Final JIMF Paper

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    1/25

    Risk factor and industry effects in the cross-country

    comovement of momentum returns

    Andy Naranjo a,*, Burt Porter b

    a University of Florida, Warrington College of Business, Department of Finance, P.O. Box 117168, Gainesville, FL 32611-7168, USAb Iowa State University, College of Business, 3345 Gerdin Business Building, Ames, IA 50011-1350, USA

    JEL classification:

    G12

    G15

    Keywords:

    International return momentum

    Comovement

    Asset pricing

    Risk factors

    Industry effects

    Integration

    a b s t r a c t

    This paper examines the sources of cross-country comovement of

    momentum returns over the 19752004 period. Using data on

    more than 17,000 individual firms across 100 industries from 40

    countries, we document the profitability of country-neutral indi-

    vidual firm, industry, and industry-adjusted return momentum.

    We show that country-neutral momentum returns are signifi-cantly correlated across countries, the correlation is time-varying,

    and that comovement among industries cannot explain the

    comovement of country-neutral momentum returns. However, we

    find that standard risk factor models do explain a significant

    portion of the cross-country comovement of momentum returns,

    even though they do not explain average momentum returns.

    Published by Elsevier Ltd.

    1. Introduction

    Over the past decade, numerous researchers have provided evidence on the profitability of

    momentum trading strategies in both the U.S. and many other countries around the world (e.g.,

    Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993, 2001; Rouwenhorst, 1998, 1999; Chui et al., 2003; Griffin et al., 2003).

    While there is strong evidence that momentum strategies earn positive profits, there is no consensus as

    to the source of these profits. In this paper, we provide evidence consistent with the existence of

    systematic risk exposure of momentum portfolio returns by investigating the sources of the

    comovement of country-neutral momentum returns across developed and emerging markets.1

    * Corresponding author. Tel.: 1 (352) 392 3781; fax: 1 (352) 392 0301.

    E-mail address: [email protected] (A. Naranjo).1 Country-neutral momentum is defined as a zero-cost investment strategy long recent winners and short recent losers

    where winners and losers are defined relative to all stocks within a specific country. Factor betas are likely to differ between

    long and short portfolios, so country-neutral does not imply factor-neutral.

    Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

    Journal of International Money

    and Financej o u r n a l h o m e p a g e : w w w . e l s e v i e r . c o m / l o c a t e / j i m f

    0261-5606/$ see front matter Published by Elsevier Ltd.

    doi:10.1016/j.jimonfin.2009.06.007

    Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299

    mailto:[email protected]://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/02615606http://www.elsevier.com/locate/jimfhttp://www.elsevier.com/locate/jimfhttp://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/02615606mailto:[email protected]
  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    2/25

    The comovement of country-neutral momentum returns is a puzzle that is closely related to the prof-

    itability of momentum trading strategies. Rouwenhorst (1998) finds that European and U.S. momentum

    returns have a correlation of 0.43 during the 19801995 period and that by conditioning the returns of

    a European momentum strategy on the returns to a U.S.-only strategy, the average return of the European

    momentum portfolio is reduced from 0.93 to 0.65 percent per month, implying a common component to

    the two series.2 Rouwenhorst (1998) argues that these results could be consistent with a momentum factorin returns, but the dependence could also be due to non-zero exposures to other common priced factors

    (such as SMB), common unpriced factors (industry factors) or a combination of both.

    In this paper, we examine the extent to which the comovement in momentum returns is driven by

    systematic risk factors. To investigate the sources of cross-country comovement of momentum returns,

    we assemble a large data set that consists of more than 17,000 individual firms across 100 industries

    from 40 developed and emerging markets over the 19752004 period. Using momentum portfolio

    sorts, we examine the profitability and cross-country comovement of unadjusted, industry-adjusted,

    and risk-adjusted momentum returns across countries and over time.

    We show that country-neutral momentum strategies are profitable for both developed and

    emerging markets, yielding an average of 54 and 75 basis points per month respectively over the 1975

    2004 sample period. This result is consistent with the international evidence presented by Rou-wenhorst (1998, 1999) and Griffin et al. (2003). We also find both an industry momentum effect and

    a firm momentum effect independent of industry for individual countries and on average across

    developed countries using country-neutral momentum strategies. In contrast, for the emerging market

    countries, we do not find significant industry momentum effects, though we do find significant firm

    effects independent of industry. Using both domestic and global versions of a single factor market

    model and of a Fama-French three factor model, we confirm that simple risk factor models generally do

    a poor job of explaining the level of momentum returns in both developed and emerging markets.

    We find that the payoffs to country-neutral momentum returns are significantly correlated across

    countries. This relationship is positive and time varying, with a small average correlation in the early

    1980s and an increasing average correlation in the 1990s through early 2000s. Conditioning on

    industry versus firm independent of industry momentum effects, we find that comovement amongindustries cannot explain the comovement of country-neutral momentum returns. However, we

    provide evidence that common asset pricing models explain a large portion of the comovement of

    country-neutral momentum returns. We find that the rational determinants of value explain the cross-

    country comovement of momentum returns, even though these very same rational determinants are

    unable to explain the level of momentum returns. That is, the correlation of known risk factor payoffs

    across countries induces correlated time varying factor loadings in country-neutral momentum

    strategies that in turn induce cross country correlation in momentum portfolio payoffs. While standard

    factor models are unsuccessful in explaining average momentum returns, they are successful in

    explaining a large part of the cross-country comovement of momentum returns.

    The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 provides a brief review of the momentum

    literature. Section 3 describes our methodology and data. Section 4 documents the cross-countryevidence on the profitability of country-neutral momentum returns, while Section 5 examines cross-

    country comovement of momentum returns. Section 6 provides evidence on risk factor and

    momentum return comovement across countries. Section 7 concludes.

    2. Momentum returns and comovement: the literature

    Many researchers have documented the profitability of momentum trading strategies in both

    developed and emerging markets. For example, using U.S. data, Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) find that

    a strategy that is long recent winners and short recent losers earns statistically significant average

    2 In contrast to Rouwenhorst (1998), Griffin et al. (2003) report low intraregional and interregional correlations of

    momentum profits, although these correlations are not the focus of their paper. However, we find that the averaging of

    country-neutral momentum profits within and across regions, across developed and emerging markets, and over time

    significantly attenuates country-neutral momentum return correlations resulting in low correlations similar to those reported

    by Griffin, Ji, and Martin.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299276

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    3/25

    returns of 0.95% per month over the 19651989 period. In later work,Jegadeesh and Titman (2001) find

    similar results using U.S. data from 1990 to 1998, suggesting the earlier result was not a manifestation of

    datamining. In terms of international evidence, Rouwenhorst (1998) finds significant momentum profits

    for 11 of 12 European countries, Chui et al. (2003) find mixed results for 8 Asian countries, and Rou-

    wenhorst (1999) finds mixed results for 20 emerging markets. Rouwenhorst (1998) also finds that

    country-neutral momentum returns are highly correlated across markets.Much research has also focused on explaining why momentum trading strategies are so widely

    profitable. Jegadeesh (1990), Lo and MacKinlay (1990), andJegadeesh and Titman (1993) show that the

    source of momentum profits can be decomposed into three different components: the cross-sectional

    dispersion in expected returns, momentum in systematic factors, and momentum in the idiosyncratic

    component of security returns (i.e., over-reaction/under-reaction component). With this framework

    as a backdrop, two lines of research have emerged in the investigation of momentum profits: one based

    on rational models and the other based on behavioral models.3

    Within the rational paradigm, the profitability of moment strategies arises from compensation for

    risk. Conrad and Kaul (1998) argue that momentum profits reflect cross-sectional variation in expected

    returns rather than predictable time-series variation in stock returns. They argue that the momentum

    strategys average profits reflect the result of buying (on average) high mean return stocks and selling(on average) low mean return stocks. If the cross-sectional differences in the mean returns reflect

    expected returns, then the momentum profits can be attributed to cross-sectional differences in risk

    characteristics (i.e., common identified or as yet unidentified priced risk factors).4 If common risk

    factors play a role in explaining momentum profits and the risk factor is correlated across countries,

    then country-neutral momentum returns will be correlated in a manner consistent with risk-based

    explanations. This correlation in momentum returns across markets will also likely have time-varying

    characteristics to the extent that markets have become more integrated over time.

    When testing risk-based explanations of momentum profits, many authors find that the estimated

    coefficients from regressions of momentum returns on commonly used risk factors are indistin-

    guishable from zero and often have the wrong sign. However, Grundy and Martin (2001) show that

    momentum portfolios by their very nature have time varying factor coefficients, so a simple exami-nation of the factor loadings of the long and short portfolios is misleading. After controlling explicitly

    for the time variation in the factor loadings, Grundy and Martin (2001) show that risk-based models

    still do not explain positive average momentum returns.

    Industry effects are also a potential source of common risk, and hence are a good candidate for

    understanding the source of country-neutral momentum returns and their comovement.5 For instance,

    comovement of industry portfolio returns due to common fundamentals may result in similar industry

    concentrations in the long and short momentum portfolios across countries, inducing comovement in

    country-neutral momentum portfolios. Grinblatt and Moskowitz (1999) provide evidence suggesting

    3 The behavioral models suggest that momentum profits arise from inherent biases in the way that investors interpretinformation (e.g., Barberis et al., 1998; Daniel et al., 1998; Hong and Stein, 1999). Each of these models addresses particular

    constraints on investor rationality that cause an under-reaction of prices to information in the short-run, thereby producing

    return persistence. Brav and Heaton (2002) distinguish between behavioral models and rational structural uncertainty models

    where investors are rational but have imperfect information, and they find that each class of model has similar implications for

    asset pricing and therefore provides an explanation for the momentum effect. While the behavioral models attempt to explain

    the level of momentum profits, they do not address implications for the comovement of country-neutral momentum strategies.

