Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    1/14

    1

    LOCAL GOVERNMENT FINANCE IN OECD COUNTRIES

    Dr. Janice Caulfield

    University of New South Wales

    Paper presented to Local Government at the Millennium International SeminarFebruary 19

    th, 2000, University of New South Wales.

    In OECD countries there has been a growing mismatch between the functional competencies

    and fiscal responsibility of local government. In all countries local authorities have broad land

    planning and infrastructure provision powers and provide a wide range of local amenities.

    Some have functional responsibility for important areas of public spending in education, health

    and employment services. Continued population growth, especially in urban areas, has seen a

    steady increase in demand for municipal services. While the last quarter of the Century has

    witnessed measures of legislative and administrative decentralisation to meet these demands

    (reforms which have tended to broaden the economic and social functions of local and

    regional authorities), these measures have not been matched by a decentralisation of financial

    control. Where financial decentralisation has occurred, it is generally the intermediate

    governments that have benefitted, often in the name of new federalism (Owens and

    Norregard, 1991). In those unitary countries without intermediate level governments such as

    New Zealand and the United Kingdom, the problem of fiscal autonomy for local authorities

    has not been given a high priority even by reforming governments (Martin, 1991), although

    the issue was vigorously debated in the UK following the Blair governments Select

    Committee report on local government finance[1]

    . The phenomenon of inadequate growth in

    local government revenue, and the subject of this paper, is common to many OECD countries.

    This paper offers a comparative analysis of local government finance in OECD countries. Its

    aims are twofold: one is to examine the problem of fiscal autonomy for local government2;

    the other is to compare and contrast selected countries through a descriptive account of

    patterns and trends in local financial arrangements. The fiscal autonomy of local governments

    hinges on the degree of discretion or control available to them over their revenue source. Thus

    the focus here is on revenue rather than expenditure data. Fiscal autonomy has been the

    subject of long standing debate in the fiscal federalism literature where the problem of vertical

    fiscal imbalance between the centre and the states has received much attention (Mathews,

    1997; Watts, 1996). Vertical fiscal imbalance (VFI) exists where sub-national governments

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    2/14

    2

    depend for their expenditure needs on transfers from higher levels of government. The key

    argument in support of fiscal balance between revenue and expenditure powers (i.e.fiscal

    autonomy) is that it increases the accountability and responsiveness of sub-central

    governments. In the economic literature, it is generally agreed that fiscal decentralisationresults in a number of economic welfare gains, and that a willingness to mobilise local revenue

    is the most allocative efficient way of organising public finance (Pola, 1996; OECD 1999).

    The counter-economic argument, made in the 1950s in a climate of welfare economics (the

    legacy of which continues to restrain local government fiscal autonomy), was that only central

    governments could achieve local economic efficiency through policies of fiscal equalisation

    and redistribution (Tiebout, 1956; Musgrave, 1973).

    Diversity in Local Government Finance

    The most striking feature of local government finance in OECD countries is the amount of

    diversity that exists. There is wide variation in the proportion of local government spending

    which is financed from revenue sources under local control. There are variations in the

    numbers of local taxes, and in the extent to which particular tax bases are allocated to local

    government. This diversity is explained, in part, by the fundamental differences in the context

    and functions of local government in the different member states. The diversity of functions

    reflect the balance between the choice and agency roles that local government can perform.

    In the choice model, local governments may be seen as a means of allowing local communities

    to make decisions which match their needs and preferences better than centralised decisions

    could. In the agency model, local government is seen as a vehicle for the implementation of

    policies and decisions of central government. In this case, central government will wish to see

    a decision-making process which allows local discretion to be exercised only to the extent that

    it does not conflict with the objectives of the centre (Smith, 1996). While local governments

    universally combine elements of both roles, countries will tend more towards one or other of

    these models. The diversity of contexts has to do with political culture and administrative

    tradition, so that while some broad grouping of countries can be attempted, there is often as

    much variation within these groupings as between them. Nonetheless for organising purposes

    OECD countries can broadly be seen to fit into one of the following categories: i) Nordic

    countries; ii) Anglo countries; iii) Continental countries (Franco and Prussian models); and iv)

    Eastern countries (exemplified here by Japan but also including Turkey and Greece).

