Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

  • Upload
    usikpa

  • View
    219

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    1/12

    26 May 2011

    Thoughts from a Renaissance manEurozone debt and the rise of DM political risk

    Charles Robertson+44 (207) [email protected]

    As we are repeatedly asked about our views on the eurozone, we have compiled what we believe are the key graphs to look at.

    Greeces public debt ratios are 33% worse than the next highest country, Italy, and appear to beunsustainable. This is not true of Portugal or Ireland, whose debt ratios, even by 2012, are on course to be below Italys, which hasmanaged a debt ratio of 120% for roughly 20 years (albeit helped out along the way by the 1992 devaluation).

    As Greece would still run a budget deficit roughly equivalent to its education budget even if it wrote off100% of its debt, then we believe no default or restructuring can occur without the permission of the EU and IMF. Or rather, Greececan of course do what it likes, but no one will fund its residual primary deficit, so very painful cuts would still be required. The EUdoes not expect Greece to achieve a primary balance in 2011-2012.

    Few trust Greece to deliver the austerity it needs to manage its debt burden, in part because previous

    governments blew up a good fiscal position even when the economy was booming. Debt restructuring, with the imposition of losseson the ECB and others, is our base case for 2013 at the latest.

    The major problem for others on the periphery of Europe is not sovereign debt but private sectordebt. The total debt burden is actually higher for Ireland, Portugal and Spain than for Greece. We struggle to see how any of thesecountries will improve living standards in the coming decade. The private sector debt boom which fuelled the good times of 1990-2008 is over, and finance, construction and retail are presumably dead in the water for years to come. Ireland might at least benefitfrom exports of goods and service (over 100% of GDP), but Portugal and Spain do not have this advantage. All face tax hikes,government spending cuts, less bank lending to fuel consumption or investment, and years of tough choices. Private sector debtdefaults will presumably be a theme for the coming years.

    Voters are already rebelling against the austerity required, with the worst government defeat in Irish historyoccurring this year and the worst election result in thirty years for the incumbent Socialist party in Spain. Meanwhile, voters innorthern Europe are rebelling against the bail-outs for peripheral Europe and seem likely to resist any significant move towards a

    federal Europe.

    The obvious economic solution is for countries to leave the eurozone.Argentinas economy returned to stronggrowth after devaluation even though exports were just 10% of GDP (similar to Greece). Unfortunately, it would probably trigger abanking collapse as depositors fled to euro accounts in Germany, and could perhaps force the imposition of capital controls.Eurozone leaders will try to resist this, but they cannot prevent voters from choosing this option.

    Therefore, it is now political risk which markets must watch, with elections in Portugal (2011), Spain(2012), Greece (2013), France (2012) and many others. European political risk might displace emerging market (EM)political risk as a major cause of market distress over the coming years.

    In the meantime, we would not be surprised by an earlier Greek debt restructuring, even as we assume theEU will do what it can to push the problem into the future, in the hope that a weaker euro, falling commodity prices, surprisinglysuccessful productivity improvements in peripheral Europe or the arrival of magical leprechauns with pots of gold will rescue the

    situation. Given the options, we believe investors are better off in EMs and future reports will concentrate on those opportunitiesinstead.

    2011 Renaissance Securities (Cyprus) Limited. All rights reserved. Regulated by the Cyprus Securities and E xchange Commission (Licence No: KEPEY 053/04).Hyperlinks to important information accessible at www.rencap.com: Disclosures andPrivacy Policy, Terms & Conditions, Disclaimer

    http://www.rencap.com/eng/legal_notice.asp#privacyhttp://www.rencap.com/eng/legal_notice.asp#privacyhttp://www.rencap.com/eng/legal_notice.asp#privacyhttp://www.rencap.com/eng/legal_notice.asp#privacy
  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    2/12

    2

    26 May 2011 Thoughts from a Renaissance man Renaissance Capital

    The debt problems in the eurozone are particularly acute for Greece. Its public debt

    in 2011 of 158% of GDP will be nearly one-third higher than Italys public debt of

    120% of GDP, and nearly double the average eurozone debt level of 88% of GDP.

