11
Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden Ing-Marie Gren Monica Campos Lennart Edsman Patrik Bohman Received: 27 December 2007 / Accepted: 28 August 2008 / Published online: 23 October 2008 Ó Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2008 Abstract This article analyzes and carries out an econometric test of the explanatory power of economic and attitude variables for occurrences of the nonnative signal crayfish in Swedish waters. Signal crayfish are a carrier of plague which threatens the native noble crayfish with extinction. Crayfish are associated with recreational and cultural traditions in Sweden, which may run against environmental preferences for preserving native species. Econometric analysis is carried out using panel data at the municipality level with economic factors and attitudes as explanatory variables, which are derived from a simple dynamic harvesting model. A log-normal model is used for the regression analysis, and the results indicate significant impacts on occurrences of waters with signal crayfish of changes in both economic and attitude variables. Variables reflecting environmental and recreational preferences have unexpected signs, where the former variable has a positive and the latter a negative impact on occurrences of waters with signal crayfish. These effects are, however, counter- acted by their respective interaction effect with income. Keywords Attitudes Income Interest rate Invasive species Signal crayfish Sweden Introduction Invasive alien species, defined as ‘‘alien species which become established in natural or semi-natural ecosystems or habitat, is an agent of change, and threatens native biological diversity’’ (IUCN 2000), is not a new phe- nomenon, but can be traced back to the arrival of agriculture 10000 years ago. During the last decades, scientists have documented a number of alien and inva- sive species that have detrimental economic effects, and on biodiversity (e.g., Pimentel and others 2001). Esti- mated annual costs of invasive alien species (IAS) for different countries show a considerable variation with a range of 3 Euro/capita and 344 Euro/capita (Gren and others 2008). However, in spite of ecologists’ and biolo- gists’ relatively early recognition and concern about eventual damage and social costs associated with invasive species, there is relatively little environmental economic research on this topic (e.g., Shogren and Tschirhart 2005). Since most of the scant research has been focused on theoretical analysis of efficient management strategies (e.g., Perrings and others 2000; Horan and Lupi 2005; Knowler and Barbier 2005; Shogren and Tschirhart 2005; Gren 2008), or on cost benefit calculations of programs preventing, controlling, or eradicating damage from spe- cies’ invasion (see Born and others 2005; Lovell and others 2006; Olson 2006), there is insufficient under- standing of the causes for spread of IAS, in particular within a national territory. The purpose of this article is to derive and test hypotheses on the spread of an invasive I.-M. Gren (&) M. Campos Department of Economics, Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences, Box 7013, 750 07 Uppsala, Sweden e-mail: [email protected] M. Campos e-mail: [email protected] L. Edsman P. Bohman Freshwater Laboratory, Bars Holm Road 2, 178 93 Drottningholm, Sweden e-mail: lennart.edsman@fiskeriverket.se P. Bohman e-mail: patrik.bohman@fiskeriverket.se 123 Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220 DOI 10.1007/s00267-008-9210-7

Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species:An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

Ing-Marie Gren Æ Monica Campos ÆLennart Edsman Æ Patrik Bohman

Received: 27 December 2007 / Accepted: 28 August 2008 / Published online: 23 October 2008

� Springer Science+Business Media, LLC 2008

Abstract This article analyzes and carries out an

econometric test of the explanatory power of economic and

attitude variables for occurrences of the nonnative signal

crayfish in Swedish waters. Signal crayfish are a carrier of

plague which threatens the native noble crayfish with

extinction. Crayfish are associated with recreational and

cultural traditions in Sweden, which may run against

environmental preferences for preserving native species.

Econometric analysis is carried out using panel data at the

municipality level with economic factors and attitudes as

explanatory variables, which are derived from a simple

dynamic harvesting model. A log-normal model is used for

the regression analysis, and the results indicate significant

impacts on occurrences of waters with signal crayfish of

changes in both economic and attitude variables. Variables

reflecting environmental and recreational preferences have

unexpected signs, where the former variable has a positive

and the latter a negative impact on occurrences of waters

with signal crayfish. These effects are, however, counter-

acted by their respective interaction effect with income.

