12
Urbanization, Technology, and the Division of Labor: International Patterns Author(s): Jack P. Gibbs and Walter T. Martin Reviewed work(s): Source: American Sociological Review, Vol. 27, No. 5 (Oct., 1962), pp. 667-677 Published by: American Sociological Association Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2089624 . Accessed: 21/03/2012 15:04 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at . http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected]. American Sociological Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to American Sociological Review. http://www.jstor.org

Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

Urbanization, Technology, and the Division of Labor: International PatternsAuthor(s): Jack P. Gibbs and Walter T. MartinReviewed work(s):Source: American Sociological Review, Vol. 27, No. 5 (Oct., 1962), pp. 667-677Published by: American Sociological AssociationStable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2089624 .Accessed: 21/03/2012 15:04

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range ofcontent in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new formsof scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

American Sociological Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access toAmerican Sociological Review.

http://www.jstor.org

Page 2: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

URBANIZATION, TECHNOLOGY, AND DIVISION OF LABOR 667

international relations and read C. Wright Mills' The Causes of World War III. The results were even more striking than in the first pilot study. The students acquired a more informed image of war, and a greater concern with it as a problem. Moreover, some 85% showed an increase in scores on the nuclear knowledge scale, and over 90% showed an increase in scores on the pacifism scale. Clearly, under the circumstances of the pilot studies, knowledge and sophistica- tion were associated with rejection of war rather than acceptance of it.28

28An interesting difference was noted in the ef- fects of the stimuli used in the two pilot studies. "Community of Fear" resulted in marked changes in attitudes on those items of the pacifism scale evaluating the threat of war (for example, the percentage who agreed that "the real enemy today is no longer Communism but rather war itself" increased from 55 to 90 per cent). Agreement with nonmilitary solutions to international problems (items 2, 3, and 7) did not increase, but tended to

These pilot studies are necessarily in- conclusive, although the results are con- sistent with the interpretation that it is not knowledge, interest, and sophistication per se that are associated with acceptance of war, but rather the nature of the information which is readily available. Information garnered from the mass media seems to contribute to acceptance of war, but when the subjects are presented with data and viewpoints ordinarily neglected by the mass media, increased information may have the opposite effect.

decrease, presumably because of a general despair over any solution to the problem of war (a senti- ment which many subjects expressed). The Mills- lecture stimulus resulted in comparable changes in the items evaluating the threat of war, and also in a marked increase in the acceptance of non- military solutions to international problems. For example, the percentage agreeing with item 2-

the U. S. should take unilateral initiatives in dis- armament-increased from 13 to 78 per cent.

URBANIZATION, TECHNOLOGY, AND THE DIVISION OF LABOR: INTERNATIONAL PATTERNS *

JACK P. GIBBS WALTER T. MARTIN

University of Texas University of Oregon

The present paper reports tests of several propositions linking the degree of urbanization, the division of labor, the dispersion of objects of consumption, and the level of technological de- velopment. The propositions provide a basis for deducing a direct relationship between urbanization and dispersion of objects of consumption. The propositions were tested with data for 45 countries. The percentage of' the population residing in metropolitan areas was used as a measure of urbanization, an original measure of the diversification of industry was used as a gauge of division of labor, the per capital consumption of energy was taken as a measure of technological development, and an original measure of the dispersion of external resources was utilized. The degree of relationship was measured by the coefficient of rank- difference correlation. Positive results were obtained for all tests of the propositions.

IN a previous paper 1 the authors ad- vanced a theory which links the degree of urbanization in a society to the spatial

dispersion of objects consumed by the popu-

nation. A series of tests based on pre-World War II data yielded strong supporting evi- dence.2

* Revision of a paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Sociological Association, Washington, D. C., 1962. Certain portions of the research reported here were made possible by sup- port from the Office of Scientific and Scholarly Re- search, University of Oregon, and the Population Research Center, Department of Sociology, The University of Texas.

1Jack P. Gibbs and Walter T. Martin, "Ur-

banization and Natural Resources: A Study in Or- ganizational Ecology," American Sociological Re- view, 23 (June, 1958), pp. 266-277.

2 Additional tests for a larger number of countries and with improved measures of urbanization and dispersion of resources also provided strong sup- port. See Walter T. Martin, "Urbanization and National Power to Requisition External Resources." (Scheduled for publication in Pacific Sociological Review, 5 [Fall, 1962]).

Page 3: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

668 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

The theory does not assume a simple cause and effect relationship; on the con- trary, it recognizes that a high degree of urbanization depends on widely scattered materials and represents the type of spatial organization necessary for acquiring them. The present paper seeks to identify those factors which underlie both urbanization and the dispersion of objects of consumption.

