990sandlackingexperienceindecentralized urbanmanagement,manylocalauthoritiesstruggledtorunthese services. Public transport ridership fell in most cities, with more peo-ple commuting in private vehicles. Recycling networks disappeared, andsoaringconsumptionoverwhelmedsolidwastemanagement systems.Districtheatingsystemsbecamelargeenergysieveshard torunandmaintainwithoutsubsidies.Plaguingwatersystemsare large shares of nonrevenue water, and low tariffs do not ensure the cost recovery needed for upgrades and repairs. Finally, many Eurasian cities do not have the capacity to be self-sufficient financially. These cities depend largely on central govern-menttransfers,andprogressincreatingtoolsforgeneratingmore localrevenue(forexample,strategicallyusingmunicipalland)has been slow. Moreover, a reluctance to charge market prices for public serviceshasledtothecontinuingdeteriorationofexistingsystems. For example, heating tariffs, kept artificially low, not only encourage people to squander energy, but also make it hard for district heating systems to cover operating costs.Eurasian cities have to find the right balance between markets and institutionstobecomesustainable.Beforethe1990s,institutions Forewordxvwere strong, but markets were nonexistent. In the 1990s, many insti-tutionscrumbled,andmarketsdidnotdevelopasfastashasbeen hoped.The2000swereadecadeofreadjustment,withincipient market principles making more headway in Eurasian cities and with local institutions becoming stronger and more self-reliant. The future shouldseeEurasiancitiescontinuallystraddlingafinebalance between markets and institutionsa balance key to their sustainable development. Thisbookdiscussesallfiveoftheseissuesrethinking,planning, connecting, greening, and financingin more detail. It seeks to analyze thekeychallengescreatedbycentralplanning,outlinehowthese challenges were addressed in the transition years, and identify some steps Eurasian cities should take to chart a sustainable development path for themselves. The book also shows how some of the most pro-gressive cities in the region have been tackling these problems and, in doing so, shedding the last vestiges of the socialist economy.Philippe Le HourouIndermit GillVice PresidentChief EconomistEurope and Central AsiaEurope and Central AsiaAbout the AuthorsSouleymane Coulibaly is the lead author of this book. He is currently theWorldBankSeniorCountryEconomistforArmeniaandthe EuropeandCentralAsiaregionaltradecoordinator.Hewasoneof the principal authors of the World Development Report 2009: Reshaping EconomicGeography.Hispublicationsandongoingresearchfocuson the impact of geography on firms location, trade flows, and regional integration. Prior to joining the World Bank, he was a lecturer at the Ecole Nationale Superieure de Statistiques et dEconomie Applique (ENSEA)ofAbidjan,ateachingassistantattheUniversityofLaus-anne, and an economist at the Economic and International Relations department of NESTLE in Vevey, Switzerland. He holds a dual Ph.D. degreeinInternationalTradeandEconomicGeographyfromthe UniversityofParis1Pantheon-SorbonneandtheUniversityof Lausanne. UweDeichmannisaresearcherintheEnvironmentandEnergy Team of the World Banks Development Research Group, where he worksprimarilyonspatialeconomicandenvironmentalissues.He was one of the principal authors of the World Development Report 2009: ReshapingEconomicGeography.PriortojoiningtheWorldBank,he worked for the UN (United Nations) Environment Program and the xviixviiiAbout the AuthorsUN StatisticsDivision. He holds a Ph.D. in Economic Geography and RegionalScience from the University of California.William R. Dillinger has a B.A. from the University of California at BerkeleyandamastersdegreefromHarvardUniversity.Hejoined the World Bank in 1978 and has devoted most of his career to public finance,regionaldevelopment,andhumanresourcemanagement issues. He has worked in 35 developing and transitional countries in allsixoftheWorldBankregions.Hisrecentpublicationsinclude Poverty and Regional Development in Eastern Europe and Central Asia (World Bank Working Paper 118, 2007) and Intergovernmen-talFiscalRelationsintheNewEUMemberStates:Consolidating Reforms (World Bank Working Paper 111, 2007).MarcelIonescu-HeroiujoinedtheWorldBankinApril2008,and since then has worked on a range of issues, such as brownfields rede-velopment, cultural heritage development, solid waste management, energyefficiencyincities,one-companytowns,interjurisdictional spillovers,andmoregeneralurbanplanningandurbaneconomics areas. Prior to joining the Bank, he was a project manager for a small software company in Cluj-Napoca (Romania) and was lead editor for the WorldmarkEncyclopediaofNations. He also worked as a teaching assistantandlectureratCornellUniversity.HehasaPh.D.in Regional and Urban Development from Cornell University.Ioannis N. Kessides is a Lead Economist in the World Banks Devel-opment Research Group.His areas of specialization are competition, regulatory,andprivatizationpoliciesinnetworkutilities;market structure and firm conduct; determinants of entry and exit; and con-testabilityanalysis.PriortojoiningtheWorldBankin1990,he taughtattheUniversityofMarylandandwasaneconomistinthe LineofBusinessProgramoftheU.S.FederalTradeCommission. MorerecentlyhetaughtatPrincetonUniversity.HereceivedB.S. andM.A.degreesinPhysicsandPlasmaPhysicsfromCaltechand Princeton, and a Ph.D. in Economics from Princeton.Charles Kunaka is a Senior Trade Specialist in the International Trade DepartmentoftheWorldBank.Heworksontradefacilitationand logisticswithaparticularfocusontradeandtransportfacilitation projects and trade corridor diagnostics. He has published on logistics for small-scale producers in lagging regions and on the regulation of international road freight transport services. He has a Ph.D. in Trans-portEconomicsandPolicyfromUniversityCollegeLondon.Before joiningtheInternationalTradeDepartment,hewaswiththeSub-SaharanAfricaTransportPolicyProgramintheAfricaRegion,and About the Authorsxixprior to that, he was a senior officer with the Southern African Devel-opment Community.Daniel Saslavsky joined the World Bank in 2009 to work as a trade facilitationandlogisticsconsultantfortheInternationalTrade Department. Prior to this post, he was Deputy Director of the Inter-nationalTradeProgramoftheCenterforImplementationofPublic Policies for Growth (CIPPEC), the leading public policy think tank in Argentina. He has also worked for the Inter-American Development Bank and other multilateral institutions. He completed his graduate studies in International Affairs at SAIS-Johns Hopkins University and Universidad Torcuato Di Tella. His main areas of expertise are trade facilitation and logistics.AcknowledgmentsThis book was prepared by a core team led by SouleymaneCoulibaly andincludingUweDeichmann,WilliamDillinger,MarcelIonescu-Heroiu,IoannisKessides,CharlesKunaka,andDanielSaslavsky. AustinKilroypreparedthespotlights,chaptersummaries,andkey issues.ChorchingGohandChristineKessidesco-ledtheteamthat started this study, with support from Igor Burakovsky (Institute for EconomicResearchandPolicyConsulting,Kiev),MikhailDmitriev (Center of Strategic Research, Moscow), Vladimir Dubrovskiy (Cen-terforSocialandEconomicResearch,Kiev), VernonHenderson (BrownUniversity),ObidKhakimov(WestminsterInternational University,Tashkent),LeonidLimonov(LeontiefCenter,St.Peters-burg), Aleksander Puzanov (Institute of Urban Economics, Moscow), and Joseph Salukvadze (Tbilisi State University). Otto Simonett, Vik-torNovikov,andZurabJincharadzefromZoinet provideduseful comments and produced most of the maps included in the book.The book benefited from thoughtful comments by peer reviewers EllenHamilton,SomikLall,andYanZhang,aswellasfromElena Karaban, Andrew Kircher, Larisa Leshchenko, and Tamar Sulukhia. ElenaKantarovichandRhodoraMendozaPaynorprovidedtimely support to the team. Asad Alam, Pedro Alba, Ivailo Izvorski, Stephen Karam,MotooKonishi,LaszloLovei,MartinRaiser,andYvonne Tsikata provided managerial support, guidance, and oversight. Bruce xxixxiiAcknowledgmentsRoss-Larson edited the book, and Zakia Nekaien-Nowrouz and Sarah NankyaBabiryeformattedit.TheteamespeciallythanksIndermit Gillforhistime,advice,suggestions,andideasaboutthebooks structure and contents. BackgroundnoteswerepreparedbyEvgenyVinokurovanda teamintheStrategyandResearchDepartmentoftheEurasian DevelopmentBank:JennetHojanazarova(Turkmenistan),Farhod Jurahonov(Uzbekistan),VahramAvanesyan(Armenia),Lado Vardosanidze(Georgia),VolodymyrVakhitov(Ukraine),Dymitro Lyapin (Ukraine), Victor Moroz (Moldova), Valeriu Prohnitchi (Mol-dova), Sergey Belanovsky (the Russian Federation), Denis Kadoch-nikov (Russia), Arthur Batchev (Russia), Nikita Mkrtchyan (Russia), VyacheslavBaburin(Russia),andIlyaVoznyuk(Russia).Barbara Lipman, Richard Podolske, and Irina Novikova (World Bank consul-tants) also provided useful background notes.AbbreviationsASAair service agreementsBSFOCSBlack Sea Fiber Optic Cable SystemBtuBritish thermal unitCEECentral and Eastern EuropeanCISCommonwealth of Independent StatesCOMECONCouncil for Mutual Economic AssistanceEPAEnvironmental Protection AgencyESCAPUnited Nations Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the PacificEUEuropean UnionEU15European Union-15FDIforeign direct investmentFFFSRFederal Fund for the Financial Support of RegionsGDPgross domestic productGFSGovernment Finance StatisticsIATAInternational Air Transport AssociationICAOInternational Civil Aviation