40
FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a medium for the geographic diffusion of knowledge Joel Blit* Department of Economics University of Waterloo 200 University Ave. West Waterloo, ON, Canada N2L 3G1 [email protected] ABSTRACT: Governments promote inward foreign direct investment in the belief that it will generate positive productivity spillovers. This paper examines a mechanism through which such spillovers may be generated: the subsidiaries of multinational enterprises (MNEs) may act as a medium for the geographic diffusion of remote knowledge. The results suggest that the presence of a foreign MNE subsidiary increases the flow of knowledge from the MNE's headquarters to firms in the subsidiary’s host country. This subsidiary effect on knowledge diffusion is largest in host countries and sectors with strong but not world-class capabilities that have both the motivation and absorptive capacity to learn from foreign parties. The findings also suggest that knowledge diffusion is greatest when subsidiaries are staffed with local staff and not expatriates. Keywords: knowledge flows, diffusion, innovation, foreign direct investment, patents JEL Classification: O3; F2; L2 * I am grateful to Ajay Agrawal, Ignatius Horstmann, Joanne Oxley, and Daniel Trefler for their indispensable guidance, helpful comments, and discussions. Gilles Duranton offered valuable suggestions as a discussant for an early version of this paper. I gratefully acknowledge funding from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada. I acknowledge the National University of Singapore and the Melbourne School of Business for giving me access to their patent data. Any errors and omissions are my own.

FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a

medium for the geographic diffusion of knowledge

Joel Blit*

Department of Economics

University of Waterloo

200 University Ave. West

Waterloo, ON, Canada N2L 3G1

[email protected]

ABSTRACT: Governments promote inward foreign direct investment in

the belief that it will generate positive productivity spillovers. This paper

examines a mechanism through which such spillovers may be generated:

the subsidiaries of multinational enterprises (MNEs) may act as a

medium for the geographic diffusion of remote knowledge. The results

suggest that the presence of a foreign MNE subsidiary increases the flow

of knowledge from the MNE's headquarters to firms in the subsidiary’s

host country. This subsidiary effect on knowledge diffusion is largest in

host countries and sectors with strong but not world-class capabilities

that have both the motivation and absorptive capacity to learn from

foreign parties. The findings also suggest that knowledge diffusion is

greatest when subsidiaries are staffed with local staff and not expatriates.

Keywords: knowledge flows, diffusion, innovation, foreign direct investment, patents

JEL Classification: O3; F2; L2

* I am grateful to Ajay Agrawal, Ignatius Horstmann, Joanne Oxley, and Daniel Trefler

for their indispensable guidance, helpful comments, and discussions. Gilles Duranton

offered valuable suggestions as a discussant for an early version of this paper. I

gratefully acknowledge funding from the Social Sciences and Humanities Research

Council of Canada. I acknowledge the National University of Singapore and the

Melbourne School of Business for giving me access to their patent data. Any errors and

omissions are my own.

Page 2: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

1

1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in

emerging markets. As of 2010, Fortune 500 companies had 98 R&D facilities in China

and 63 in India.1 Cisco is investing more than US$1 billion to build a second global

headquarters in Bangalore, while Microsoft's Beijing R&D Centre is now the firm's

largest outside of its headquarters.1 Developed-world MNEs are establishing themselves

in emerging countries not only to access their already large and growing markets but also

to tap into the multitude of qualified science, engineering, and computer science

graduates that these countries are producing. And by going into these countries, they

may be promoting development in their host country.

Indeed, many countries have implemented policies to attract foreign MNEs

operating in knowledge-intensive sectors in the belief that the activities of their

subsidiaries will generate spillover benefits to local firms. Given this context, it is not

surprising that numerous scholars have conducted empirical studies to determine whether

FDI indeed confers spillover benefits. Particularly salient is the work of Haddad and

Harrison (1993) and Aitken and Harrison (1999), who use micro-level panel data from

Morocco and Venezuela to determine whether FDI affected the productivity of domestic

firms. More recently, Haskel et al. (2002), Keller and Yeaple (2003), Javorcik (2004),

and Kee (2015) have examined the productivity spillover effects of FDI in the U.K., the

U.S., Lithuania, and Bangladesh, respectively. Overall, the evidence is mixed, in part

because productivity gains as a result of FDI are difficult to measure in the face of

numerous possible confounding factors (Gorg and Strobl 2001, Gorg and Greenaway

2004).

Perhaps, then, the way forward is to more closely examine specific mechanisms

through which FDI may increase productivity in the host country. For example, it might

be the case that productivity increases are achieved through the fostering of indigenous

innovation by the presence of multinational subsidiaries. Such a relationship has yet to

be methodically examined in the literature, and one contribution of this paper is to

present qualitative evidence that this is the case. As shown in Figure 1, it seems that, at

least in China, innovative activity by foreign multinationals is associated with increased

1 The Economist, "Special report on innovation in emerging markets," April 17, 2010. p. 4.

Page 3: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

2

indigenous innovation in the same sector some years later. The figure presents Chinese

indigenous patent counts (patents developed in China by Chinese firms) and MNE

offshore patent counts (patents developed in China by foreign multinationals) over time

for the four technological subcategories with the most patenting activity: electrical

devices, power systems, drugs, and computer hardware and software. In each of these

sectors, there is initially no innovation, and we observe the rise of indigenous innovation

some years after multinationals enter China and start innovating there. This relationship

is examined more formally and for more countries in Section 5.

If subsidiaries are encouraging indigenous innovation, it may be because they are

generating knowledge spillovers that provide indigenous firms with inputs for the

innovation process. In particular, subsidiaries may be the knowledge link between

indigenous firms and the outside world. Examining this role of subsidiaries as a medium

for the geographic diffusion of knowledge is the primary focus of this paper.

Knowledge spillovers, in general, have received much attention given their central

role in economic growth (Romer 1990). Numerous scholars have examined the extent to

which these knowledge spillovers are localized; while the results are mixed, the

consensus is that there is some degree of localization (Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Henderson

1993, Audretsch and Feldman 1996, Keller 2002, Thompson and Fox-Kean 2005,

Thompson 2006). How then, do firms in emerging countries get access to knowledge

generated in the developed world? Coe and Helpman (1995), Keller (1998), and

MacGarvie (2006) examine whether the import of manufactured goods can serve as a

channel for knowledge flow. More recently, van Biesebroeck (2005), De Loecker (2007),

and Lileeva and Trefler (2010) have also examined the possibility of learning by

exporting.

A different way that firms in emerging countries may access remotely generated

knowledge is through MNE subsidiaries that locate near them. This paper presents

evidence that subsidiaries increase the flow of knowledge (as measured by patent

citations) from the MNE's headquarters to firms located in the subsidiary's host country.

Due to the localized nature of knowledge, such a medium for the geographic diffusion of

knowledge might be particularly crucial for firms in emerging countries that do not yet

have the foreign presence or networks to tap into remote sources of know-how.

Page 4: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

3

The first to study the relationship between FDI and knowledge flows was

Branstetter (2006), who examines a group of Japanese firms and finds a positive

relationship between the firm's level of outward FDI to the U.S. and the number of

citations that the firm’s patents receive from U.S. patents. As expected, he finds the

relationship to be particularly strong for Japanese FDI investments in American R&D and

product development facilities. In a more recent working paper, Fons-Rosen (2012)

analyzes changes in the degree to which firms in Central and Eastern Europe cite the

patents of foreign firms entering the market. He ingeniously employs a difference in

difference analysis where the treated group is the foreign firms who won privatization

tenders (and hence entered the country) and the control group consists of the losing

bidders. He finds that, on average, the winning bidders experienced a 20% increase in

citations received relative to the losers.

However, such results do not necessarily imply that subsidiaries facilitate the flow

of geographically remote knowledge (from the headquarters) into the host country. It

could simply be that the increased citation rates stem from citations to patents (and

knowledge) developed by the subsidiary in the host country since knowledge diffuses

locally. Therefore, to determine whether subsidiaries act as channels for the geographic

diffusion of remote knowledge, this paper examines whether there is an increase in the

number of domestic firm citations to the stock of patents generated in the headquarters of

the firm doing FDI.

This paper also differs from previous work on FDI and knowledge diffusion in

that, contrary to the large majority of the literature that focuses on one country, or at most

one region, the analysis conducted here examines the effect over 121 host countries. This

allows not only a more general treatment of the topic but also a cross-country comparison

of the country characteristics that facilitate or hinder the flow of remote knowledge

through the medium of the subsidiary. One important finding in this respect is that a host

country’s level of technological development is a critical factor, with knowledge

diffusion through the subsidiary being greatest in countries and sectors with strong, but

not world-class, capabilities. In addition, this analysis spans a much longer timeframe

than other studies (1976-2004).

Page 5: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

4

Finally, this paper also considers whether subsidiary staffing policy impacts

knowledge diffusion though the subsidiary. While geographic knowledge diffusion

through the subsidiaries is beneficial from the perspective of international growth and

development, the MNE may be rightly concerned that it weakens its competitive position.