It is helpful to begin by recognizing that a city, as a large population settled in a small area, cannot possibly develop, within its own limits, the materials necessary for its inhabitants to survive. Stated otherwise, a city depends on the acquisition of objects of consumption originating outside of its boundaries. However, as we shall see, it is only through the division of labor and an advanced technology that a population is able to bring material from great distances. It is in this particular connection that the relationship between urbanization and the spatial dispersion of objects of consumption can best be understood. For if large-scale urbanization requires that materials be brought from great distances, and if a high degree of division of labor and technologi- cal development are necessary for this, then the level of urbanization is contingent, at least in part, on the division of labor and technology.

DISPERSION OF OBJECTS OF CONSUMPTION,

DIVISION OF LABOR, AND

LEVEL OF TECHNOLOGY

For purposes of discussion two types of dispersion of objects of consumption are distinguished. The degree of "internal dis- persion" in a society refers to the average distance between the points of origin of raw materials and the points at which the mate- rials are consumed, with both points being within the society's boundaries. The degree of "external dispersion," on the other hand, is the average distance between the points when the origin is outside the society.

A high degree of internal dispersion im- mediately suggests that the society is char- acterized by territorial specialization and a certain minimal level of technology. As a rule, objects are not imported unless they are derived from raw materials that are not a natural resource of the area. Speaking

colloquially, one does not take coal to New- castle. It is this exchange among different geographical areas of a society that forms one dimension of the division of labor. The very fact of exchange means that different objects are being produced. This is a basic factor in occupational differentiation. Fur- ther division of labor is suggested by the fact that movement of materials necessitates the development of specialized occupations related to transportation and communica- tion. The movement of materials also re- quires the establishment of commercial in- stitutions and related occupations to facil- itate the exchange. In addition, the flow of raw materials often calls for processing to reduce their bulk or to preserve them. This activity forms the basis for numerous occu- pations and industries. In each of these in- stances, the development of specialized oc- cupations and industries goes hand in hand with technological advances.

The development of specialized occupa- tions and industries, for whatever reason, leads to the use of greater varieties and amounts of raw materials. On a proba- bilistic basis, this makes for a greater disper- sion of objects of consumption. Moreover, occupational specialization plays a major role in the creation of new objects of con- sumption. For example, unlike certain food items, rubber in its raw state is relatively useless. However, given occupational spe- cialization and a certain type of technologi- cal system, raw rubber can be processed and put to many uses, and it is sought over the world as a consequence.

Still another consideration is the fact that different kinds of raw materials may be com- bined in a way that increases the demand for each. Thus, the automobile has increased the demand for both rubber and steel. As a consequence, these materials travel great distances between their raw material states and points of acceptance as parts on an automobile. Such combinations, needless to say, are not possible without an elaborate division of labor and an advanced tech- nology.

Most of what has been said about the relationship of internal dispersion to tech- nology and occupational specialization ap- plies equally well to external dispersion. The establishment of trade with countries

Page 4: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

URBANIZATION, TECHNOLOGY, AND DIVISION OF LABOR 669

throughout the world requires, as a rule, the production and processing of a variety of different objects for exchange. Even if a country can establish extensive trade rela- tions on the basis of one natural resource, it is still necessary to have transportation, communication, and commercial industries to process the export and handle the flow of imports.

The line of reasoning pursued in the earlier paper led to the following proposi- tion: The degree of urbanization in a society varies directly with the dispersion of objects of consumption.3 This generalization, even when strongly supported by empirical data, does not explain the relationship. However, the additional observations expressed above generate four propositions which link urban- ization to dispersion. In propositions IA and IB the division of labor serves as the con- necting link:

IA. The degree of urbanization in a society varies directly with the divi- sion of labor;

IB. The division of labor in a society varies directly with the dispersion of objects of consumption.

In propositions IIA and IIB the connect- ing link is the level of technological devel- opment:

IIA. The degree of urbanization in a society varies directly with tech- nological development;

IIB. Technological development in a society varies directly with the dis- persion of objects of consumption.

Note that if these statements are treated as postulates, the proposition advanced in the earlier paper can then be stated as a derived theorem. In addition, there is an important corollary proposition: III. The degree of the division of labor in a society varies directly with technological develop- ment. Thus, it can be seen that all of the propositions are logically interrelated in such a way that evidence supporting any one of the propositions can be regarded as lending credence to all of them. Specifically, propositions IA, IB, and IIA, IIB, if sup- ported by the data, will show that the direct

relationship between urbanization and dis- persion of objects of consumption is neither fortuitous nor inexplicable.

THE DIVISION OF LABOR AND ITS MEASURE-

MENT AT THE SOCIETAL LEVEL

The concept of division of labor has had a somewhat strange career in the history of sociology. On the one hand, the concept has achieved wide acceptance, particularly since Durkheim's classic treatment.4 On the other hand, it is rarely employed in the generation of testable hypotheses. This is even true for the field of human ecology where, like competitions the concept is often invoked in pure theory but remains in the background as far as research is concerned.