OrganizationICTinformation and communications technologyKAFOSKaradeniz Fiber Optik Sistemikbpskilobits per secondMbpsmegabits per secondxxiiixxivAbbreviationsMMBtumillion British thermal unitOECDOrganisation for Economic Co-operation and DevelopmentRCCRegional Commonwealth in the field of CommunicationsSARspecial administrative regionSTMSynchronous Transport ModuleSZDSovetskie Zheleznye DorogiTAETrans-AsiaEuropeTASIMTrans-Eurasian Information SuperhighwayTIRTransit International RoutierTRACECATransport Corridor Europe-Caucasus-AsiaVATvalue-added taxWTOWorld Trade OrganizationNote: All dollar amounts are U.S. dollars unless otherwise indicated.OverviewTheWorldDevelopmentReport2009:ReshapingEconomicGeography shows that agglomeration, migration, and specialization cause cities to become the main driver of growth through the structural transfor-mation from agriculture to industry to services (World Bank 2009). This is true even in regions where the location of economic activities is a political decision engineered and imposed from the top. Consider theformerSovietUnion,excludingtheBalticcountries(Eurasia). Before the breakup of the Soviet Union, the population was increas-ing, and cities were expanding (exhibit O.1). Estimated at 280 mil-lion in 1990, the population reached 283 million in 1993. By then, theSovietUnionhaddisintegrated,inducingmovementsofpeople acrossandbeyondthenewlyestablishedborders.Thepopulation begantofallsteadilyandstabilizedatbelow277millionby2007, before climbing back to 280 million in 2011. ThesepopulationdynamicsreflecttremendouschangesinEur-asia: the breakup of the Soviet Union; the return of the market as the driving force in society; and the emergence of regional powers such as the European Union (EU), China, and India competing with the Russian Federation over its former satellites. For centuries, burgeon-ingcitiesalongtheSilkRoadtradedgoodsbetweeneastandwest, includingjewels,spices,glassware,medicines,muskandother xxvxxviOverviewEXHIBIT O.1Size Distribution of Cities in the Soviet Union, 1939, 1959, 1974, and 1989a. 1939b. 1959continuedOverviewxxviiEXHIBIT O.1ContinuedSource: Authors, based on data from Lewytzkyj (1979).c. 1974d. 1989> 1,000,000 300,0001,000,000 50,000300,000xxviiiOverview perfumes, and silk, satin, and other fine fabrics. During the Romanov Dynasty and the Soviet era, a north-south trade axis overlay Eurasia, withMoscowasthemainhub.Tofacethepostbreakupchanges, Eurasia needs to rethink its cities along the Silk Road.First,urbanizationhasregainedmomentuminEurasia,ifata slower pace than in the rest of the world. The share of the people in cities of more than 1 million rose from a plateau of 14 percent over 199094to15percentin2011,comparedwitharisefrom17to 20percent in the rest of the world. The share of Eurasians of working age fell from 65 to 64 percent over 199094 before rising to 70 per-cent in 2011fewer than half of them men. And the share of elderly rose from 9 to 12 percent over 19902007 before falling to 11 percent in 2011, with more than 90 percent of them women. These population dynamics suggest that the function and form of Eurasian cities have to change. Urban planning in a country with a shrinking urban population is not the same as that in a country with growing cities. Connecting cities in a country specializing in services is not the same as that in a country strengthening its manufacturing or agriculture. The livability of cities in an aging country implies a dif-ferentdesignfromthatinacountrystrivingtoattractyoung families. Looking ahead, policy makers need to promote changes that will make Eurasian cities the main drivers of growth. For this, they need to identify the changes to be promoted or combatedand to explore all the financing available to afford these changes. This book proposes some ideas for rethinking Eurasian cities.Eurasian Cities Are ReorganizingBased on the population share of cities with more than 1 million peo-ple in a countrys total population, Armenia, Azerbaijan, and Georgia are urbanized, and the nine remaining Eurasian countries are urban-izing (figure O.1). After the breakup of the Soviet Union, the share of the people in the capital city stabilized at 35percent in Armenia and 25 percent in Georgia, while it has consistently declined in Azerbai-jan,ifstillabovetheworldtrend.Thegrowthofurbanprimacyin Belarus, the Kyrgyz Republic, and Russia has been close to the world trend,whileKazakhstan,Tajikistan,Turkmenistan,andUkraine trended 5 to 10 percent below it.Due to agglomeration, some cities expanded while others shrank (exhibit O.2). A diverse portfolio of places is emerging in Russia and Ukraine,whiletherestofEurasiafacesasimpleconsolidationof Overviewxxixcore-periphery differences between the capital city and the rest of the country.SomeregionalhubsAlmaty,Astana,Kiev,Minsk, St. Petersburg,andTashkentarealsoemerging,whileMoscow remains the only Eurasian city with the potential to become a global city like London, New York, Paris, or Tokyo.1This spatial reorganization is driven by renewed mobility in Eur-asia. The early years of transition, with high cross-border migration after the removal of Soviet restrictions on mobility, were followed by theeruptionofcivilandtransborderconflictsamongtheregions newly emergent countries. As conflict abated and economic reform took root, economic motivations became the key driver of migratory flowsinformercommunistcountries.PeopleintherestofEurasia migrated to their capital cities and to Russia and Ukraine, while those in Russia and Ukraine migrated to Europe.Accompanyingtheselabormovementswerechangesinthe directionandcompositionoftradethatreinforcedlabormobility andagglomerationinleadingEurasiancities.Forinstance,the rapid diversification of the export products and trading partners of RussiaandUkrainefavoredtheemergenceofsecondarycitiesto FIGURE O.1Population Shares Living in Cities of 1 Million People or More,19902010percentSource: World Bank 2011.Note: Number of people living in the largest city is used for the Kyrgyz Republic, Moldova, Tajikistan, and Turkmenistan.051015202530354019901992199419961998200020022004200620082010051015202519901992199419961998200020022004200620082010ArmeniaGeorgiaAzerbaijanworldworldBelarusMoldovaRussian FederationKyrgyz RepublicUkraine TurkmenistanTajikistanKazakhstanyear yearxxxOverview complementMoscowSt.PetersburgandKievwhileexportsof therestofEurasiaremainedconcentratedontraditionalproducts and trading partners, reinforcing the largest cities role as produc-tion and transportation hubs.Eurasian Cities Need Better Planning, Better Connectivity, and Better GreeningIn the post-Soviet era, the proximity to the EU market and the deeper integrationshapedtheinternalgeographyofCentralandEastern EXHIBIT O.2Population Trends in Eurasian Cities, 19922011B l a c k S e aDnieperDanubeVolgaUralDonObObIrtyshSyr DaryaAmu DaryaYeniseiYeniseiYarkant HeIliSev. DvinaPechoraIshimTobolIndusCaspianSeaLake OnegaAral SeaLake BalkashAngaraMoscowBucharestChisinauSofiaAnkaraWarsawKievMinskVilniusTallinnRigaHelsinkiStockholmYerevanTbilissiBakuTeheranAshgabatKabulIslamabadDushanbeTashkentBishkekAstanaKaliningradLvivOdessaIstanbulIzmirBursaAntalya AdanaKonyaGaziantepDnipropetrovskDonetskRostov-on-DonKrasnodarGrozny MakhachkalaBurgasSimferopolTrabzonSamsunVanTabrizRashtTurkmenbashiMashhadGorganPeshawarSrinagarLahoreMazar-eSharifNukusBukharaHeratSamarkandFerganaOshAlmatyShymkentKashgarHotanAksuShiheziAktauAtyrauAstrakhanVolgogradSaratovSamaraAktobeKostanayPetropavlovskKaragandaSemipalatinskMurmanskTromsoUmeaArkhangelskSaint PetersburgTulaRyazanYaroslavlNizhny NovgorodKazanUlyanovskPenzaVoronezhOrenburgUfaChelyabinskYekatarinburgOmskSurgutVorkutaNovosibirskBarnaulTomskKemerovoKrasnoyarskBratskAbakanB E L A R U SF I N L A N DS W E D E NN O R W A YESTONIAUKRAINELATVIALITHUANIAPOLANDR O M A N I AMOLDOVAT U R K E YBULGARIARUSSIAGEORGIAARMENIAAZERBAIJANI R A NT U R K M E N I S T A NP A K I S T A NA F G H A N I S T A NU Z B E K I S T A NI N D I ATAJIKISTANKYRGYZSTANCHINAKAZAKHSTANRUS.MONG.250 500 750 1,000 km 0Map produced by ZO Environment Network, January 2012 Population10,000,0005,000,0002,000,0001,000,000500,000100,000Population density(inhabitants per km2)Population in urban centres Population trendincreasedecreasestagnationgrowth of informal settlements1 5 25Source: World Bank data.OverviewxxxiEuropean countries, favoring the emergence of urban centers closer to Western Europe while reinforcing economic diversification in their capitalcities.AgglomerationdynamicsinEurasiawereattenuated duetothelongdistancestoleadingworldmarkets,whichfavored the consolidation of capital cities and a few other leading cities such as Almaty, Kazan, and Yekaterinburg. This is not a handicap. Around the world, leading cities play a key role in production and exportbydeliveringarangeofservices,sustainingeconomic activities,anddrivingtheurbanizationdynamicsintherestofthe country.Leadingcitiestendtobewellconnecteddomesticallyand externallyandtoofferthemostdiversifiedproduction.Leading Eurasian cities in the former Soviet countries are no exception, and they can drive the integration of the region into world markets. But for this to happen, policy makers need to plan their cities better, con-nectthembetterinternallyandwithkeyexternalhubs,andgreen them to make them more attractive to young and talented workers. Planningcitiesbettermeanspromotingpoliciestodevelopland andhousingmarketsandimprovepublicservicedelivery.Policy makersneedtomodernizeandenforcelanduseregulationsand