The MNE may thus take measures to better protect its knowledge when venturing abroad.

One such measure may be to staff the subsidiary with expatriates since they have

shallower links to the local environment. Indeed, the results suggest that knowledge

leakage is smaller in subsidiaries that are staffed with higher ratios of expatriates,

although the analysis does not establish a causal relationship.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly discusses why we might

expect the subsidiaries of multinational firms to promote the geographic diffusion of

knowledge into their host country and why this flow of knowledge might depend on the

subsidiary’s staffing policy and the country’s existing technical capabilities. Section 3

discusses the data and methodology used to address this question and section 4 presents

the results and discusses the findings. Section 5 offers a first look into the larger question

of whether subsidiaries promote indigenous innovation. Finally, section 6 concludes.

2. Background

The principal question addressed in this paper is whether the subsidiaries of

multinational firms act as a medium for the geographic diffusion of knowledge. In

particular, the paper asks whether subsidiaries give indigenous firms in the subsidiary’s

host country increased access to knowledge generated in the subsidiary’s headquarters.

For subsidiaries to effectively increase this flow of knowledge, two things must

happen. First, MNE headquarters must share its technological expertise with its

subsidiaries. Second, this knowledge must spill out from the subsidiary to local firms.

The fact that, in general, a headquarters shares knowledge with its subsidiaries should not

come as a surprise. As Dunning (1977) and Kogut and Zander (1993) argue, the very

existence of MNEs may be due to the fact that they are an efficient organizational vehicle

through which to transfer and share knowledge across borders. MNEs that fail to share

knowledge among their different locations lose many of the advantages of being an MNE.

Page 6: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

5

We would therefore expect MNEs to actively share headquarters knowledge with its

subsidiaries.

Once a subsidiary has received knowledge from the parent, this knowledge can

spill over to local firms through the usual diffusion mechanisms of local input-output

linkages, social networks, and labor mobility (Von Hippel 1988, Rogers and Larsen 1984,

Almeida and Kogut 1999, Agrawal, Cockburn, and McHale 2006). Whether or not this

overall flow of knowledge - from headquarters to subsidiary to other firms in the

subsidiary’s location - occurs, is an empirical question and the primary focus of this

paper.

We would, of course, expect the magnitude of this overall knowledge flow to be

mediated both by characteristics of the MNE and of the local environment in which the

subsidiary resides. MNEs have an incentive to institute policies and mechanisms that

curtail outward knowledge flow to potential competitors. One way they might achieve

this is for subsidiaries to focus on technologies that are more internally-oriented and

hence useless to third parties [Zhao (2006)].

Another way that firms may be able to protect their knowledge is by staffing key

R&D positions in their foreign units with expatriates instead of locals. While this may

seem counterproductive, given that expatriates are likely to possess more critical

technical capabilities and institutional knowledge of the firm, expatriates are also less

likely to allow knowledge to diffuse to their local environment. By virtue of being

foreign, expatriates are devoid of the local social networks that facilitate localized

knowledge spillovers. They are also less likely to move to another local firm, thereby

passing on their knowledge. Overall, the effect of staffing subsidiaries with expatriates

on total knowledge diffusion is ambiguous: it increases the stock of subsidiary knowledge

that potentially can diffuse, but the likelihood of a given piece of knowledge being passed

on is lower. It is therefore an empirical question: the findings suggest that subsidiaries

staffed with high ratios of expatriates experience less leakage of their headquarters’

knowledge, although the analysis does not establish causality.

A second important factor that mediates the overall flow of knowledge from

headquarters to firms in the subsidiary’s location is the characteristics of local firms. As

Cohen and Levinthal (1990) argue, firms with little expertise in a particular sector may

Page 7: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

6

fail to recognize the value of new information or may not be able to assimilate it. In an

international context marked by great disparities in technological capabilities across

countries and sectors, the absorptive capacity (or lack thereof) of local firms is likely to

be a primary driver of whether local firms benefit from the presence of more advanced

MNEs. Hence, we would expect knowledge inflows from MNE headquarters to be

greater in more technologically advanced countries and sectors.

The caveat to this argument is that country/sectors that are already world-class

have little to gain from MNEs that are based in less-advanced countries. Instead, they are

likely to focus their energy on learning from other firms in their home country.

Consistent with this, Singh (2007) finds that knowledge inflows from foreign MNE

subsidiaries to local firms are smaller than knowledge outflows only in technologically

advanced countries.2 The combination of these two arguments leads to the hypothesis that

knowledge diffusion from the MNE headquarters to local firms may be an inverted U

function of the host country's capability in the given technological sector.3 This is indeed

confirmed by the empirical findings.

3. Data and Methodology

To determine whether the subsidiaries facilitate the flow of headquarters

knowledge to third-party firms in their host country I use data on patents granted by the

United States Patents and Trademarks Office (USPTO) from two separate sources. The

NBER Patent Data Project provides a dataset with the application year, technology class

(type), technology subclass (subtype), assignee (owner), and assignee headquarters

country of all patents granted between 1976 and 2006, inclusive. This is supplemented

with inventor country and citation data from the NUS-MBS Patent Database.4 Since the

latter is restricted to patents granted up to 2004, the final sample consists of all patents

granted between 1976 and 2004.

2 Singh’s focus is on local knowledge flows between subsidiaries and host country firms. He does not

consider remote knowledge flows between the headquarters and firms in the host country. 3 More formally, this hypothesis would follow by claiming that both the costs and benefits of knowledge

acquisition from foreign subsidiaries are decreasing in their own technological capabilities (C'<0, B'<0) but

that benefits decrease faster than costs (C''>0, B''<0). 4 The National University of Singapore-Melbourne Business School(NUS-MBS) Patent Database is

available at: http://kwanghui.com/patents/.

Page 8: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

7

Patents are assigned to an innovating country based on the residence of the

inventors. Implicit in this definition is the belief that the inventor’s country of residence

most closely proxies for the location where the process of innovating occurred.

Knowledge flows are measured using patent citations. Although citations are a noisy

measure of knowledge flows, studies comparing citation data with inventor surveys have

shown that the correlation between patent citations and actual knowledge flows is high

enough to justify their use in large samples [Jaffe and Trajtenberg, Chapter 12 (2002),

Duguet and MacGarvie (2002)].

The first step in the construction of the dataset consists of identifying firms with

patenting activity in more than one country. While the country of the headquarters is

listed directly in the data,5 the other locations (henceforth referred to as the "subsidiaries")

are determined by looking at the other locations where the firm has innovative activities

(using the country of residence of the firm's patents' inventors). In total, 7264 firms with

foreign innovative activities are spread over 12,953 subsidiaries. These subsidiaries have

generated on average seven U.S. patents, with 6987 generating only one patent, 2090 two

patents, 1007 three patents, and 2869 four or more patents.6

There are two types of cited patents in the analysis: treated and control. The set

of treated patents is composed of all patents generated in the headquarters of these MNEs.

These patents are “treated” in the sense that the knowledge they embody may have

diffused to the host country through the medium of the subsidiary. In order to control for

patterns of geographic agglomeration of technological activity that could be related to the

choice of location for the subsidiary, I generate a matched control group.7 In particular,

each patent in the treated group is matched to a control patent from the same country,

application year, technology class, and if possible technology subclass. Moreover, the

assignee of the control patent cannot have patented in the same country as the treated

firm's subsidiary (i.e., the owner of the patent cannot have a subsidiary in the same host

country). If several potential control patents match the criteria, I choose the patent

belonging to the MNE whose number of locations most closely matches the number of

5 In more than 95% of firms, the "headquarters" country is also the country with the most patenting activity. 6 Focusing on subsidiaries with larger patent outputs yields larger estimates of the subsidiary effect on

knowledge diffusion. 7 The methodology builds on that of Jaffe et al. (1993) and Agrawal et al. (2006).

Page 9: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

8

locations of the treated firm. Patents belonging to single-location firms are chosen as a

last resort. If two or more patents are equally suitable controls according to these six

criteria, one is picked randomly. Any treated patent with no matching control is dropped

from the sample. I find controls for 97% of the 10,453,898 potential treated

patent/subsidiary combinations, of which 5,517,325 matches are at the subclass level and

4,620,901 at the class level.8

Figure 2 provides an illustration of the methodology for Microsoft Corporation's

Chinese subsidiary.9 The question of interest is whether headquarter patents are

disproportionately cited by third parties in the locations where the headquarters have a

subsidiary. In particular, the analysis compares the proportion of citations received by

patents in the treated group that are from third-party patents in the subsidiary's location

(�̂�𝑇) to the proportion of citations received by patents in the control group that are from

third-party patents in the subsidiary location (�̂�𝐶). We can interpret the ratio of these as

the MNE subsidiary's effect on knowledge diffusion.