The empirical referents of the division of labor have yet to be specified in any rigorous fashion, but there are two general ideas associated with the concept. First, there is the suggestion of occupational dif- ferentiation. However, more is involved than individuals "doing different things." In ad- dition to differentiation there is functional interdependence. Occupational groups do something more than produce different goods and services. They also exchange goods and services and it is this exchange which under- lies occupational differentiation.

A second idea associated with the con- cept is often confused with the first. In the process of differentiation a person's occu- pational status may be determined, more or less, by biological characteristics, ethnic- caste status, or territorial location. These distinctions may be called the bases of the division of labor, but they are not to be confused with the degree of the division of labor. Occupations in a society may be closely correlated with non-occupational distinctions, but, at the same time, the num- ber of different occupations may be small. This means a low degree of division of labor.

If one is concerned, as we are here, with the degree and not the basis of the division

3 Gibbs and Martin, op. cit., p. 270; Martin, op. cit.

4 Emile Durkheim, The Division of Labor in Society, translated by George Simpson, Glencoe, Illinois: The Free Press, 1949. Durkheim suggests a direct relationship between division of labor and urbanization in this work (pp. 256-260).

5 Amos H. Hawley, "Ecology and Human Ecol- ogy," Social Forces, 22 (May, 1944), p. 401.

Page 5: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

670 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

TABLE 1. ILLUSTRATIONS OF THE MEASUREMENT OF INDUSTRY DIVERSIFICATION

Hypothetical Hypothetical United States New Zealand Industries Society A Society B 1950 * 1951 *

Agriculture, forestry, hunting and fishing 500,000 2,000,000 7,331,353 135,889

Mining and quarrying ...... 2,000,000 968,702 7,807 Manufacturing ...... 2,000,000 16,113,479 177,430 Construction ...... 2,000,000 3,743,183 62,314 Electricity, gas, water,

and sanitary services ...... 2,000,000 797,528 8,298 Commerce ...... 2,000,000 11,082,470 121,681 Transport, storage, and

communication ...... 2,000,000 4,184,123 78,066 Services ...... 2,000,000 14,221,018 143,936 Not classifiable elsewhere ...... 2,000,000 1,595,591 5,075

2X 500,000 18,000,000 60,037,447 740,496 JX2 25,000,000,000 3,600,000,000,000 674,090,085,916,761 95,603,959,708

1- [ JX2/(2(X2)] .0000 .8889 .8130 .8256

* Source of data: Demographic Yearbook, 1956, Table 12.

of labor, then the most relevant data per- tain to occupations and industries. The dis- tinction between occupation and industry in the analysis of the degree of the division of labor has evidently not been determined, conceptually or empirically. For present pur- poses, however, it makes little difference since the only data available for a large number of countries pertain to the industry composition of the labor force (i.e., the economically active population). The data consist of the number of persons in nine industry categories by countries and terri- tories, as reported by the United Nation's Statistical Office.6 Only autonomous coun- tries have been considered in this study, and many of these could not be included because data on them were either not avail- able or not reported in a way comparable to other countries.

The industry categories employed in the Statistical Office's report are shown in Table 1, with the United States and New Zealand serving as examples.

Regardless of the type of measure con- sidered, there are certain obvious short- comings in the industry statistics. The cate- gories, for one thing, are far too gross, par- ticularly manufacturing, commerce, and services. In addition, they do not directly

take occupational differentiation into ac- count. Furthermore, the data at best only indicate differentiation and not the degree of functional interdependence.

Certain technical deficiencies are also present in the data. There are reasons to believe that the industry categories are not applied in an absolutely uniform way from one country to the next. This is particularly true for the category "Not classifiable else- where." This category was retained only after experimentation revealed that its ex- clusion had no appreciable effect on the adopted measure. A more detailed discus- sion of limitations as to reliability and com- parability is provided in the Statistical Office's report.7

Measurement of the degree of division of labor. The statistics at hand make possi- ble only a measure of industry diversifi- cation, and it is used on the assumption that it would bear a close relationship to a more refined measure of the division of labor. In columns 1 and 2 of Table 1, two hypo- thetical societies are considered-one (So- ciety A) in which industry diversification is at a minimum and the other (Society B) in which it is at a maximum. To measure the deviation of countries from these polar types a formula has been developed which differentiates between the two. With "X" as the number of persons in each of the nine industry categories, this formula is: 1 [EX2/(YX)2]. Where all of the economi-

6 United Nations, Demographic Yearbook, 1956, New York: 1956, Table 12, pp. 344-387. Some data on occupations by countries are also reported in this source (Table 13), but they are not nearly as complete and comparable as is the case for in- dustry data. 7 Ibid., p. 38.