    In order for the comovement evidence to be consistent with the behavioral models, the information about firm value to which

    investors underreact must be correlated across markets.4 Many researchers have examined various factors as potential explanations for momentum profits. These include market

    beta, firm size, book-to-market, cash-flow-to-price, business cycles, and macroeconomic risks among others (see, for instance,

    Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993; Fama and French,1996; Carhart, 1997; Daniel et al., 1997; Grinblatt and Moskowitz,1999; Chordia

    and Shivakumar, 2002; Griffin et al., 2003).5 Industry factors can be viewed as a catch-all risk proxy or an unpriced factor. Barberis et al. (2005), argue that industry

    factors in returns are at least in part due to industry-level common factors in cash flows, resulting in fundamentals-induced

    comovement. However, to the extent that investors employ common industry asset allocation strategies across countries, the

    comovement can also be category-induced. Behavioral underpinnings can also play a role in determining industry sources of

    momentum effects and their comovement to the extent that there is slow information diffusion within industries and across

    countries (see Hou, 2007; Hong et al., 2000; Chan et al., 1996).

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299 277

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    4/25

    that momentum in industry risk factors explains the profitability of momentum strategies. That is,

    momentum profits in individual stocks disappear after controlling for industry effects. However,

    Grundy and Martin (2001) and Asness et al. (2001) find that the profitability of momentum strategies is

    not fully explained by industry risk exposure. In particular, Grundy and Martin (2001) find that neither

    industry effects nor cross-sectional differences in expected returns explain the level of momentum

    profits. Rather, the strategies profitability reflects momentum in the stock-specific (idiosyncratic)component of returns. Asness et al. (2001) also find both an industry effect and a firm effect inde-

    pendent of industry in momentum.

    In recent work on the general comovement of security returns, Barberis et al. (2005) argue that there

    are three explanations for the observed comovement among different securities: fundamentals-induced,

    category-induced, and habitat-induced comovement. The fundamental approach explains the comove-

    ment of securities by positive correlations in the rational determinants of their values. Category-induced

    comovement occurs when investors classify different securities into the same asset class and shift

    resources in and out of this class in correlated ways. Habitat-induced comovement arises when a group of

    investors restricts its trading to a given set of securities and moves in and out of that set in tandem.

    Consistent with the earlier research, these three explanations also suggest that comovement of securities

    arises from fundamental factors, behavioral/mechanically-induced factors, or a combination of both.The fundamentals-induced comovement explanation proposed by Barberis et al. (2005) suggest that

    the payoffs of country-neutral momentum portfolios should be correlated if momentum portfolios are

    exposed to one or more risk factors and markets are integrated. That is, we would expect to see cross-

    countrycomovement in the payoffsto country-neutralmomentum strategies whenmarkets are integrated

    and if momentum returns are compensation for systematic risk or if momentum returns have a behavioral

    or mechanical interpretation but share a common exposure to an unpriced risk factor. When markets are

    not integrated, we would expect little or no comovement in country-neutral momentum returns.

    The comovement in country-neutral momentum returns could also arise from the habitat or

    category-induced comovement caused by institutional traders pursuing international momentum

    trading strategies across countries or within industries across countries. A pervasive behavioral bias

    might also induce comovement in momentum returns with a common unpriced risk factor exposure ifinformation flows to which investors over/under react are correlated across markets. Since cross

    country institutional trading data is not available over large sample periods and for most markets and

    measuring the information flows that induce behavioral biases is also problematic, our paper focuses

    on fundamentals-induced momentum return comovement.6

    3. Methodology and data

    3.1. Methodology

    We construct monthly relative strength momentum portfolios by ranking stocks within each

    country on their total return during the previous 12 months, omitting the month immediately prior.We refer to this variable as Past(2,12). Several papers find that skipping a month between portfolio

    ranking and investment periods avoids confounding bid/ask bounce and nonsyncronous trading

    effects. We define winning and losing stocks as those in the top and bottom three deciles, respectively.

    The self-financing momentum portfolio return is the return on an equally-weighted portfolio of

    winners less the equally-weighted portfolio of losers. For each portfolio strategy, we examine the

    average monthly profit from a strategy of buying a portfolio of winners and shorting a portfolio of

    losers and holding the position for 1 month.7 The portfolios are rebalanced monthly. Although our

    results are reported in local currency returns, U.S. dollar returns are similar.

    6 Froot et al. (2001), for instance, are able to acquire proprietary institutional international flow data for only a 4 12 year

    sample period from 1994 to 1998. They find that there is a small correlation in contemporaneous cross-country flows, which

    suggests that comovement in flows cannot explain comovement in momentum returns.7 As further robustness checks, we also employed FamaMacBeth regression techniques in place of momentum portfolio

    sorts, defined winners and losers as the top and bottom 10%, used value-weighting, and employed alternative prior month

    return ranking periods and alternative holding periods. In each case, we obtained similar results.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299278

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    5/25

    We first examine the profitability of unadjusted, industry-adjusted, and risk-adjusted momentum

    returns in both developed and emerging markets. We then examine the cross-country comovement

    of momentum returns associated with each of these components. To the extent that there are

    industry effects in momentum and industry returns are correlated across countries, the correlation

    in country neutral momentum returns could arise from across-country industry effects in

    momentum returns.

    3.2. Sample construction

    Our primary data source is the Thomson Datastream (TDS) database. TDS has return data for more

    than 30,000 firms in over 50 countries. Our initial sample includes all firms covered by TDS from

    January 1975 through December 2004. Following Ince and Porter (2006) who show that the TDS must

    be carefully screened, we screen our sample for issues other than common equity and for firms that are

    not traded on the countrys major exchange(s).8 To eliminate double counting and to isolate country

    effects, we also exclude all listings other than those on a firms home country exchange (i.e., cross-

    listings and depository receipts).9

    We also exclude from our portfolios any firm whose market capitalization is below the 25thpercentile market capitalization of all NYSE stocks, converted to the local currency, in any month

    during the ranking period. These firms are excluded to avoid significant liquidity constraints, to

    mitigate any survivorship bias problems, and as Ince and Porter (2006) demonstrate, because many of

    the difficulties encountered with TDS are concentrated in the smallest deciles. Since smaller stocks

    typically have higher volatility and we sort on past returns, our market capitalization screen may

    induce a bias against finding significant momentum returns. However, our country-neutral

    momentum results are consistent with those reported by Jegadeesh and Titman (1993, 2001), Rou-

    wenhorst (1998, 1999), Chui et al. (2003), and Griffin et al. (2003). Our reported conclusions are also

    robust to alternative capitalization screens.

    Emerging markets often report erroneous return data. Therefore, following Rouwenhorst (1999),

    we assign as missing returns below the 2.5 percentile and above the 97.5 percentile of the returndistribution for each emerging market in each month during the ranking period. Finally, to insure that

    we have a series of sufficient length to examine for evidence of comovement, we eliminate countries

    from the sample that have fewer than 30 valid momentum return months. Our momentum screens

    eliminate nine emerging market countries from the sample, leaving 17,449 firms representing 101

    industries and 40 countries over the 19752004 time period.10

    A strength of TDS is that they use the same criteria for defining industries across countries. As

    argued by Griffin and Stulz (2001), this consistent classification minimizes the risk of finding low cross-

    country industry comovement because of firm misclassification. Griffin and Karolyi (1998) argue that

    using broad industrial classifications leads to lumping together heterogeneous industries that often

    include widely disparate lines of business, which can mask the importance of industry effects. In our

    investigation, we use TDSs most disaggregated industry classification, level 6, which includesapproximately 100 separate industry definitions.11

    8 For example, in the U.S., we include only firms that trade on the NYSE, Amex, or Nasdaq and exclude such non-common

    equity issues as preferred stock, closed end funds, real estate trusts and investment companies.9 Cross-listings and depository receipts can induce a positive dependence in country-neutral momentum returns. For

    instance, Karolyi and Stulz (1996) find significant return comovements between depository receipts and share returns of the

    underlying security in the home market as well as aggregate market returns in the home market.10 Following the momentum screens, the nine emerging market countries dropped from the sample because they have less

    than 30 valid momentum return months are: Columbia, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Egypt, Hungary, Morocco, Pakistan, Peru, and

    Venezuela.11 As a robustness check, we compare industry results from the U.S. using the CRSP database with firms sorted into industries

    by their 4 digit SIC classification and using TDSs level six industry definitions. We obtain very similar results using either

    dataset. As a further robustness check, we also compare our results for individual countries with those from Rouwenhorst

    (1998, 1999) who uses a different data source. The results are similar.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299 279

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    6/25

    3.3. Summary statistics

    Table 1 reports summary statistics for our sample. There are 22 developed and 18 emerging market

    countries in our sample. Looking at the second column ofTable 1, we see that most of the start dates for

    the developed market countries begin in 1975, while the majority of the emerging markets begin in the

    late 1980s and early 1990s. The U.S., Japan, and the U.K. have the largest number of firms, the broadestindustry representation, and the largest market capitalizations of all the countries in our sample.

    Together, these three countries represent over 55% of the firms in the sample and 48% of December

    2004 market capitalization. Although much smaller on average, the larger emerging markets have both

    more firms and more industries than the smaller developed markets. Fig. 1 illustrates the overlap in

    market size between developed and emerging markets in our sample.12

    4. Cross-country evidence on the profitability of momentum returns

    4.1. Profitability of unadjusted momentum returns across countries

    The first three columns of Table 2 report unadjusted momentum profits for portfolios formed onwithin country Past(2,12) and held for 1 month. We report the average monthly return, t-statistic, and

    number of months with valid momentum returns, where a valid month is one in which both the long

    and short portfolios have at least three stocks. In the next set of columns, we report the difference in

    return between the portfolio of past winners and the local market return and the difference between

    the local market return and the portfolio of past losers.