Since knowledge diffuses locally, using countries as the geographic level of

analysis could significantly bias the results downward.10 For example, it is not clear

whether a subsidiary in Beijing would help headquarters knowledge diffuse to firms

located in Shanghai. The results presented in Section 4.3 indeed suggest the presence of

this bias since countries with a more concentrated urban population experience higher

measured knowledge flows. Therefore, we may want to place less emphasis on the

estimated magnitude of this MNE effect on knowledge diffusion and instead view the

estimate as a lower bound on the actual effect. On the other hand, how this effect differs

across host countries can provide relevant insights for management and policy. In

particular, is it the case that this effect is larger in technology-poor countries where

MNEs presumably play a more pivotal role in the inward diffusion of knowledge?

8 There are a total of 428 different three-digit U.S. patent technology classes (with the most active being

"drugs" and "semiconductors") and more than 100,000 technology subclasses. 9 Microsoft Corporation is the U.S. firm with the most patenting activity in China. Research at the Beijing

lab focuses on natural user interface, next generation multimedia, data-intensive computing, search and

online ads, and computer science fundamentals. 10 The geographic unit of analysis is at the country level due to data limitations. Reliable city-level

inventor locations are only available for the U.S. and Canada.

Page 10: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

9

GDP per capita is too aggregate a measure of technological capability since

countries are heterogeneous in their technological capabilities across sectors. A more

appropriate measure is the patent stock per capita in any given country/sector/year.

Patent stocks are constructed by counting patents in a given country, technology class,

and up to a given year. A discount rate of 15% per year is applied to patents from

previous years to account for technological obsolescence.11 These patent stocks are

normalized by the host country's population (as obtained from the UN Statistics Division)

in the given year to obtain patent stocks per capita. The baseline estimating equation is:

(�̂�𝑇 − �̂�𝐶)𝑝𝑖

= 𝛼 + 𝛽1𝑃𝑎𝑡𝑆𝑡𝑜𝑐𝑘𝑝𝑐𝑖𝑐(𝑝)𝑡(𝑝) + 𝛽2𝑃𝑎𝑡𝑆𝑡𝑜𝑐𝑘𝑝𝑐𝑖𝑐(𝑝)𝑡(𝑝)2 + 𝛽3𝑿𝑖𝑡(𝑝) + 𝛽4𝑿𝑖

+ 𝛽5𝑿𝑖𝑗(𝑝) + 𝛼𝑡(𝑝) + 𝛼𝑐(𝑝) + 𝜀𝑝𝑖

The dependent variable is the proportion of citations to the treated patent that is from the

host country minus the proportion of citations to the associated control patent that is from

the host country.12 The unit of observation is the headquarters (treated) patent p and

subsidiary country i. The independent variable PatStockpcic(p)t(p) is the patent stock per

capita for the subsidiary country i, in the technology class of the treated patent c(p), in the

application year of the treated patent t(p). Xit(p) , Xi , and Xij(p) are vectors of control

variables at the subsidiary country/year, subsidiary country, and subsidiary

country/headquarters country levels. respectively. 𝛼𝑡(𝑝) and 𝛼𝑐(𝑝) are year and

technology class fixed effects.13 Table 1 presents the description and source of these

control variables, and summary statistics are presented in Table 2.

4. Results

11 In addition, this is multiplied by the correction term

1 .85200419761

1 .85t19761 (where t is the stock year) to

adjust for the fact that the dataset has no observations prior to 1976.

12 Using

ˆ P T / ˆ P C as the dependent variable results in a loss of 90% of the observations due to values of

ˆ P C 0 . As Table 7 shows, this alternative dependent variable does not change the principal results (and

in particular the confirmation of the inverted U hypothesis). 13 Due to computational limitations, technology class fixed effects cannot be utilized, and instead fixed

effects at the more aggregate subcategory level are used. The data contains 443 technology classes

aggregated into 37 technology subcategories. Demeaning the dependent variable by technology class

before running the regression does not change the results presented in Section 3.3.2.

Page 11: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

10

4.1 Subsidiary Effect on Knowledge Diffusion

A primary hypothesis of this paper is that the subsidiary is a medium for the

geographic diffusion of knowledge, allowing firms in the host country to receive a

disproportionately large amount of knowledge generated in the headquarters of the firm

that established the subsidiary. The findings presented in Table 3 (Column 1) are

consistent with this. While 3.52% of the citations received by the MNEs' headquarters

(treated) patents are from third parties in the location of their subsidiary, only 3.06% of

the citations received by the control group are from third parties in the location of the

corresponding treated patent's subsidiary (�̂�𝑇=.0352 and �̂�𝐶=.0306). Performing a

difference of proportions t-test with unequal variances as in Almeida (1996) yields a t-

statistic of 144.1.14 I compute the effect of the subsidiary on knowledge diffusion to the

host country as �̂�𝑇

�̂�𝐶= 1.15, suggesting that host country firms receive on average 15%

more knowledge from the headquarters.

Columns 2-4 present the results when the same analysis is performed separately

for emerging, middle-income, and developed countries. Countries are classified into

these groups based on 1990 per capita GDP measured at current U.S. dollars as obtained

from the United Nations Statistics Division. Countries with per capita GDP of less than

$5000 are classified as emerging, between $5000 and $15000 as middle-income, and

above $15000 as developed. Table 4 shows each group's countries with the most

patenting activity (though all 121 countries with a subsidiary are included in the analysis).

As expected, the diffusion effect is biggest for emerging host countries.15

4.2 Difference in Differences

It could be the case that the finding of a subsidiary effect on knowledge diffusion

is spurious and results from firms choosing to set up subsidiaries in locations that are

14 Letting H0: PT = PC and H1: PT > PC , I calculate the t-statistic as:

t = P̂T - P̂C( ) / P̂T 1- P̂T( ) / nT + P̂C 1- P̂C( ) / nC , where nT and nC are the total number of citations

received by the treated and control group, respectively. 15 The comparison is qualitative in nature because there is no clear statistic to test the hypothesis that the

diffusion effect is bigger for developing countries than for developed ones.

Page 12: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

11

disproportionately sourcing their headquarters' knowledge. For example, firms may

establish subsidiaries in locations that specialize in the same technological areas as

themselves. Then, if control patents match imperfectly, the fact that patents are more

likely to cite within their narrow technology class could lead to finding a subsidiary effect

when none exists. This section addresses this concern, finding that the subsidiary effect

is robust to this critique.

The endogeneity of the location decision is addressed using the time structure of

the data. The principal challenge with deploying this approach is that the date of

establishment of a subsidiary is not directly observed in the patent data. What is

observed is a proxy for the date of establishment: the application date of the first patent

from the subsidiary location. Since patents are generally the result of many years of

development (and many subsidiaries may initially perform non-innovative tasks), the

year of the first application will invariably lag behind the actual year of establishment.

Since the years right before the first application date of a subsidiary patent are the most

problematic to define as pre- or post-subsidiary, I define a "grey window" as the period

starting w years before the first subsidiary patent application and ending the year before

the first patent application.16 This window is dropped from the analysis, and the pre-

subsidiary period is defined as ending w+1 years prior to the first subsidiary patent. The

post-subsidiary period begins the year the first subsidiary patent application is observed.

Clearly, it will still be the case that many subsidiaries are operating and diffusing

knowledge in what has been defined in this way as the “pre-subsidiary” period

(especially for smaller windows). However, this will bias against finding a difference in

knowledge diffusion after the date of the first application.

To ensure that the pre- and post-subsidiary patents are similar, I restrict the

sample to patents from firms that have headquarters patents in each of the pre- and post-

subsidiary periods. I then employ a difference in differences methodology. Observations

are at the patent level, with a treated patent and its associated control patent being

separate observations. The dependent variable (match_ratioi) is the proportion of patent

i's citations that are from third-party patents in the subsidiary location. The explanatory

variables include a dummy variable (treated) that is 1 when the patent is from the treated

16 As will be shown, the results are consistent across different values of w.

Page 13: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

12

group and 0 if it is from the control group, a dummy variable (postsub) that is 1 when the

patent's application year is in the post-subsidiary period and 0 if it is in the pre-subsidiary

period, and the interaction (treated_postsub) of these two variables. Table 5 presents the

results of an OLS regression with clustering by firm and robust standard errors for

different window sizes.

The interaction term treated_postsub is highly significant in all cases, suggesting

that the establishment of the subsidiary facilitates knowledge diffusion to third-party

firms in their host country. Given the previously discussed bias associated with not

knowing the actual date of establishment, it is not surprising that the coefficient on

treated is positive and significant. The large decrease in the size of this coefficient and

increase in the coefficient of treated_postsub as larger windows are chosen offers

evidence that this bias is indeed present. Overall, Table 5 suggests that at the very least,

the large majority of the subsidiary effect computed in Section 4.1 is due to actual

knowledge flows through the subsidiary and not to firms establishing subsidiaries in

locations where third-party firms already disproportionately source headquarters'

knowledge.

4.3 Technological Capability

As previously discussed, we expect an inverse U relationship between the amount

of knowledge diffusion received through subsidiaries and the technological stock of the

host country. This hypothesis is tested by regressing (�̂�𝑇-�̂�𝐶) on patent stocks per capita

The results are presented in Tables 6 and 7. While this is the preferred specification

because it allows for values of �̂�𝐶 = 0, the results for the alternative dependent variable

(�̂�𝑇/�̂�𝐶) are presented in Table 8.