Page 6: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

URBANIZATION, TECHNOLOGY, AND DIVISION OF LABOR 671

TABLE 2. PERCENTAGE OF POPULATION IN METROPOLITAN AREAS AND MEASURES OF INDUSTRIAL

DIVERSIFICATION, TECHNOLOGICAL DEVELOPMENT, AND THE EXTERNAL DISPERSION OF

OBJECTS OF CONSUMPTION, FOR 45 COUNTRIES, Circa, 1950

(Col. 1) (Col. 2) (Col. 3) (Col. 4)

Percentage Measure of Measure of Measure of of Population Industrial Technological External

in Metro- Diversification Development Dispersion Country politan Areas* (MID) ** (MTD) * (MED) ****

Argentina, 1947 44.6 .8147 0.76 604 Australia, 1947 55.4 .8348 3.12 1457 Austria, 1951 37.7 .7911 1.54 237 Belgium, 1947 41.4 .7969 0.28 793 Canada, 1951 42.7 .8197 6.47 1373 Ceylon, 1946 9.5 .6723 0.08 197 Colombia, 1951 19.3 .6624 0.27 119 Costa Rica, 1950 19.9 .6565 0.24 224 Cuba, 1953 26.1 .7420 0.48 248 Denmark, 1950 37.3 .8007 2.09 464 Dominican Republic, 1950 11.2 .6293 0.09 100 Ecuador, 1950 14.9 .6793 0.12 81 Egypt, 1947 19.6 .6394 0.22 143 El Salvador, 1950 11.9 .5689 0.09 134 Finland, 1950 17.0 .7193 1.17 509 France, 1954 34.7 .8100 2.03 360 Greece, 1951 22.0 .7114 0.22 235 Guatemala, 1950 10.5 .5086 0.14 82 Haiti, 1950 6.0 .3010 0.02 46 Honduras, 1950 7.3 .3029 0.15 73 India, 1951 7.8 .4788 0.10 34 Ireland, 1951 27.5 .7631 1.10 504 Israel, 1948-52 55.8 .8187 0.80 919 Japan, 1950 36.6 .7055 0.78 164 Malaya, 1947 12.7 .5500 0.28 846 Mexico, 1950 20.6 .6303 0.60 95 Netherlands, 1947 45.5 .8132 1.96 655 New Zealand, 1951 43.6 .8256 2.43 3310 Nicaragua, 1950 13.3 .5140 0.09 51 Norway, 1950 21.8 .8098 4.37 738 Pakistan, 1951 5.1 .4033 0.04 42 Panama, 1950 23.9 .6956 0.30 234 Paraguay, 1950 15.6 .6549 0.02 104 Peru, 1940 11.0 .5816 0.19 58 Philippines, 1948 10.3 .5418 0.09 235 Portugal, 1950 19.6 .7073 0.26 129 Spain, 1950 25.5 .7014 0.57 41 Sweden, 1950 22.4 .8007 3.22 873 Switzerland, 1950 28.9 .7762 2.15 882 Thailand, 1947 6.8 .2735 0.02 35 Turkey, 1950 9.5 .4082 0.26 82 Union of So. Africa, 1951 29.9 .7059 1.89 796 United Kingdom, 1951 71.5 .7687 4.42 1188 United States, 1950 55.9 .8130 7.74 381 Venezuela, 1950 25.2 .7597 0.77 420

* Source: Data prepared by International Urban Research. These percentages supersede earlier provisional figures reported by Gibbs and Davis in the American Sociological Review, 23 (October, 1958), pp. 504-514.

**Source: Demographic Yearbook. See text for a description of the measure. *** Source: Statistical Yearbook. Commercial consumption of energy expressed in metric tons of

coal per capita. **** Source: United Nations, Statistical Papers, Series T, Vol. 6, No. 10. See text for a description

of the measure.

Page 7: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

672 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

cally active are concentrated in one industry, the measure would be .0000; and for a popu- lation with an even distribution throughout the nine industries the measure would be .8889. Measures of industry diversification for 45 countries are shown in column 2 of Table 2.

A problem in measurement is posed with regard to one of the polar types, the so- ciety in which industry diversification is at a maximum (.8889). For a population to reach this point the number of economi- cally active in what is usually considered a minor industry (public utilities, for ex- ample) would have to equal the num- ber in a major industry (agriculture and manufacturing). This suggests that the polar type is unrealistic in that it is virtually im- possible for a society to resemble it. The objection is made less serious by the fact that 14 of the 45 countries are within .1000 of the maximum value, while none of the countries is this close to the lowest possible value. There would appear to be little doubt, however, that numerous historical societies and non-literate peoples closely resembled the polar type in which the measure is at a minimum.