building codes, lower the costs of land transactions, use public infra-structuredevelopmenttoguidelanddevelopmentstrategicallyand sustainably, and build the institutional capacity to redevelop brown-fields. In housing, policy makers need to unlock rental markets, revi-talizehomeownerassociations,createandenforcerulesforusing publicspaces,andlowerthecostsofpropertytransactions,suchas buying an apartment block. For public service infrastructure, policy makers need to continually upgrade and maintain utility networks, adjusttariffstoensuresystemsustainability,encourageandenable interjurisdictionalcooperationtoprovidesuchservicesasregional sewageandwatermanagementsystems,andmaintainandextend public transit networks.Connectingcitieswithtransportandtelecommunicationsto facilitatethemovementofgoods,people,andinformationacross citiesandcountriesrequiresnewpolicies,institutions,andinfra-structure.Tofosterinterurbanconnectivity,policymakersneedto upgradethetransitsysteminlargecities,improvetheenergy efficiency of private vehicles by introducing market prices for gaso-line, introduce or adjust gasoline taxes where needed, and encourage walking and biking through the redesign of city centers. In addition to leveraging the hub function of Moscow on air and rail connectiv-ity, they need to devise and implement airline policies that increase competitioninairserviceandadoptopenskypolicieswithother strategicpartnerstosubstantiallyreducethecostoftransporting xxxiiOverviewgoodsandpeopleacrossandbeyondEurasia.Andtheyneedto reinforce the connectivity of emerging regional hubs by developing theinstitutionalframeworktosupportroadtransportandensure smooth cross-country connections. In addition, Eurasian cities need tobeanchoredinthedigitalerabyparticipatinginregionaland global information and communications technology (ICT) initiatives.Greening Eurasian cities means ensuring their sustainable devel-opment through strong markets and institutions that encourage the efficientuseofresourcesanddelivergrowth.Touseresourceseffi-ciently, policy makers need to put in place adaptation and mitigation measures.Policymakersneedtoscaleupinterventionstoaddress immediatepollutionproblems.Theyneedtopromotetheplanning ofgreenercitiesinnewdevelopmentsandbrownfieldredevelop-ments, which will help Eurasian cities in the global competition for investments and skilled labor. Indeed, cities offering a high quality of lifethroughbetterairandwaterquality,lesscongestion,more green space, and other amenitieswill be better positioned to attract skilled workers and innovative firms.Eurasian Cities Need New Financing MechanismsThesystemforfinancingcitiesandtheinfrastructureconnections amongthemhavetransformedsubstantiallysincethebreakupof the Soviet Union. On subnational finance, policy makers first need to improvethetechnicalandeconomicefficiencyofpublicutilities. Only then will it make sense to explore ways of making people who benefitfrompublicserviceinfrastructurepaybyincreasingtaxes. This could include increasing personal income tax rates in big cities; taxing agglomeration rents; improving the administration of property tax; and increasing tariffs and fees through enforcing the payment of housing maintenance fees, raising water tariffs, expanding metering, and raising public transport tariffs to at least cost-recovery levels.SeveralEurasiancountrieshavebeenencouragingmoreprivate sector investment in transport and other infrastructure investments, reflecting the global trend that started in the 1990s. But private sector investments have been limited because the financing of cross- country infrastructureisaffectedbyexternalitiesandcoordinationfailures. Depending on the public good, policy makers could consider different meansoffinancing:purelyprivate(sometelecominfrastructureis commerciallyviable);public-privatepartnershipsusing,say,tollsto partlyrecovercosts;richerorleadingcountriessubsidiesofinfra-structure for poorer countries if this reinforces network externalities Overviewxxxiiiin their own country; contributions from a reputable regional devel-opment bank, leveraged with funds raised on international markets. Planning,greening,andconnectingEurasiancitieswillrequire scaling subnational finance as well as adopting instruments to facili-tate cross-country finance and help these cities prepare for a sustain-able future (table O.1).Structure of the BookThisbookrespondstopressingquestionsforpolicymakersinEur-asiancitiesandnationalgovernments.Facedwithchangingeco-nomic circumstances and a reorientation of trade toward Europe and Asia, will Eurasias cities be able to adjust? Will some cities be granted the flexible regulations and supportive policies necessary for growth? Andwillsomebepermittedtoshrinkandtheirpeopleassistedin finding prosperity elsewhere in the region?According to the evidence in this book, some Eurasian cities and countrieshaveadjustedbetterthanothers.Economicactivityis TABLE O.1Issues That Cities Face in the Former Soviet Union and Ways ForwardPeriod Planning Connecting Greening FinancingSoviet past Master plans instead of zoning and central planners instead of urban planners; cities built around industrial areas and land misallocatedHierarchical structure oriented toward Moscow, with limited horizontal links among lower order centersCost of externalities not considered in public policies; broad access to public transport; high rates of access to water and sanitation; recycling programsSystem based on plan targets and intraparty negotiations; tariffs highly subsidizedTransitional present High ownership rates and weak rental markets, with misallocated housing stock and missing or poorly enforced city planning regulationsInstitutions established to manage connectivity infrastructure and develop sector plans, but progress moving at different pace across the region Reduced pollution as firms went bankrupt; collapse of recycling systems; deterioration of public transitMove to modern subnational finance with transparent systems of revenue sharing and equalization transfers, with some countries moving faster than othersMarket future Collaboration between local and central government to solve property issues, modernize land use regulations, and use public infrastructure development strategicallyPromotion of a few cities well connected to world markets by road, rail, air, and telecommunication links; development of regional institutions for corridor management and interstate cooperation on connectivity issuesPreservation of positive features of the former Soviet Union; enforcement of existing regulations; improvement of livability by building cities for people and taking care of the environmentIncrease in personal income tax rates; enforcement of payment of housing maintenance fees; increase in water tariffs; expanding of metering and raising of public transport tariffs; for big cities, exploration of public-private partnerships for large connectivity projectsxxxivOverviewbecomingconcentratedinspecificcities,reflectingtheeconomic advantagesthoseplacesofferandatrendtowarddecentralization and autonomy in setting regulations to exploit the advantages. But evenasEurasiancitiesdiverge,theyfacesharedchallenges.Policy makers have a key role in assisting spatial restructuring, particularly in addressing imperfect information and coordination failures. Thebookhasfivechapters:RethinkingCities;PlanningCities; Connecting Cities; Greening Cities; and Financing Cities.Rethinking Cities, an overview from a regional vantage, traces the historical origins of Eurasias urban structure, which evolved as a function of the Silk Road linking Asia and Europe, and later as a product of Soviet planning. Since the end of the Soviet Union, Eur-asias economy has been reoriented spatially toward Europe in one direction and Asia in the other. But Eurasias urban structure has not yetfullyrespondedtoreflecttheseneweconomicrealities,and national policies have tended to be preoccupied with spatial equity.Planning Cities focuses on the structural changes in Eurasian cit-ies, together with the regulatory and planning constraints they face. Special attention is given to weak rental markets, misallo-cated housing stocks, and missing or poorly enforced city planning regulations. These bottlenecks on efficient cities could be alleviated through collaboration between local and central government to resolve property issues, modernize land use regulations, and imple-ment strategic public infrastructure. Cities must be able to respond flexiblyanddynamicallytochangingeconomiccircumstances. Land use planning should protect cultural heritage buildings and provide social services and parklandbut where there is no clear reason for government intervention, decisions on land use should be left to land purchasers, without overly prescriptive zoning and attempts to second-guess what is best for a city.Connecting Cities reviews the progressive changes in Eurasias physical and ICT infrastructure, from a hierarchical structure ori-entedtowardMoscowandtoamoremultipolarstructurethat reflects the emergent economic importance of Europe and Asia in Eurasia.Ithighlightstheeconomicgainsfrombetterinterstate cooperation on transport corridor management, since borders and bottlenecks hamper trade. Cities could better connect by introduc-ing less restrictive international aviation policies, encouraging com-petition in air transport markets, and promoting ICT connectivity. Greening Cities shows how Eurasian cities have many of the