Table 6 presents the results of an OLS regression with no country fixed effects.

The coefficients on patent stock per capita and its square are highly significant and

consistent with an inverted U relationship.17 The apex of the estimated inverted U is at a

patent stock per capita value of 4.96e-5, which is well within the 0 to 8.38e-4 range of

patent stock per capita but in the 99.8th value percentile of the variable. This result

17 The coefficients are almost identical when running the four regressions on the original patent stock

variables without taking the natural logarithm.

Page 14: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

13

suggests that the most prominent issue for most countries/sectors is a lack of absorptive

capacity that limits their ability to learn from the subsidiary. However, the most

technologically sophisticated countries/sectors also gain less from foreign subsidiaries

since these have little to teach them, though this only applies to truly world-class

clusters.18

The estimated coefficients on the control variables also offer interesting insights.

The coefficient on largest city population % is, as expected, positive and significant at

the .1% level. To reiterate, the motivation for including this variable is that we would

expect a subsidiary in Beijing, for example, to generate spillovers to indigenous firms in

Beijing but not necessarily to indigenous firms in Shanghai. Our finding is consistent

with subsidiaries transferring knowledge to firms in their local (city) environment.

Highly decentralized countries tend to experience a smaller subsidiary effect because the

subsidiary’s presence benefits a smaller fraction of the country’s firms (primarily those

that are located in the same city).

The host country's GDP per capita and its square are also significant but only

when using their logged values. Countries with higher Internet penetration and telephone

installations benefit less from the presence of subsidiaries. While this result seems

counterintuitive, the Internet (and the telephone) facilitates the global flow of knowledge

and may hence be a substitute for the acquisition of knowledge through subsidiaries.

More knowledge is exchanged between countries that have a shared primary language

since this facilitates communication. Countries with a shared colonial past (legal origin)

benefit less from the presence of a satellite, perhaps because of alternative shared

institutions through which knowledge is exchanged.

In Columns 1 and 2, the coefficients on infrastructure and rule of law are also

significant. However, these are host country level variables; when the standard errors are

clustered by host country (Column 3), they lose their significance.

Table 7 incorporates host country fixed effects. The results suggest that the

relationship between patent stock per capita and knowledge acquisition through foreign

18 It may be the case that this applies more broadly but the highly aggregated technological sectors are

masking the effect. A country may be at the technological frontier (and not learning) in half of the

subsectors that make up a sector but some distance behind the frontier (and learning) in the other subsectors.

Page 15: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

14

subsidiaries also applies across technological sectors within countries.19 Column 3

presents the results for a Tobit regression with left censoring of the dependent variable at

-1 and right censoring at 1. The estimated coefficients are unchanged. Table 8 shows

that the results are robust to using (�̂�𝑇-�̂�𝐶) as an alternative dependent variable.

4.4 Expatriates and Knowledge Diffusion

While we do not directly observe the number of expatriates in a particular

subsidiary, we can construct a proxy using inventor mobility between the headquarters

and the subsidiary. In particular, I count the number of inventors who generated a patent

in the headquarters location and subsequently in the subsidiary location. This count is

normalized by the total number of different inventors having generated a patent in the

subsidiary location. The variable expat then measures the fraction of subsidiary inventors

who were originally from the headquarters location. The estimating equation is:

(�̂�𝑇/�̂�𝐶)𝑓𝑖

= 𝛼 + 𝛽1𝑒𝑥𝑝𝑎𝑡𝑓𝑖 + 𝑠𝑢𝑏𝑠_𝑝𝑎𝑡𝑠𝑓𝑖 + 𝐻𝑄_𝑝𝑎𝑡𝑠𝑓 + 𝑙𝑜𝑐𝑠𝑓 + 𝛼𝑓 + 𝛼𝑖 + 𝜀𝑓𝑖.

The unit of observation is the subsidiary (firm f and subsidiary country i).20 This

higher level of aggregation permits the use of (�̂�𝑇/�̂�𝐶) as the dependent variable. The

independent variable expatfi is our explanatory variable of interest. The variables

subs_patsfi (number of patents generated by the subsidiary), HQ_patsf (number of patents

generated by the headquarters), and locsf (number of countries where the firm has

patented) are controls for firm size, and 𝛼𝑓 and 𝛼𝑖 are firm and host country fixed effects,

respectively.

The first two columns of Table 9 present the results with no firm fixed effects.

Subsidiaries with high ratios of expatriates experience significantly lower rates of

knowledge leakage. The coefficient on the ratio of expatriates is significant at the .1%

level (Columns 1 and 2). Among the controls, only the size of the headquarters is

significant. One explanation is that third parties can more readily monitor from a

19 The results are similar when absolute patent stocks are used instead of per capita patent stocks. 20 Multiple firm subsidiaries in the same country are lumped as a single subsidiary due to data limitations.

Page 16: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

15

distance the innovative activities of larger firms while smaller firms largely fall under the

radar unless they have a presence in the country.

The coefficient on expatfi is larger when firm fixed effects are added to the

regression, though it is only significant at the 6% level. The weaker significance is not

surprising given the limited number of within-firm observations. Of the 7264 firms in the

sample, more than 70% have only a single foreign subsidiary and only 15% have three

subsidiaries or more.

5. Indigenous and MNE Subsidiary Innovation

The principal focus of this paper is to present evidence that subsidiaries facilitate

the flow of foreign knowledge to firms in their host country. However, arguably a more

important objective is to determine the effect of subsidiaries, not on knowledge flow, but

rather on more economically significant variables like innovation and productivity.

There should be a relationship between knowledge flows and innovation since knowledge

is an important input into the innovation process. Thus, given our findings from section 4,

we would expect that the presence of MNE subsidiaries would ultimately result in

increased indigenous innovation and that this would be particularly true in emerging

countries where firms have access to few other sources of knowledge.

This section examines whether the country-level evidence is consistent with this

hypothesis. If so, we should observe that increases in multinational innovative activity in

an emerging country should be associated with increased indigenous innovation in the

same sector some years later. Figure 1 presents Chinese indigenous patent counts

(patents developed in China by indigenous firms) and offshore patent counts (patents

developed in China by foreign multinationals) over time for the four technological

subcategories with the most patenting activity: electrical devices, power systems, drugs,

and computer hardware and software. We observe little indigenous innovation until

multinationals enter the country and start innovating domestically. As this section will

show, increases in offshored innovation are associated with future increases in indigenous

innovation in emerging countries, but not in developed countries where technological

capabilities already largely exist and do not need to be imported through MNEs.

Page 17: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

16

5.1 Data

Innovation is measured using patents granted by the United States Patents and

Trademarks Office (USPTO). As before, the dataset provided by the NBER Patent Data

Project provides the application year, patent technology class, and assignee home country

of all patents granted between 1976 and 2006, inclusive. Inventor data is obtained from

the NUS-MBS Patent Database; since it only contains patents granted up to 2004, this

restricts the sample to the grant years 1976-2004. As before, patents are assigned to an

innovating country based on the residence of the inventors.

The analysis focuses on a patent's application year because it captures the timing

of an innovation better than the patent's year of granting. In addition, since the delay

between applying for a patent and obtaining it varies greatly across patents, technology

classes, and over time, using the grant year would introduce additional noise (see Figure

3). Unfortunately, using the application year could result in a selection bias due to

truncation. For example, since our dataset includes patents granted up to the end of 2004,

the only patents with a 2004 application year are the ones that were granted within 12

months of application. As Figure 3 shows, the truncation problem is most pronounced in

the years 2001-2004; therefore, these years are dropped from the sample.21 The sections

that follow restrict the analyses to the application years 1986-2000.22

For the purpose of the analysis, countries are classified into three groups as before,

based on 1990 per capita GDP measured at current U.S. dollars as obtained from the

United Nations Statistics Division. Countries with per capita GDP of less than $5000 are

classified as emerging, between $5000 and $15000 as middle-income, and above $15000

as developed. The final sample consists of each group's countries with the most patenting

activity.23 The countries in the sample and their group assignations are listed in Table

4.24

21 98% of patents are granted within four years 22 Since innovation by emerging countries is a relatively recent phenomenon, the analysis uses the most

recent possible sample. Nonetheless, using an older sample to better address truncation yields the same

qualitative results. 23 As will soon become apparent, countries with little innovative activity will be at best uninformative and

in all likelihood will significantly increase the noise in the results. 24 The sample includes all emerging countries with 175 or more patents with the exception of Russia and

the Czech Republic, which are omitted because of difficulties in allocating patents prior the breakup of the

USSR (1991) and Czechoslovakia(1993), respectively; all middle-income countries with more than 1300

Page 18: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

17

The principal variables of interest are total offshore patent counts and total

indigenous patent counts by country, technology class, and application year. A patent is

counted as indigenous to country i if all inventors are from country i and the assignee

headquarters is also in country i. A patent is counted as offshore to country i if at least

one inventor is from country i and the assignee headquarters are in a country other than

i.25

5.2 Methodology

To test whether offshored innovation promotes indigenous innovation, I compute

Kendall’s τ on the first difference of indigenous patent counts and lagged offshored

patent counts (see Appendix A for a discussion of measures of association and Kendall's τ

in particular). Kendall's τ measures the relationship between two variables by considering

every pair of observations and counting the number of such pairs that are concordant

versus discordant. A pair of observations (Xi, Yi) and (Xj, Yj) is said to be concordant if

either Xi < Xj and Yi < Yj or Xi > Xj and Yi > Yj. In this case, τ takes on the value 1.