    Overlaying this politico-regional grouping is the constitutional dimension where countries are

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    3/14

    3

    classified as either federal or unitary. ( This latter categorisation has a number of problems,

    discussed below).

    Intergovernmental Transfers and GrantsLocal governments in most OECD countries rely on intergovernmental transfers for a

    substantial percentage of their revenues. The constitutional basis on which the transfers to

    local government are determined varies; some member states (such as Germany) provide such

    transfers through stable tax-sharing arrangements, while others allocate grants on the basis of

    discretionary choices by central government (Smith, 1996). Intergovernmental transfers

    constitute at least 30 per cent of local budgets in many countries and in some (UK, the

    Netherlands, Ireland) more than 70 per cent (OECD, 1997). Central governments becameincreasingly involved in the financing of sub-national governments during the 1960s and 70s,

    initially as a response to growing demands for government services at the local and regional

    levels and then, in their efforts to confront the problem of growing regional and metropolitan

    disparities in the 1980s and 90s , through strategies offiscal equalisation (Caulfield, 1997).

    In the current period of financial austerity at the national level, it is now clear these past

    interventions have placed sub-national governments in a tenuous position. Not only have sub-

    national governments expanded their policy arenas and service provisions but they are now

    having to find new ways to fund programs in the face of cut backs in grants from central

    government. Discretionary transfers are a mixed blessing. Faced with restrictive tax policies,

    local governments rely on central government grants to meet their expenditure shortfalls.

    Moreover, grants are less politically painful forms of revenue raising, and many local

    communities depend on their equalising or redistributive effects. The implications for local

    autonomy will depend on three factors. First, the proportion that grants represent in the total

    revenue budget of local governments; second, the form in which the grant is given, as a

    specific purpose or general grant; and third, the formula used for distributing the grant.

    Beginning in the late 1980s, special-purpose grants became the object of critical examination

    in some countries. The conclusion was that not only did they violate the right of local self-

    determination, but they led to the inefficient use of local resources (Netherlands Scientific

    Council Report, 1990). Indeed, an OECD survey in 1983 supported the argument in favour of

    fiscal autonomy by showing that in countries where local government was not responsible for

    tax decisions, local expenditures increased more rapidly. The trend in government financial

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    4/14

    4

    transfers away from specific purpose payments and towards block grants has been a general

    one in most Member countries. The question is whether the current preference of central

    governments for general grants is more closely related to their efforts to rein in levels of local

    expenditure, than to any real commitment to local autonomy.

    The Data

    The analysis which follows uses as its base data OECD country statistics which are collected

    in an annual publication of the OECD[3]

    . The main aggregate indicator used by the OECD is

    the tax-to-GDP ratio, showing the share of tax revenues in Gross Domestic Product[4]

    .

    Sources of revenue are divided into three categories; (i) tax, (ii) non-tax, and (iii) grants.

    There are two major problems with the data as it is currently calculated. One is the standardclassification of revenue where the assumption has been that the tax share of local government

    revenue is a measure of its fiscal autonomy. The tax classification, however, takes no account

    of local government discretion over locally raised taxes, so that even where local government

    receives a larger share of total tax revenues of general government, this cannot be taken to

    mean greater fiscal independence from central government. For example, while Norway and

    Finland had roughly the same percentage share of general government tax revenue in 1995 (at

    20 and 22 percent respectively) local government in Finland can set its own tax rate whereas

    Norway must accept a centrally determined revenue split.

    A recent project of the OECDs Working Party on Tax Policy Analysis has developed a

    framework for further classification of revenue data based on degrees of autonomy of local

    taxation arrangements. The new classification (still being developed) takes account of a

    countrys institutional arrangements which give more or less control to local authorities (see

    Appendix).

    The combination of all government units operating in a country is typically called general

    government, consisting of four sub-sectors:

    i) federal, central or national government;

    ii) state, provincial, cantonal, or regional governments when they exist within a country;

    iii) local governments including municipalities, school boards, etc.; and

    iv) any supranational authorities exercising taxation and public expenditure functions

    within the national territory(OECD, 1999).