    Figure 1: Public debt-to-GDP ratios in the EU, 2009-2011

    Source: Eurostat, EU Commission forecasts

    Figure 2 shows that Italy has been able to sustain a debt level of 120% of GDP

    since the early 1990s. This suggests Ireland (118% of GDP in 2012) and Portugal

    (107% of GDP in 2012) could manage a burden this large. Note that while Belgium

    survived a debt burden of 140% of GDP, this was sustainable thanks to a

    devaluation in the 1980s and only rising interest rates associated with German

    reunification delayed a quicker reduction in Belgian debt after this.

    Figure 2: Public debt as % of GDP in high debt eurozone countries 1992-2012

    Source: OECD 1992-2008, Eurostat 2009-2010, EU Commission forecasts 2011-2012

    At the sovereign level, Greece looks to be in a unique position in Europe. From a

    global perspective only Japan has a higher debt burden.

    0%

    20%

    40%

    60%

    80%

    100%

    120%

    140%

    160%

    Estonia

    Lux

    B

    ulgaria

    R

    omania

    S

    weden

    Lithuania

    Cze

    chRep

    S

    lovenia

    S

    lovakia

    Latvia

    D

    enmark

    Finland

    Poland

    Cyprus

    Neth

    erlands

    Malta

    Spain

    Austria

    H

    ungary

    G

    ermany

    UK

    UK

    France

    Eurozone

    Belgium

    P

    ortugal

    Ireland

    Italy

    Greece

    2009 2010 2011

    Italy has sustained public debt of 120% of GDPfor decades, which suggests Ireland andPortugal can manage such loads; Greece's publicdebtwill be nearly 160%of GDP in 2011

    0%

    20%

    40%

    60%

    80%

    100%

    120%

    140%

    160%

    180%

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    2001

    2002

    2003

    2004

    2005

    2006

    2007

    2008

    2009

    2010

    2011

    2012

    Belgium France Greece Ireland

    Italy Portugal Spain Eurozone

    Belgium's situation is not as encouragingfor Greece as it looks

  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    3/12

    Renaissance Capital Thoughts from a Renaissance man 26 May 2011

    3

    Figure 3: Flow and stock of public debt as % of GDP

    Source: Eurostat, national sources

    The key difference between Greece and Japan is that Japanese household savings

    of nearly 170% of GDP in cash and bonds are almost equal to the government debt

    level. This means that not only can Japan finance its own debt but it can do so at

    very low interest rates, allowing the fiscal burden to be managed (for now). In

    Greece, the relative numbers are household savings of around 85% of GDP against

    a debt level of nearly 160% of GDP. This huge gap means that Greece looks

    particularly dependent on foreigners at the sovereign level.

    Figure 4: Household savings data from 2008 (unless otherwise stated) as % of GDP and public debt in 2011as % of GDP

    Source: Eurostat

    Therefore, to get external support for a high level of government debt requires: 1) a

    high level of domestic savings, or 2) a high level of external trust that the debt

    burden is sustainable. Greece has neither.

    The key problem for Greece is not actually the debt burden itself, although it is far

    more expensive for Greece to manage than for Japan. After all, Greece was able to

    sustain interest payments of 11% of GDP annually from 1992-1996 (although

    Estonia

    -Russia

    KazakhChina

    Bulgaria

    Romania

    Ghana

    Mexico

    Ukraine

    S Africa

    Serbia

    Nigeria

    Sweden

    Czech Rep

    Kenya

    Croatia

    Slovakia

    Turkey

    Denmark

    Thailand

    Latvia

    S Korea

    Indonesia

    Finland

    Malaysia

    Poland

    Phillipines

    Spain

    Netherlands

    Brazil

    Austria

    Egypt

    Germany

    UK

    Hungary

    India

    Israel

    Portugal

    France

    Eurozone

    US

    Ireland (exc bailout)