Similarly, a pair is discordant if either Xi < Xj and Yi > Yj or Xi > Xj and Yi < Yj, in which

case τ=-1. Observation pairs for which either Xi = Xj or Yi = Yj are said to be tied and

τ=0. Because τ focuses on the ordering and not the exact magnitude of a pair of

observations, it is a robust statistic (though the cost is a loss of information).

As shown in Figure 1, indigenous and offshored patent counts are trending

variables. A correlation between the two may then be spurious and driven by omitted

factors. I address this by looking at the relationship between their first differences.26

Therefore, X will be the lagged increase/decrease in offshored patent counts across two

subsequent periods and Y the increase/decrease in indigenous patent counts across two

subsequent periods. To reduce the volatility in patent counts for a particular country and

patents, with the exception of Spain; and all developed countries with more than 10,000 patents, with the

exception of the U.S. since U.S. patent data is being used for the study. 25 The same patent can be an offshore patent for more than one country. However, the number of such

occurrences is small; this does not cause inconsistencies for the issues addressed in this paper. 26 This addresses first-order trends but does not solve the problem if both variables exhibit exponential

growth (or decay). However, the empirical results are not consistent with double exponential growth since

offshore patents are found to promote indigenous patents but not the converse.

Page 19: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

18

technology class over time, I consider non-overlapping three-year periods and sum the

total counts within each period.27

Figure 4 illustrates the methodology in more detail. The first step is to compute

the total patent counts in each period. The first differences of these counts across

subsequent periods are then computed to obtain D_OC2, D_OC3, D_IC4, and D_IC5,

where D_OC2 is the total number of offshored patents (by country and sector) in years

1989, 1990, and 1991 minus the total number of offshored patents in years 1986, 1987,

and 1988 (D_IC is the counterpart for indigenous patent counts). The association

measure τ is then computed on these first differences. In particular:

𝜏 = {

1 𝑖𝑓 (𝐷𝑂𝐶2 − 𝐷𝑂𝐶3)(𝐷𝐼𝐶4 − 𝐷𝐼𝐶5) > 0

0 𝑖𝑓 (𝐷𝑂𝐶2 − 𝐷𝑂𝐶3)(𝐷𝐼𝐶4 − 𝐷𝐼𝐶5) = 0

−1 𝑖𝑓 (𝐷𝑂𝐶2 − 𝐷𝑂𝐶3)(𝐷𝐼𝐶4 − 𝐷𝐼𝐶5) < 0

}

This provides one of three values of τ for each patent technology class/country

combination. As is apparent from Figure 1, τ will most often take values of zero because

emerging countries have zero patents in most sectors in a given year (Figure 1 shows the

most active patent classes). These are relatively uninformative for our purposes and are

therefore thrown out. The analysis consists of comparing whether we observe τ=1 more

often than τ=-1. In particular, the statistic of interest is 𝜏̅, the average τ across all non-

zero τ values within a group of countries (emerging, middle-income, or developed) across

all technology classes. A positive statistic suggests that for that group of countries,

offshored innovation promotes indigenous innovation.

To determine whether the computed association is significantly different from

zero, we take as the null hypothesis that the two variables D_OC and D_IC are

independent. Under the null, we would expect to observe τ = 1 and τ = -1 each about

half the time. Under the null, 𝜏̅ has a binomial distribution with (n, p=.5) where n is the

27 It is not possible to implement a longer period due to lack of observations. Patenting activity in

developing countries is a relatively recent phenomenon generally dating back no earlier than the mid-1980s.

Page 20: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

19

total number of country/industry combinations in the group. This allows us to compute

𝜏̅'s level of significance.28

When considering the reverse relationship (whether domestic counts drive

offshore counts), the exact same methodology applies with the variable names reversed in

Figure 4 and the above description.

To ensure that the results are not unduly influenced by technological sectors with

little patenting activity where noise is likely to play a bigger role, it may make sense to

restrict the analysis to the technological classes with the most patenting activity. In

addition to showing results for the full sample, the following section presents results for

the sample of the 25% and 50% of technology classes where emerging countries have the

most patents.

5.3 Results

Applying the above methodology to analyze the relationship between offshored

and indigenous innovation yields the results presented in Tables 10a, 10b, and 10c. Table

10a presents the results for a subsample comprised of the 25% of patent classes with the

most emerging country activity, 10b for the 50% most active classes, and 10c for the full

sample. For each country group, the table presents 𝜏̅, n (the number of country/class

combinations over which 𝜏̅ was computed) and the p-value associated with the two-sided

hypothesis test that the variables are related. The table presents the tests for both

offshored innovation promoting indigenous innovation and the converse.

The results strongly support the hypothesis that offshored innovation promotes

indigenous innovation in emerging countries.29 As expected, this is not the case in more

technologically advanced (richer) countries where domestic sources of innovative know-

how are widely available. In addition, it does not seem that indigenous innovation

attracts offshored innovation to any significant degree.

28 If we believe that τa is correlated across patent classes within a country (or across countries within a

patent class), this approach underestimates the variance of the aggregate τ and will over-reject the null that

the variables are independent. 29 The fact that indigenous patent counts do not promote offshored patent counts in developing countries

suggests that this association is not a result of external factors driving both variables to grow at rates that

would require a second or higher order difference to detrend (exponential growth, for example).

Page 21: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

20

6. Conclusion

While there is a large established literature examining the impact of foreign direct

investment on productivity, the mechanisms through which this may occur are not well

understood. This paper examines whether subsidiaries of multinational firms act as a

medium for the geographic diffusion of knowledge. The results suggest that this is

indeed the case, with subsidiaries increasing the flow of knowledge from their

headquarters to third-party firms in their host country by about 25% for emerging

countries, and 15% overall. Further, this learning through subsidiaries is found to be

largest in countries and sectors with strong but not world-class capabilities, presumably

because these have both the motivation and absorptive capacity to learn from foreign

parties.

Since knowledge is a critical input into the innovative process, we would expect

these spillovers to, in turn, impact real economic variables like innovation and

productivity. Section 5 presented an initial analysis of whether multinational subsidiaries

promote innovation in their host country. The strong correlation between innovation by

MNE subsidiaries and follow-on indigenous innovation is a first glance into this bigger

question. The results suggest that for emerging countries, subsidiaries do indeed play a

key role in promoting innovation.

Overall, the findings lend credence to policies designed to attract foreign MNE’s

operating in technology-intensive sectors, since the subsidiaries not only promote

knowledge flow, but also innovation. They further suggest which countries and sectors

are most likely to benefit from policies designed to promote FDI. Lastly, the findings

offer a potentially important prescription for firms that are concerned about protecting

their intellectual property when venturing abroad; staffing key subsidiary technical

positions with expatriates may limit outward knowledge leakage.

In summary, this paper offers a micro-level analysis of the knowledge flows

associated with subsidiaries. As such, it increases our understanding of how FDI may

contribute to development and economic growth and, more importantly, in which

instances it is likely to do so.

Page 22: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

21

References

Agrawal, A., Cockburn, I., McHale, J. 2006. Gone but not forgotten: knowledge flows,

labor mobility, and enduring social relationships. Journal of Economic Geography 6:

571-591.

Aitken, B., Harrison, A. 1999. Do Domestic Firms Benefit from Direct Foreign

Investment? Evidence from Venezuela. The American Economic Review 89:605-618.

Almeida, P. 1996. Knowledge sourcing by foreign multinationals: patent citation analysis

in the U.S. semiconductor industry. Strategic Management Journal 17: 155-165.

Almeida, P., B. Kogut. 1999. Localization of knowledge and the mobility of engineers in

regional networks. Management Science 45(7) 905-917.

Audretsch, D. B., Feldman, M. P. 1996. R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation

and production. American Economic Review 86: 630-640.

Aw, B., Chen, X., Roberts, M. 2001. Firm-level evidence on productivity differentials,

turnover, and exports in Taiwanese manufacturing. Journal of Development Economics

66:51-86.

Bernard, A., Jensen, J. 1999. Exceptional exporter performance: cause, effect, or both?

Journal of International Economics 47: 1-25.

Blalock, G., Gertler, P. 2008. Welfare gains from foreign direct investment through

technology transfer to local suppliers. Journal of International Economics 74: 402-421.

Branstetter, L. 2006. Is foreign direct investment a channel of knowledge spillovers?

Evidence from Japan’s FDI in the United States. Journal of International Economics 68:

325-344.