LEVEL OF TECHNOLOGICAL DEVELOPMENT

AND ITS MEASUREMENT AT THE

SOCIETAL LEVEL

Technology, like division of labor, is a concept frequently utilized in sociological discourse, especially in observations on the location, growth, development, and physical structure of individual cities.8 Less attention has been given to the relationship between technological development and the amount or rate of urbanization, but observations and research findings do suggest that the two are closely related.9

Among sociologists, at least, there appears to be a general consensus as to the meaning

of technology.10 In some cases there is an emphasis on technology as material culture, a conception which is rejected by those who stress the ideational content, i.e., the application of knowledge and beliefs.11 De- spite the differing emphases, however, there is general recognition that technology in- volves the application of knowledge and beliefs in carrying out tasks and includes the artifacts developed to reduce the amount of labor or to accomplish what cannot be achieved by manpower alone. In societies where technical knowledge is primitive, the utilitarian artifacts are simple and operate with little or no use of inorganic energy; where technical knowledge is highly ad- vanced there is a great complex of utilitarian artifacts that operate largely through inor- ganic energy. Stated otherwise, societies with primitive technologies are low-energy societies, those with advanced technologies are high-energy societies.12 Thus, the best indicator of the level of technological de- velopment would appear to be the per capita consumption of energy.13 In this study the data used are for the estimated consumption of commercial sources of energy expressed in metric tons of coal per capita reported in the Statistical Yearbook.14 These data are shown in column 3 of Table 2 for 45 coun- tries.

MEASURES OF THE DEGREE OF URBANIZATION

Census reports and publications of the United Nation's Statistical Office make pos- sible a variety of measures of urbanization

8 See, e.g., William Fielding Ogburn, "Technology and Cities: The Dilemma of the Modern Metropo- lis," The Sociological Quarterly, 1 (July, 1960), pp. 139-153.

9 Kingsley Davis, "The Origin and Growth of Urbanization in the World," American Journal of Sociology, 60 (March, 1955), pp. 431-432; and Jack P. Gibbs and Leo F. Schnore, "Metropolitan Growth: An International Study," American Jour- nal of Sociology, 66 (September, 1960), pp. 160- 170.

10 Francis R. Allen, et al., Technology and Social Change, New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts, Inc., 1957, Chapter 1.

11 Kingsley Davis, Human Society, New York: Macmillan Company, 1949, pp. 435-436; Robin M. Williams, Jr., American Society, New York: Alfred A. Knopf, 1960, p. 24.

12 See Fred Cottrell, Energy and Society, New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc., 1955.

13 See William F. Ogburn and Francis R. Allen, "Technological Development and Per Capita In- come," American Journal of Sociology, 65 (Sep- tember, 1959), pp. 127-131; William F. Ogburn, "Technology and the Standard of Living in the United States," American Journal of Sociology, 60 (January, 1955), pp. 380-386; William F. Og- burn, "Population, Private Ownership, Technology, and the Standard of Living," American Journal of Sociology, 56 (January, 1951), pp. 314-319.

14 United Nations, Statistical Yearbook, 1953, New York: 1953, Table 127, pp. 276-278.

Page 8: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

URBANIZATION, TECHNOLOGY, AND DIVISION OF LABOR 673

at the national level. However, the most reliable and comparable measure is the per- centage of the total population who reside in the Metropolitan Areas delimited by In- ternational Urban Research.15 The percent- age is shown for 45 countries in column 1 of Table 2.

MEASUREMENT OF EXTERNAL DISPERSION

OF OBJECTS OF CONSUMPTION

The measure of the external dispersion of objects of consumption (MED) used in the present research is considerably im- proved over the one employed in the earlier study,16 although still necessarily far from precise. It considers the amount of materials (expressed in dollar value) imported by a given country from all other countries and the distance the materials are transported in each instance. For example, in the case of Switzerland, the dollar value of imports in 1951 was obtained for each country ex- porting to Switzerland. The value of each country's shipments 17 was then multiplied by the distance between the center of that country and the center of Switzerland fol- lowing usual traffic lanes as closely as pos- sible.18 The resulting products were summed and the total divided by the 1950 popula- tion of Switzerland to give a per capita figure.19 This per capita figure is thus a

gauge of the extent to which the Swiss na- tion acquired globally dispersed objects. MED's for 45 countries are shown in column 4 of Table 2. There are clearly many defi- ciencies in this measure, e.g., (1) the weight of goods imported is not considered; (2) the measure assumes that all goods originate at the geographic center of the exporting country and are consumed at the approxi- mate geographic center of the importing country, an assumption that obviously dis- torts the situation; 20 and (3) the measure necessarily assumes that the movement of all goods between any two countries follows a single route. These deficiencies appear to influence the preciseness of the measure rather than its general ability to rank coun- tries in terms of the external dispersion of their objects of consumption. Thus there appears to be no doubt that objects of con- sumption in New Zealand and Canada are much more externally dispersed than are those in Thailand, Pakistan, and even the United States. Note, however, that in no instance does MED reveal the "internal dispersion" of objects of consumption, and a truly adequate test of any theory pertain- ing to dispersion of objects of consumption cannot be conducted without considering both external and internal dispersion. Since international data on internal dispersion are not available, it has been necessary to assume that there is a fairly close relation between the two kinds of dispersion. How- ever, this may not be true for certain coun- tries (particularly the large ones), and therefore some exceptions to the predicted relationship between dispersion and other variables are not unexpected.