    BelgiumItaly

    Greece

    Japan

    -12

    -10

    -8

    -6

    -4

    -2

    0

    0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200

    Budgetbalanceas%o

    fGDP,

    2010

    Public debt as % of GDP, 2010

    0%

    50%

    100%

    150%

    200%

    250%

    Portugal

    UK

    Spain

    US

    Germany

    Austria

    France2007

    Japan2007

    Greece

    Italy

    HH cash and bond savings Public debt (2011)

    Greece cannot financeits own debt

  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    4/12

    4

    26 May 2011 Thoughts from a Renaissance man Renaissance Capital

    inflation was higher then, so the real burden might not have felt so harsh), while in

    2012, the EU Commission expects Greece to only be paying 7.4% of GDP.

    Rather, the problem is that Greece might never get its budget deficit under control.

    The EU Commission believes that Greece will still be running a budget deficit of

    9.3% of GDP in 2012, so the debt burden will continue to mount. Greece needs to

    run a budget deficit of 3% of GDP and have a growing economy to stabilise the debt

    burden.

    Figure 5: Budget balance as % of GDP, 2009-2012

    Source: Eurostat 2009-2010, EU Commission forecasts 2011-2012

    How can Greece grow? In expenditure terms, government consumption is ruled out.

    In 2011, Greece will be spending 50% of GDP and it needs to cut spending, not

    increase it. Higher taxes to reduce the budget deficit are likely to hurt private

    consumption, and banks are going to be reluctant to lend. Net exports areunfortunately not going to help much either as exports account for a small share of

    Greek GDP. Meanwhile, which companies will invest heavily in this environment?

    Presumably very few. To cap it all, Greeces central bank (the ECB) is raising

    interest rates. The EU Commission expects Greece to record only marginal growth

    in 2012, after three years of GDP contraction. Argentinas record suggests three

    years of contraction is as much as a population is prepared to take before politicians

    give up.

    Figure 6: No decent growth in these countries, GDP % change YoY, 2009-2012

    Source: Eurostat 2009-10, EU Commission forecasts 2011-2012

    Why are the EU Commission and the market so pessimistic on Greece? Is it

    unrealistic to assume that Greece might push through harsh austerity?

    -16%

    -14%

    -12%

    -10%

    -8%

    -6%

    -4%

    -2%

    Eurozone

    Belgium

    Ireland

    Greece

    Spain

    France

    Italy

    Portugal

    2009 2010 2011F 2012F

    -10%

    -8%

    -6%

    -4%

    -2%

    0%

    2%

    4%

    Eurozone Belgium Ireland Greece Spain France Italy Portugal

    2009 2010 2011F 2012F

  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    5/12

    Renaissance Capital Thoughts from a Renaissance man 26 May 2011

    5

    The IMF produced a research report in 2010 (clickhereto access Default in Todays

    Advanced Economies: Unnecessary, Undesirable, and Unlikely) which showed that

    many countries with high debt burdens were able to avoid default through the 1980s

    and 1990s. What the authors failed to highlight is that nearly all these countries

    devalued their currencies significantly to achieve the growth needed to improve their

    budget picture. So, history is not an encouraging guide.

    Nor is Greek fiscal history very encouraging. Leaving aside the often-quoted

    comments that Greece has spent 100 of the past 200 years in default, we only need

    to look back at the 2000s to make a call on the Greek appetite for austerity.

    In the early 1990s, the Greek economy grew at just 1% annually, and the

    governments primary surplus, its revenues minus its expenditure excluding interest

    payments, was 1.6% of GDP.

    Attracted by what would be a 6.3% of GDP annual saving in interest payments, and

    helped by a currency devaluation in 1998, the government had political support to

    increase the primary surplus by 1.9% of GDP annually to 3.5% over 1997-2001.