Clerides, S., Lach, S., Tybout, J. 1998. Is learning by exporting important? Micro-

dynamic evidence from Colombia, Mexico, and Morocco. Quarterly Journal of

Economics 113: 903–948.

Cohen W., Levinthal, D. 1990. Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and

innovation. Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 128-152.

De Loecker, J. 2007. Do exports generate higher productivity? Evidence from Slovenia.

Journal of International Economics 73: 69-98.

Duguet, E., MacGarvie, M. 2005. How well do patent citations measure flows of

technology? Evidence from French innovation surveys. Economics of Innovation and

New Technology 14: 375-393.

Page 23: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

22

Dunning, J. 1977. Trade, location of economic activity and the multinational enterprise:

A search for an eclectic approach. In B. Ohlin, P.O. Hesselborn & P.M. Wijkman, editors,

The international allocation of economic activity. London. Macmillan.

Fons-Rosen, C. 2012. Knowledge flows through FDI: the case of privatisations in central

and eastern Europe. Working Paper.

Frost, T.S. 2001. The geographic sources of foreign subsidiaries’ innovations. Strategic

Management Journal 22:101-23.

Ginarte, J.C., Park, W.G. 1997. Determinants of patent rights: A cross-national study.

Research Policy 26:283-301.

Gorg, H. and Greenaway, D. 2004. Much ado about nothing? Do domestic firms really

benefit from foreign direct investment? The World Bank Research Observer 19: 171-197.

Gorg, H. and Strobl, E. 2001. Multinational companies and productivity spillovers: a

meta-analysis. The Economic Journal 111: F723-F739.

Haddad, M., Harrison, A. 1993. Are there positive spillovers from direct foreign

investment? Evidence from panel data from Morocco. Journal of Development

Economics 42(1):51-74.

Hall, B. H., Jaffe, A. B., Trajtenberg, M. 2001. The NBER Patent Citation Data File:

Lessons, Insights and Methodological Tools. NBER Working Paper 8498.

Haskel, J., Pereira, S., Slaughter, M., 2002. Does inward foreign direct investment boost

the productivity of domestic firms? NBER Working Paper 8724.

Jaffe, A. B., Trajtenberg, M., Henderson, R. 1993. Geographic localization of knowledge

spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108: 577-598.

Jaffe, A.B., Trajtenberg, M. 2002. Patents, Citations, and Innovations: A Window on the

Knowledge Economy, MIT Press: Cambridge and London.

Javorcik, B. 2004. Does foreign direct investment increase the productivity of domestic

firms? In search of spillovers through backward linkages. American Economic Review

94 (3):605– 627.

Kaufmann, A.K., Mastruzzi, M. 2009. Governance Matters VIII: Aggregate and

individual governance indicators, 1996-2008. World Bank Policy Research Working

Paper 4978.

Kee, H. L. 2015. Local intermediate inputs and the shared supplier spillovers of foreign

direct investment. Journal of Development Economics 112: 56-71.

Page 24: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

23

Keller, W. 2002. Geographic localization of international technology diffusion. American

Economic Review 92: 120-142.

Keller, W., Yeaple, S., 2003. Multinational enterprises, international trade, and

productivity growth: firm-level evidence from the United States. NBER Working Paper

9504.

Kogut, B., Zander, U. 1993. Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of the

multinational corporation. Journal of International Business Studies 24: 625-645.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R. 1999. The Quality of

Government. Journal of Law, Economics and Organizations 15: 222-279.

Liebetrau, Albert M. 1983. Measures of Association, Beverly Hills, USA: Sage

Publications Inc.

Lileeva, A., Trefler, D. 2010. Improved access to foreign markets raises plant

productivity... for some plants. Quarterly Journal of Economics 125: 1051-1099.

MacGarvie, M. 2006. Do firms learn from international trade? Review of Economics and

Statistics 88: 46-60.

Rogers, E., J. Larsen. 1984. Silicon Valley fever. Basic Books, New York.

Romer, P. 1990. Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98:

S71-S102.

Singh, J. 2007. Asymmetry of knowledge spillovers between MNCs and host country

firms. Journal of International Business Studies 38: 764-786

Song, J., Shin, J. 2008. The paradox of technological capabilities: a study of knowledge

sourcing from host countries of overseas R&D operations. Journal of International

Business Studies 39: 291-303.

Thompson, P. 2006. Patent citations and the geography of knowledge spillovers:

evidence from inventor- and examiner-added citations. Review of Economics and

Statistics 88: 383-389.

Thompson, P., Fox-Kean, M. 2005. Patent citations and the geography of knowledge

spillovers: a reassessment. American Economic Review 95: 450-460.

Van Biesebroeck, J. 2005. Exporting raises productivity in sub-Saharan African

manufacturing firms, Journal of International Economics 67: 373-391.

Von Hippel, E. 1988. Sources of innovation. Oxford University Press, New York.

Page 25: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

24

Zhao, M. 2006. Conducting R&D in countries with weak intellectual property rights

protection. Management Science 56(7): 1185-99.

Page 26: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

25

FIGURES

Figure 1: Chinese Indigenous and Offshored Patent Counts by Application Year

Notes: The figure presents indigenous and offshored patent counts in the four technology

subcategories with the most patenting activity in China. Indigenous patents are patents

with all local (Chinese) inventors and a local assignee, while offshored patents are patents

with at least one local inventor and a foreign assignee. We observe that for each of these

sectors, innovation by multinationals seems to precede indigenous innovation.

020

40

60

80

Nu

mbe

r of P

ate

nts

1985 1990 1995 2000Year

Indigenous Patent Counts

Offshored Patent Counts

Electrical Devices

010

20

30

40

Nu

mbe

r of P

ate

nts

1985 1990 1995 2000Year

Indigenous Patent Counts

Offshored Patent Counts

Power Systems

05

10

15

Nu

mbe

r of P

ate

nts

1985 1990 1995 2000Year

Indigenous Patent Counts

Offshored Patent Counts

Drugs

05

10

15

20

Nu

mbe

r of P

ate

nts

1985 1990 1995 2000Year

Indigenous Patent Counts

Offshored Patent Counts

Computer Hardware and Software

Page 27: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

26

Figure 2: Illustration of Methodology Using Microsoft Corporation's U.S.

Headquarters and Chinese Subsidiary

Notes: I examine whether the treated patents’ proportion of citations that are from third

party patents in the host country (�̂�𝑇), is greater than the control patents’ proportion of

citations received from third party patents in the host country (�̂�𝐶). Treated patents

consist of the patents generated in the headquarters of a firm with a subsidiary in the host

country, while control patents are patents that are matched one to one to these treated

patents so as to be from the same country, application year, class, and to the extent

possible, subclass. The ratio �̂�𝑇/�̂�𝐶 is a measure of the MNE subsidiary's effect on

knowledge diffusion.

Page 28: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

27

Figure 3: Illustration of Truncation Using Patents Granted Between 1976 and 2004

Notes: The figure shows the average time between patent filing and granting by the

application year of the patents. Because the dataset includes patents granted up to the end

of 2004, the only 2004-filed patents that appear in the dataset are those granted within the

same year of filing. As a result, using patents filed in 2004 could introduce a selection

bias. The analysis is therefore conducted on patents with application years 2000 and

earlier where there is a relatively insignificant selection bias due to truncation.

0.5

11.5

22.5

Avera

ge

Dela

y in

Gra

nting

1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005Application Year

Average Delay Between Patent Filing and Granting

Page 29: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

28

Figure 4: Methodology for Computing τa Between Lagged Offshore Patent Counts

and Indigenous Patent Counts

Notes: D_OC2, D_OC3, D_IC4, and D_IC5 are the difference between the patent counts in

subsequent periods for offshored and indigenous patents, respectively. The association

measure τ is then computed on these first differences according to

𝜏 = {

1 𝑖𝑓 (𝐷𝑂𝐶2 − 𝐷𝑂𝐶3)(𝐷𝐼𝐶4 − 𝐷𝐼𝐶5) > 0

0 𝑖𝑓 (𝐷𝑂𝐶2 − 𝐷𝑂𝐶3)(𝐷𝐼𝐶4 − 𝐷𝐼𝐶5) = 0

−1 𝑖𝑓 (𝐷𝑂𝐶2 − 𝐷𝑂𝐶3)(𝐷𝐼𝐶4 − 𝐷𝐼𝐶5) < 0

}

The statistic of interest is 𝜏̅, the average τ across all non-zero τ values within a group of

countries (emerging, middle-income, or developed) across all technology classes. A

positive statistic suggests that for that group of countries, offshored innovation promotes

indigenous innovation.