Keywords Attitudes � Income � Interest rate �Invasive species � Signal crayfish � Sweden

Introduction

Invasive alien species, defined as ‘‘alien species which

become established in natural or semi-natural ecosystems

or habitat, is an agent of change, and threatens native

biological diversity’’ (IUCN 2000), is not a new phe-

nomenon, but can be traced back to the arrival of

agriculture 10000 years ago. During the last decades,

scientists have documented a number of alien and inva-

sive species that have detrimental economic effects, and

on biodiversity (e.g., Pimentel and others 2001). Esti-

mated annual costs of invasive alien species (IAS) for

different countries show a considerable variation with a

range of 3 Euro/capita and 344 Euro/capita (Gren and

others 2008). However, in spite of ecologists’ and biolo-

gists’ relatively early recognition and concern about

eventual damage and social costs associated with invasive

species, there is relatively little environmental economic

research on this topic (e.g., Shogren and Tschirhart 2005).

Since most of the scant research has been focused on

theoretical analysis of efficient management strategies

(e.g., Perrings and others 2000; Horan and Lupi 2005;

Knowler and Barbier 2005; Shogren and Tschirhart 2005;

Gren 2008), or on cost benefit calculations of programs

preventing, controlling, or eradicating damage from spe-

cies’ invasion (see Born and others 2005; Lovell and

others 2006; Olson 2006), there is insufficient under-

standing of the causes for spread of IAS, in particular

within a national territory. The purpose of this article is to

derive and test hypotheses on the spread of an invasive

I.-M. Gren (&) � M. Campos

Department of Economics, Swedish University of Agricultural

Sciences, Box 7013, 750 07 Uppsala, Sweden

e-mail: [email protected]

M. Campos

e-mail: [email protected]

L. Edsman � P. Bohman

Freshwater Laboratory, Bars Holm Road 2,

178 93 Drottningholm, Sweden

e-mail: [email protected]

P. Bohman

e-mail: [email protected]

123

Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220

DOI 10.1007/s00267-008-9210-7

Page 2: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

species in Sweden, signal crayfish (Pacifastacus lenius-

culus), which include economic and attitude variables as

explanatory factors.

To the best of our knowledge there are only two other

studies testing the explanatory power of different factors

for introduction and spread of alien species, and both

these studies are applied to international spread of inva-

sive species (Dalmazzone 2000; Vila and Pujadas 2001).

Trade is then regarded as an important vector of IAS,

which can ‘‘hitchhike’’ with cargoes and goods or be

traded in the international markets for exotic plants or

animals (e.g., Perrings and others 2000). The trade

hypothesis has been tested by both studies on spread of

invasive species. Dalmazzone (2000) also includes income

per capita as an explanatory variable which is supposed to

reflect the economic activity in a country. This study is

complementary to the two earlier studies on causes of

occurrences of invasive species in two respects: One is the

analysis and empirical test of different factors explaining

spread of an invasive species within a single country,

which is based on unique panel data on occurrences of

signal crayfish in Swedish municipalities. Similar to Dal-

mazzone (2000), economic activity is introduced as an

explanatory variable. The other contribution is the analysis

and test of the explanatory power of variables reflecting

attitudes for the spread of signal crayfish, which extends

the scarce empirical literature on attitudes as determinants

of environmentally friendly behavior (Owen and Videras

2007; Kahn 2007).

By the inclusion of income as explanatory variable to

spread of an invasive signal crayfish in Sweden, the study

is also related to the relatively large literature on the so-

called environmental Kuznets curve, which, since the

seminal contributions of Grossman and Krueger (1995),

has been testing the relation between changes in income

and environmental performance in countries and regions

(see Dinda 2004 for a review). A common result is that

environmental degradation, often measured as emissions

of different pollutants, increases at relatively low income

levels and decreases at higher incomes. An interesting

policy conclusion is then that environmental problems

may vanish as average income grows in a country or

region. In spite of the considerably large number of

studies, there are few studies estimating the relation

between biodiversity-related changes and income (Dal-

mazzone 2000; Ehrardt-Martinez and others 2002;

McPherson and Nieswiadomy 2005). Since these studies

apply cross-country data, this study constitutes a contri-

bution by estimating an environmental Kuznets curve for

biodiversity-related changes by using panel data within a

country. Furthermore, since there is a direct linkage

between action, introduction of signal crayfish, and envi-

ronmental impact, decline of the number of populations of

the endemic noble crayfish (Astacus astacus), this study is

one of the few studies estimating environmental Kuznets

curves for local action and associated environmental

impact.

The article is organized as follows. First, a brief pre-

sentation is provided on traditions and environmental

concern with respect to Swedish signal crayfish. It provides

a basis for the modeling of crayfish introduction, which is

used for identifying explanatory variables in the econo-

metric test. Chapter 4 presents data retrieval of included

variables, which is followed by a chapter presenting the

econometric model and results. The article ends with a

brief summary and discussion.