    This would not have felt too painful as the growth rate trebled to 3.8% of GDP

    annually, and as banks were lending large amounts to households and corporates.Today there is no such pot of gold at the end of the austerity rainbow.

    Once Greece was in the eurozone and interest rates had fallen, the interest burden

    was down to 4.8% of GDP over 2002-2006, and despite high growth of 4.2%

    annually, the government spent so much it ran a 0.9% primary deficit. This is

    remarkable to us. Despite everything working in its favour, and despite it being given

    an extra 2.9% of GDP annually from saved interest payments, the government cut

    taxes by 2% of GDP and increased non-interest spending from 37.4% of GDP to

    40.0% of GDP. It worsened its fiscal position by 4-5% of GDP. It is little wonder that

    now, when nothing is working in Greeces favour, few believe that Greece can

    achieve a primary surplus.

    Figure 7: How Greece blew its primary surplus: GDP % change YoY and key budget data as % of GDP

    Source: EU Commission

    Greece can only afford to default with permission from the EU/IMF

    This primary deficit position is extremely important. It means that, even if Greece

    wrote off all its debt, the government still could not cover its expenditure. Last year,

    excluding interest payments its deficit was 5% of GDP even closing down all

    education (roughly 4% of GDP) would not have covered the gap. To close theforecast primary deficit of 2% of GDP in 2012 would still require half of the Greek

    education budget to be removed.

    -20%

    -15%

    -10%

    -5%

    0%

    5%

    10%

    15%

    1992-96

    1997-2001

    2002-2006

    2006

    2007

    2008

    2009

    2010

    2011

    2012

    GDP % ch Interest expenditure Primary balance Budget balance

    http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1012.pdfhttp://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1012.pdfhttp://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1012.pdfhttp://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/spn/2010/spn1012.pdf
  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    6/12

    6

    26 May 2011 Thoughts from a Renaissance man Renaissance Capital

    But even the most aggressive forecasts do not assume a total write-off of Greek

    debt, so Greece still needs to borrow considerably more than 2-3% of GDP in 2011-

    2012, and as the markets will not fund Greece, that makes it dependent on the

    eurozone and IMF. Debt restructuring can only take place with their consent.

    So, the question is when does Europe want to accept a Greek default? Media noise

    out of Germany suggests they might be prepared to accept this in 2011 under a

    different name, such as restructuring or re-profiling; but the ECB is opposed, arguing

    that restructured bonds will not be acceptable collateral for the ECB, so it would stop

    providing liquidity to Greek banks which would then go bust. It is not clear to us what

    solution the ECB sees for Greeces problems, but, in the end, we assume the ECB

    will have to change its tune as it did in 2010 when it decided to accept sub-

    investment grade debt as collateral

    We would not be surprised by a restructuring this year, and expect a default no later

    than 2013, which happens to be an election year.

    Greek default contagion to other sovereigns.

    The charts above show that Greece is a unique case. No other country matches its

    high level of public debt or the low coverage of this debt by household savings.

    Irelands fiscal mess is similar to Greeces, but its growth is better, while Portugals

    GDP performance will be nearly as weak as Greeces, but its debt-to-GDP ratio

    looks better. The EU may be prepared to deal with the consequences of Greek

    default, but we think it will not see the same justification for default by Ireland or

    Portugal.

    Of course, Greeces unique public sector debt problem did not stop Ireland and

    Portugal both having to turn to the EU and IMF for support, and Spain may follow

    later this year. A key signal of market distress is evidently the yield of Spanish debtover German bunds. But just because these countries borrow from the IMF and EU

    does not necessarily mean they will also have to restructure their public debt.

    But what about the private sector? This is where the real problem lies for peripheral

    Europe, except, surprisingly, for Greece. Private sector debt is around 200% of

    GDP in Ireland, Spain and Portugal, against 114% in Greece or 125% in Italy. Note

    that we include two data series here for internal bank lending and eurozone-wide

    bank lending to each country. We will use the former series in the subsequent charts

    as it gives us more history.