Page 30: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

TABLES

Table 1: Control Variable Descriptions

Variable Description Unit of Observation Source

GDP Per Capita GDP per capita at current prices in U.S. Dollars Country/Year

(215 countries, 1970-2004)

UN Statistics Division

Geographic Distance Great Circle distances between capital cities of MNE

headquarters and subsidiary countries in thousands of

kilometers

Country pair

(9045 country pairs)

Jon Haveman†

Shared Language Indicator for whether the MNE headquarters and

subsidiary countries share the same primary language

Country pair

(14028 country pairs)

Jon Haveman†

Shared Legal Origin Indicator for whether the legal origin of the MNE

headquarters and subsidiary countries are the same

(among British, French, German, Scandinavian,

Socialist)

Country pair

(22,366 country pairs)

Laporta et al. (1999)

Largest City Population

Percentage

Population of largest city as a percentage of the

country's urban population

Country/Year

(118 countries, 1960-2004)

World Bank Urban

Development

Telephone Lines Fixed telephone lines per 100 inhabitants Country/Year

(211 countries, 1975-2004)

UN World Telecom/ICT

Indicators Data

Internet Penetration Estimated Internet users per 100 inhabitants Country/Year

(206 countries, 1990-2004*)

UN World Telecom/ICT

Indicators Data

IP Rights Index of intellectual property rights Country/Year

(120 countries, 1960-1995)

Ginarte and Park (1997)

Infrastructure Infrastructure quality index Country

(60 countries)

Laporta et al. (1999)

Rule of Law Rule of law index for 1996 Country

(171 countries)

World Bank Governance

Matters VIII

Corruption Index of corruption Country

(126 countries)

Laporta et al. (1999)

*I extend the Internet Penetration variable to earlier years by assuming zero Internet penetration prior to 1990.

†http://www.macalester.edu/research/economics/page/haveman/trade.resources/tradedata.html

Page 31: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

Table 2: Summary Statistics

Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max.

Patent Stock Per Capita 2.33e-06 5.63e-06 0 .000838

GDP Per Capita 15532 10387 72.5 102246

Geographic Distance 7322 3995 174 19007

Shared Language .212 .409 0 1

Shared Legal Origin .303 .460 0 1

Largest City Population % 28.8 18.6 2.6 101.8

Telephone Lines 21.1 20.1 .07 89.20

Internet Penetration 3.35 10.03 0 81.00

IP Rights 2.67 .872 0 4.86

Infrastructure 7.30 1.48 2.5 9.15

Rule of Law 1.40 .809 -1.57 2.17

Corruption 8.29 1.75 1.67 10

Table 3: Magnitude of MNE Subsidiary Effect on Knowledge Diffusion to Host

Country

All

Countries

Emerging

Countries

Middle-Inc.

Countries

Developed

Countries

% Treated Matching 3.52 0.023 0.58 5.37

% Controls Matching 3.06 0.019 0.51 4.67

t-statistic 144.13 7.89 23.10 141.75

Effect 1.15 1.25 1.15 1.15

N - Treated Citations 60,469,336 11,272,109 10,144,120 38,443,828

N - Control Citations 63,959,472 12,158,719 10,547,492 40,618,492

Notes: The first column shows that while 3.52% of the citations received by headquarter

(treated) patents are from third parties in their subsidiary’s host country, only 3.06% of

the citations received by the control patents are from that same country. The ratio of the

two is 1.15, suggesting that host country firms receive on average 15% more knowledge

from the headquarters as a result of having the subsidiary. We note that the effect of the

subsidiary on knowledge diffusion is largest for emerging host countries (column 2).

Page 32: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

31

Table 4: Classification of Countries

Emerging Countries Middle-Income

Countries

Developed Countries

Argentina Hong Kong Canada

Brazil Israel France

China South Korea Germany

Hungary Singapore Italy

India Taiwan Japan

Malaysia Netherlands

Mexico Sweden

Poland Switzerland

South Africa U.K.

Venezuela

Notes: Countries are classified according to their 1990 per capita GDP at current U.S.

dollars. Countries with per capita GDP of less than $5000 are classified as emerging,

between $5000 and $15,000 as middle-income, and above $15,000 as developed.

Although all 121 countries are used in the analysis, for illustrative purposes only those

with the most patenting activity are included in the table.

Page 33: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

32

Table 5: Difference in Differences Estimation of Subsidiary Effect

Dependent variable: match_ratioi

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

0 year

window

1 year

window

2 year

window

5 year

window

10 year

window

15 year

window

Treated .00145*** .00130*** .00128*** .00130*** .00104*** .000765**

(.00029) (.00028) (.00029) (.00031) (.00029) (.00030)

Post Subsidiary .0229*** .0236*** .0241*** .0251*** .0261*** .0279***

(.0032) (.0032) (.0033) (.0034) (.0036) (.0039)

Treated*Post Sub .00241*** .00253*** .00256*** .00241*** .00258*** .00276***

(.00048) (.00049) (.00049) (.00051) (.00056) (.00064)

Clustering by Firm Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Robust Std Errors Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Observations 15,154,131 14,509,815 13,938,391 12,532,913 10,780,629 9,293,737

R-Squared .0056 .0056 .0055 .0049 .0035 .0023

Standard Errors in Parentheses

*p<0.05, **p<0.01, ***p<0.001

Notes: The regression is at the level of the patent, with treated (headquarters) and their

associated control patents being separate observations. The dependent variable,

match_ratio, is the proportion of the patent’s citations that are from third-party patents in

the subsidiary’s location. Treated is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the patent was

generated by the headquarters and 0 if the patent is a control. Post subsidiary is equal to

1 when the patent’s application year is after the subsidiary’s first patent application, and

equal to 0 otherwise. Since the subsidiary’s first patent application year will invariably

be some time after the subsidiary has been established, I drop from the sample some of

the years directly before the first patent application (since it is not clear whether these

should be considered pre or post). The different columns present the results when

dropping increasingly large windows from the analysis. As expected, the coefficient on

treated decreases with the window size and the coefficient on the interaction term

increases. Overall, the results suggest that the large majority of the observed subsidiary

effect is due to knowledge flows through the subsidiary and not to firms establishing

subsidiaries in locations where third-party firms already disproportionately cite them.

Page 34: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

33

Table 6: Host Country Characteristics and Magnitude of MNE Subsidiary Effect on

Knowledge Diffusion (�̂�𝑻-�̂�𝑪) - No Country Fixed Effects

Dependent variable: (�̂�𝑇-�̂�𝐶)

(1) (2) (3)

Ln(1+Patent Stock Per Capita) 1558*** 1558*** 1558*

(401) (278) (691)

Ln(1+Patent Stock Per Capita) ^2 -1.57E7*** -1.57E7*** -1.57E7*

(3.81E6) (2.87E6) (6.58E6)

Ln(GDP Per Capita) -.0104* -.0104* -.0104

(.0045) (.0045) (.0061)

Ln(GDP Per Capita) ^2 -.000838** -.000838* -.000838

(.000312) (.000329) (.000422)

Geographic Distance .000081 .000081 .000081

(.000086) (.000072) (.000169)

Shared Language .00336*** .00336*** .00336

(.00102) (.00079) (.00227)

Shared Legal Origin -.00245** -.00245*** -.00245

(.00085) (.00065) (.00162)

Largest City Population % .000119*** .000119*** .000119

(.000025) (.000025) (.000092)

Telephone Lines -.000247*** -.000247*** -.000247*

(.000055) (.000059) (.000115)

Internet Penetration -.00186 -.00186** -.00186*

(.00098) (.00061) (.00070)

IP Rights .000002 .000002 .000002

(.000525) (.000511) (.001369)

Infrastructure .00220** .00220** .00220

(.00073) (.00070) (.00192)

Rule of Law -.00338*** -.00338** -.00338

(.00099) (.00111) (.00413)

Corruption -.000060 -.00006 -.00006

(.000550) (.00044) (.00117)

Year, Class Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Country Fixed Effects No No No

Clustering Country/Class Country/Year Country

Robust Standard Errors Yes Yes Yes

Observations 4,059,850 4,059,850 4,059,850

R-squared .0021 .0021 .0021

Standard Errors in Parentheses

*p<0.05, **p<0.01, ***p<0.001

Page 35: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

34

Table 7: Host Country Characteristics and Magnitude of MNE Subsidiary Effect on

Knowledge Diffusion (�̂�𝑻-�̂�𝑪) - Country Fixed Effects

Dependent variable: (�̂�𝑇-�̂�𝐶)

(1) (2) (3) Tobit

Ln(1+Patent Stock Per Capita) 1719*** 1719** 1736***

(379) (617) (44)

Ln(1+Patent Stock Per Capita) ^2 -1.67E7*** -1.67E7** -1.69E7***

(3.45E6) (5.57E6) (6.47E5)

Ln(GDP Per Capita) .0009 .0009 .0008

(.0075) (.0047) (.0029)

Ln(GDP Per Capita) ^2 -.000112 -.000112 -.000107

(.000454) (.000271) (.000159)

Geographic Distance -.000116 -.000116 -.000117***

(.000114) (.000078) (.000035)

Shared Language .00300* .00300 .00302***

(.00141) (.00187) (.00048)

Shared Legal Origin -.00149 -.00149 -.00150***

(.00106) (.00168) (.00034)

Largest City Population % -.00009 -.00009 -.0000881

(.00017) (.00016) (.0000861)

Telephone Lines .000060 .000060 .000060

(.000085) (.000058) (.000033)

Internet Penetration -.000355 -.000355 -.000362**

(.000987) (.000744) (.000115)