    The results in Table 2 show significant momentum profits in many, but not all countries. We find

    that 14 of 22 developed and 5 of 18 emerging markets have a significant momentum effect in our

    sample period. Of the 13 developed markets that have data for the entire time period, only Japan, the

    second largest market, does not have a significant momentum effect. Chui et al. (2003) and Griffin et al.

    (2003) also find an insignificant momentum effect for Japan.13 We also do not find a significant

    momentum effect for several of the other Asian and Scandinavian countries. Although the proportion

    of emerging markets with significant momentum returns is much lower than for developed markets,

    this result is due in part to higher standard errors resulting from shorter time series and the smaller

    median number of firms in emerging markets. 10 of 18 emerging markets have higher average

    momentum returns than the smallest significant average return in the developed markets.

    To further examine developed versus emerging market returns, we create country-neutral

    momentum portfolios for all developed markets by forming an equally weighted portfolio of all stocks

    classified as winners when ranked within country and shorting all stocks classified as losers. We also

    form a similar portfolio for emerging markets. We find statistically significant average returns of 54

    basis points per month for the developed markets and 75 basis points per month for the emerging

    markets over our full sample. This higher average return for the emerging market portfolio comes from

    both higher returns on the long portfolio (10 basis points) and on the short portfolio (11 basis points).

    Returns from the loser portfolio exceed those of the winner portfolio for both developed and emerging

    markets, although the difference is only 6 basis points for developed markets and 7 basis points for

    emerging markets.14 Finally, the results reported at the bottom of each panel show that there is time

    variation in the magnitude of the momentum effect in both developed and emerging market countries.

    4.2. Industry and firm effects in momentum returns

    Firms within an industry may have similar exposure to both priced and unpriced risk factors. The

    extent to which industry effects are present in momentum returns can be a potential source of

    12 We omit three countries from Fig. 1: U.S. (6,036 firms), Japan (2,199) and U.K. (1,496). Each of these markets contains more

    than twice the number of firms than the largest country included in the figure.13 Though not reported, if we exclude the two largest countries (Japan and the U.S.) from our sample, both the magnitude and

    significance level of the average, country-neutral momentum effect increases.14 Bris et al. (2007), however, show that short selling is difficult to implement and not feasible in many markets.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299280

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    7/25

    comovement of country-neutral momentum returns. That is, if there are industry effects in momentum

    returns, similar industry concentrations in both long and short momentum portfolios across countries,

    and if industry returns significantly comove across countries, then country-neutral momentum returns

    would be correlated.

    Table 1

    Summary statistics by country: 19752004.

    Starting date Number of firms Number of

    industries

    Market capitalization

    (December 2004, $Bil)

    Developed markets

    Australia 1975:01 364 77 $632Austria 1975:01 107 40 $427

    Belgium 1975:01 124 49 $231

    Canada 1975:01 610 83 $883

    Denmark 1975:01 113 37 $134

    Finland 1987:01 100 45 $166

    France 1975:01 658 88 $1,535

    Germany 1975:01 622 80 $1,311

    Hong Kong 1975:01 384 69 $710

    Ireland 1975:01 46 29 $102

    Italy 1975:01 300 64 $725

    Japan 1975:01 2,199 89 $3,508

    Luxembourg 1991:03 30 17 $162

    Netherlands 1975:01 206 57 $583

    New Zealand 1986:01 45 28 $29

    Norway 1975:01 156 40 $126

    Singapore 1975:01 156 44 $192

    Spain 1986:01 167 52 $623

    Sweden 1975:01 316 61 $330

    Switzerland 1975:01 403 69 $131

    UK 1975:01 1,496 95 $2,586

    USA 1975:01 6,036 101 $14,192

    All developed 14,638 $29,318

    Emerging markets

    Argentina 1992:01 47 22 $31

    Brazil 1993:01 151 42 $163Chile 1989:07 86 32 $82

    Greece 1988:01 211 56 $93

    India 1988:07 324 59 $285

    Indonesia 1990:04 133 39 $50

    Israel 1989:11 48 25 $56

    Korea 1980:10 304 65 $330

    Malaysia 1975:01 318 70 $117

    Mexico 1988:01 132 37 $147

    Philippines 1976:11 86 22 $17

    Poland 1993:11 25 16 $53

    Portugal 1988:01 62 26 $65

    Russia 1994:01 61 18 $146

    South Africa 1985:01 117 47 $210

    Taiwan 1987:09 441 60 $279Thailand 1987:01 175 53 $76

    Turkey 1988:03 90 31 $66

    All emerging 2,811 $2,268

    All 17,449 $31,586

    We list countries as Developed or Emerging based on the International Finance Corporations (IFC) categorizations. Start date is

    the first month that a firm meeting all the data requirements outlined in Section 3 enters the sample. Number of Firms and

    Industries are the total number of unique firms and industries represented in the sample. Market capitalization is the total value

    (in billions of U.S. dollars) of firms in the sample in December 2004.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299 281

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    8/25

    We create country-neutral industry momentum portfolios and industry-adjusted momentum

    portfolios by first creating equally-weighted industry portfolios within each country using level 6 TDS

    industry classifications. We require each industry portfolio to have a minimum of three firms. We

    create industry-adjusted returns by taking the difference between the firms monthly return and thereturn on its country-specific industry portfolio. Then, we create across-industry momentum portfolios

    by ranking the total return to each industry portfolio over Past(2,12) and forming an equally-weighted

    portfolio of the top 30% of industries within the country and shorting the bottom 30% and holding for

    one month before rebalancing. Within-industry portfolios are formed by ranking total industry-

    adjusted returns over Past(2,12) and going long the top 30% and short the bottom 30%.

    The last six columns ofTable 2 show returns to both across-industry and within-industry (industry-

    adjusted) momentum portfolios. For developed markets, we find significant across-industry

    momentum for 7 of the 19 countries with sufficient data to calculate across-industry momentum. Of

    these 7 countries, 6 also have a significant average unadjusted momentum return. We also find that the

    magnitude of the average developed market across-industry momentum return of 56 basis points per

    month to be similar to the unadjusted momentum effect of 54 basis points per month. Similar to theunadjusted market-wide momentum results reported earlier for the developed markets, we also find

    time-variation in across-industry momentum.

    There is sufficient data to calculate industry momentum for only 9 of the 18 emerging markets. We

    find no evidence of significant positive across-industry momentum in emerging markets; however, the

    number of industries in each market and the average number of firms in each industry portfolio is

    much smaller than in the developed markets. Overall, the across-industry momentum effect is nearly

    zero for the emerging markets in both the full sample period and across sub-periods.

    The last three columns ofTable 2 show returns to within-industry (industry-adjusted) momentum.

    For the developed markets, 6 of 20 countries have a significant positive within-industry momentum

    effect. Of these 6, all also have significant unadjusted momentum and 3 also have significant positive

    across-industry momentum returns. For the emerging markets, 2 of 16 countries have a significantpositive within-industry momentum effect, one of which also has significant unadjusted momentum

    returns. Taken together, the across-industry and within-industry results show that industry

    momentum does not subsume unadjusted momentum, consistent with the evidence in Grundy and

    Martin (2001) and Asness et al. (2001).

    Fig. 1. We categorize countries as Developed or Emerging based on the International Finance Corporations (IFC) categorizations.

    Number of Firms is the total number of unique firms represented in the sample. The largest three developed markets: U.S., Japan,

    and U.K are not shown.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299282

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    9/25

    Table 2

    Momentum returns for unadjusted, across-industry, and within-industry portfolios: portfolios formed on Past(2,12) ranking

    period and held for one month 19752004.

    Unadjusted Returns versus local market index Across-industry Within-industry

    Average

    monthly

    return

    t-stat n Winner

    portfolio

    t-stat Loser

    portfolio

    t-stat Average

    monthly

    return

    t-stat n Average

    monthly

    return

    t-stat n

    Developed markets

    Australia 0.98 4.19 347 0.37 3.06 0.61 4.33 0.29 1.09 347 0.55 2.91 347

    Austria 0.15 0.40 198 0.16 0.82 0.31 1.07 0.38 0.42 44 0.50 0.93 80

    Belgium 0.94 4.08 347 0.33 2.73 0.61 3.92 0.49 1.15 176 0.42 1.30 223

    Canada 0.83 3.54 347 0.33 3.13 0.49 3.28 0.47 1.59 347 0.45 2.48 347

    Denmark 0.88 2.98 347 0.31 2.14 0.57 2.85 1.15 0.85 87 0.71 1.45 161

    Finland 0.25 0.45 189 0.35 1.35 0.10 0.27 0.72 0.32 12 0.09 0.05 38

    France 0.83 3.44 347 0.40 3.76 0.42 2.74 0.82 3.07 347 0.36 1.93 347

    Germany 0.73 3.09 347 0.32 3.16 0.41 2.54 0.67 2.39 347 0.25 1.53 347

    Hong Kong 0.74 2.65 347 0.43 2.69 0.31 1.75 0.05 0.12 287 0.31 1.19 347

    Ireland 1.18 2.21 174 0.33 1.27 0.85 2.24

    Italy 1.42 4.73 347 0.73 4.82 0.68 3.65 1.32 3.06 306 0.47 1.71 306 Japan 0.08 0.32 347 0.00 0.03 0.08 0.62 0.41 1.55 347 0.18 1.05 347