    Figure 8: Private sector (household and corporate) debt as % of GDP in 2010

    Source: IMF, CEIC

    0%

    50%

    100%

    150%

    200%

    250%

    Ireland Spain Portugal Eurozone Italy Greece France Belgium

    Internal lending to Europe-wide lending to

  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    7/12

    Renaissance Capital Thoughts from a Renaissance man 26 May 2011

    7

    If we add the private sector (internal only) and public sector debt levels together, we

    get quite a different picture.

    Figure 9: Private sector (non-bank) and government debt as % of GDP in 2010

    Source: Eurostat, IMF, CEIC

    Now it is Ireland, Portugal and Spain that look in a worse position than Greece. The

    default story is hitting Greece now because it is one single borrower that is having a

    severe refinancing problem. But the debt burden is greater for the others.

    If we do not believe that Greece can grow out of its problems, should we be more

    optimistic about the others? The short answer is no. All four of the peripheral

    countries boomed from the early 1990s on the back of a private debt explosion, from

    an unweighted average of 60% of GDP in 1992 to 102% in 2001 and 185% by 2010.The resultant rise of the financial and construction sectors, as well as the retail

    sector, is now presumably over.

    Figure 10: Private sector (household and corporate) debt as % of GDP (LHS) and GDP % changeYoY since 1992 (RHS)

    Source: IMF, CEIC, EcoWin, EU Commission

    0%

    50%

    100%

    150%

    200%

    250%

    300%

    350%

    Ireland Portugal Spain Greece Italy Eurozone France Belgium

    Private sector debt 2010 (internal) Public sector debt 2010

    -10%

    -8%

    -6%

    -4%

    -2%

    0%

    2%

    4%

    6%

    8%

    10%

    12%

    0%

    50%

    100%

    150%

    200%

    250%

    199

    2

    1992-9

    6

    1997-200

    1

    2002-200

    6

    200

    6

    200

    7

    200

    8

    200

    9

    201

    0

    201

    1

    201

    2

    Ireland - GDP % ch Spain - GDP % ch

    Portugal- GDP % ch Greece- GDP % ch

    Ireland private sector debt/GDP - end-period Spain private sector debt/GDP - end-period

    Portugal private sector debt/GDP - end-period Greece private sector debt/GDP - end-period

  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    8/12

    8

    26 May 2011 Thoughts from a Renaissance man Renaissance Capital

    We should therefore assume a long drawn-out period of many years where sluggish

    growth becomes the norm and debt burdens rise, a little like Italy in a best-case

    scenario. Wages need to fall relative to Germany, while unemployment has already

    increased, which will make existing debt harder to afford. Rising ECB interest rates

    will add to the actual cost of existing debt in Spain, most mortgages are variable.

    Governments will have to follow austerity policies. Investment will be sluggish.

    Countries like Spain, where household debt is very high, will look enviously at the

    US and UK as they inflate away their debt.

    Figure 11: Household cash and bond savings minus household debt as % of GDP

    Source: Eurostat, Japanese central bank, Federal Reserve, BIS

    Figure 12: The unemployment rate in Spain has returned to 1993-1994 levels, but without the prospect of aprivate sector debt boom to reduce it

    Source: CEIC

    As with Greece, there may be a reliance on exports to boost growth, but a strong

    euro will hamper this. Only Ireland has a particularly open economy which will

    benefit from higher external demand. We would not be surprised by increased trade

    tension with China which Beijing may try to ameliorate by buying eurozone bonds

    (including Spains).