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    5/14

    5

    This leads to the second problem with the OECD revenue data which classifies sub-national

    government revenue as either state or local according to a countrys constitution as federal or

    unitary. Thus, while there is a break down for federal countries between their respective sub-

    national government revenues, there is no similar break down for unitary countries eventhough many of these have intermediate and multiple levels of government. The revenue data

    from unitary countries with cantonal or regional governments is classified by the OECD as

    local, even though these intermediate units of government may exercise a competence

    independently of central government. The OECD in its turn takes this classificatory system

    from the International Monetary Fund which probably has less interest in the institutional

    diversity of government and its ramifications for fiscal policy.

    Local Government Finance Compared

    The following analysis reveals first and foremost the diversity that exists between countries.

    Yet despite this diversity, some common themes and generalisations can be made, especially

    about the directions of change in local government finance. These themes indicate what may

    be some key problems for local government autonomy. However, at this stage of the

    research, the data is indicative only and more detailed country studies will be needed before

    any firm conclusions can be drawn[5]

    .

    Local Government Total Revenue (tax, non-tax and grants) as a percentage of GDP for the

    years 1980 and 1995.

    Denmarks local government has the largest income to GDP followed closely by the other

    Scandinavian countries, Sweden, Norway and Finland. These countries local authorities are,

    of course, responsible for major areas of public spending such as health and education,

    typically provided by state governments in federal countries, and central governments in other

    unitary countries. The financially poorest of thefederal countries are Mexico and Australia.

    New Zealand fares marginally better than Australia, but as the third poorest ofunitary

    countries after Greece and Turkey, indicates New Zealands strong centralist regime. The next

    poorest group of unitary country local governments is Japan, Luxembourg, Iceland and

    France. The Netherlands, Ireland and the UK are financially stronger; but what is significant

    here is that when compared to the 1980 data, it is these latter three countries (together with

    New Zealand) that have lost ground in the 15 year period. Sweden, and to a lesser extent

    Denmark, also suffered a decline in revenue over the period.

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    6/14

    6

    There were marginal increases in most federal country local government revenues over the

    period, while Finland, Spain, Italy, France and Norway made more substantial gains[6]

    .

    Local Government Own Source and Total Revenue, 1995 (as % of GDP)

    By comparing own source revenue to total revenue we can see the degree of local

    government dependence on higher levels of government. In light of the above discussion on

    intergovernmental grants, this is an important comparison for what it says about local

    government autonomy. Countries most heavily reliant on grants are the Netherlands, the UK,

    Ireland, Spain and Italy where more than 70 per cent of total local revenue comes in this form.

    (As newly regionalised countries, Spain and Italy are in a sense special cases). Belgium,

    Canada, and Denmark depend for approximately half their revenues on grants, whereas for

    Norway, Luxembourg and the USA grant income is around 30 percent. Australia, Austria,

    New Zealand and Iceland receive less than 20 per cent of their revenues in grants.

    LOCAL GOVERNMENT TOTAL REVENUE, 1980 AND 1995 ( % OF GDP)

    0.0

    5.0

    10.0

    15.0

    20.0

    25.0

    30.0

    35.0

    40.0

    AUS

    AUT

    BEL

    CAN

    DEU

    SWZ

    USA

    DEN

    FIN

    FRA

    IRL

    ISL

    ITA

    JAP

    LUX

    NLD

    NZL

    NOR

    ESP

    SWE

    UKD

    COUNTRY

    PERCENTAG

    1980

    1995

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    7/14

    7

    Main Taxes as a % of Total Local Tax Revenues, 1997

    There are two main sources of local government tax; these are the income tax and the

    property tax, but there is a wide range of taxes used by many countries, from use tax to goods

    and services tax to payroll tax. The income (and profit tax) is, taken overall, the mostimportant tax for local government in the OECD at an average of 41 per cent. This tax takes

    a number of forms including tax sharing arrangements with higher levels of government

    (Germany); separate tax rates but a central tax system (Belgium); separate rate and allowance

    structures (Sweden); and separate tax systems (Switzerland). The property tax dominates the

    Anglo speaking countries; Australia, for example, is 100 per cent reliant on the property tax.