    Luxembourg 0.58 0.90 103 0.27 0.80 0.31 0.70 1.51 2.92 4

    Netherlands 0.90 3.38 347 0.36 2.82 0.54 3.24 1.13 2.65 281 0.57 2.09 296

    New Zealand 0.71 1.30 121 0.44 1.76 0.26 0.67

    Norway 0.54 1.18 236 0.22 1.01 0.32 0.96 0.61 0.71 111 0.80 1.50 144

    Singapore 0.38 1.13 325 0.06 0.30 0.33 1.43 0.08 0.12 211 0.30 0.95 253

    Spain 0.54 2.48 194 0.42 3.20 0.12 0.81 0.80 1.82 161 0.39 1.92 192

    Sweden 0.32 0.85 263 0.21 1.26 0.11 0.44 0.90 1.96 200 0.44 1.45 212

    Switzerland 0.68 3.75 347 0.20 2.34 0.48 4.13 0.21 0.76 347 0.31 2.03 347

    United Kingdom 0.71 3.14 347 0.33 3.68 0.38 2.49 0.64 2.74 347 0.47 3.82 347

    USA 0.66 2.96 347 0.33 3.85 0.33 2.17 0.67 3.34 347 0.48 3.70 347

    Total developed: 0.54 3.34 347 0.24 3.90 0.30 2.77 0.56 3.88 347 0.25 2.53 347

    19751980 0.87 3.47 59 0.40 3.16 0.47 3.51 0.89 3.96 59 0.48 3.11 59

    19811985 0.32 1.38 60 0.09 0.82 0.23 1.71 0.19 0.77 60 0.14 0.84 60

    19861990 0.46 1.78 60 0.16 1.28 0.30 1.91 0.42 1.57 60 0.19 1.07 60

    19911995 0.35 1.41 60 0.14 1.52 0.21 1.26 0.45 2.29 60 0.09 0.42 60

    19962000 0.94 1.70 60 0.46 2.24 0.48 1.27 0.94 2.00 60 0.60 1.95 60

    20012004 0.23 0.33 48 0.18 0.78 0.06 0.12 0.48 0.75 48 0.05 0.13 48

    Emerging markets

    Argentina 0.19 0.31 75 0.15 0.48 0.05 0.09 3.49 1.35 5

    Brazil 1.34 1.71 92 0.57 1.13 0.77 1.77 2.35 2.29 45

    Chile 0.30 0.85 138 0.49 2.39 0.19 0.77 0.86 0.83 3 0.31 0.73 74

    Greece 1.23 2.18 123 0.64 2.24 0.59 1.38 0.57 0.53 37

    India 0.61 1.57 167 0.36 1.69 0.25 0.90 1.01 1.33 87 0.63 1.15 114

    Indonesia 1.10 1.78 105 0.79 2.25 0.31 0.67 0.24 0.21 32 0.61 0.64 35Israel 0.75 1.54 82 0.46 1.72 0.28 0.88 0.46 0.27 3

    Korea 0.53 1.18 168 0.20 0.86 0.33 1.15 1.35 2.28 106 0.03 0.08 125

    Malaysia 0.31 0.99 182 0.21 1.18 0.10 0.45 0.40 1.00 140 0.14 0.45 158

    Mexico 1.29 3.30 184 0.55 2.14 0.74 2.67 0.47 0.47 57 1.02 1.63 81

    Philippines 2.49 0.62 80 0.69 1.76 3.18 0.80 0.47 0.39 29

    Poland 1.48 1.60 33 0.50 1.20 0.98 1.27

    Portugal 1.27 2.50 98 0.96 3.54 0.31 0.86 1.90 1.23 14

    Russia 0.76 0.54 29 0.77 0.80 0.01 0.01 3.94 0.77 9

    South Africa 0.97 2.63 203 0.47 2.45 0.50 2.05 1.95 1.56 58 0.94 1.92 95

    Taiwan 0.40 1.10 181 0.31 1.50 0.10 0.33 0.05 0.10 165 0.54 1.82 168

    Thailand 1.39 2.28 145 1.15 3.61 0.23 0.59 0.91 0.61 30 2.11 2.53 63

    Turkey 0.45 0.44 88 0.02 0.04 0.42 0.56

    Total emerging: 0.75 3.64 225 0.34 2.23 0.41 2.17 0.02 0.05 194 0.72 3.96 194

    19861990 0.81 1.23 57 0.26 0.54 0.55 0.92 1.24 1.34 26 0.70 1.16 26

    19911995 0.75 3.29 60 0.31 1.65 0.44 1.96 0.19 0.70 60 0.10 0.38 60

    19962000 0.62 1.80 60 0.34 1.34 0.28 0.81 0.60 1.05 60 0.94 2.59 60

    (continued on next page)

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299 283

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    10/25

    We create country-neutral momentum portfolios for all markets in a manner similar to that used for

    developed and emerging markets. The results are reported in the last panel of Table 2. The results arenearly identical to those for developed markets due to the large fraction of firms traded in developed

    markets.

    We also examine alternative methods for constructing industry portfolios, including value-

    weighting rather than equal-weighting, using global rather than local industry portfolios and using

    a mix of local and global industry portfolios for those industries where the primary finished product is

    tradable. See Griffin and Karolyi (1998) for more on the role of traded vs. non-traded industries. Our

    reported results are robust to each of the alternative methods.

    4.3. Risk adjusted momentum returns

    In this section, we verify that simple factor models cannot explain the level of average momentumreturns. We use a single-factor market model and a three-factor model similar to that of Fama and

    French (1992, 1993, 1996). Our measure of the market return is the value-weighted average of all

    stocks local currency return. Our size factor, SMB, is calculated using the monthly NYSE 30th and 70th

    percentile breakpoints converted to local currency.15 The Small and Big portfolios are value-weighted

    and must each have at least three stocks. The SMB factor is the simple difference between the two

    portfolios. The HML factor is from Ken Frenchs website.16

    Since Grundy and Martin (2001) show that the factor coefficients are time varying, we estimate

    momentum portfolio factor coefficients from individual stock factor coefficients. For each month and

    for each stock, we estimate each factor model using a minimum of 24 and a maximum of 36 past

    months of stock returns and factor realizations to estimate stock specific factor loadings. The

    Table 2 (continued)

    Unadjusted Returns versus local market index Across-industry Within-industry

    Average

    monthly

    return

    t-stat n Winner

    portfolio

    t-stat Loser

    portfolio

    t-stat Average

    monthly

    return

    t-stat n Average

    monthly

    return

    t-stat n

    20012004 0.84 3.15 48 0.46 2.75 0.38 1.92 0.38 0.41 48 1.23 3.60 48

    Total All: 0.55 3.57 347 0.24 4.08 0.30 2.96 0.55 3.83 347 0.25 2.66 347

    19751980 0.87 3.47 59 0.40 3.16 0.47 3.51 0.89 3.96 59 0.49 3.16 59

    19811985 0.32 1.38 60 0.09 0.87 0.23 1.67 0.19 0.77 60 0.14 0.84 60

    19861990 0.46 1.80 60 0.13 1.01 0.32 2.04 0.40 1.51 60 0.19 1.08 60

    19911995 0.38 1.64 60 0.15 1.69 0.23 1.42 0.42 2.24 60 0.08 0.42 60

    19962000 0.90 1.75 60 0.49 2.46 0.41 1.18 0.89 1.95 60 0.58 1.99 60

    20012004 0.31 0.46 48 0.19 0.91 0.12 0.25 0.47 0.75 48 0.01 0.03 48

    We report average monthly momentum profit for portfolios of winners minus losers using monthly return data from January

    1975 through December 2004. An average return of 0.50 is 50 basis points per month. Winners and losers are defined based on

    total return during the ranking period of month t 2 through t 12 (Past(2,12)). Unadjusted refers to the ranking of all stocks by

    average monthly return within a country during the ranking period. Winners and losers are defined as the top and bottom threedeciles, respectively. Across-Industry Portfolios are formed based on total return to equal-weighted industry portfolios during

    the ranking period. Winning industries are the top 30% and losers the bottom 30% of industries with valid data during the

    ranking period. The average monthly profit from a strategy of buying an equally weighted portfolio of the winning industry

    portfolios and shorting the losing industries and holding for 1 month is reported. Within-Industry refers to the ranking of all

    stocks by difference in return from their equal-weighted industry average. Winners are defined as the top 30% of stocks during

    the ranking period and losers the bottom 30%. The average monthly profit from a strategy of buying an equal-weighted portfolio

    of winners and shorting an equal-weighted portfolio of losers and holding the position for 1 month is reported. To be included in

    any momentum portfolio, a firm must be above the 25th percentile market capitalization of all NYSE stocks in every month

    during the ranking period. All returns are in local currency. Industry portfolios have a minimum of three firms. Across-industry

    strategies must have a minimum of four valid industries from which winning and losing industries are selected.

    15 The sample of stocks used to calculate SMB is not subject to the 25th NYSE market capitalization decile screen used to

    calculate momentum portfolio returns.16 For countries that do not have an HML factor available, we use a two factor model.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299284

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    11/25

    momentum portfolio factor loading for month t is then calculated from the individual stock factor

    loadings calculated from t 1 through t 36 (i.e., it is the simple average of the factor loadings of the

    individual stocks). We calculate the fitted values for time tusing the estimated portfolio factor loadings

    and the factor realizations from time t.17

    Table 3 provides the risk-adjusted momentum return results. Since we require that a stock must

    have a minimum of 24 months of prior returns to calculate its factor loadings, the sample used to formmomentum portfolios is slightly smaller than that used in Table 2. For comparison purposes, the first

    column of Table 3 reports the average unadjusted momentum returns using this smaller sample.

    The results in Table 3 show that the local market model, Model 1, does a poor job of explaining the

    level of momentum returns. Of the 13 developed markets with significant momentum returns, the

    average fitted value is positive and significant for only 2. The fraction of unadjusted momentum return

    variance that is explained by the variance of the fitted returns, %VarE, averages 28%.18 These results are

    consistent with Grundy and Martin (2001) who show that a single factor model does a poor job of

    explaining the level of momentum returns.