    -20%

    0%

    20%

    40%

    60%

    80%

    100%

    120%

    140%

    Japan2008

    Italy

    China

    Greece

    Austria

    Hungary

    CzechRep

    Germany

    Indonesia

    France

    Portugal

    Poland

    US2007

    Romania

    Turkey

    Ukraine

    UK

    Spain

    Inflation should be politicallypopular in these countries

    Deflation should be politicallypopular in these countries

    The Spanish should want to inflatetheir debt away - like the US or UK

    0%

    5%

    10%

    15%

    20%

    25%

    Apr-86

    Apr-87

    Apr-88

    Apr-89

    Apr-90

    Apr-91

    Apr-92

    Apr-93

    Apr-94

    Apr-95

    Apr-96

    Apr-97

    Apr-98

    Apr-99

    Apr-00

    Apr-01

    Apr-02

    Apr-03

    Apr-04

    Apr-05

    Apr-06

    Apr-07

    Apr-08

    Apr-09

    Apr-10

  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    9/12

    Renaissance Capital Thoughts from a Renaissance man 26 May 2011

    9

    Figure 13: Exports of goods and services as % of GDP (balance of payments data)

    Source:CEIC

    The stress will show up in elections. Voters will reject incumbent governments thatare unable to deliver even modest improvements in l iving standards in the coming

    years. Ireland has already seen the previously dominant Fianna Fail suffer the worst

    election defeat of a sitting government since independence in 1921. In Spain, the

    ruling Socialist party suffered the worst defeat in 30 years at the local elections in

    May 2011, and are expected to lose the March 2012 elections. Portugals

    forthcoming elections are now expected to show a defeat of the ruling Socialist

    party, and in Greece the Socialist party is set to lose the elections due in 2013 if

    the party can even remain united until that point.

    Incoming governments will not fare well either. They too will be forced to continue

    with austerity policies, while the ECB hikes rates and perhaps the euro strengthens.

    Within five-to-ten years, voters may be rejecting both major parties in all four

    peripheral countries. In Spain, the recently established 15 May movement (15-M) is

    already doing just that. As politics gets ever tougher, peripheral Europe will be

    looking for another solution.

    Figure 14: Key poll and election figures

    Opinion poll Election results

    March 2011 Finland 2007 2011

    Marine Le Pen (National Front) 23 True Finns 4 19Nicolas Sarkozy (incumbent) 21

    Martine Aubrey (Socialist) 21 Ireland 2007 2011

    Fine Gael 27 36Fianna Fail (incumbent) 42 17

    Labour 10 19

    Portugal 2009 2011Socialist 37 ?Social Democrats 29 ?

    Spain - local elections 2007 2011

    Socialists 35 28People's Party 36 38

    Source: Wikipedia, Google

    Towards a federal Europe?

    An obvious solution is for the eurozone to offer far greater fiscal support to the

    periphery nations. We see two key obstacles to this.

    First, when the Germans agreed to sacrifice their beloved Deutschmark in the 1990s

    in return for French acceptance of reunification, Germany expected the rest of

    Europe to accept the new euro as a sort of gold standard. When Germans have

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%70%

    80%

    90%

    100%

    110%

    Ireland Portugal Spain Greece

    Exports goods Exports services Exports goods and services

  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    10/12

    10

    26 May 2011 Thoughts from a Renaissance man Renaissance Capital

    faced competitive problems, they have accepted real wage cuts relative to the rest

    of Europe to regain competitiveness. As there was no bail-out clause in the

    Maastricht Treaty, they believed the rest of Europe would also have to accept this

    model. Germany and others with a similar model find the idea of bail-outs very hard

    to stomach.

    Second, even if political leaders in Germany and other countries wanted to give

    more money to peripheral Europe, an ever-increasing number of their voters do not

    agree. The True Finns, who object to the current bailouts, saw their support surge

    from 4% in the 2007 Finnish elections to 19% in 2011. We can assume that many

    others were sympathetic to the party but were not prepared to back such untested

    politicians. In France, Marine Le Pen might make the run-offs of the French

    presidential election in 2012 (but few believe she can win), and she has gone still

    further, suggesting France should leave the eurozone so it can devalue and protect

    its industry. In Germany, the liberal Free Democrats have been reportedly

    considering a shift towards euro-scepticism in a bid to improve their standing in the

    polls. In Slovakia, there was great reluctance to even support the first package for

    Greece in 2010, which is understandable as the Slovaks are poorer than the

    Greeks.