TESTS OF THE PROPOSITIONS

According to proposition IA, there is a direct relationship at the societal level be- tween the degree of urbanization and the division of labor. On this basis we should find a high positive correlation between the percentage of the population in Metropolitan

15 See Jack P. Gibbs and Kingsley Davis, "Con- ventional Versus Metropolitan Data in the Inter- national Study of Urbanization," American Socio- logical Review, 23 (October, 1958), pp. 505-514; and International Urban Research, The World's Metropolitan Areas, Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, 1959.

16 Gibbs and Martin, op. cit. 17 Statistical Office of the United Nations, "Di-

rection of International Trade," in Statistical Pa- pers, Series T, Vol. 6, No. 10.

18 This figure was calculated in most cases by taking sea-lane mileage between major ports and adding the approximate mileage from the two ports to the center of their respective countries.

19 The operations can be summarized as follows: n 2 (XI) (YI)+(XJ) (Yj)?. (X.) (Yn) i XPa X1000

Where: i... n countries from which imports are received.

Xi: $ value of imports from country i. Yi: estimated average miles imports from

i were transported. Pa: population of the importing country.

20 In a few extreme cases an adjustment was made to take into account the fact that the heavy concentration of population near the port of entry made it very unlikely that on the average the im- ported materials were transported as far as the center of the country.

Page 9: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

674 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Areas and the measures of industrial di- versification. A rank-order correlation co- efficient of +.91 between the values in columns 1 and 2 of Table 2 provides strong support for the proposition.

Proposition IB anticipates a direct rela- tionship between the division of labor and the dispersion of objects of consumption. The two variables used to test the propo- sition are the measures of industrial diversi- fication and the measures of external dis- persion in columns 2 and 4 of Table 2. Rho in this instance is +.83 and, accordingly, consistent with the proposition.

On the basis of proposition IIA, a direct relationship should hold between the per- centage of the population in Metropolitan Areas and the measures of technological development shown in column 3 of Table 2. A rho value of +.84 indicates that the re- lationship is substantially as predicted.

The prediction in the case of proposition IIB is the existence of a direct relationship between the measures of technological de- velopment and the measures of external dispersion of objects of consumption. A rho value of +.79 is thus consistent with the proposition.

Finally, proposition III leads to the pre- diction of a direct relationship between the measures of industrial diversification and the measures of technological development. A rho of +.85 represents supporting evi- dence.21

Another aspect of the relationships. If both the division of labor and technological development are closely linked to the dis- persion of objects of consumption, then their relationship to urbanization should conform to a particular pattern. The earlier study 22 revealed that dispersion of objects of consumption bears the closest relation- ship to large-scale urbanization,23 the per-

centage of the total population in urban places of 100,000 population or more, and the least relationship to small-scale urban- ization, the percentage of the total popula- tion in urban places of 5,000-9,999 inhabi- tants. Similar findings based on more recent data have also been reported elsewhere.24 These differential relationships were antici- pated on the grounds that large-scale urban- ization makes it necessary for the inhabitants of the large cities to draw their objects of consumption from a great distance. A large proportion of the population in small urban places, however, does not necessitate a high degree of dispersion of objects of consump- tion, since the inhabitants of such places can live off their immediate environs. In short, the percentage in small urban places varies independently of the dispersion of ob- jects of consumption because a high degree of dispersion is not a necessity for survival.

Just as it is necessary for the popula- tions of large cities to draw objects of con- sumption from great distances so is it equally necessary for them to have a high degree of division of labor and technologi- cal development to accomplish the task. Conversely, small urban places can survive with or without a high degree of division of labor and technological development. If this is the case, then MID and MTD should be more closely associated with large- scale urbanization than with small-scale urbanization.

The data in Table 3 provide a basis for a test of the hypothesis stated above. They show for each of 41 countries the percentage of the population who reside in urban local- ities by size range of localities.25 Variation in census practices makes it necessary to consider two types of localities. Type A localities are agglomerations delimited with- out regard to political boundaries. They

21 Rho was used in this series of tests rather than r because of the existence of non-linear relation- ships in all cases. In each instance, an increase in one variable beyond a certain point is associated with progressively greater or smaller increase in the other variable. Although rho is applicable in such cases, it probably underestimates the degree of as- sociation. The relationships should eventually be expressed as a correlation ratio (eta).

22 Gibbs and Martin, op. cit. 23 Referred to in the earlier study as "metro-

politanization."

24 Martin, op. cit. 25 Five of the countries in Table 2 (Austria,

Belgium, Egypt, Spain, and Switzerland) are not included in Table 3 because their locality statistics in the Demographic Yearbook are based on minor civil divisions (Type C localities) rather than Type A or Type B localities. Yugoslavia is the only country in Table 3 which is not also in Table 2. It was excluded from Table 2 because data relating to Metropolitan Areas and imports could not be obtained. MID for Yugoslavia is .5250, and its MTD is 0.41.