    A local version of the FamaFrench three-factor model, Model 2, also does a poor job of explaining

    the level of momentum returns. The fitted values are significant in only 3 of the developed countries. In

    unreported results, we find that of the 13 developed markets with significant momentum returns, 10have significant average factor loadings on one or more of the factors, although their magnitudes are

    too low to explain the level of momentum profits.

    The bottom of Table 3 provides the country-specific risk adjustment results for the emerging

    markets. We again find that the country-level single and multi-factor models do a poor job of

    explaining average momentum returns. Of the 5 countries with significant momentum returns, the

    fitted values are significant for only one. The fraction of unadjusted momentum return variance that is

    explained by the variance of the fitted returns is also less than half that of the developed markets.

    In unreported results, we use global versions of the single and multifactor models to risk adjust

    returns. The global market return is the value-weighted average of local market U.S. dollar returns. The

    global market return is then converted into each local currency. The global SMB factor value-weights

    the country specific Small and Big portfolio U.S. dollar returns, calculates the difference, and thenconverts to each local currency. The global HML factor is from Ken Frenchs website. The global factor

    models are less successful than the local versions at explaining the level of country-neutral momentum

    returns. This result is consistent with Griffin (2002) who finds that domestic versions of the Fama

    French model have lower pricing errors than do global versions.

    5. Cross-country comovement of momentum returns

    The previous section shows that a significant momentum effect exists for a broad cross-section of

    countries, and it has a time varying component. The results also show that there are both industry and

    firm effects independent of industry in momentum returns and standard risk factors do a poor job of

    explaining average momentum returns.19

    In this section, we examine the cross-country comovementof momentum returns.

    5.1. Correlation of unadjusted momentum returns across countries

    Table 4 provides evidence that country-neutral momentum returns significantly comove. Panel A of

    Table 4 reports the average correlation of country-neutral momentum returns within developed

    markets over the full sample period 19752004, while Panel B reports the average correlation within

    17 Korajczyk and Sadka (2004) model the time variation of the coefficients on the winner and loser portfolios as a function of

    average factor realizations in the portfolio selection period. Although easier to compute, this approach is more restrictive than

    the method we use.18 %VarE (Variance of the fitted return/Variance of the total return)*100. Since the coefficients are estimated out of sample, it

    is possible to have the variance of the fitted exceed the variance of the total.19 In unreported results, we also find that the factor models do a poor job of explaining the level of across-industry and

    within-industry momentum.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299 285

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    12/25

    Table 3

    Risk-adjusted momentum returns 19752004.

    Unadjusted

    momentum returns

    Model 1 Model 2

    Avg t-stat n Fitted t-stat Errors t-stat % VarE Fitted t-stat Errors t-stat % VarE

    Developed markets

    Australia 0.99 4.12 334 0.05 0.45 1.05 4.99 25.02 0.12 0.71 0.87 4.08 47.87

    Austria 0.14 0.38 192 0.32 1.59 0.18 0.49 27.82 0.04 0.12 0.43 1.07 44.31

    Belgium 1.02 4.24 334 0.01 0.12 1.01 4.55 9.64 0.40 2.21 0.62 2.41 38.51

    Canada 0.87 3.63 334 0.14 0.95 0.74 3.56 34.92 0.17 1.08 0.70 3.52 43.57

    Denmark 0.86 2.85 334 0.31 2.34 0.55 1.91 19.35 0.28 0.87 0.20 0.48 53.20

    Finland 0.27 0.45 177 0.45 1.50 0.18 0.32 24.80 0.53 1.02 0.47 0.76 52.07

    France 0.80 3.26 334 0.06 0.51 0.74 3.47 25.99 0.01 0.06 0.77 3.74 44.81

    Germany 0.74 3.21 334 0.25 1.63 0.49 3.07 45.60 0.18 0.92 0.56 3.67 74.24

    Hong Kong 0.75 2.64 334 0.30 1.58 0.46 1.82 43.66 0.30 1.31 0.38 1.34 61.32

    Ireland 1.06 1.84 161 0.21 1.46 0.85 1.51 6.04 0.71 1.51 0.46 0.62 36.00

    Italy 1.34 4.35 334 0.26 1.68 1.08 3.93 25.77 0.62 2.48 0.44 1.61 57.43

    Japan 0.01 0.04 334 0.02 0.150.01 0.04 21.98 0.06 0.32 0.07 0.34 54.76

    Luxembourg 0.15 0.21 89 0.29 1.67 0.44 0.59 5.57 0.30 0.69 0.73 0.61 12.73Netherlands 0.89 3.31 334 0.09 0.98 0.80 3.23 11.77 0.21 1.44 0.68 2.83 28.98

    New Zealand 0.61 1.00 88 0.04 0.22 0.65 1.08 8.44

    Norway 0.60 1.26 230 0.05 0.27 0.55 1.19 13.61 0.68 0.90 1.32 1.47 49.40

    Singapore 0.36 1.03 312 0.06 0.35 0.30 0.94 23.50 0.41 1.15 0.30 0.73 46.98

    Spain 0.51 2.40 187 0.26 2.26 0.25 1.23 28.64 0.26 1.72 0.25 1.21 49.36

    Sweden 0.25 0.67 251 0.24 1.28 0.01 0.04 24.76 0.44 2.05 0.08 0.26 29.47

    Switzerland 0.67 3.47 334 0.12 1.23 0.55 3.15 26.84 0.22 1.59 0.43 2.50 49.43

    UK 0.72 3.13 334 0.05 0.65 0.66 3.18 11.97 0.08 0.49 0.63 3.38 54.29

    USA 0.63 2.83 334 0.02 0.16 0.61 3.42 29.93 0.08 0.46 0.55 3.18 65.56

    Total developed: 0.52 3.22 334 0.06 0.68 0.46 3.68 28.19 0.08 0.63 0.42 3.69 55.25

    Emerging markets

    Argentina 0.07 0.10 64 0.10 0.57 0.03 0.04 5.92 0.18 0.59 0.45 0.57 15.60

    Brazil 1.67 1.88 64 0.09 0.24 1.76 2.15 19.36 0.18 0.34 1.49 1.67 34.41

    Chile 0.33 0.90 136 0.07 0.62 0.41 1.17 10.51 0.34 1.25 0.06 0.13 31.54

    Greece 1.33 2.28 109 0.31 1.57 1.02 1.79 11.41 0.47 1.37 1.42 2.03 21.82

    India 0.34 0.80 155 0.16 1.31 0.18 0.41 8.73 0.24 1.41 0.10 0.23 15.95

    Indonesia 0.46 0.68 100 0.39 1.10 0.85 1.19 26.72 0.58 0.49 0.14 0.09 149.32

    Israel 0.51 0.80 56 0.25 1.53 0.26 0.40 6.71 0.51 0.60 0.72 0.44 17.59

    Korea 0.42 0.89 162 0.06 0.42 0.48 1.02 8.70 0.67 2.89 0.94 1.86 20.10

    Malaysia 0.27 0.85 179 0.28 1.76 0.01 0.02 24.68 0.18 0.70 0.05 0.18 47.62

    Mexico 1.07 2.64 170 0.01 0.07 1.08 3.02 26.06 0.29 1.13 0.63 1.85 33.84

    Philippines 2.99 0.61 65 0.77 0.83 3.76 0.76 3.59 0.85 1.18 11.60 0.89 0.32

    Poland 1.48 1.43 27 1.03 2.95 0.45 0.45 11.50

    Portugal 1.46 2.55 81 0.83 3.17 0.63 1.11 20.76 0.88 2.21 1.02 1.23 19.35

    Russia 0.54 0.38 27 0.06 0.11 0.60 0.47 13.24 0.66 0.87 1.73 1.11 22.29South Africa 0.94 2.43 190 0.05 0.66 0.99 2.47 4.21 0.42 2.53 0.52 1.27 18.53

    Taiwan 0.41 1.07 168 0.14 0.96 0.56 1.50 15.03 0.02 0.07 0.43 1.22 32.07

    Thailand 1.53 2.34 137 0.19 1.00 1.34 2.12 8.52 0.46 0.83 1.91 2.77 43.90

    Turkey 0.14 0.14 83 0.72 2.98 0.86 0.86 5.87

    Total emerging: 0.78 2.17 261 0.27 2.23 0.50 1.51 11.80 0.39 2.35 0.06 0.28 16.59

    Model 1 Country-specific market model.

    Model 2 Country-specific FamaFrench three-factor model.

