36
GREAT EXPECTATIONS AND A TALE OF TWO CONFOUNDERS A BAYESIAN ANALYSIS OF INVESTOR OVERCONFIDENCE

GREAT EXPECTATIONS AND A TALE OF TWO …mihaylofaculty.fullerton.edu/FacultyWebsites/Daniel-Cavagnaro/... · ... and employee stock- ... investment knowledge > ... B.M., Odean, T.,

  • Upload
    buidiep

  • View
    216

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

GREAT EXPECTATIONS AND A TALE OF TWO CONFOUNDERSA BAYESIAN ANALYSIS OF INVESTOR OVERCONFIDENCE

2

To know what you

know and what you

don’t know, that is

true knowledge

Confucius

Gerlach

Content

• Introduction

• The Impact of Gender and Isolated Decision-Making on Investor Overconfidence

• Diagnostics and Results

• Sensitivity Analysis

• Discussion

311.03.2018

Importance of Overconfidence

411.03.2018

Note: 1-gram and bigram model (Michel et al. (2010), Lin et al.

(2012)) with third order smoothing on books published in English

(Oxford English Dictionaries (2017))

Prior Studies

Post-WWII

•Confidence independent of accuracy (e.g. Goldberg (1959))

•Oskamp (1965) connected both aspects in his seminal paper

1970s

•Lichtenstein, Fischhoff, and Slovic developed consistent measures

•Half-range and fixed interval are still very popular

611.03.2018

Common Measures

• Full-range Interval

• Half-range Interval

• Fixed 90% Confidence Interval

11.03.2018 7

0 100

50 100

Estimate Minimum Maximum

Prior Studies

2000s

• New measures and growing interest from other fields

• E.g. in economics with Shiller (2000), Barber and Odean (2001), Malmendier and Tate (2005)

In Consumer Research

• Alba and Hutchinson (2000), Bearden and Hardesty (2001), Billeter et al. (2010), etc.

Most Recently

• Kyle et al. (2017), Seo et al. (2017), Pikulina et al. (2017), etc.

811.03.2018

Why does it matter?

Behavior

• The 16-year-old who speeds without wearing a seatbelt (Semrud-Clikeman (2001))

Outcome

911.03.2018

NJ.com

Why does it matter?

Behavior

• The 16-year old who speeds without wearing a seatbelt (Semrud-Clikeman (2001))

• The student who willingly increases the probability to fail by answering a bonus question (Bengtsson et al. (2005))

Outcome

1011.03.2018

Clip Art

Why does it matter?

Behavior

• The 16-year old who speeds without wearing a seatbelt (Semrud-Clikeman (2001))

• The student who willingly increases the probability to fail by answering a bonus question (Bengtsson et al. (2005))

• The GM worker who did not diversify and lost his job, health insurance, and employee stock-based retirement fund within a year (Shiller (2014))

Outcome

1111.03.2018

MFI Miami

11.03.2018 12

Overconfidence

Unrealistic optimism Better-than-

average effect

Illusion of knowledgeIllusion of

control

Miscalibration

Self-serving

bias

Contribution

11.03.2018 13

Passive & DescriptiveResearch

Active &

Intervention

Research

Research Questions

What is the impact of

• gender (R1) and

• shared financial decision-making (R2)

on investor overconfidence?

11.03.2018 14

APS

Shared Decision-Making with Financial Planner, Broker, Professional

11.03.2018 15

Intrahouse-hold Decision-Making

Measure of overconfidence

Subjective assessment of investment knowledge > Actual level of

investment knowledge

On a scale from 1 to 7,

where 1 means very low

and 7 means very high,

how would you assess

your overall knowledge

about investing?

10 items worth 0.7 pts

each:

If a company files for

bankruptcy, which of the

following securities is

most at risk of becoming

virtually worthless?11.03.2018 16

Descriptive Statistics

79.50%

11.03.2018 17

Descriptive Statistics

Independent variables

Shared decision-making(binary indicators)

Lone Wolf 30.85%

Primary Decision-maker w/ advisor 35.65%

Intra-household only 10.80%

Intra-household w/advisor 22.25%

11.03.2018 18

Conceptual Model

11.03.2018 19

𝑜𝑐𝑖 = 𝛽0 + 𝛽1𝑠ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑒_𝑜𝑛𝑙𝑦_𝑎𝑑𝑣𝑖 + 𝛽2𝑠ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑒_𝑜𝑛𝑙𝑦_ℎℎ𝑖 + 𝛽3𝑠ℎ𝑎𝑟𝑒_𝑏𝑜𝑡ℎ𝑖 + 𝛽4𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑖 +

𝛽5𝑔𝑒𝑛𝑑𝑒𝑟𝑖 + 𝛽6𝑚𝑎𝑟𝑔𝑖𝑛𝑖 + 𝛽7𝑒𝑑𝑢𝑖 + 𝛽8𝑚𝑎𝑟𝑟𝑖𝑒𝑑𝑖 + 𝛽9𝑖𝑛𝑐𝑖 + 𝛽10𝑒𝑡ℎ𝑛𝑖𝑐𝑖𝑡𝑦𝑖 + 𝜏𝑖 (1)

Priors

11.03.2018 20

PRIOR FOR

REGRESSOR ON

OBJECTIVE MEAN OBJECTIVE

PRECISION

SUBJECTIVE MEAN SUBJECTIVE

PRECISION

SOURCE OF PRIOR

INTERCEPT 0 0.0001 1.6 0.5454 Piehlmaier (2014)

SHARED DM 0 0.0001 -0.157 8.7016 Li and Bao (2016)

AGE 0 0.0001 -0.29 61.3798 Piehlmaier (2014)

GENDER 0 0.0001 0.24 73.4376 Piehlmaier (2014)

ETHNICITY 0 0.0001 0.11 0.1849 Acker and Duck

(2008)

EDUCATION 0 0.0001 -0.93 12.2242 Piehlmaier (2014)

MARITAL STATUS 0 0.0001 0.014 27.9947 Xia et al. (2014)

INCOME 0 0.0001 -0.0188 2.7601 Bhandari and

Deaves (2006)

MARGIN

ACCOUNT

0 0.0001 -0.2215 0.28582 Kyrychenko and

Shum (2009)

RESIDUALS

(GAMMA)

OBJECTIVE

SHAPE

OBJECTIVE

SCALE

SUBJECTIVE

SHAPE

SUBJECTIVE

SCALE

SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS 0.01 0.01 N/A N/A

Informative Priors

11.03.2018 21

Gelman-Rubin

Diagnostic

Parameters Point Estimate Upper 95% CI

Intercept 1 1.01

Only Advisor 1 1.01

Only Household 1 1.00

Both 1 1.00

Age 1 1.00

Gender 1 1.00

Margin 1 1.00

Education 1 1.00

Married 1 1.01

Income 1 1.01

Ethnicity 1 1.00

Tau 1 1.00

Informative Priors

11.03.2018 22

Informative Priors

11.03.2018 23

11.03.2018 24

Highest Posterior Density

Quantiles

Intercept

Only Advisor

Only HH

Both

Age

Gender

Margin

Education

Married

Income

Ethnicity

Tau

Sensitivity Analysis

How are these results affected by the selection of subjective priors?

The sensitivity analysis applies objective priors to Eq. 1

11.03.2018 25

Uninformative Priors

11.03.2018 26

Gelman-Rubin

Diagnostic

Parameters Point Estimate Upper 95% CI

Intercept 1 1.01

Only Advisor 1 1.00

Only Household 1 1.00

Both 1 1.00

Age 1 1.00

Gender 1 1.00

Margin 1 1.00

Education 1 1.00

Married 1 1.02

Income 1 1.00

Ethnicity 1 1.00

Tau 1 1.00

Uninformative Priors

11.03.2018 27

Uninformative Priors

11.03.2018 28

11.03.2018 29

Quantiles

Intercept

Only Advisor

Only HH

Both

Age

Gender

Margin

Education

Married

Income

Ethnicity

Tau

Highest Posterior Density

Model Comparison

Subjective Priors

>Objective Priors

Mean Deviance: 7,694

Penalty: 14.15

Penalized Deviance: 7,708

11.03.2018 30

Mean Deviance: 7,694

Penalty: 12.64

Penalized Deviance: 7,707

Results

Impact of shared decision-making on overconfident investors

With spouse/ someone in household

With broker/ advisor

[9.51%; 1.91%]

4.38% to 0.69%

11.03.2018 31

Key Findings from the Cross-Section

• Sharing investment decision-making reduces overconfidence (R2)

• However, the effect can only be observed when investors share the financial decision-making with someone in their household (e.g., her/his spouse)

• Female investors are significantly more overconfident than male investors (R1)

11.03.2018 32

Limitations of the Cross-Section

• Causality

Endogeneity problem regarding the connection between overconfidence and shared decision-making

• Single measure for key construct

Overconfidence – single measure of subjective knowledge

11.03.2018 33

34

It ain’t what you don’t

know that gets you into

trouble. It’s what you know

for sure that just ain’t so.

Mark Twain

Boston University

DiscussionThank you for your attention

References• Alicke, M.D., Klotz, M.L., Breitenbecher, D.L., Yurak, T.J., Vredenburg, D.S., 1995. Personal contact, individuation, and the

better-than-average effect. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 68, 804.