ingredients for sustainable urban development: extensive public Overviewxxxvtransport systems, dense residential areas, and district power and heating systems that carry economies of scale. But recycling sys-tems have collapsed since the end of the Soviet Union, and public transithasdeterioratedamidrapidlyincreasingcarownership. Despitesomesuccesses(inreducinggreenhousegasemissions even while Eurasias economies have been growing), Eurasia is still the worlds least energy-efficient region. Quality urban environ-ments are integral to a citys economic success because they con-tribute to competitiveness and facilitate economic activity.Financing Cities surveys how Eurasia is moving toward modern subnational finance, with equalization transfers and transparent systems of revenue sharing, and notes how some countries are moving faster than others. It explores the room for local revenue enhancementthroughincreasingpersonalincometaxrates, enforcing the payment of housing maintenance fees, raising water tariffs, expanding metering, and raising public transport tariffs. It closes with an annex that looks at options to finance cross-country connectivity infrastructure.Note1. Sassen(1991)identifiesfournewwaysthatglobalcitiesfunction:as highly concentrated command points in the organization of the world economy; as key locations for finance and specialized service firms, which have replaced manufacturing as the leading economic sectors; as sites of production, including the production of innovation, in these leading sec-tors; and as markets for the products and innovations produced.ReferencesLewytzkyj,Borys.1979.TheSovietUnion:Figures-Facts-Data.Munich: K. G. Sauer.Sassen,Saskia.1991.TheGlobalCity.Princeton,NJ:PrincetonUniversity Press.World Bank. 2008. World Development Report 2009: Reshaping Economic Geogra-phy. Washington, DC: World Bank.. 2011. World Development Indicators. Washington, DC: World Bank.Chapter SummariesChapter 1Rethinking CitiesForcenturies,theSilkRoadjoinedAsiaandEuropethroughan extensive network of overland and maritime trade routes, with cities emerging at key locations. Later, during the Soviet era, central plan-ners determined a citys location based on transport efficiency, inter-regional equity, and defensive capacity. Some cities were created to colonize empty territory. Today, this urban network does not fit Eur-asiasemergingeconomicprofile.Eurasiancitiesmustrespondto three big changes: the breakup of the Soviet Union, the return of the market as the driving force of society, and the emergence of regional powers such as the European Union, China, and India that are com-peting with the Russian Federation for markets and influence in its former satellites.Several methods of analysis indicate an imbalance across Eurasia, implying a need to readjust Eurasias urban structure. For example, Russia has fewer midsize cities than do Brazil or the United States. Its population is still scattered, even though economic activity is concen-tratedinafewregions.Comparedwithsimilarlyremoteregionsof Canada,SiberiaandtheFarEastmayhaveabout18milliontoo xxxviixxxviiiChapter Summariesmanypeople.Between1989and2004,almostallnewfirmschose tolocate near Moscow and St. Petersburg. Policy makers may need to helpRussiaspopulationtomovetoeconomicdensityasfirmsare doing.NationalpoliciesinEurasiaarestillpreoccupiedwithspatial equity. But the concentration of economic activity in large cities is fun-damentaltonationalcompetitiveadvantage:theyfosterinnovation throughtheirdiversityofindustriesandreduceproductioncosts through their economies of scale.Chapter 2Planning CitiesFollowingthedemiseofcommunismintheearly1990s,many countries reversed course, adapting systems in which the market reignedsupremeandplanningplayedlittleornorole.With almost complete laissez-faire approaches, dwindling budgets, and minimalexperienceofdecentralizedcitymanagement,many Eurasianurbancentersstruggledduringthetransitiontoamar-ket economy.Goodplanningispartofthebasictoolkitofpublicinterventions forenhancingmarketefficiencies(businesscompetition,accessto information)whilemitigatingmarketinefficiencies(pollution,con-gestion).Thisdoesnotmeanchoosingoneurbandesignthatopti-mizes a city foreverimpossible, since the configuration of economic activitywillchangeovertime.Ratheritmeansputtingregulations andinstitutionsinplacethatallowacitytorespondflexiblyand dynamically to economic circumstances. Land pricing and land regu-lationsareimportantcomponentsofthissystem.Landpricing ensures that not all people and businesses locate in just one city, since people must pay more to be in the most successful cities. Individuals and firms that do not need to be there will locate elsewhere. Within a city,thesamerationaleapplies.Landshouldbepermittedtobe tradedfreelyandtransparentlytorespondtochangingcircum-stances. Property rights should be guaranteed. And transaction costs in land markets (say, the cost of finding the owner of a parcel of land) should be reduced.Eurasiancitiesareundergoingprofoundchanges:population densities in Moscows central city are rising, while densities at its peripheryarefalling.Butmanycitiesstilllackresponsivenessto Chapter Summariesxxxixnewcircumstances.Somecitieshaveanacuteshortageofrental housing,leadingtodisproportionatelyhighrents.Anapartment inAlmaty,Kiev,Moscow,orSt.Petersburgismoreexpensive thanasimilarapartmentinAmsterdam;Berlin;Stockholm;or Washington, DC. Bishkek and Dushanbe have housing shortages measuredinhundredsofthousandsofunits.Eurasiancitiesare still underserved for retail spacein 2007, the Russian Federation had 39 square meters of gross leasable shopping center space per 1,000 inhabitants, and Ukraine had 19, compared with 448 in the Netherlands,408inSweden,266intheUnitedKingdom,and 245 in France. Policy makers must be willing to facilitate adjustments using land and property regulations. This is already happening in some placesofthe10RussiancitiessampledbytheWorldBankssubnational DoingBusinessIndicators,Kazanisfarmorecompetitivethan Moscow, thanks to reforms to its construction and property regula-tions. But Armenia, Georgia, and the Kyrgyz Republic beat even Rus-sias most progressive cities: obtaining a construction permit in these countriesrequires1020procedures,comparedwithmorethan 20 in Kazan. Indeed, Georgia ranks first in the world in the ease of registeringproperty,andfourthintheeaseofdealingwithcon-structionpermits.ButMoldova,Russia,Tajikistan,Ukraine,and Uzbekistan have some way to go to meet these high standards. For example, St. Petersburgs land use regulations include 54 different land use categories.Somepublicinterventionsmayberequired,too.Brownfield (formerly industrial) land is often in prime areas in central cities, but it may require public funds to catalyze its redevelopment for residen-tial or commercial uses, especially by helping to remove site contami-nation.Roadsandparkingspacesareunderprovidedandrequire public investment.Policymakersfacingtheserecommendationsmayask:Where shouldthebalanceofgovernmentinterventionlie?Andwhen should city planners intervene and when should they let land mar-ketsdecide?Goodplanninghelpsensurethatsociallyvaluedout-comes take place and that individuals pursuit of well-being does not undulyaffectthewell-beingofothers.Landuseplanningshould seek to protect cultural heritage buildings and provide social services andparklandbutwheregovernmentinterventionlacksaclear rationale,decisionsonlanduseshouldbelefttolandpurchasers, withoutoverlyprescriptivezoningandattemptstosecond-guess what is best for a city. xlChapter SummariesChapter 3Connecting CitiesPotential trade between the former Soviet Union and the European Union has been estimated at more than four times higher than the actualvolumeoftradebetweenthetworegionsatthetimeofthe SovietUnionscollapse.TradewithAsia,whichhasbeengrowing over the past two decades, also has a large potential. Inrecognitionofthispotential,therehavebeenconsiderable effortstodefineanddevelopanetworkoflandtraderoutesacross Eurasia,includingthroughregionalagreementsandthroughpro-gramsanddevelopmentprojectsliketheCentralAsiaRegional EconomicCooperationcorridors,theTransportCorridorEurope-Caucasus-Asia (TRACECA), and the Eurasian Economic Community. New roads, railways, ports, and other transport are being built along suchcorridors.Overall,morethan40traderouteinitiativeslink more than 130 major cities across Eurasia.But the sheer number of initiatives means there has been some duplication and waste; more important, there have been problems, suchasborderdelays,anonerousbureaucracy,andinformalpay-ments, in harnessing these initiatives. Transit fees should be harmo-nized, taking into account the interests of both the transit country and the landlocked country, along the lines of work ongoing under TRACECA.Borderproceduresforroadandrailshouldbeharmo-nized across the former Soviet Union, and the Transit International Routier (TIR) Convention should be adhered to, including abolish-ingcustomsescortsfornormal,nonsuspiciouscargo.Another impetusfortheseimprovementswouldbeifparticipantcountries were to systematically monitor and assess the performance of trans-port corridors.Commercialairnetworkshavealsochangedconsiderablysince the Soviet era. Bottoming out a few years after the breakup of the Soviet Union, air traffic rebounded impressively in the past 10 years. Eurasiancapitalcitiesandotherregionalcenters(especiallyMos-cow) have expanded the number of available nonstop destinations, whilesmallercitieshavebecomelessconnectedandincreasingly