    We risk adjust momentum returns using either a single-factor market model or a three-factor model similar to that of Fama

    French. The country-specific market return is the value-weighted average of all stocks local currency returns where there are

    three or more firms. For the FamaFrench three factor country-specific model, we use the local market return along with an SMB

    factor calculated using NYSE 30/70 breakpoints converted to local currency. Small and Big portfolios are value weighted and

    must have at least three stocks. The SMB factor is the simple difference between the two portfolios. The HML factor is from Ken

    Frenchs website. Since we require that a stock must have a minimum of 24 months of prior returns to calculate its factorloadings, the sample used to form momentum portfolios is slightly smaller here than that used in Table 2. For comparative

    purposes, the first column reports the average unadjusted momentum returns from using this smaller sample. %Var-

    E (Variance of the fitted return/Variance of the total return) * 100.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299286

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    13/25

    Table 4

    Average pairwise correlations of unadjusted momentum returns across countries: portfolios formed on Past(2,12) ranking period and he

    Average

    of all

    correlations

    n t-statistic Average of

    significant

    correlations

    # of significant

    () correlations

    # of significant

    () correlations

    Range

    () co

    Panel A: Average pairwise correlations of unadjusted momentum returns for developed markets (19752004)

    Developed markets

    Australia 0.19 21 11.03 0.21 0 16 0.13

    Austria 0.18 21 10.56 0.22 0 14 0.14

    Belgium 0.18 21 12.15 0.21 0 16 0.12

    Canada 0.27 21 11.22 0.28 0 20 0.11

    Denmark 0.20 21 11.61 0.23 0 16 0.16

    Finland 0.24 21 10.20 0.28 0 17 0.16

    France 0.34 21 12.41 0.35 0 20 0.19

    Germany 0.32 21 10.78 0.33 0 20 0.12

    Hong Kong 0.15 21 8.66 0.20 0 12 0.12

    Ireland 0.21 21 9.41 0.26 0 14 0.15

    Italy 0.23 21 12.72 0.24 0 19 0.15

    Japan 0.15 21 9.39 0.20 0 11 Luxembourg 0.27 21 11.85 0.33 0 15 0.21

    Netherlands 0.30 21 11.78 0.31 0 20 0.11

    New Zealand 0.12 21 7.25 0.25 0 2 0.23

    Norway 0.19 21 10.13 0.23 0 17 0.13

    Singapore 0.13 21 8.07 0.18 0 11 0.11

    Spain 0.18 21 10.31 0.22 0 15 0.15

    Sweden 0.28 21 9.97 0.34 0 16 0.17

    Switzerland 0.31 21 14.97 0.31 0 21 0.180

    United Kingdom 0.33 21 11.68 0.34 0 20 0.180

    USA 0.32 21 10.86 0.33 0 20 0.160

    Total developed: 0.23 231 29.19 0.27 0 176 0.110

    19751980 0.11 91 8.30 0.33 0 11 0.26019811985 0.02 105 1.43 0.23 2 7 0.260

    19861990 0.08 136 5.29 0.34 0 21 0.260

    19911995 0.16 190 14.40 0.35 0 54 0.260

    19962000 0.27 231 21.62 0.42 0 123 0.260

    20012004 0.41 210 28.05 0.51 0 149 0.290

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    14/25

    Table 4 (continued)

    Average

    of all

    correlations

    n t-statistic Average of

    significant

    correlations

    # of significant

    () correlations

    # of significant

    () correlations

    Range

    () co

    Panel B: Average pairwise correlations of unadjusted momentum returns for emerging markets (19902004)

    Emerging markets

    Argentina 0.02 15 0.73 0.29 0 1 0.29

    Brazil 0.08 16 2.56 0.21 0 1 0.21

    Chile 0.02 16 0.76 0.22 1 0

    Greece 0.03 16 0.69 0.02 1 1 0.23

    India 0.05 16 2.25 0.21 0 1 0.21

    Indonesia 0.00 15 0.13 0.27 0 1 0.27

    Israel 0.01 14 0.68

    Korea 0.01 16 0.45 0.23 0 1 0.23

    Malaysia 0.01 16 0.34 0.04 1 1 0.29

    Mexico 0.05 16 2.26

    Philippines 0.06 14 1.52 0.27 0 1 0.27

    Poland 0.07 11 1.21

    Portugal 0.00 15 0.15 0.22 1 0

    South Africa 0.01 16 0.58 0.21 1 0

    Taiwan 0.00 16 0.12 0.21 2 0

    Thailand 0.03 16 1.26 0.21 1 0 Turkey 0.01 16 0.26

    Total emerging: 0.01 130 1.41 0.02 4 4 0.21

    19911995 0.02 44 0.99 0.32 1 0

    19962000 0.01 78 0.61 0.17 1 2 0.38

    20012004 0.05 86 2.96 0.32 0 2 0.31

    Panel C: Average pairwise correlations of unadjusted momentum returns across developed and emerging markets

    All

    Emerging w/developed 0.08 373 12.58 0.20 5 62 0.14

    19901995

    Emerging w/developed 0.04 200 3.27 0.23 3 18 0.26

    19962000Emerging w/developed 0.04 308 4.22 0.24 5 27 0.26

    20012004

    Emerging w/developed 0.12 294 11.64 0.34 2 54 0.29

    We report correlations of unadjusted momentum returns for portfolios of winners minus losers from 1975 to 2004 for developed countri

    markets in Panel B. In Panel C, we report average correlations of unadjusted momentum returns between developed and emerging m

    average monthly return during the ranking period. Unadjusted refers to the ranking of all stocks by total return within a country during th

    as the top and bottom 30% of firms. To be included in a portfolio, a firm must be above the 25th percentile market capitalization of all NYS

    returns are in local currency.

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    15/25

    emerging markets over the 19902004 sample period. The begin date for the emerging markets

    correlation results in Panel B corresponds to the starting date available for many of the emerging

    markets. We also report the average correlation between equally-weighted country market indices for

    comparison.

    For each developed market in Panel A, we find that the average pairwise correlations of country-

    neutral momentum returns with the other developed markets are significant. The average of thepairwise correlations range from 0.30 and above for France, the U.K., the U.S., Germany, Switzerland,

    and the Netherlands to 0.12 for New Zealand. With the exception of New Zealand, we find that for each

    country well over half of the pairwise correlations are individually significant.20 Seven countries have

    20 or more of a possible 21 positive and significant pairwise correlations, while only one developed

    country, New Zealand, has less than 10 positive and significant pairwise correlations. No pair of

    developed countries has a significant negative correlation in their momentum returns.

    The range of statistically significant pairwise correlations for the developed markets in the eighth

    column shows that the averages often mask the magnitude of the relationship between country-

    neutral momentum returns. For example, the momentum returns for the U.K. and the U.S. have

    a pairwise correlation of 0.55 over the full sample period. Many of the other developed markets also

    have substantial pairwise momentum return correlations. At the bottom of Panel A, we see that thecomovement in momentum has grown over time. If we broaden our correlation analysis to the

    intraregional and interregional levels and mix the developed and emerging markets, we obtain much

    smaller correlations similar to those reported in Griffin et al. (2003).

    For comparison, we provide the correlation of country return indices. However, it is important to

    note that the correlation of country return indices does not imply that country-neutral momentum

    returns should necessarily be correlated. The contemporaneous market return average correlations are

    all positive, significant, and larger than the average momentum return correlations.

    Panel B ofTable 4 provides the average pairwise correlations for the emerging markets. The magnitude

    and significance of the momentum return correlations are much smaller than with the developed

    markets. The average of all correlations among the emerging markets is only 0.01, compared with 0.23

    among the developed markets. Of the 17 emerging markets shown in Table 4, the average correlation ofeach emerging market with the others ranges from0.06 to 0.08. The average market index correlations

    are all significantly positive, though lower in magnitude than within developed markets.21

    Panel C of Table 4 shows average correlations of developed with emerging markets. The average

    correlation is positive and significant, though smaller in magnitude than the average within only

    developed countries.

    Although emerging markets display higher average momentum returns than developed markets,

    country-neutral momentum returns within emerging markets do not generally comove. Comovement in

    country-neutral momentum returns is concentrated primarilyamong developed countries. Thispattern is

    consistent with integrated equity markets across developed countries but not across emerging countries

    and is also consistent with the broader literature on the integration of global equity markets (e.g., Puchkov

    et al., 2005; Bekaert et al., 2002; Bekaert and Harvey, 1995 among others.) The concentration ofcomovement among integrated markets observed here is also similar to that documented for other asset

    classes, for example: syndicated loans (Carey and Nini, 2007; Itzkowitz et al., 2008), bonds (Barr and

    Priestley, 2004), and real estate (Hastings and Nordby, 2007; Ling and Naranjo, 1999).

    5.2. Correlation of country neutral across-industry and within-industry momentum returns

    If country-specific industry portfolio returns are correlated across countries, then industry effects

    might explain the comovement of country-neutral momentum returns. For example, if the auto

    20 The correlations for the long portfolios across countries and short portfolios across countries are also similar, suggesting

    that contagion is not the source of the dependence in momentum returns across markets. Cross country contagion effects can

    potentially be a source of the comovement in momentum returns to the extent that momentum profits arise primarily from the

    relation in short positions across countries. Contagion strategies entail selling assets from one country when crisis hits another

    (see, for instance, Bekaert et al., 2005; Kaminsky et al., 2004).21 This is consistent with the findings of others. See, for instance, Goetzmann et al. (2005) and Longin and Solnik (1995, 2001).

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299 289

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    16/25

    industry has a good year in both the U.S. and Japan, then momentum portfolios in both countries would

    be long auto industry stocks. To the extent that cross-country industry comovement explains the

    comovement in unadjusted country-neutral momentum, we would expect country-neutral across-

    industry momentum to comove and within-industry momentum portfolios not to comove.

    In Table 5 we examine the extent to which across-industry and within-industry momentum returns

    comove. Panel A of Table 5 reports the average pairwise correlation between developed markets forcountries where we can calculate across-industry momentum returns in at least 30 months of the

    sample period. Although from Table 2 we see that the level of across-industry momentum of 56 basis

    points per month is slightly higher than unadjusted momentum return of 54 basis points per month,

    the average developed market across-industry pairwise correlation of 0.08 is much lower than the

    unadjusted momentum correlation of 0.23. The country-neutral within-industry momentum portfo-

    lios are more highly correlated than the across-industry momentum portfolios. It is clear from Table 5

    that industry comovement does not by itself explain the comovement in momentum returns.

    We repeat the analysis for emerging markets in Panel B. Similar to the earlier results for the

    comovement of unadjusted momentum returns within emerging markets reported in Table 4, we find

    little evidence of comovement of across and within-industry momentum returns in emerging markets.

    6. Risk factor and momentum return comovement

    Industry comovement does not explain the comovement in country-neutral momentum returns.