IP Rights -.000844 -.000844 -.000860

(.000827) (.000593) (.000486)

Year, Class Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Country Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Clustering Country/Class Country Pair No

Robust Standard Errors Yes Yes No

Observations 4,183,122 4,183,122 4,183,122

R-squared .0031 .0031 -.0041

Standard Errors in Parentheses

*p<0.05, **p<0.01, ***p<0.001

Page 36: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

35

Table 8: Host Country Characteristics and Magnitude of MNE Subsidiary Effect on

Knowledge Diffusion (�̂�𝑻/�̂�𝑪)

Dependent variable: (�̂�𝑇/�̂�𝐶)

(1) (2) (3)

Ln(1+Patent Stock Per Capita) 35056*** 35056*** 32,693***

(4623) (8674) (4862)

Ln(1+Patent Stock Per Capita) ^2 -4.31E8*** -4.31E8** -3.47E8***

(9.22E7) (1.48E8) (9.8E7)

Ln(GDP Per Capita) .761*** .761 1.43***

(.222) (.560) (.31)

Ln(GDP Per Capita) ^2 -.0372** -.0372 -.0686***

.0140 .0301 (.0168)

Geographic Distance .00701*** .00701 .00155

(.00199) (.00461) (.00246)

Shared Language .269*** .269*** .201***

(.026) (.066) (.028)

Shared Legal Origin -.153*** -.153*** -.118***

(.020) (.031) (.021)

Largest City Population % .00255*** .00255 .0174

(.00067) (.00151) (.0112)

Telephone Lines -.00484*** -.00484 -.00205

(.00120) (.00341) (.00271)

Internet Penetration -.0218** -.0218 -.0103

(.0065) (.0114) (.0071)

IP Rights .203*** .203* .153*

(.021) (.088) (.072)

Infrastructure .295*** .295***

(.011) (.039)

Rule of Law -.201*** -.201

(.045) (.209)

Corruption -.162*** -.162

(.019) (.082)

Year, Class Fixed Effects Yes Yes Yes

Country Fixed Effects No No Yes

Clustering Country/Class Country Country/Class

Robust Standard Errors Yes Yes Yes

Observations 505,775 505,775 506,095

R-squared .0387 .0387 .0408

Standard Errors in Parentheses

*p<0.05, **p<0.01, ***p<0.001

Page 37: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

36

Table 9: Expatriates and Magnitude of MNE Subsidiary Effect on Knowledge

Diffusion

Dependent variable: (�̂�𝑇/�̂�𝐶)

(1) (2) (3)

Expatriates -.278*** -.244** -.363

(.074) (.081) (.193)

Subsidiary Patent Count (1000s) -.247 .122 .077

(.159) (.194) (.215)

Headquarters Patent Count (1000s) -.0222*** -.0205**

(.0065) (.0070)

Firm Number of Locations .0114 -.0029

(.0065) (.0078)

Host Country Fixed Effects No Yes Yes

Firm Fixed Effects No No Yes

Clustering by Firm Yes Yes Yes

Robust Standard Errors Yes Yes Yes

Observations 8181 8181 5665

R-squared .0019 .0204 .3464

Standard Errors in Parentheses

*p<0.05, **p<0.01, ***p<0.001

Notes: The regression is at the level of the subsidiary. Subsidiaries with more expatriates,

as measured by the fraction of subsidiary inventors that previously patented while living

in the country of the headquarters, decrease knowledge flow through the subsidiary. The

decrease associated with expatriates remains significant (at the 10% level) even when

controlling for host country and firm fixed effects.

Page 38: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

37

Table 10a: Relationship Between Offshore and Indigenous Patent Counts by

Country Group - 25% of Patent Technology Classes with Most Emerging Country

Activity.

Country

Group

Offshore Patents Promoting

Indigenous Patents

Indigenous Patents Promoting

Offshore Patents

𝜏̅ n p 𝜏̅ n p

Emerging 0.16* 159 0.028 0.06 156 0.236

Middle Inc. 0.08 215 0.138 -0.02 231 0.347

Developed 0.02 904 0.286 -0.06* 916 0.035

Table 10b: Relationship Between Offshore and Indigenous Patent Counts by

Country Group - 50% of Patent Technology Classes with Most Emerging Country

Activity.

Country

Group

Offshore Patents Promoting

Indigenous Patents

Indigenous Patents Promoting

Offshore Patents

𝜏̅ n p 𝜏̅ n p

Emerging 0.13* 196 0.037 0.08 206 0.148

Middle Inc. 0.07 340 0.106 0.02 387 0.380

Developed -0.01 1612 0.283 0.00 1656 0.451

Table 10c: Relationship Between Offshore and Indigenous Patent Counts by

Country Group - All Patent Technology Classes with Most Emerging Country

Activity.

Country

Group

Offshore Patents Promoting

Indigenous Patents

Indigenous Patents Promoting

Offshore Patents

𝜏̅ n p 𝜏̅ n P

Emerging 0.14* 208 0.022 0.09 225 0.091

Middle Inc. 0.06 424 0.112 0.01 488 0.410

Developed -0.01 2391 0.270 0.01 2509 0.302

Notes: Tables 10a, 10b, and 10c examine the relationship between offshore patents and

indigenous patents, for the 25% of patent classes with the most emerging country

patenting activity, the 50% with the most activity, and all patent classes, respectively.

The first panel examines whether offshore patents are correlated with future indigenous

patents, and the second panel examines the converse. The table presents 𝜏̅ (the average

measure of association), n (the number of country/class combinations over which 𝜏̅ was

computed) and the p-value associated with the two-sided hypothesis test that 𝜏̅ is

significantly different from zero. The results support the hypothesis that offshored

innovation promotes indigenous innovation in emerging countries, while the converse is

not true. This relationship is furthermore not present in middle income and developed

countries.

Page 39: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

38

Appendix A: Measures of Association

Measures of association can be classified according to the requirements they place

on the data. While some measures have been developed to examine the association of

nominal variables, others are designed for ordinal or even continuous data. The table

below presents some of the most commonly used measures classified according to the

lowest data requirement. For example, while Cramer’s V can be applied on nominal,

ordinal, or continuous data, Kendall’s τa is only applicable to cases where both variables

are continuous. Hence, measures requiring only nominal data are more generally

applicable. However, when analyzing data that is not nominal, they have less power than

a measure that is designed specifically for the data type in question since they ignore

information.

Classification of Most Commonly Used Measures of Association

Nominal Variables Ordinal Variables Continuous Variables

Pearson Chi-Square

Likelihood ratio Chi-Square

Cramer’s V

Kendall’s τb

Goodman-Kruskal γ

Somer’s d

Correlation (ρ)

Kendall’s τa

Spearman’s ρs

The most commonly used continuous measure is Correlation (ρ). This measure (ρ)

is the best choice when the variables in question are normally distributed. Otherwise,

Kendall’s τa or Spearman’s ρs may be a better choice (Liebetrau, 1983).

Kendall’s τa is computed by considering every possible pair of observations in the

dataset and determining whether that pair is concordant, discordant, or tied. A pair of

observations (Xi, Yi) and (Xj, Yj) is said to be concordant if either Xi < Xj and Yi < Yj or Xi >

Xj and Yi > Yj. Similarly a pair is discordant if either Xi < Xj and Yi > Yj or Xi > Xj and Yi

< Yj. Observation pairs for which either Xi = Xj or Yi = Yj are said to be tied. Hence,

Kendall’s τa is simply a measure of the total number of concordant pairs minus the total

number of discordant pairs, divided by the total number of pairs in the dataset:

𝜏𝑎 =2(𝐶 − 𝐷)

𝑛(𝑛 − 1)

Page 40: FDI and indigenous innovation: Foreign R&D subsidiaries as a … · 2015-07-09 · 1 1. Introduction Multinational enterprises (MNEs) are increasingly conducting their R&D in emerging

39

where n is the total number of observations, C is the total number of concordant pairs,

and D is the total number of discordant pairs.

By definition, -1 ≤ τa ≤ 1. If the two variables in question are monotonically

related, then τa=-1 or τa=1, depending on whether the relationship is positive or negative.

These end values can only be reached if no pair of observations in the data is tied. Hence,

for discrete data (such as patent counts), it is best to take ties into consideration. In

particular, we would like a measure where the denominator (total number of pairs)

decreases along with the numerator when there are ties. To account for this, Kendall

developed a related measure with an adjusted denominator called τb:

τ𝑏 =𝐶 − 𝐷

[((𝑛2) − 𝑈) ((𝑛

2) − 𝑉)]

12⁄

where n, C, and D are defined as before. U is the total number of observation pairs not

counted in computing C-D because of tied X values. Similarly, V is the total number of

observation pairs not counted in computing C-D because of tied Y values. Hence,

although the numerators of τb and τa are the same, the denominator of τb is the geometric

mean of the total number of pairs with distinct X values and the total number of pairs

with distinct Y values. Although neither τa nor τb are able to achieve their extreme values

of -1 or 1 when ties are present, the range of τb is the less restricted of the two.