Background

Sweden has a long tradition of enjoying crayfish as a

delicious food and also as giving recreational pleasure and

economic benefits at harvesting times. The noble crayfish is

the only native crayfish in the country and it is believed to

have immigrated into the country after the last ice age

(Skurdal and others 1999). The species has been appreci-

ated for centuries as a delicacy and was enjoyed already in

the sixteenth century by the Swedish Wasa kings (West-

man and Ackerfors 1992). However, the situation changed

during the nineteenth century when the popularity of

crayfish increased significantly also outside the royal house

and the aristocracy. Stories about crayfish can also be

found by famous authors, such as August Strindberg

(Swahn 2004). Today, Sweden has the highest consump-

tion of crayfish worldwide, which corresponds to 0.5 kg/

person and year. Most is consumed on a few occasions

during the more or less ritual crayfish parties, in which

most Swedes take part, and which are held on the mellow

nights of August. Crayfish caught in Swedish lakes and

rivers accounts for approximately 35% of the total con-

sumption while the rest is imported. Signal crayfish today

account for approximately 85% of the crayfish that is

harvested nationally. However, it is not only the eating of

crayfish that is appreciated but also the harvesting. Rec-

reational fishing by fishing right owners accounts for more

than 90% of the total catch of crayfish in Sweden as

compared to what is caught by commercial fishermen (SBF

2000).

The signal crayfish, originating from North America,

was introduced into Sweden in the 1960s by the authorities,

to substitute for the native noble crayfish fishery which had

been lost, mainly due to the disease crayfish plague caused

by a fungus (Aphanomyces astaci). It was then assumed

that the signal crayfish would fill the ecological niche once

held by the noble crayfish and also be the basis for a

productive fishery, since the species was thought to

Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220 211

123

Page 3: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

resemble the noble crayfish in both morphology and ecol-

ogy (Fjalling and Furst 1985). The plague is a parasite on

crayfish and is spread by infected crayfish and spores in the

water. Infected populations of native crayfish can be wiped

out within a few weeks. The plague was carried to Sweden

in 1907 by infected crayfish from Finland, and 50 percent

of the native noble crayfish populations had been struck by

1960 (Unestam 1969).

The signal crayfish (Pacifastacus lenisculus) is more

resistant to the plague, and for that reason it was introduced

to compensate for the losses in the noble crayfish fishery.

However, in the early 1970s it was realized that the signal

crayfish is a chronic carrier of crayfish plague (e.g., Une-

stam 1972; Cerenius and Edsman 2002), and may also be

susceptible to acute plague when stressed (Cerenius and

Edsman 2002). This, in turn, implies that noble crayfish and

signal crayfish cannot coexist in the same water since the

population of noble crayfish will be infected by the plague.

If signal crayfish is introduced into waters with noble

crayfish, the latter disappears (Fiskeriverket and Natur-

vardsverket 1998). Owing to these impacts on the native

species, a regulation was introduced which requires permits

for introducing signal crayfish in waters. A liberal appli-

cation of this regulation has resulted in a steady increase in

the number of waters with signal crayfish, which now

constitute approximately 25% of all waters where the signal

crayfish population can survive (Bohman and others 2006).

A Simple Model of Signal Crayfish Harvesting

in Sweden

In order to test for causes of spread of signal crayfish in

Sweden, a simple model of a representative water owner’s

decision to introduce and harvest signal crayfish is con-

structed. The main purpose is to identify relevant

parameters and their expected signs in the regression

equation presented in Chapter 5. Admittedly, due to lack of

data, there is no perfect match between the variables in this

theoretical chapter and in the reduced regression form,

which allows for a thorough test of the model. Neverthe-

less, we argue that the theoretical exercises carried out in

this chapter are useful by its guidance of choice of inde-

pendent variables included in the econometric test and in

assessing their impact on occurrences of signal crayfish.

The basic assumption is then that a representative water

owner introduces signal crayfish, S, when the streams of

discounted net utility of introducing crayfish, V(S), at the

steady-state level of the stock, S*, is positive, i.e. when

V(S*) [ 0 where V(S) is the value function.

Utility from crayfish introduction arises from provision

of several different attributes, such as recreational values

and environmental impacts. Following Lancaster (1966),

we derive demand for introducing signal crayfish from the

attributes that the signal crayfish populations, S, provide.