reliant on connecting flights through hubs (most notably Moscow). Even so, connectivity varies greatly among Eurasian cities, depend-ing onamong othersthe extent of liberalization and competition in air transport markets. In general, the sustainability and accessibil-itytoairservicescouldbenefitfromimprovingregulationsand strengtheningthecapacityofinstitutionsgoverningthissector. Chapter SummariesxliIncreased knowledge can enhance the role of Eurasian cities in the global urban system.A complete understanding of connectivity should also include information and communications technology (ICT) infrastructure and links. Several recent studies suggest that the economic impacts of broadband are substantial and robust, improving an economys globalintegrationandcompetitiveness.Indeed,a10percentage point increase in broadband household penetration has been asso-ciatedwitha1.3percentagepointincreaseineconomicgrowth. BroadbandpenetrationremainsfairlylowinEurasia(around aquarterorlessoftheratesintheUnitedStatesorEurope). Improving this situation will require new investment and regional cooperationas with the Trans-AsiaEurope fiber-optic cable sys-temandtheBlackSeaFiberOpticCableSystem.Additional improvementscouldincludeconstructingparallelemergency lines,aprerequisiteforsuccessfulcompetitionininternational data transit markets.Eurasia has thus seen a reorientation of land transport links and emphasized concentration of air transport links on the old center of Moscow and a few other large cities. ICT connectivity is more flexi-ble, and Eurasian cities and countries have several evolving options for regional and global connectivity.Chapter 4Greening CitiesThe core challenge for city administrators is to enhance and encour-age the positive aspects of urban development (for example, the con-nectionsbetweenrelatedindustries),whilemitigatingthenegative sideeffects(suchaspollutionandcongestion).Thischapterfocuses onpoliciestomitigatethesenegativesideeffects.Suchpolicies include direct interventions, such as enforcing pollution regulations, buttheyalsoinvolvelongertermgoals,suchasdevelopingurban areas around transportation hubs to increase the efficiency of a citys public transport network and thus reduce peoples incentives to travel by car and create congestion.The first section of this chapter argues that the Soviet Union failed to tackle environmental challenges adequately because, despite hav-ingstronggovernmentinstitutions,ithadnomarketsignalsto ensure that resources were used efficiently and no nonstate institu-tions to promote environmental causes.xliiChapter SummariesThesecondsectionreviewstheenvironmentalperformanceof cities in the former Soviet Union during the transition. It argues that thefirsthalfofthetransitionfrom1991tothelate1990swas plaguedbyweakstateandnonstateinstitutions,andbyalackof well-functioning,formalmarkets.Thetransitionprovidedsome environmental dividends, as the most inefficient industries went out ofbusiness,butitalsoledtothewidespreaddisintegrationofthe infrastructureforenvironmentalmanagement.Thesecondhalfof the transition (until 2010) saw markets for goods and services emerge andinitialinstitutionalsupportforenvironmentalpoliciesdevelop. With diverging growth paths of countries in the former Soviet Union came growing differences in the managerial and financial capacities of cities. The third section discusses why cities in the former Soviet Union shouldimproveenvironmentalmanagementandhow.Itargues that,forthesecitiestodevelopsustainably,theyneedbothstrong marketsthatdelivergrowthandencourageresourceefficiencyand strong institutions that ensure inclusive and sustainable growth. Eurasiancitieshaveinheritedanumberofproblemsfromthe Soviet erabut also a number of benefits:Industrial concentration in some cities generated pollution on an unprecedentedscale.TheRussiancityofNorilsk,forexample, emitted more sulfur dioxide in 1989 than all of Italy. But this same industrial concentration may make it easier to mitigate pollution, and countries in the former Soviet Union have been among a select group that have reduced their greenhouse gas emissions in the 1990s and 2000s while increasing economic growth.District heating plants were built with poorly insulated, low-quality piping, leading to losses of heat and water. Heat is not always deliv-ered when neededsuch as on cold autumn daysand residents cannot adjust the temperature to their needs, leading to phenom-ena like Siberian housing blocks with their windows flung wide open in winter. But if these problems can be fixed, these plants are potentially a cost-effective and environmentally friendly way of delivering heatas shown by their adoption in forward-looking cities, like Copenhagen and Stockholm.Public transport networks in Eurasian cities are extensive but have been allowed to deteriorate in recent years. Since 1993, car owner-ship rates have tripled in Belarus and Russia; have more than dou-bled in Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, and Moldova; and have almost doubled in Turkmenistan and Ukraine. Traffic gridlocks, already a Chapter Summariesxliiidaily happening in Moscow, are considered one of the citys most pressing problems.Residential housing was similarly designed, with thin walls and large windows, regardless of local climate conditionsin Ashgabat in the Central Asian desert or in Norilsk above the Arctic Circle.RecyclingnetworksinmostcitiesintheformerSovietUnion disappeared during the 1990s. The networks had no funding, no adequatepricing,andnoinstitutionaloversightorproper management.Creative,cost-efficientsolutionsincludechargingpeoplewho drivecarsinthecityforcongestion,reservingparkingspacesfor environmentallyfriendlycars,upgradingdistrictheatingnetworks, and providing public information on the benefits of housing insula-tion.Thischapterreviewsanumberoftheseproblemsandtheir potential solutions.Chapter 5Financing CitiesSubnational governments in the former Soviet Union are respon-sibleforawiderangeofurbaninfrastructureservices,suchas constructing and maintaining streets and operating the water sup-ply, sewerage, district heating, and public transport systems. These servicesarefinancedinlargepartthroughcentralgovernment transfers.Overthepast20years,suchtransfershavebecome increasingly transparent, objective, and predictable. Even so, cities find themselves unable to raise additional revenues from the most appropriatesource:theconsumersofurbanservicesthemselves. This chapter reviews the subnational financing in several Eurasian countriesanddiscussesthemeritsofalternativesourcesoftax revenuesandurbanservicecharges.Thischaptercloseswithan annex that looks at options to finance cross-country connectivity infrastructure.1CHAPTER 1Rethinking CitiesSpotlightRethinking Kramatorsk, UkraineLikemanyEurasiancities,KramatorskinUkrainehaslost manyinhabitantsinthepasttwodecades.Itspopulation shrank 15 percent between 1989 and 2010, from 198,000 to 167,850.Itsmainemployeraheavymachineryplantwas one of the largest in the Soviet Union, but its workforce has diminished from 40,000 to 14,000.HowisKramatorskrespondingtochangedcircum-stances?First,itiscapitalizingonitslocation:itisabout 1.5 hours from the regional capital, Donetsk, and not too far fromtheoftheRussianFederationborder.Kramatorsks heavy machinery plant exports 40 percent of its production totheEuropeanUnion,Japan,Brazil,andelsewhere.Sec-ond, the city is modernizing its infrastructure. The machinery planthasmadeitsproductionlinemorecompetitive,and the city is upgrading its urban infrastructure, such as district heatingnetworks,thoughexpensivefinancingishindering this process greatly. Third, Kramatorsk is reorienting its eco-nomicprofile.Somejobslostfrommanufacturinghave 2Eurasian Cities: New Realities along the Silk RoadFor centuries the Silk Road connected the Far East, the Middle East, andEuropethroughanextensivenetworkofoverlandandmari-time trade routes. Transport costs were high, but long-distance trade was an integrating dynamic in developing the great civilizations of Arabia,China,Egypt,India,Persia,andRome.Goods,transported on an east-west axis, included jewels; glassware; spices; medicines; muskandotherperfumes;andsilk,satin,andotherfinefabrics, which,becauseofhightransportcosts,wereluxuries.Inmodern times,tradeintheformerSovietUnionwasmainlyonanorth-south axis, with Moscow serving as the main hub.Through most of the 20th century, Soviet planning controlled the economies of many nations once located along the Silk Road. Since the fall of the Soviet Union, transport costs have fallen. The transport networkforthe21stcenturyaimstocarrymorediversetradein goods, services, capital, labor, and ideas and information. It encom-passesair,rail,androadtransportationandtelecommunications. WhenanewSilkRoademerges,itwillhavetobebiaxial,in been taken up by an emergent jewelry industry, which now produces about 10 percent of Ukraines jewelry output and aims to reach 20 percent. The industry began with a family businessrepairingearringsandnecklaces,whichthen evolvedintoaworkshoptocraftthemfromrawmaterials. Now,ithaslargeofficebuildingswithjewelryexhibition rooms, and the industry continues to grow.Key IssuesEurasian cities evolved as a function of the Silk Road linking Asia and Europe, and later as a product of Soviet planning.Since the end of the Soviet Union, Eurasias economy has been reoriented spatially toward its edgesEurope in one direction and Asia in the other.Policy makers need to