Page 10: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

URBANIZATION, TECHNOLOGY, AND DIVISION OF LABOR 675 TABLE 3. PERCENTAGE OF POPULATION IN URBAN LOCALITIES FOR 41 COUNTRIES, Circa, 1950 *

Percentage of Population in Localities by Size

(Col. 1) (Col. 2) (Col. 3) (Col. 4) (Col. 5) (Col. 6) Countries by 2,000- 5,000- 10,000- 20,000- 50,000-

Type of Locality ** 4,999 9,999 19,999 49,999 99,999 100,000+

Type A Argentina, 1947 5.6 4.2 4.4 6.2 4.9 37.2 Australia, 1947 7.8 4.8 4.3 4.9 1.0 51.4 Cuba, 1953 5.9 4.1 4.4 8.0 6.6 21.9 Denmark, 1950 3.1 4.3 6.6 8.1 3.2 33.5 France, 1954 7.8 5.6 7.0 8.6 6.2 15.0 India, 1951 16.6 5.8 3.3 3.3 2.1 6.6 Ireland, 1951 5.0 3.3 3.9 4.6 6.1 17.6 Israel, 1949 7.4 4.3 10.6 5.7 0.0 45.6 Netherlands, 1947 9.0 7.5 6.3 8.5 8.6 32.7 Norway, 1950 3.8 1.9 5.7 6.7 6.2 19.8 Pakistan, 1951 0.2 0.9 1.1 2.1 0.8 5.1 Portugal, 1950 6.6 5.2 3.0 3.7 0.0 12.7 Sweden, 1950 6.5 5.1 7.3 7.5 6.1 19.4 United States, 1950 4.8 4.1 4.2 5.2 2.9 43.9

Type B Canada, 1951 5.4 5.1 5.1 7.6 4.2 23.3 Ceylon, 1946 0.4 0.8 2.6 2.7 3.3 5.4 Colombia, 1951 5.6 3.6 3.1 4.2 3.5 14.7 CostaRica, 1950 4.9 4.9 7.9 0.0 10.9 0.0 Dominican Republic, 1950 3.0 2.5 4.9 0.0 2.6 8.5 Ecuador, 1950 3.7 2.7 3.5 3.2 0.0 14.6 El Salvador, 1950 5.9 4.4 4.4 1.4 2.8 8.7 Finland, 1950 3.5 3.4 6.0 8.0 0.0 14.2 Greece, 1951 11.4 4.4 7.1 10.8 3.3 12.7 Guatemala, 1950 7.1 4.3 1.3 1.0 0.0 10.2 Haiti, 1950 1.8 1.9 1.2 0.8 0.0 4.3 Honduras, 1950 5.4 2.0 3.0 1.5 5.3 0.0 Japan, 1950 1.6 7.3 8.6 8.9 7.6 25.6 Malaya, 1947 3.1 2.2 1.9 6.9 2.8 7.4 Mexico, 1950 10.9 5.7 4.9 5.3 3.6 15.1 New Zealand, 1951 5.5 3.2 2.8 12.6 8.8 32.8 Nicaragua, 1950 6.3 2.7 3.8 4.9 0.0 10.3 Panama, 1950 8.7 6.0 5.4 0.0 6.5 15.9 Paraguay, 1950 7.9 1.8 3.2 0.0 0.0 15.2 Peru, 1940 5.1 2.9 3.6 3.4 2.1 8.4 Philippines, 1948 7.2 4.9 2.6 2.2 0.7 3.4 Thailand, 1947 0.1 0.9 2.2 2.2 0.0 4.5 Turkey, 1950 6.3 3.7 4.2 4.4 1.9 8.2 Union of So. Africa, 1951 3.6 3.0 2.5 2.5 4.2 24.0 United Kingdom, 1951 2.1 3.6 7.1 16.1 14.7 36.1 Venezuela, 1950 7.3 5.6 4.6 7.5 4.1 20.6 Yugoslavia, 1948 0.0 1.0 3.1 4.1 1.9 6.3

* Sources: Demographic Yearbook and census reports. ** See text for a description of the two types of localities.

therefore correspond to an urban area as a physical entity, in much the same sense as the Urbanized Areas delimited by the Bureau of the Census. Type B localities, in contrast, have definite administrative limits and thereby correspond to cities as political entities.

According to the hypothesis in question,

we should find that the magnitude of the correlation coefficients between MID or MTD and component measures of urban- ization increase directly with the size range of the urban localities. Thus, the coefficient of correlation should be at a minimum for urban localities of 2,000-4,999 inhabitants and at a maximum where the size of the

Page 11: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

676 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

TABLE 4. RANK-ORDER COEFFICIENTS OF CORRELA-

TION BY COUNTRIES BETWEEN MEASURES OF

TECHNOLOGICAL DEVELOPMENT AND THE

PERCENTAGE OF THE POPULATION IN

URBAN LOCALITIES *

Countries Grouped by Type of Locality **

Urban Localities Type B Types A and B by Size Range (N=27) (N=41)

100,000+ .652 .79 50,000-99,999 .648 .56 20,000-49,999 .67 .72 10,000-19,999 .43 .55 5,000- 9,999 .51 .40 2,000- 4,999 .01 .07

* Sources of data on percentage of population in urban localities: Demographic Yearbook and census reports on individual countries.