This approach has been greatly applied in environmental

economics for deriving demand for recreational services

(e.g., Bockstael and McConnell 1981; Smith 1991). Let

ai = a1,…,am be the different attributes possessed by

either the populations as such or by harvesting of signal

crayfish. The amount of attribute i the individual obtains

from S is a function of the ‘‘technology’’ parameter ai

which transforms the stock of signal crayfish into attribute

i, ai = aiS. In this article, this technology parameter

is interpreted as reflecting attitudes. The stronger attitude

for providing recreational values, for example, the higher

is ai in generating recreational attribute from signal

crayfish.

There is a large literature on the formation of values,

attitudes and beliefs related to environmental and other

issues (e.g., Ester and others 2004), and two distinct lines

of thought can be identified. One is the extensively

applied idea in environmental economics on the trade-off

between economic growth and environmental concern

that depends on income level (e.g, Inglehart 1977, 1995).

The other line of reasoning originates mainly from psy-

chologists and emphasizes the role of value clusters, such

as self-interest, concern for others and the biosphere,

from which environmental and other attitudes can be

derived (e.g., Schwartz 1992, 1994). In this article we

therefore decompose the attribute productivity parameter

into two parts: one reflecting a basic or intrinsic attitude,

ai; and the other depending on the income level, Y, which

is given a simple linear form and written as

ai ¼ ai þ biY:

In addition to affecting attitudes, crayfish harvesting, x,

may contribute to utility as a source of income from sales

of crayfish. Incomes are obtained from sales of crayfish, px,

where p is the unit price, minus cost from harvesting, cx,

where c is the unit harvesting cost. A simplification is made

by assuming that the harvesting cost is independent of the

crayfish population. Total income for a water owner then

includes income from other sources, Yo, and from sales of

crayfish, which gives Y = Yo ? (p - c)x. Utility in each

period of time is then U = U(a1,…,am, Y), which is

assumed to be increasing at a decreasing rate in income,

and can be either increasing or decreasing in the attribute

parameters.

Once introduced, the growth in signal crayfish, _S, is

determined by its natural growth, G(S), minus harvesting,

x. Given all assumptions, the water owner maximizes

current and future streams of net utility given the growth

function of signal crayfish and the attribute generating

relations according to:

212 Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220

123

Page 4: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

Max V ¼R1

t¼0

Uða1; . . .; am; YÞe�qtdt

x s:t:_S ¼ GðSÞ � xai ¼ aiS; i ¼ 1; . . .;mY ¼ Yo þ ðp� cÞxSð0Þ ¼ S

ð1Þ

where q is the discount rate. Assuming sustainable

harvesting, i.e., the natural growth equals harvest or

G(S) = x, the optimal level of signal crayfish, S*, is

determined where the discount rate equals return from

signal crayfish according to:

q ¼ GS þP

i Uaiai

ðP

i Uai biSþ UYÞðp� cÞProof: see Appendix A

ð2Þ

which shows that optimal steady-state level of the stock,

S*, and harvesting of signal crayfish occur where the dis-

count rate q equals the rate of return on the signal crayfish.

The discount rate is the marginal cost of keeping signal

crayfish since it shows the return on investment that can be

obtained elsewhere in the economy. The marginal benefit

from keeping signal crayfish, the right hand side, includes

the natural growth rate and the marginal stock effect, the

second term at the right-hand side. Incentives to keep

signal crayfish are thus decreasing in higher discount rate

and increasing in natural growth and marginal stock

effects.

The marginal stock effect is, in turn, determined by the

marginal impacts on utility from attribute changes in the

numerator and the net impacts on income and associated

change in utility from the income determined part of the

attributes in the denominator. When marginal utility is

negative from an attribute, such as the perception of an

increase in threat to the noble crayfish from a larger signal

crayfish stock, the marginal return decreases whereas it

increases from an attribute generating positive marginal

utility, such as recreational values. The denominator shows

the effect on the stock from harvesting of crayfish, which

includes obtained incomes from harvesting and associated

effects on attitudes.

The impact on the populations from changes in intrinsic

attitudes and income can be obtained by applying the

implicit function theorem on Eq. 2. Since both attitude and

income parameters affect several variables, the final

expressions can be quite involved and indeterminate. When

simplifications are made with respect to the utility function,

it is shown in Appendix A that an increase in intrinsic

attitudes generating negative marginal utility, such as

environmental preferences for preservation of noble cray-

fish, has a negative impact on the populations of signal

crayfish (see Eq. A6 in Appendix A). Similarly, an increase

in income generates either an increase or a decrease in the

populations depending on if the marginal utility from

associated attribute change is negative or positive (see

Eq. A7 Appendix A). Since several attributes may act

simultaneously, the final outcome is theoretically indeter-

minate. Environmental concern for protection of the native

noble crayfish acts for a decline in the population of signal

crayfish, while demand for recreational experiences is a

driving force for a larger population.