    While peripheral European voters will increasingly vote against the austerity policies

    demanded by the north, northern European voters look increasingly likely to vote

    against policies offering more support for the south.

    Why not leave the eurozone?

    The most logical solution for those countries looking for an export boost, additional

    jobs, a budget revenue boost and a return to GDP growth is, evidently, to leave the

    eurozone. Time and time again in EMs, when excess debt was built up, devaluation

    proved to be the right (political) answer; however, many arguments were madeagainst this solution. Even in Argentina, where exports of goods were just 10% of

    GDP in 2000-2001, devaluation did work. After an 11% GDP fall in 2002, Argentina

    recorded average growth of 8.8% over 2003-2007.

    The main difficulty is that it is likely to result in the bankruptcy of the banking system.

    For anyone holding euros in Spain, it would make sense to shift those deposits to a

    German bank in Germany, so we would see a run on the banking system. The

    problem then is that European banks are so intertwined with Spanish banks, that the

    global financial system would again be threatened. Capital account restrictions could

    be imposed, but this would run counter to the European single market. Leaving the

    eurozone would be more manageable if it was just Greece alone, but would be seen

    as contagious.

    So were stuck with the current mess?

    Hence were stuck with the current mess. The most stable scenario is for Greece to

    restructure its debt, by no later than 2013, and for Europe to accept the loss this will

    entail for the ECB and other holders of Greek bonds. We should expect European

    banks to raise capital against this forthcoming loss. We should assume the Greek

    banking sector will be supported to prevent it being wiped out. Meanwhile, the

    Portuguese and Spanish private sectors will suffer the pain of eurozone membership

    for many years to come, while Ireland will hope to benefit from broader eurozone

    growth. This seems to us to be the eurozones plan.

  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    11/12

    Renaissance Capital Thoughts from a Renaissance man 26 May 2011

    11

    The most positive scenario is a weakening of the euro and falling commodity prices,

    with a rise in Iberian innovation, which would help produce better-than-expected

    growth.

    A more worrying scenario would be for Greece to leave the eurozone, which might

    be right for Greece but would then lead to speculation that others could follow, with

    destructive effects for banks around the region.

    Impact on EMs

    The current situation offers some advantages for EMs. The periodic return of risk

    aversion helps reduce EM currency and commodity appreciation pressures, and

    slows the rise in EM stock markets, helping to prevent bubbles. At the same time,

    the stark contrast between the near bankruptcy of some developed markets and the

    far better debt profiles of EMs only underline the relative attractions of EMs.

    We, of course, have to fear the worst-case scenario of eurozone defaults spreading

    to Spain, or multiple breakaways from the eurozone coinciding with banking

    collapses in peripheral Europe. But unlike a typical EM crisis of the 1990s, it is hard

    to see how markets can force this to happen now they have been removed from the

    financing equation by the EU and IMF in Greece, Portugal and Ireland, which means

    we will have to watch the political calendar in Europe.

    Enough political shocks in peripheral Europe might result in unilateral withdrawal

    from the euro. Political risk in Europe may therefore displace EM political risk as the

    main threat to market stability over the coming years.

    Figure 15: Key economic data, 2010

    Ireland Portugal Spain Greece

    GDP (EURbn) 154 173 1,063 230

    Goods (EURbn) 84 37 191 16as % of GDP 54 21 18 7

    Services (EURbn) 73 18 94 28as % of GDP 48 10 9 12

    Exp GS as % of GDP 102 32 27 19

    Debt as % of GDP 96.2 93 60.1 142.8Debt (EURbn) 148 160 639 329Budget balance as % of GDP -32.2* -9.1 -9.2 -10.5Budget balance (EURbn) -50* -16 -98 -24Outstanding value of bonds (EURbn) 89 108 465 255Note: *Budget was -12.2% and EUR19bn excluding the banks bail out