    In equity terms, it is seen as a regressive tax in that higher income households pay relatively

    less tax than lower income households. The advantage of an income tax over the property taxis seen to be its relative progressivity (OECD, 1983). British experience, however, might

    suggest that a property tax has more to commend it than, for example, a flat rate poll tax

    which is equally regressive and has resulted in a complex system of rebates (Travers, 1989;

    Bird and Slack, 1991). In fiscal autonomy terms the property tax has proved to be the most

    controversial largely because of its inflexibility. It is a highly visible tax and therefore resistant

    to growth[7]

    . Large fluctuations in property values can occur and hence, as a source of income

    for local governments, it is unpredictable. Moreover, it is subject to central governmentcontrols in the form of rate capping. Countries with the most diverse tax bases (and therefore

    LOCAL OWN SOURCE AND TOTAL REVENUE, 1995 ( % OF GDP)

    0.0

    5.0

    10.0

    15.0

    20.0

    25.0

    30.0

    35.0

    40.0

    AUS

    AUT

    BEL

    CAN

    DEU

    SWZ

    USA

    CHE

    DEN

    FIN

    FRA

    IRL

    ISL

    ITA

    LUX

    NLD

    NZL

    NOR

    ESP

    SWE

    TUR

    UKD

    COUNTRY

    PERCENTAGE

    OWN

    SOURCE REV

    TOTAL

    REVENUE

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    8/14

    8

    the greatest flexibility) are Austria, Japan and Spain, where these countries have between six

    and seven different tax bases to draw on.

    Local Government Tax Revenue as a % of GDP 1975, 1985 and 1997

    Tax as a source of income for local government in many OECD countries has steadily declined

    since 1975, most notably in those countries heavily reliant on property tax, and in most federal

    countries. Britain suffered the biggest losses as a direct result of central government policies

    under the Thatcher government. But Norway too has lost ground. Growth in tax over the

    period has occurred in other Nordic and Continental countries and in Japan. As a proportion

    of general tax revenue, however, Japan has lost ground to central government, as has Finland.

    Indeed, most countries have reduced their share of tax at the local government level. The

    notable exceptions are Denmark, France, the Netherlands, Iceland, Italy and Spain.

    MAIN TAXES AS A % OF TOTAL LOCAL TAX REVENUES, 1997

    0%

    20%

    40%

    60%

    80%

    100%

    AUS

    AUT

    BEL

    CAN

    DEU

    SWZ

    USA

    DEN

    FINFRA

    ISL ITA JAP

    LUX

    NLD

    NZL

    NOR

    ESP

    SWE

    UKD

    COUNTRY

    PERCENTAG

    OTHER TAXES

    TAXES ON USE

    SPE GOODS &

    SERV

    GENERAL TAXES

    PROPERTY

    PAYROLL

    INCOME & PROFIT

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    9/14

    9

    LOCAL GOVERNMENT TAX REVENUE AS A % OF GDP 1975, 1985 AND 1997

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    14

    16

    18

    AUS

    AUT

    BEL

    CAN

    DEUSW

    ZUSA

    DEN

    FIN FRA IR

    LISL ITA JA

    PLUX

    NLD

    NZL

    NOR

    ESP

    SWE

    UKD

    COUNTRY

    PERCENTAGE

    1975

    1985

    1997

    LOCAL GOVERNMENT TAX REVENUE AS A % OF GENERAL TAX REVENUE

    1975, 1985 AND 1997

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    35

    AUS

    AUT

    BEL

    CAN

    DEU

    SWZ

    USA

    DNK

    FIN

    FRA

    ISL

    IRL

    ITA

    JPN

    LUX

    NLD

    NZL

    NOR

    ESP

    SWE

    UKD

    COUNTRY

    PERCENTAG

    1975

    1985

    1997

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    10/14

    10

    Local Government Own Source and Tax Revenue, 1995 as a % of GDP

    A comparison of own source (ie. local tax andnon-tax sources of revenue) with tax only

    reveals some important differences and patterns among countries. Japan is the only country

    whose own source income is 100 per cent dependent on tax. Most countries rely for theirown source revenue on a mixture of taxes andfees and charges (or non-tax). Countries

    which rely most heavily on non-tax forms of income are the Netherlands, UK, Ireland,

    Austria, Germany, Switzerland and Finland. The downward trend in tax revenue has been

    partly ameliorated by a substantial shift to non-tax revenue such as user charges. This is

    especially the case in federal countries. In North America( and increasingly in Australia), user

    charges are viewed as highly efficient and politically acceptable (Bird & Slack, 1991; Kincaid,

    1991). Unless they are pure public goods or the policy intention is redistributive, there is thepresumption that local public services should be charged for. To this extent local governments

    in these countries have demonstrated residual powers of local autonomy (Pierre, 1990). Non-

    tax revenue has less appeal in unitary countries which showed variable results. The exceptions

    are Finland where non-tax as a revenue source more than doubled between 1980 to 1995. In

    Norway, the Netherlands, France, Spain and Luxembourg there was growth, but in the UK

    there was a marked decline as there was in Iceland, Sweden and New Zealand. Privatisation of

    local government enterprises has been an important contributing factor to the decline in non-

    tax revenue in the UK and New Zealand (Stoker, 1999; Martin, 1991).