• Amico, K.R., 2009. Percent Total Attrition: A Poor Metric for Study Rigor in Hosted Intervention Designs. Am. J. Public Health 99, 1567–1575. https://doi.org/10.2105/AJPH.2008.134767

• Araújo, D., Davids, K., Hristovski, R., 2006. The ecological dynamics of decision making in sport. Psychol. Sport Exerc., Judgement and Decision Making in Sport and Exercise 7, 653–676. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.psychsport.2006.07.002

• Arkes, H.R., Christensen, C., Lai, C., Blumer, C., 1987. Two methods of reducing overconfidence. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process. 39, 133–144. https://doi.org/10.1016/0749-5978(87)90049-5

• Barber, B.M., Odean, T., 2001. Boys Will be Boys: Gender, Overconfidence, and Common Stock Investment. Q. J. Econ. 116, 261–292.

• Baumeister, R.F., Heatherton, T.F., Tice, D.M., 1993. When ego threats lead to self-regulation failure: negative consequences of high self-esteem. J. Pers. Soc. Psychol. 64, 141.

• Bechara, A., Damasio, A.R., Damasio, H., Anderson, S.W., 1994. Insensitivity to future consequences following damage to human prefrontal cortex. Cognition 50, 7–15. https://doi.org/10.1016/0010-0277(94)90018-3

• Bechara, A., Damasio, H., Tranel, D., Damasio, A.R., 1997. Deciding advantageously before knowing the advantageous strategy. Science 275, 1293–1295.

• Beer, J.S., 2014. Exaggerated Positivity in Self-Evaluation: A Social Neuroscience Approach to Reconciling the Role of Self-esteem Protection and Cognitive Bias: Social Neuroscience of Exaggerated Positivity. Soc. Personal. Psychol. Compass 8, 583–594. https://doi.org/10.1111/spc3.12133

• Benartzi, S., Thaler, R.H., 2007. Heuristics and Biases in Retirement Savings Behavior. J. Econ. Perspect. 21, 81–104.

• Bengtsson, C., Persson, M., Willenhag, P., 2005. Gender and overconfidence. Econ. Lett. 86, 199–203.

• Bunch, K.M., Andrews, G., Halford, G.S., 2007. Complexity effects on the children’s gambling task. Cogn. Dev. 22, 376–383.

• Campbell, W.K., Sedikides, C., 1999. Self-threat magnifies the self-serving bias: A meta-analytic integration. Rev. Gen. Psychol. 3, 23–43. https://doi.org/10.1037/1089-2680.3.1.23

• Educational Attainment by Selected Characteristic: 2010, 2012. , in: Current Population Survey, Statistical Abstract of the United States. US Census Bureau, p. 152.

• Faja, S., Murias, M., Beauchaine, T.P., Dawson, G., 2013. Reward-based Decision Making and Electrodermal Responding by Young Children with Autism Spectrum Disorders During a Gambling Task. Autism Res. Off. J. Int. Soc. Autism Res. 6, 494–505. https://doi.org/10.1002/aur.1307

• Fischhoff, B., Slovic, P., Lichtenstein, S., 1977. Knowing with certainty: The appropriateness of extreme confidence. J. Exp. Psychol. Hum. Percept. Perform. 3, 552.

• Fuchs, V.R., Krueger, A.B., Poterba, J.M., 1998. Economists’ Views about Parameters, Values, and Policies: Survey Results in Labor and Public Economics. J. Econ. Lit. 36, 1387–1425.

• Gale, C.L., 2017. A Study Guide for Sophocles’s “Oedipus Rex (aka Oedipus the King).” Gale, Study Guides.

• Gibbons, R., Roberts, J., 2013. The Handbook of Organizational Economics. Princeton University Press.

• Goethe, J.W., 2016. Prometheus: Dramatisches Fragment. BoD – Books on Demand.

• Grubb, M.D., 2015. Overconfident Consumers in the Marketplace. J. Econ. Perspect. 29, 9–35.

• Hootman, J.M., Dick, R., Agel, J., 2007. Epidemiology of Collegiate Injuries for 15 Sports: Summary and Recommendations for Injury Prevention Initiatives. J. Athl. Train. 42, 311–319.

• Hughes, B.L., Beer, J.S., 2013. Protecting the self: the effect of social-evaluative threat on neural representations of self. J. Cogn. Neurosci. 25, 613–622.

• Johnson, D.D.P., 2009. OVERCONFIDENCE AND WAR. Harvard University Press.

• Johnson, D.D.P., Fowler, J.H., 2011. The evolution of overconfidence. Nature 477, 317–320. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature10384

• Kerr, A., Zelazo, P.D., 2004. Development of “hot” executive function: The children’s gambling task. Brain Cogn., Development of Orbitofrontal Function 55, 148–157. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0278-2626(03)00275-6

• Lagattuta, K.H., Sayfan, L., 2013. Not All Past Events Are Equal: Biased Attention and Emerging Heuristics in Children’s Past-to-Future Forecasting. Child Dev. 84, 2094–2111. https://doi.org/10.1111/cdev.12082

11.03.2018 36