    Although unable to explain the level of momentum returns, it is possible that common asset pricing

    models may be able to explain the comovement of momentum returns. As Grundy and Martin (2001)

    point out, buying recent winners and selling recent losers guarantees time-varying factor exposures in

    accordance with the performance of common risk factors during the ranking period. If risk factors covary

    across countries, then the time varying factor exposures of the long and short portfolios must also covary.

    6.1. Correlation of risk adjusted momentum returns across countries

    In Table 6 we report risk-adjusted correlations corresponding to the country-specific versions of the

    factor models. In Panel A, we use the domestic version of the market model, while in Panel B we use the

    domestic version of the FamaFrench model. We only include countries that have data available to

    estimate both models so that we can more accurately compare across models without deviations

    caused by different countries or sample periods.22

    When using a one factor model to risk adjust momentum returns, we find that the correlations of the

    fitted returns are large and significant. The average correlation across countries of the fitted values is 0.37,

    with a t-statistic of 9.03. Although the correlations of the errors from the one-factor model are also large

    and significant, the average correlation of 0.16 is less than half as big as the average fitted correlations.

    However, we must be careful in comparing the correlations of the fitted values and of the residuals as the

    variance of the residuals is typically much higher, potentially masking differences in covariance.

    We decompose the covariance of country-neutral momentum returns as:

    CovRA; RB Cov

    RFitA RErrA ; R

    FitB R

    ErrB

    Cov

    RFitA ; RFitB

    Cov

    RErrA ; R

    ErrB

    h

    Cov

    RFitA ; RErrB

    Cov

    RErrA ; R

    FitB

    i

    1 Percent Fit Percent Error Percent Other; (1)

    where RA is the country-neutral momentum of countryA, RFit

    A is the return explained by the model, and

    RErrA is the return not explained by the model. RFit

    A and RErr

    A are not orthogonal since the factor loadings

    are estimated out of sample.

    22 If we allow the sample to vary across models, we obtain qualitatively similar results for the developed countries. Due to

    insufficient data, many of the models cannot be estimated for the emerging markets, and the fit is generally poorer when the

    estimates can be obtained.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299290

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    17/25

    The covariance of the fitted values explains 30% of the variance of the country-neutral momentum

    returns and the errors 45%. For 16 of 19 developed markets, the covariance of the errors explains

    a greater percentage of the covariance of the momentum returns than does the covariance of the fitted

    values. The sub-sample results show that there is considerable time variation in the fitted and error

    correlations and confirms that the fitted values explain a smaller portion of the covariance relative to

    the errors with the exception of the 20012004 sub-period.In Panel B of Table 6, we report the results from using the domestic version of the FamaFrench

    model to risk adjust momentum returns. The fitted values explain an average of 40% of the variance of

    the country-neutral momentum returns compared to 30% for the one factor model. The portion of the

    variance explained by the errors falls from 45% to 33%. For 14 of 19 developed markets, the fitted values

    explain a greater percentage of the covariance in momentum returns than the errors. The sub-sample

    results at the bottom of the panel also show that there is considerable time variation in the fitted and

    error correlations. The proportion of the covariance explained by the fitted values and errors also varies

    over time, with the fitted values explaining an increasing portion of the covariance through time.

    In unreported results, we use global versions of the one and three factors models and get quali-

    tatively similar results. However, the percentage of the covariance explained by the errors is larger with

    the global versions of the factor models, suggesting a general deterioration in the fit of these modelsrelative to the domestic versions. These results are consistent with the relatively poorer fit of global

    factor models relative to the domestic versions as reported by Griffin (2002).

    6.2. Does the comovement of risk factors explain the comovement of country-neutral momentum returns

    across countries?

    The risk-adjusted momentum results in Table 6 suggest a relationship between the correlation of

    momentum returns and risk factors. To explore this relationship in greater detail, we first examine if

    country pairs with higher factor covariance also have higher country-neutral momentum return

    covariance. We then examine if the covariance of factor returns during the measurement period

    predict the covariance of momentum returns in the holding period.

    6.2.1. Risk factor and momentum return covariation

    For the first set of tests, we estimate the sample pairwise covariance of country-neutral momentum

    returns and risk factors. We then regress the covariance of momentum returns on the covariance of risk

    factors for all pairs of developed countries with sufficient data to calculate local factors, have a valid

    momentum return on or within 12 months of the factor realization, and where the covariances are

    estimated with a minimum of 30 data points. We report the regression results in Panel A ofTable 7. The

    first three columns are results from univariate regressions corresponding to each risk factor, while the

    fourth column contains the multivariate regression results with all three risk factors included. The fifth

    and sixth columns contain the multivariate results over two equal length 15-year sub-periods:

    19751989 and 19902004.Each risk factor in the univariate regressions has a positive and significant coefficient. In other

    words, countries whose risk factors have high covariance also tend to have high covariance of country-

    neutral momentum. In the last two columns, we see that the factor covariances do a better job at

    explaining the covariance of momentum returns in the second sub-sample, which corresponds to the

    period when momentum return covariances are the largest over the entire sample.

    6.2.2. Does factor return covariation predict the covariation of momentum returns?

    In the second set of tests, we examine whether or not the covariance in factor returns during the

    measurement period predicts the covariance of momentum returns in the holding period. For each

    country-neutral momentum strategy and for each local factor realization, we calculate the following

    deviations from country specific time-series means:

    3i;t Ri;t RigRMRF

    i;t RMRFi;t RMRFi; (2)

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299 291

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    18/25

    Table 5

    Average pairwise correlations of across-industry and within-industry momentum returns across countries: portfolios formed on Past(2,1

    Pairwise correlations of industry and industry-adjusted momentum returns

    Across-industry momentum Within-industry-adjusted

    All correlations Individually significant correlations All correlations

    Average n t-stat. Average N () N () Range Average n t-stat.

    Panel A: Developed markets (19752004)

    Developed markets

    Australia 0.07 17 2.61 0.22 0 4 0.130.31 0.10 18 7.43

    Austria 0.00 16 0.07 0.00 1 1 0.310.31 0.10 17 2.59

    Belgium 0.03 17 1.75 0.16 18 4.44

    Canada 0.13 17 4.32 0.23 0 8 0.160.35 0.13 18 6.59

    Denmark 0.01 16 0.42 0.05 18 2.48

    Finland 0.17 17 5.92

    France 0.12 17 3.41 0.15 1 9 0.130.34 0.18 18 7.05

    Germany 0.12 17 4.40 0.23 0 8 0.160.35 0.23 18 7.07

    Hong Kong 0.10 17 3.83 0.20 0 8 0.160.29 0.06 18 3.34

    Ireland

    Italy 0.10 17 3.14 0.20 0 8 0.120.32 0.16 18 6.35

    Japan 0.09 17 5.56 0.17 0 4 0.150.21 0.14 18 9

    Luxembourg

    Netherlands 0.14 17 4.23 0.23 0 10 0.130.38 0.17 18 5.55

    New Zealand

    Norway 0.02 17 0.83 0.12 18 5.96

    Singapore 0.06 17 3.73 0.19 0 1 0.190.19 0.15 18 7.15

    Spain 0.05 17 2.74 0.19 0 1 0.190.19 0.09 18 4.36

    Sweden 0.10 17 4.66 0.19 0 5 0.160.24 0.13 18 6.92

    Switzerland 0.11 17 6.02 0.18 0 8 0.120.22 0.16 18 7.20

    UK 0.17 17 4.51 0.26 0 12 0.150.38 0.21 18 7.19

    USA 0.03 17 0.97 0.16 0 5 0.120.22 0.22 18 9.29

    Total developed: 0.08 152 8.17 0.20 1 46 0.120.38 0.14 170 16.50

    19751980 0.06 45 2.47 0.24 1 4 0.310.47 0.09 45 4.81

    19811985 0.05 36 1.65 0.16 2 3 0.440.52 0.06 55 2.70

    19861990 0.04 91 2.23 0.16 2 6 0.260.37 0.06 91 4.26

    19911995 0.07 136 5.15 0.23 2 13 0.260.42 0.12 153 10.19

    19962000 0.17 136 8.62 0.45 0 42 0.290.70 0.15 153 11.58

    20012004 0.21 91 10.34 0.41 1 29 0.300.66 0.34 105 16.44

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    19/25

    Panel B: Emerging Markets (19902004)

    Emerging markets

    Argentina

    Brazil 0.06 4 0.69

    Chile 0.16 7 2.77

    Greece 0.08 2 0.33

    India 0.03 7 0.34 0.38 0 1 0.38 0.38 0.03 9 0.45

    Indonesia 0.06 3 0.36 0.38 0 1 0.38 0.38 0.00 5 0.03

    IsraelKorea 0.03 6 1.39 0.04 7 0.80

    Malaysia 0.04 7 0.91 0.06 9 1.44

    Mexico 0.09 4 1.35 0.08 7 1.42

    Philippines

    Poland

    Portugal

    Russia

    South Africa 0.00 4 0.04 0.01 7 0.15

    Taiwan 0.01 7 0.21 0.02 10 0.42

    Thailand 0.05 4 0.43 0.06 7 0.85

    Turkey

    Total Emerging: 0.02 21 0.52 0.38 0 1 0.380.38 0.02 37 0.75

    19911995 0.02 6 0.57 0.00 10 0.0919962000 0.03 3 0.35 0.09 5 0.81

    20012004 0.07 1 0.10 11 1.54

    Panel C: Across developed and emerging markets

    All

    Emerging w/Developed 0.03 134 2.81 0.06 4 9 0.160.41 0.03 192 2.95

    19901995

    Emerging w/Developed 0.04 66 2.20 0.21 1 6 0.280.34 0.03 90 1.84

    19962000

    Emerging w/Developed 0.06 63 2.92 0.02 1 1 0.330.33 0.02 86 1.20

    20012004

    Emerging w/Developed 0.09 28 3.11 0.01 1 1 0.320.32 0.07 90 4.50

    We report average correlations of across-industry and within-industry momentum portfolio returns from 1975 to 2004 for developed countr

    markets in Panel B. In Panel C, we report average correlations of across-industry and within-industry momentum portfolio returns betwee

    losers are defined based on total return during the ranking period. Across-Industry portfolios are formed based on total return to equal-weig