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    11/14

    11

    Local Government Fiscal Autonomy

    Historically, the size of a local governments tax share has been seen as a measure of its fiscal

    autonomy. However, the OECD now recognises that fiscal autonomy is a more complex

    matter. According to its Working Party on Tax Policy Analysis, fiscal autonomy is greatest if

    sub-central governments are free to determine both the taxable base and the rates of a

    particular tax, without any aggregate limits on revenues, base or rate enforced by the central

    government[8]

    . In Table 1 of the working partys report Taxing Powers of State and Local

    Government, 1999 (see Appendix), revenues are organised by degree of tax autonomy usingeight categories as follows

    [9].

    a) sub-central government sets tax rate and tax base

    b) sub-central government sets tax rate only

    c) sub-central government sets tax base only

    d) tax sharing arrangements

    i) SCG determines revenue-split

    ii) revenue-split can only be changed with consent of SCGiii) revenue-split fixed in legislation, may unilaterally be changed by central

    government

    iv) revenue-split determined by central government as part of the annual budget

    process

    e) central government sets rate and base of sub-central government tax[10]

    By way of example, we see in Table 1 (Appendix) that New Zealands local government shareof general government tax at 5 per cent is very much lower than Norways which in 1995

    ,

    0.0

    5.0

    10.0

    15.0

    20.0

    25.0

    AUS

    AUT

    BEL

    CAN

    DEU

    USA

    DEN

    FIN

    FRA

    IRL

    ISL

    ITA

    JAP

    LUX

    NLD

    NZL

    NOR

    ESP

    SWE

    UKD

    COUNTRY

    PER

    CENTAG

    TAXREVEN

    OWN

    SOURC

    REV

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    12/14

    12

    accounted for 20 per cent of total taxes, and yet New Zealands level of autonomy is much

    greater because it has discretion over both the tax rate and base, whereas Norway has

    effectively no fiscal discretion. It can be concluded therefore that countries that have both

    attributes, that is where local government has a relatively large share of national taxationtogether with high fiscal discretion over that share, have more autonomy. These countries

    include Sweden, Switzerland and Japan.

    Conclusion

    From the foregoing analysis we see a great deal of diversity in local government financial

    arrangements around the world. The data shows variations along a number of dimensions.

    These include whether a country is unitary or federal, whether its tax base is primarilyproperty or income; its level of dependence on intergovernmental transfers, and its

    discretionary powers over taxation. The overall picture at the end of the millenium is one of

    fiscal constraint either through reductions in grants or loss of tax revenue and in two cases,

    Britain and New Zealand, a decline in non-tax revenue as services in these countries have been

    progressively privatised. Countries especially affected by a loss in taxation are those

    dependent on the property tax. These mostly Anglo countries have been subject to various

    central government intrusions such as rate-capping or, even more extreme, central government

    take-overs as happened in Britain with the business tax. A partial solution for many countries

    (except New Zealand and Britain which have lost trading enterprises) has been to turn to non-

    tax sources such as user charges to balance their budgets. Central-local decentralisation then

    must be seen as only partial and ultimately unsatisfactory as long as functional responsibilities

    continue to be devolved without an appropriate devolution of fiscal autonomy for local

    governments.

    .

    [1]The Environment, Transport and Regional Affairs Committees Report Local Government

    Finance (1999). See also Modern Local Government, In Touch with the People the White

    Paper, British Government, July, 1998.

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    13/14

    13

    2

    This paper does not enter into theoretical debates on local autonomy which have been more

    than adequately covered by Harold Wolman and Michael Goldsmith (1992) and Desmond

    King (1987,1990)

    [3]OECD. Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (1999)Revenue

    Statistics, 1965/1998. A problem for this paper has been the availability of recent data. Themost recent collected data is for 1997 but here it is only tax revenue that is available. Data

    which includes other sources of income i.e. non-tax and grants is available only for 1995.