accept the growth of some cities and the shrinkage of others. Remote regions of Siberia and the Far East may now have about 18 million too many people.Rethinking Cities3responsetoopportunitiespresentedbythethreemostimportant development stories in the past several decades:The fall of the Soviet Union. The failure of the Soviet economic model opened the former Soviet Union to market-oriented reforms that stimulated growth and integrated the region into the global econ-omy. Within the region, production and intraregional trade can expand in line with comparative advantage.The rise of the European Union (EU). Western Europe has risen in prominence, purchasing power, and ease of access. Further, the EU has adopted an explicit policy to deepen its economic ties with Eastern European countries through the European Neighborhood policy.The rise of Asia. China, Japan, and the Republic of Korea have been the most dynamic growth stories of the past 50 years. They will offer new trade opportunities as they continue to integrate withtheworldeconomy.Indiajoinedthemtwodecadesago andisalsoreapingthegrowthbenefitsofreformsandnew investments.This book focuses on the former Soviet Union (Eurasia), exclud-ing the Baltic countries, and addresses two questions: How is the spa-tialstructureofeconomicactivitybeingreorganizedinthefaceof these changes? How will Eurasias economic landscape evolve as its citiesarereshapedbymigrationandtradewiththeEUandAsia (exhibit1.1)?Thesequestionsarefundamental,sincecitiesare engines of growth. Policy makers can influence the economic land-scape over the next 20 years if they carefully rethink the form, func-tion, and connectivity of cities. The book provides a framework for rethinking Eurasian cities in a way that supplements todays main economic centersMoscow and St. Petersburgwith other vibrant cities along a 21st-century SilkRoad.ItlooksathowEurasiancitiescandiversifybypro-moting trade, mobility, and scale economies. As a country moves fromlowtomediumtohighincome,itundergoesastructural transformation from agriculture to industry to services. Traditional agriculture tends to be replaced slowly as agriculture-related activ-ities emerge in response to more demand from urban areas within and outside the country (World Bank 2007a). In these activitiessuchasstoring,sorting,conditioning,packaging,transporting, processing,distributing,andriskmanagementservicesinternal and external economies of scale drive productivity and the ability to export. 4Eurasian Cities: New Realities along the Silk RoadEXHIBIT 1.1Population Trends in Eurasian Cities, 19922011Source: World Bank data. Note: Km2 = square kilometer.B l a c k S e aDnieperDanubeVolgaUralDonObObIrtyshSyr DaryaAmu DaryaYeniseiYeniseiYarkant HeIliSev. DvinaPechoraIshimTobolIndusCaspianSeaLake OnegaAral SeaLake BalkashAngaraMoscowBucharestChisinauSofiaAnkaraWarsawKievMinskVilniusTallinnRigaHelsinkiStockholmYerevanTbilissiBakuTeheranAshgabatKabulIslamabadDushanbeTashkentBishkekAstanaKaliningradLvivOdessaIstanbulIzmirBursaAntalya AdanaKonyaGaziantepDnipropetrovskDonetskRostov-on-DonKrasnodarGrozny MakhachkalaBurgasSimferopolTrabzonSamsunVanTabrizRashtTurkmenbashiMashhadGorganPeshawarSrinagarLahoreMazar-eSharifNukusBukharaHeratSamarkandFerganaOshAlmatyShymkentKashgarHotanAksuShiheziAktauAtyrauAstrakhanVolgogradSaratovSamaraAktobeKostanayPetropavlovskKaragandaSemipalatinskMurmanskTromsoUmeaArkhangelskSaint PetersburgTulaRyazanYaroslavlNizhny NovgorodKazanUlyanovskPenzaVoronezhOrenburgUfaChelyabinskYekatarinburgOmskSurgutVorkutaNovosibirskBarnaulTomskKemerovoKrasnoyarskBratskAbakanB E L A R U SF I N L A N DS W E D E NN O R W A YESTONIAUKRAINELATVIALITHUANIAPOLANDR O M A N I AMOLDOVAT U R K E YBULGARIARUSSIAGEORGIAARMENIAAZERBAIJANI R A NT U R K M E N I S T A NP A K I S T A NA F G H A N I S T A NU Z B E K I S T A NI N D I ATAJIKISTANKYRGYZSTANCHINAKAZAKHSTANRUS.MONG.250 500 750 1,000 km 0Map produced by ZO Environment Network, January 2012 Population10,000,0005,000,0002,000,0001,000,000500,000100,000Population density(inhabitants per km2)Population in urban centres Population trendincreasedecreasestagnationgrowth of informal settlements1 5 25Urbanization results from the spatial transformations accompany-ingthisprocess(WorldBank2008).Enablingcitiestosupportthis processischallenging,becausecitieshaveinertiabuiltinbytheir inheritedgeographyandinfrastructure.Mobilityshouldincrease urbanization, and a more urbanized region will be a more integrated region, trading domestically and externally. As this structural trans-formation occurs, cities tend to play an increasing role in production and trade. Agriculture modernizes and requires fewer workers, free-ingthesurpluslabortomigratetocitiesandparticipateinthe advanced division of labor that is the essence of any city. Cities allow thesharingofprivateandpublicproductionfactors,thepoolingof labor markets, and the sharing of information. Rethinking Cities5Thisprocesshasacumulativeeffect,makingsomecitiesglobal players that shape the world economy. Global cities function in four new ways (Sassen 1991): As highly concentrated command points in the organization of the world economyAs key locations for finance and specialized service firms, which have replaced manufacturing as the leading economic sectorsAs sites of production, including the production of innovation, in these leading industriesAs markets for the products and innovations.Althoughnotallcitiescanbecomeglobalcities,thediversityof Eurasian cities suggests that some may become lively nodes of a more integrated region in a globalized world. Thischapterexaminesthreekeyperiods:theSovietpast,the transitional present, and the market future. During the Soviet era, the location and size of cities were centrally planned in Moscow to fulfill the objectives of successive five-year plans. During the transi-tion,marketforceswithinformerSovietrepublicsreinforcedthe role of cities as drivers of productivity and diversification within the newly established independent countries. While continuing to pro-motethisinternaldynamic,policymakersnowneedtoconnect thesecitiesthroughregionalandglobalintegrationpoliciesto strengthenmarketforcesandcompletethetransformationof EurasiancitiessustainedbyanewbiaxialSilkRoad(north-south and east-west).The Effect of the Breakup of an Empire on the Regions CitiesCities have always been the driving forces of world civilizations. Nini-veh was at the heart of the Assyrian civilization, and Babylon was the symbol of the Babylonian civilization. When Peter the Great, third in the Romanov Dynasty, became Russias ruler in 1696, the influence of Moscow began to expand. Peter strengthened the rule of the tsar and westernized Russia while at the same time making it a power in Europe and greatly expanding its borders. By 1918, the year that saw the end of the Romanov Dynasty, the Russian empire covered a vast territory from Western Europe to China. AsPetertheGreatandhissuccessorsstrovetoconsolidatetheir reign over this empire, major social, economic, cultural, and political changes were in the making in the urban centers. Moscow led these changes, followed by St. Petersburg, which was built as a gateway to 6Eurasian Cities: New Realities along the Silk Roadfilter and channel western civilization through the empire. By foster-ingdiversificationthroughconnectivity,specialization,andscale economies,thesecitiesstartedthestructuraltransformationofthe Russianempireawayfromdependingoncommoditiesandlimited markets in a way that more effectively served local demand (World Bank 2008). Some of its city-based activities, such as literature and art, became prominent, with the production of such literary master-piecesasCrimeandPunishmentandWarandPeaceandthepainting Ivan the Terrible and the Death of his Son by Ilya Repin. The Soviet era altered this dynamic. Framework of Spatial Location during the Soviet EraAlthoughmarketforceswereinherentlypresentduringtheSoviet era,thestateapparatusalteredthemthrougheachfive-yearplan (known as Gosplan), with the ownership structure biased toward an almighty state. Three forms of ownership operated (table 1.1): Public ownership was vested in the government.Cooperativeownershipwasvestedincooperativeassociations, whose members were either workers engaged in or consumers patronizing the organization.Private ownership was also present.In the early days of the Soviet Union, private producers contributed nearly 20 percent of total production, mainly reflecting farmers con-tributiontotheeconomy.Theownershipofland,includingmineral deposits and forest reserves, became vested exclusively in the govern-ment,whileindividualfarmersbecameinconsequentialwhenthe governmentdecidedtocollectivizewholesaleactivitiesinJanuary 1930. This shift became irreversible as the five-year plans became the major policy-making tool of the Soviet Union by 1957 (Bergson 1964).TABLE 1.1Industrial Production in the Former Soviet Union, by Ownership Type, 1928, 1937, 1950, and 1960percentage of total industrial productionOwnership type 1928 1937 1950 1960Public 69.4 90.3 91.8 97.0Cooperative 13.0 9.5 8.2 3.0Private 17.6 0.2 0 0Source: Bergson 1964.Rethinking Cities7Production was also organized spatially to consolidate the Soviet Union.Theunderlyingdriverofthisspatialorganizationwasthe attempttoaddressthemismatchoffactorsofproductioninthe SovietUnion,inwhichrawmaterialwealthwasmostplentifulin Siberia, natural population growth was highest in Central Asia, and industrialplantandskilledlaborweremostabundantinEuropean