    Source: Bloomberg, Eurostat, CEIC

  • 8/6/2019 Eurozone Debt and the Rise of DM Political Risk

    12/12

    Renaissance CapitalMoscowT + 7 (495) 258 7777

    Renaissance Capital Ltd.LondonT + 44 (20) 7367 7777

    RenCap Securities, Inc.New York+ 1 (212) 824-1099

    Renaissance Securities (Cyprus)Ltd.NicosiaT + 357 (22) 505 800

    Renaissance Securities (Nigeria)Ltd.LagosT +234 (1) 448 5300

    Renaissance CapitalNairobiT +254 (20) 368 2000

    Renaissance CapitalUkraineKyivT +38 (044) 492-7383

    Renaissance CapitalAlmatyT + 7 (727) 244 1544

    Renaissance Capital (Hong Kong)Ltd.Hong KongT +852 3972 3800

    Renaissance BJMJohannesburgT (+27 11) 750 0000

    Renaissance CapitalHarareT +263 (4) 788336

    Pangaea Renaissance SecuritiesLtd.LusakaT +260 (21) 123 8709

    This Communication is for information purposes only. The Communication does not form a fiduciary relationship or constitute advice and is not and should not be construed as a

    recommendation or an offer or a solicitation of an offer of securities or related financial instruments, or an invitation or inducement to engage in investment activity, and cannot be relied upon asa representation that any particular transaction necessarily could have been or can be effected at the stated price. The Communication is not an advertisement of securities nor independentinvestment research, and has not been prepared in accordance with legal requirements designed to promote the independence of investment research and is not subject to any prohibition ondealing ahead of the dissemination of investment research. Opinions expressed therein may differ or be contrary to opinions expressed by other business areas or groups of the RenaissanceGroup as a result of using different assumptions and criteria. All such information is subject to change without notice, and neither Renaissance Capital nor any of its subsidiaries or affiliates isunder any obligation to update or keep current the information contained in the Communication or in any other medium.

    Descriptions of any company or issuer or their securities or the markets or developments mentioned in the Communication are not intended to be complete. The Communication should not beregarded by recipients as a substitute for the exercise of their own judgment as the Communication has no regard to the specific investment objectives, financial situation or particular needs ofany specific recipient. The material (whether or not it states any opinions) is for general information purposes only and does not take into account your personal circumstances or objectives andnothing in this material is or should be considered to be financial, investment or other advice on which reliance should be placed. Any reliance you place on such information is therefore strictlyat your own risk. The application of taxation laws depends on an investors individual circumstances and, accordingly, each investor should seek in dependent professional advice on taxationimplications before making any investment decision. The Communication has been compiled or arrived at based on information obtained from sources believed to be reliable and in good faith.Such information has not been independently verified, is provided on an as is basis and no representation or warranty, either expressed or implied, is provided in relation to the accuracy,completeness, reliability, merchantability or fitness for a particular purpose of such information, except with respect to information concerning Renaissance Capital, its subsidiaries and affiliates.All statements of opinion and all projections, forecasts, or statements relating to expectations regarding future events or the possible future performance of investments represent RenaissanceCapitals own assessment and interpretation of information available to them currently. Any information relating to past performance of an investment does not necessarily guarantee futureperformance.

    The Communication is not intended for distribution to the public and may be confidential. It may not be reproduced, redistributed or published, in whole or in part, for any purpose without thewritten permission of Renaissance Capital, and neither Renaissance Capital nor any of its affiliates accepts any liability whatsoever for the actions of third parties in this respect. The informationmay not be used to create any financial instruments or products or any indices. Neither Renaissance Capital and its affiliates, nor their directors, representatives, or employees accept any

    liability for any direct or consequential loss or damage arising out of the use of all or any part of the Communication.

    2011 Renaissance Securities (Cyprus) Limited. All rights reserved. Regulated by the Cyprus Securities and Exchange Commissi on (Licence No: KEPEY 053/04).