** See text for a description of the locality types.

localities is 100,000 or more. Tables 4 and 5 show that the correlation coefficients do vary in substantially the way predicted.

Complete conformity to the predicted pat- tern would prevail if each coefficient were of greater magnitude than all coefficients below it on the urbanization scale and of less magnitude than all coefficients above it on the urbanization scale. Among the Type B countries in Table 4 (which considers the relationship between MTD and com- ponent measures of urbanization) there are only six exception to the expected pattern in a total of 30 comparisons, and the cor- responding figures for Types A and B com- bined are two and 30. On the basis of chance we would expect to find 30 exceptions in

TABLE 5. RANK-ORDER COEFFICIENTS OF CORRELA-

TION BY COUNTRIES BETWEEN MEASURES OF

INDUSTRIAL DIVERSIFICATION AND THE PER-

CENTAGE OF THE POPULATION IN URBAN

LOCALITIES *

Countries Grouped by Type of Locality

Urban Localities Type B Types A and B by Size Range (N=27) (N=41)

100,000+ .77 .87 50,000-99,999 .58 .47 20,000-49,999 .537 .66 10,000-19,999 .536 .58 5,000- 9,999 .43 .29 2,000- 4,999 -.11 .22

* See footnotes for Table 4.

60 comparisons, but there are in fact only eight.

The coefficients of correlation between MID and the component measures of ur- banization in Table 5 also conform closely to the predicted pattern. There is no excep- tion in a total of 30 comparisons for Type B countries, and only six exceptions in the 30 comparisons for Types A and B com- bined. Thus, whereas 30 exceptions in 60 comparisons would be expected on the basis of chance, there are actually only six.

These findings leave little doubt that both the division of labor and technological de- velopment are, as anticipated, more closely related to large-scale urbanization than to small-scale urbanization.

OTHER CONSIDERATIONS AND CONCLUSIONS

The findings of this study and those pre- sented in earlier papers demonstrate con- sistent relationships among urbanization, the division of labor, the level of technological development, and the dispersion of objects of consumption. The relationships are ob- viously not so close as to preclude exceptions. Exceptions do occur, and some of them are probably "real" exceptions, that is, not sub- ject to explanation in terms of inadequate data or crude measures. We do not deny the possibility of exceptions, but we do maintain that societies can deviate only within certain limits and, in any case, there are certain identifiable consequences of devi- ation. For example, some societies may have a much higher degree of urbanization than would be anticipated on the basis of the present propositions. There is, however, a limit as to how high urbanization can go without increases in the division of labor, in technological efficiency, and in the dis- persion of objects of consumption. And, with regard to consequences of deviation, one effect of over-urbanization is likely to be a low standard of living.

The explanation of deviant cases and the identification of the consequences of devi- ation must await improvements in the scope and quality of international statistics, par- ticularly data pertaining to the degree of the internal dispersion of objects of con- sumption and to the division of labor. Even before this, however, we can anticipate al-

Page 12: Gibbs_Martin_Urbanization Technology and the Division of Labor

URBANIZATION, TECHNOLOGY, AND DIVISION OF LABOR 677

ternative explanations of urbanization and the relationships reported here. Of the vari- ous alternative explanations, there is a cer- tain type which particularly deserves con- sideration, because it is traditionally viewed in opposition to the theoretical orientation which characterizes the present paper.

One could argue that a high or low degree of urbanization and the relationship of ur- banization to other variables is largely a matter of socio-cultural values and ideolo- gies. We reject such an interpretation and emphasize that a high degree of urbanization depends on the division of labor, technology, and organization to requisition dispersed materials. The value systems of some socie- ties may in fact favor a high degree of ur- banization, but there is no particular set of values that is a sufficient condition for a high degree of urbanization. It makes no great difference whether the population professes socialism or capitalism, liberalism or conservatism, Buddhism or Free Method-

ism; for if a high degree of urbanization is to be maintained, widely dispersed ma- terials must be requisitioned, and this can be accomplished only through the division of labor and technological efficiency.

Note, however, that the writers do not deny that values and ideologies may largely determine certain types of behavior. It may even be true that, within certain limits, socio- cultural values and ideologies influence ur- banization. But we do reject these phenom- ena as possible explanations of the particular relationships observed in this study. This would be the case even if a spatial associa- tion between urbanization and certain types of values could be demonstrated. It is en- tirely possible that as urbanization occurs certain values will come to prevail. Un- fortunately, this opens the door to future confusion by making it possible at some later date for observers to conclude that the presence of these values explains urban- ization.