Russia. Schiffer (1989) describes Soviet decisions on spatial resource allocation as based on efficiency, equity, and geopolitics.The efficiency factor suggested that production should be close to raw material and energy sources, that production of manufacturing goods and services (intermediate and final) should be close to urban centers, and that economic regions and administrative units should specialize in producing goods in which they had a competitive advan-tage, while ensuring that local demand for basic consumer goods was satisfiedlocally.Theequityfactorimpliedthateconomicactivities shouldbeevenlydistributedthroughoutthecountrytomaximize labor, infrastructure, and natural resources. The goal was to equalize industrialdevelopmentacrossrepublicsandregions,providingthe population with comparable standards of living. Production was sup-posedly located in such a way as to eliminate the social and economic differences between urban and rural areas. The geopolitics factor sug-gested that the choice of location for production units had to be con-sistentwiththeneedtostrengthenthedefensivecapacitiesofthe SovietUnion.Inthemid-1960s,Sovietpolicymakersalsoadopted the notion that economic activities should no longer be concentrated in large cities. Later, territorial specialization was defined to include the entire Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECON). But no planner can ensure that a city will be a successful place to live and workonly the people who live there can do so. What is within the planners purview is to make it easier for residents and firms to choose among good alternatives, such as moving to a dif-ferentcityorbuildingstrongrootslocally.Goodplanninghelps ensurethatcertainsociallyvaluedoutcomestakeplaceandthat individuals pursuit of well-being does not adversely affect the well-beingofothers.Goodplanningisafundamentaltoolofefficient localgovernanceameansofexpressingandcarryingoutpublic choices about the communitys growth and development.DuringtheSovietera,almostalldecisionsweremadecentrally, withalmostnopowersormajorresponsibilitiesdevolvedtolocal authorities. Few levers or incentives promoted efficient local gover-nance. Urban officials could not receive signals from the market, so they used planning in a directive rather than corrective manner. The physical development of cities was based not on zoning plans (which 8Eurasian Cities: New Realities along the Silk Roadwouldguidedevelopmentandindicateonlywhatwasnotaccept-able),butonmasterplansthatdictatedwhatwaspermitted.Land marketswerenonexistent(alllandwaspubliclyowned).Housing markets were weak and inflexible (governed by the Propiska city per-mits system, a residence permit and migration recording tool whose usewasdocumentedinlocalpoliceregistersanddesignedand developed by central authorities). Rental markets were mainly infor-mal.Andservicesandinfrastructureweresubsidizedheavilyand coordinated from the center, primarily to serve production processes and citizens as workers in the system. Impact of the Plan on the Structure of Soviet CitiesTheplanaffectedthespatialallocationofpeopleandactivitiesat thecountrylevel,byincentivizingpeopletoplaceswheremarkets wouldnothaveledthem,andatthecitylevel,byneglectingthe externalitiesofurbangrowth.Oneofthedefiningfeaturesofthe Soviet city was that it was built around a factory. In most cases, cities were developed as centers of production. Some cities were run by the industrial enterprises around which they were built. After World War II, Soviet planners pushed urban growth toward the colder areas, in an effort to populate the countrys vast territory (exhibit 1.2). Markets Source: Lydolph 1990.EXHIBIT 1.2Mean Surface Temperature in the Soviet Union, January 1990degree Celsius -40-40-40-36-36-32-32 -32-32-28-28-28-20-16-16-12-12-8-8-8-40-4-12-20-24-24NovosibirskNizhny NovgorodYekatarinburgSamaraOmskKazanUfaChelyabinskPermKrasnoyarskTolyattiUlyanovskIzhevskKhabarovskVladivostokIrkutskBarnaulNovokuzhnetskNaberezhnyyeChelnyOrenburgTyumenKemerovoTomskRethinking Cities9certainly would have favored the growth of already established cities. Severalsmallercitiesintheheartlandgrewtomorethan30times their original size (Hill and Gaddy 2003).Within50years,manySovietoblasts(second-tieradministrative subdivisionsintheformerSovietUnion)wentfrombeingmainly ruraltobeingatleast70percenturban(Lewytzkyj1979).Cities growth in these oblasts did not happen organically. Some people were forcibly moved to cities, but most were induced to move by various incentives.Thetransfershelpedcolonizeemptyterritory,guardthe vast empires borders, and exploit rich mineral deposits. The boom-ingcitiesinSiberiaoftenhadnoruralhinterlandandwerepoorly connectedtootherurbancenters.Foodandservicedeliverywere heavily subsidized, and many cities were completely cut off from the outside world in the harsh winter months. The pattern of city devel-opment and growth was the opposite of what the market would have dictatedmoving inward and away from density (exhibit 1.3).In a market economy, market forces dictate the size and distribu-tionofcities(WorldBank2008).Peoplegenerallyfollowjobsand other people. Quality of life issues (clement weather, good local ser-vices and infrastructure, affordable housing) also motivate people to locate in one place or another. Successful cities (those able to deliver productive employment and a good quality of life for residents) tend tobreedmoresuccessthroughcircularandcumulativecausation; unsuccessful cities endure slow or even negative growth. In success-ful cities, the concentration of people creates a large market, which will attract more businesses, more jobs, and more people.The great differentiator in this equation (what ensures that not all people and businesses end up in one city) is the price of land, which tendstoriseinsuccessfulcitiesasmorepeopleandfirmsmove there.1 As the price goes up, it tends to reach a threshold that blocks entry for some people and firms, who relocate to cities that can meet their needs at lower cost. But the falling values of land and property inlesssuccessfulcitiesdeterpotentialdeveloperswhoavoidEur-asian cities. These price signals profoundly influence both the distri-bution and the size of cities in a country. In a market-driven country liketheUnitedStates,thelargestcitiesaretradeoutpostssituated alongtheAtlanticandPacificcoastsoronmajorlakesandrivers, while the interior of the country is less populated.Although Russia has a population less than half that of the United States,ithasaboutthesamenumberofcitieswithpopulationsof 500,000 or fewer (Hill and Gaddy 2003). But it has a much smaller number of mid-size cities. Just 15.5 percent of the Russian popula-tion lives in cities of more than 1 million. By contrast, 51.9 percent of 10Eurasian Cities: New Realities along the Silk RoadEXHIBIT 1.3Size Distribution of Cities in the Soviet Union, 1939, 1959, 1974, and 1989a. 1939b. 1959continuedRethinking Cities11EXHIBIT 1.3 ContinuedSource: Authors, based on data from Lewytzkyj 1979.c. 1974d. 1989> 1,000,000 300,0001,000,000 50,000300,00012Eurasian Cities: New Realities along the Silk RoadtheU.S.populationlivesinsuchcities.ComparisonswithBrazil,a country closer in population size and development level to Russia, are also revealing. Both countries boast two large metropolises: Moscow (10.1 million people) and St. Petersburg (4.7 million) in Russia and SoPaolo(10.3million)andRiodeJaneiro(6.2million)inBrazil. But while Brazil has four cities with populations of about 2.5 million, Russia has none in this middle rangeSt. Petersburg is followed, at some distance, by cities of about 1 million people.Back to the Market: New Realities for Cities sincethe BreakupAfter 1991 many of the industrial enterprises of the Soviet era found themselves with overinflated rosters of workers. As people in indus-try started losing their jobs, many moved back to the rural areas they originallyhadcomefrom,ekingoutanexistencebysubsistence farming.Capitalcitieswerealsopreferreddestinationsforinternal migrants looking for job opportunities. But the most important flow wasacrossborders,withworkersfromCentralAsiaandtheSouth Caucasus choosing in large numbers to migrate to cities like Moscow andSt.Petersburg,andworkersfromthesecitiestryingtoreach WesternEuropeancities.Forformercommunistcountriesasa whole, the share of world value added in manufacturing decreased from 19.3 percent in 1980 to 8.9 percent in 1990 and 2.7 percent in 2001 (Teignier-Baqu 2010). Trade among them also collapsed due to thedropineconomicoutput;theerectionofbordercontrolsand tradebarriers,includingexportcontrols;andcomplicationsarising from the methods used to resolve payments as new currencies were introduced. The Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) coun-trieslosttheirpreferentialaccesstotheirformeralliesinEastern Europe, who reoriented their trade toward Western Europe. The loss of these captive markets rendered many of the low-quality manu-facturing goods produced in the former Soviet Union uncompetitive and unmarketable on world markets. The dissolution of the Soviet Union was followed by the integration of the former communist countries into the world trading system. In 1998,theEUacceptedapplicationsfrom13ofthesecountries;on May 1, 2004, 8 joined the EU (the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia,Lithuania,Poland,theSlovakRepublic,andSlovenia).Two more, Bulgaria and Romania, joined on January 1, 2007. At the same time, Russia