    Winning industries are the top 30% and losers the bottom 30% of industries with valid data during the ranking period. The average monthly

    portfolio of winning industry portfolios and shorting the losing industries and holdingfor 1 month is reported. Within-Industry portfolios refe

    from their equal-weighted industry average. Winners are defined as the top 30% of stocks during the ranking period and losers the bottom 3

    buying an equal-weighted portfolio of winnersand shorting an equally-weighted portfolio of losers and holding the positionfor 1 month is re

    above the 25th percentile of market capitalizationof all NYSE stocks, converted to the local currency, in every month of the portfolio formatio

    portfolios have a minimum of three firms. Across-industry strategies must have a minimum of four valid industries from which winning a

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    20/25

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    21/25

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    22/25

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    23/25

    second and third columns, we see that for all three factors, covariances of the risk factor returns during

    the measurement period are significant predictors of the covariance of country-neutral momentum

    returns during the holding period. In the last two columns, we see that the covariance of the risk factor

    returns during the measurement period play an increasingly significant role in predicting covariances

    of country-neutral momentum returns during the holding period, with increasing coefficient esti-

    mates, significance levels and explanatory power over time.We also perform several robustness checks. First, we include the intersection of developed with

    emerging markets in the regression analysis and again find that the covariance of market factor returns

    during the measurement period are significant in explaining subsequent covariances of country

    momentum returns, though the explanatory power is lower due to the sparseness of emerging market

    observations.23 Second, we include several measures of industry overlap to examine the possibility that

    industry concentration in momentum portfolios drives the cross sectional results. It does not. We also

    examine five-year sub-periods to see if there is a stationarity problem with the covariances in the

    regression analysis. Though the early five-year sample periods are sparse, the time varying significance

    of the results over each of the five-year periods suggests that there is not a stationarity problem in the

    regression analysis. Finally, to assess if there are errors-in-variables problems in the regression anal-

    ysis, we use instrumental variables procedures and again obtain similar results to those we report.

    7. Conclusion

    We examine the profitability and cross-country comovement of country-neutral momentum

    returns for both developed and emerging markets. Using relative strength portfolio sorts, we first

    document the profitability of momentum returns across countries and then decompose those returns

    by industry effects, firm effects independent of their industry and with single and multifactor models.

    In addition, we examine the relationship in momentum returns across countries and over time.

    We show that country-neutral momentum strategies are profitable on average for both developed

    and emerging markets, yielding 54 and 75 basis points per month respectively over our sample period

    extending from 1975 to 2004. This result is consistent with the international evidence presented byRouwenhorst (1998, 1999) and Griffin et al. (2003). We also find both an industry momentum effect

    and a firm momentum effect independent of its industry for individual countries and on average across

    countries using country-neutral momentum strategies. Using a market model and the FamaFrench

    three factor model, we find that the models do a poor job at explaining average momentum returns.

    We find that country-neutral momentum returns are significantly correlated across countries. This

    comovement is positive and time varying. Conditioning on industry, we find that industry comovement

    does not explain the comovement in country-neutral momentum returns. We also find that while

    standard factor models do not explain average momentum returns, they do explain a significant

    portion of the comovement of country-neutral momentum returns. This finding is of particular

    importance to the asset allocation, diversification, and risk management strategies of investors who

    employ international momentum strategies since countries whose capital markets are more highlyintegrated are likely to have correlated pay-offs to country-specific momentum portfolios. Taken

    together, our results suggest that risk factors play an important role in explaining the cross-country

    comovement of momentum returns.

    Acknowledgements

    We thank Mark Flannery, Kent Hargis, Campbell Harvey, Jason Karceski, Andrew Karolyi, Michael

    Melvin (the Editor), M. Nimalendran, an anonymous referee, and seminar participants at the University

    of Miami, University of New Orleans, and CIBER at the University of Florida for helpful comments and

    suggestions.

    23 The intersection of emerging markets with emerging markets is very sparse across the multivariate specifications and

    largely insignificant. The HML factor, for instance, is largely unavailable for the emerging markets.

    A. Naranjo, B. Porter / Journal of International Money and Finance 29 (2010) 275299 297

  • 8/3/2019 Final JIMF Paper

    24/25

    References

    Asness, C.S., Porter, R.B., Stevens, R.L., 2001. Predicting stock returns using industry-relative firm characteristics. UnpublishedWorking Paper, Iowa State University, Ames, IA.

    Barberis, N., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R., 1998. A model of investor sentiment. Journal of Financial Economics 49, 307343.Barberis, N., Shleifer, A., Wurgler, J., 2005. Comovement. Journal of Financial Economics 75, 283317.

    Barr, D., Priestley, R., 2004. Expected returns, risk, and the integration of international bond markets. Journal of InternationalMoney and Finance 23, 7197.

    Bekaert, G., Harvey, C., 1995. Time-varying world market integration. Journal of Finance 50, 403444.Bekaert, G., Harvey, C., Lumsdaine, R., 2002. Dating the integration of world equity markets. Journal of Financial Economics 65,

    203247.Bekaert, G., Harvey, C., Ng, A., 2005. Market integration and contagion. Journal of Business 78, 3969.Brav, A., Heaton, J.B., 2002. Competing theories of financial anomalies. Review of Financial Studies 15, 575606.Bris, A., Goetzman, W.M., Zhu, N., 2004. Efficiency and the bear: short sales and markets around the world. Journal of Finance

    62, 10291079.Carey, M., Nini, G., 2007. Is the corporate loan market globally integrated? A pricing puzzle. Journal of Finance 62, 29693007.Carhart, M., 1997. On persistence in mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance 52 (1), 5782.Chan, L.K.C., Jegadeesh, N., Lakonishok, J., 1996. Momentum strategies. Journal of Finance 51, 16811713.Chui, A.C.W., Titman, S., Wei, K.C.J., 2003. Momentum, legal systems and ownership structure: an analysis of Asian stock market.

    Unpublished Working Paper, University of Texas, Austin, TX.Chordia, T., Shivakumar, L., 2002. Momentum, business cycle, and time-varying expected returns. Journal of Finance 57,

    9851019.Conrad, J., Kaul, G., 1998. An anatomy of trading strategies. Review of Financial Studies 11, 489519.Daniel, K., Hirshleifer, D., Subrahmanyam, A., 1998. Investor psychology and security market under- and overreactions. Journal

    of Finance 53, 18391886.Daniel, K., Grinblatt, M., Titman, S., Wermers, R., 1997. Measuring mutual fund performance with characteristic-based bench-

    marks. Journal of Finance 52, 12171218.Fama, E.F., French, K.R., 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance 47, 427465.Fama, E.F., French, K.R., 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33, 356.Fama, E.F., French, K.R., 1996. Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anomalies. Journal of Financial Economics 51, 5584.Froot, K., OConnell, P.G.J., Seasholes, M., 2001. The portfolio flows of international investors. Journal of Financial Economics 59,

    151193.Goetzmann, W., Li, L., Rouwenhorst, K.G., 2005. Long-term global market correlations. Journal of Business 78, 138.Griffin, J.M., Karolyi, A.G., 1998. Another look at the role of industrial structure of markets for international diversification

    strategies. Journal of Financial Economics 50, 351373.

    Griffin, J.M., Stulz, R., 2001. International competition and exchange rate shocks: a cross-country industry analysis of stockreturns. Review of Financial Studies 14, 215241.

    Griffin, J.M., 2002. Are the Fama and French factors global or country specific? Review of Financial Studies 15, 783803.Griffin, J.M., Ji, X., Martin, J.S., 2003. Momentum investing and business cycle risk: evidence from pole to pole. Journal of Finance

    58, 25152547.Grinblatt, M., Moskowitz, T., 1999. Do industries explain momentum? Journal of Finance 54, 12491290.Grundy, B.D., Martin, J.S., 2001. Understanding the nature of the risks and the source of the rewards to momentum investing.

    Review of Financial Studies 14, 2978.Hastings, A., Nordby, H., 2007. Benefits of global diversification on a real estate portfolio. The Journal of Portfolio Management,

    5362 (Special issue).Hong, H., Lim, T., Stein, J.C., 2000. Bad news travels slowly: size, analyst coverage, and the profitability of momentum strategies.

    Journal of Finance 55, 265295.Hong, H., Stein, J.C., 1999. A unified theory of underreaction, momentum trading and overreaction in asset markets. Journal of

    Finance 54, 21432184.Hou, K., 2007. Industry information diffusion and the lead-lag effect in stock returns. Review of Financial Studies 20, 11131138.

    Ince, O., Porter, R.B., 2006. Individual equity return data from Thomson datastream: handle with care!. Journal of FinancialResearch 29, 463479.

    Itzkowitz, J., Houston, Naranjo, A., 2008. Borrowing beyond borders: the geography and pricing of Syndicated Bank loans.Unpublished Working Paper, University of Florida, Gainesville, FL.

    Jegadeesh, N., 1990. Evidence of predictable behavior of security returns. Journal of Finance 45, 881898.Jegadeesh, N., Titman, S., 1993. Returns to buying winners and selling losers: implications for stock market efficiency. Journal of

    Finance 48, 6591.Jegadeesh, N., Titm