    [4]As a comparative measure there are some limitations on the tax-to-GDP ratio including, for

    example, the extent to which countries engage in tax expenditures rather than direct

    government spending; differences in the measurement of GDP between countries; and the

    economic cycle.

    [5]The OECD has 28 member countries and growing. Some new members may not be

    represented in the data because of data gaps from earlier years. The most recent data available

    is for 1997 but is restricted to tax revenue. Where grants and non-tax revenues are included,

    the most recent data available is for 1995.

    [6]Italy and Spain are special cases because of their recently introduced regional governments.

    [7]A good example of this resistance is the celebrated case of Proposition 13 in the State of

    California. See OSullivan et.al. 1995.

    [8]OECD (1999) Taxing Powers of State and Local Government Tax Policy Studies No. 1.

    [9]The Working Party acknowledges that the classification is still not as finely tuned as it

    might be. For example, while the (a) classification indicates the greatest level of autonomy,

    even this does not take account of a central governments ability to impose a limit on total

    revenues to be raised from own taxes. Nor does it take account of central governments not

    infrequent restriction on the band width or range of rates that a local government (otherwise

    free to set the rate) can establish.

    [10]The table shows a predominance of type (b) tax; that is, where SCGs set tax rates only.This category averages approximately 9 per cent of total taxes of general government which is

    exactly half the sub-central government share of total tax. The most important tax base for

    this predominant category (b) is income and profits tax (OECD, 1999).

    REFERENCES

    Bird, R. and E. Slack (1991) Financing Local Government in OECD Countries: the Role of

    Local Taxes and User Charges in J. Owens and G. Panella (eds.)Local Government: an

    International Perspective (North Holland: Amsterdam)

    Caulfield, Janice (1997) Finance, Taxation and Equity within Metropolitan Areas. Paper

    presented to the OECD/Sweden Workshop Governing Metropolitan Areas: Institutions,

    Finance and Partnerships. Stockholm, 4-6 June.

    Martin, J. (1991) Devolution and Decentralization in J. Boston et.al. Reshaping the State:

    New Zealands Bureaucratic Revolution (OUP: Auckland)

  • 7/29/2019 Finance in OECD Countries IMPORTANT

    14/14

    14

    Mathews R. and B. Grewal (1997) The Public Sector in Jeopardy: Australian Fiscal

    Federalism from Whitlam to Keating (Centre for Strategic Economic Studies: Victoria)

    Musgrave, R.A. (1973) Public Finance in Theory and Practice (New York: McGraw Hill)

    Netherlands Scientific Council for Government Policy (1990)Institutions and the City: the

    Dutch Experience

    OECD (Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development) (1999)Revenue Statistics

    1965/1998 Special Feature

    _______ (1997)Managing Across Levels of GovernmentPUMA

    _______ (1983) Taxes on Immovable Property (Committee on Fiscal Affairs and the Ad Hoc

    Group on Urban Problems)

    OSullivan, A. et.al.(1995) Property Taxes and Tax Revolts: the legacy of Proposition 13

    (Cambridge University Press)

    Owens, J. and Norregaard, J. (1991) The Role of Lower Levels of Government: The

    Experience of Selected OECD Countries in J. Owens and G. Panella (eds.)Local

    Government: an International Perspective (North Holland: Amsterdam)

    Pola, G. et. al. (1996)Developments in Local Government Finance (Edward Elgar)

    Pierre, Jon (1990) Assessing Local Autonomy in King, D.S. and J. Pierre Challenges toLocal Government(Sage)

    Smith, S. (1996) European Integration and Local Government Finance in Pola op.cit.

    Stoker, G. (1999) The New Management of Britains Local Governance (Macmillan)

    Teibout, C.M. (1956) A pure theory of local government expendituresJournal of Political

    Economy, vol. 64:5

    Travers, T. (1989) Community Charge and other Financial Changes in J. Stewart and G.

    Stoker (eds.) The Future of Local Government(Macmillan:London)

    Watts, R.L. (1996) Comparing Federal Systems in the 1990s (Institute of Intergovernmental

    Relations: Kingston)