remained the largest country in the world in area and the largestnaturalgasproducer,thesecond-most-powerfulcountryin Rethinking Cities13nuclear capabilities, and the worlds second-largest producer of crude oil. Because of its dominance, it pulled Eurasian countries back into its sphere of economic and political influence, though Georgia has been demarcating itself. These two anchors, the EU and Russia, have been driving the economic and spatial restructuring of Eurasia.In the end, the dismantling of central planning made it possible for the market to become the force driving the relocation of production and people. As the new economic geography and new trade theory suggest,thecompetitiveadvantageofleadingmarketsdepends largelyonhowefficienturbancentersare(Fujita,Krugman,and Venables2001).Givenincreasingreturnstoscaleinproduction, transportcosts,andtrade,largeurbancentersbetterconnectedto domestic,regional,andglobalmarketsenjoyaself-sustaining agglomerationofeconomicactivities,makingiteasiertodiversify and expand production and exports. New Realities of Agglomeration EconomiesThe new economic geography establishes that the internal geography ofacountryisshapedbythehomemarketeffectaccordingto whichleadingproductionlocalesaremoreproductiveandthus attract more economic activities, reinforcing the divergence between leadingandlaggingareas(Fujita,Krugman,andVenables2001). Opennesstotradereinforcesthiseffect,thoughtheimpactonthe internal geography depends greatly on where the leading market is located. For instance, integration with the United States has led to a relocation of Mexican industry away from Mexico City and toward statesalongtheU.S.borderwithgoodaccesstotheU.S.market (Hanson 1996, 1997, 1998). Further, employment has grown more in regions that have larger agglomerations of industries with buyer-supplier relationships, suggesting that integration has made demand and cost link important determinants of industrial location. ClosenesstotheEUexplainsthedifferenceintheagglomeration dynamicsobservedbetweenCentralandEasternEuropean(CEE) countriesandtheEurasiancountries.Aftertheoverthrowoftheir socialistregimesin198990,mostCEEcountriesrapidlyadopted market-based economic systems and redirected their political and eco-nomicrelationstowardtheEU.OneofthemainbenefitsoftheEU enlargement has been the boost in economic activity in both accession countries and member states. Eurasian countries, at the other end of the former communist empire, were exposed to weaker global trade flows. Russia remained the major trading partner for Central Asia, the South Caucasus, and other CIS countries, confining their exposure to 14Eurasian Cities: New Realities along the Silk Roadthe market forces of agglomeration, migration, and specialization to a Russia-centric bloc (Broadman 2005; World Bank 2008). AllcapitalsandleadingcitiesofEurasiaattractedlabor-intensive economicactivities,butcountriesclosertotheEUexperiencedthe emergenceofspecializedurbancentersalongtheborderregion. Cie slik (2004), looking at the difference in the attractiveness for for-eigndirectinvestment(FDI)ofvariousPolishregions,foundthat regionsborderingBelarus,Russia,andUkrainewerelessattractive than regions along the European Union-15 (EU15) border of Poland. And Traistaru, Nijkamp, and Longhi (2003) found similar results for the geographic concentration of manufacturing in Bulgaria, Estonia, Hungary,Romania,andSlovenia.Theyfoundthatallthingsbeing equal, industries with large economies of scale tended to locate close tolargeurbancenterswhileresearch-orientedindustrieswere attracted by regions closer to the EU15. Using regional data for 19962000,BrlhartandKoenig-Soubeyran(2006)alsofoundsimilar resultsintheiranalysisofthestructuresofwageandemployment withintheCzechRepublic,Hungary,Poland,theSlovakRepublic, and Slovenia. Entrepreneurs prefer to concentrate production when their activi-ties generate increasing returns to scale. By contrast, public policy in Eurasia is still concerned with spatial equity, even after the breakup oftheSovietUnion(WorldBank2009).Thesameconcernis expressedinKazakhstan,asreflectedinthecountrysterritorial development strategy. Most Eurasian countries have designed or are thinking about designing national strategies to facilitate the adoption andcoordinationofpoliciesforregionalandspatialdevelopment. Looking ahead, policy makers need to promote the changes that will makeEurasiancitiesthemaindriversofgrowthintheircountries. For this, they need to promote the policies that can unleash the posi-tive externalities of agglomeration economies while containing nega-tive externalities such as congestion and pollution. New Realities of MigrationTheearlyyearsoftransitionsawhighlevelsofcross-bordermigra-tion,aspopulationspreviouslyunabletomovebecauseofSoviet restrictions relocated to their ethnic or cultural homelands (Mansoor and Quillin 2006). These flows emerged simultaneously with refugee movementsresultingfromeruptingcivilandtransborderconflicts amongtheregionsnewlyemergentcountries.Asconflictsabated and economic reforms took root, economic motivations became the maindriverofmigrationinEurasia.Theresultofthesetrendshas Rethinking Cities15been a broad biaxial pattern of migration among the transition econ-omies, with one axis from the western part of the region to the EU and another from the southern to the northern countries of Eurasia. Although most migrants from the poorer Eurasian countries traveled to middle-income Eurasian countries, many also moved west, toward the EU and Turkey, seeking higher earnings. A number of Eurasian migrants spent time in CEE countries or Turkey, hoping to move to Western Europe. The collapse of the Soviet Union provoked a large-scale repatria-tion,themostmassiveofwhichwasthatofRussians(table1.2). Between 1990 and 1994, 1.7 million Russians residing in non-Slavic republics14percentofthetotalRussianpopulationinthose areasmoved to Russia. The numbers moving from areas of armed conflictsweresubstantiallyhigher:42percentofRussianresidents leftTajikistan,and37percentlefttheTrans-Caucasiancountries. TABLE 1.2Ethnic Composition of Net Migration from Eurasia (Excluding the Russian Federation) and the Baltics to the Russian Federation, 199094thousands of peopleEthnic group 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994Armenians 16.1 10.5 23.6 42.7 60.7Azerbaijanis 3.9 3.8 2.9 4.7 13.1Belarussians 19.4 0.9 10.6 5.9 10.1Estonians 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.3Georgians 2.8 3.1 0.4 6.1 12.5Kazakhstanis 2.9 6.6 10.8 6.8 1.1Kyrgyz 1.5 2.1 2.1 1.0 0.1Latvians 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.3Lithuanians 0.8 0.8 0.1 0.2 0.4Moldovans 2.1 2.0 3.0 3.2Russians 199.9 117.7 360.1 419.4 612.4Tajiks 0.4 0.6 0.5 2.9 3.9Turkmens 0.5 1.6 2.1 1.2 Ukrainians 22.0 25.9 64.3 11.0 79.2Uzbeks 3.2 4.5 2.9 0.3 3.7Others 49.3 29.0 69.7 80.8 113.4Total 288.3 104.9 355.7 553.8 914.6Source: Zaionchkovskaya 1996.Note: Net migration is the difference between the number of migrants leaving and entering the region. = not available.16Eurasian Cities: New Realities along the Silk RoadRepatriations became the norm in the former Soviet Union and were notlimitedtoRussians.Intheearly1990s,alltitularnationalities began to leave Russia for their homelands, though this pattern shifted again in 1993 and 1994.Labormigrationtothrivingcitiesisnowthemostdynamicand large-scale migration flow in Eurasia. The interstate labor migration in the region is estimated at about 6.57.0 million, with about 1.52.0millionleavingRussiaforjobsoutsideEurasia,about3million entering Russia from the other Eurasian countries, and about 2 mil-lion(notincludingRussians)migratingtootherEurasiancountries oroutsideEurasia(Teignier-Baqu2010).Nearly1of3familiesin Armenia, Azerbaijan, the Kyrgyz Republic, and Moldova and 1 of 10 inKazakhstan,Russia,andUkrainedependonmigration-related earningsandremittancesbyrelatives(Teignier-Baqu2010).In 2007,theseremittancesamountedto46percentofgrossdomestic product (GDP) in Tajikistan, 34 percent in Moldova, 19 percent in the Kyrgyz Republic, 9 percent in Armenia, and 4 percent in Azerbaijan (Canagarajah and Kholmatov 2010). MigrationdynamicsinEurasiancountriesreinforcedtheircon-nection with Russias booming regions and with a few other Eurasian leading urban centers, mainly the capital cities. In the worlds most dynamiceconomies,peoplemovetomaximizethereturnstotheir education and skills (World Bank 2008). But with their legacy of cen-trallyplannedfactory-citiesandtheirinefficientfacilities,Eurasian countriesenteredthepost-Sovieterawithaneconomicgeography that sapped growth (Kontorovich 2000). The location of human and capital resources across regions and throughout the urban hierarchy differed from the patterns in advanced market economies. The move-ment out of lagging regions has been small relative to the total Eur-asian population. The estimated surplus population of Siberia and the FarEastremainshigh,at17.6million.2Eurasiahasconsiderable scope for further internal migration to rebalance the location of eco-nomicactivityandthusincreaseeconomicgrowthandimprove social welfare. The leading urban centers of the region are the ideal candidates to attract these new workers.New Realities of Trade SpecializationTradeamongtheformerSovietrepublicsdeclinedsharplyafterthe dissolutionoftheSovietUnion,largelyreflectingthedisruptionin production that the transition to a market mechanism caused, which requiredchangesinsupplypatternsandashiftinoutputtogoods d