Description of Data

From the simple model exercise in Chapter 3, we can

identify the following explanatory variables needed to be

included in the regression equation: intrinsic attitudes,

income, unit price, and harvesting cost of signal crayfish,

discount rate, and natural growth rate. However, as will be

reported in this chapter, it is not possible to obtain data on

all these variables.

Starting with the dependent variable, populations of

signal crayfish, the econometric estimates made in this

article rely on the availability of unique panel data for the

number of waters (lakes running waters and ponds) with

signal crayfish in Swedish municipalities, which is used for

defining the dependent variable (SBF 2006). The data set

covers 188 Swedish municipalities where occurrences of

signal crayfish have been recorded on different occasions

between 1983 and 2004 (SBF 2006). This includes

approximately 2/3 of all Swedish municipalities, where the

remaining municipalities are located in northern Sweden

where it is probably too cold for the signal crayfish pop-

ulations to survive (Fiskeriverket and Naturvardsverket

1998). The panel is unbalanced since the observed time

period for each municipality is discontinuous. This, in turn,

is due to local reports of signal crayfish occurrences, the

time period of which differs between municipalities. In

total, the panel consists of 556 observations.

The reports on water with signal crayfish contain no

further description of the waters, such as area or length. In

order to account for heterogeneous waters and the scale

effect associated with different sizes of the municipalities

with respect to number of waters, the dependent variable,

S in Chapter 3, is defined as the number of waters with

signal crayfish divided by the total number of waters,

where total number of waters is obtained from SMHI

(2006). This is not the ideal measurement of the depen-

dent variable, which, as presented in the foregoing

Chapter 3, would be a measurement of the total stock of

signal crayfish. However, such data is not recorded and

need to be modeled based on harvesting effort and cat-

ches. This is made for only one lake in Sweden for which

Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220 213

123

Page 5: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

necessary data exist (Kataria 2007). Instead we use the

share of waters with signal crayfish in relation to total

number of waters in each municipality as a dependent

variable. The maximum value of the variable is unity,

which occurs when there is signal crayfish in all waters.

We can think of heterogeneous waters in each munici-

pality with respect to natural growth, and an increase in

the discount rate ceteris paribus will then decrease the

share of waters with signal crayfish.

The choice of attribute parameters is restricted by the

availability of panel data at the municipality level, and two

types of attributes are therefore included: preferences for

environmental preservation and recreational values. Attri-

bute productivity parameter for environmental preferences

is approximated by preferences as expressed by voting

behavior at the municipality level. Alternative approxi-

mations are participation in different environmental NGOs,

such as Greenpeace or World Wide Fund for Nature. It is

not possible to obtain such data at the municipal level for

the period under study, and voting behavior is therefore

used as an indicator of the environmental preservation

attitude.

Swedish citizens vote for central and local (municipal-

ity) governments every fourth year. There are seven major

parties to choose between: the Conservatives (Moderater-

na), the Liberal party (Folkpartiet), the Centre party

(Centerpartiet), the Christian Democratic party (Krist-

demokraterna), the Green party (Miljopartiet), the Social

Democrat party (Socialdemokraterna) and the Left party

(Vansterpartiet). Three parties—the Green party, the Cen-

tre party and the Left party—signal environmental

ambitions, where the Green party identifies environmental

concern as its main political issue. According to the elec-

tion manifest of the Green party, the title of which is

‘‘Greener Sweden—for a better quality of life,’’ eight out of

36 points of declaration refer to environmental issues such

as saving the Baltic Sea, green local environment, and

mitigation of catastrophic climate change (MP 2006).

Votes for the Green party are therefore used as a variable

on environmental preferences. Votes for a relatively green

party have also been used as an explanatory variable in

Kahn (2007) for testing differences in consumption

patterns.

Attitudes towards recreational values are measured by

subscriptions to a magazine specialized in fisheries man-

agement, ‘‘Fiskevard’’ (Swedish federation of fishing right

owners 2008). Subscriptions concern households and this

variable is weighted by the number of inhabitants in each

municipality. Admittedly, the variable is likely to measure

general interest in recreation from fishery, and not only

from crayfish. It is still of interest if there is positive cor-

relation between recreational values from general fishery

and from signal crayfish.

Income is measured by the reports in annual tax decla-

rations and is expressed in 2006 price levels (Swedish

Statistics 2006). This excludes all nondeclared incomes

from, for example, sales of signal crayfish and others.

Owing to the conflicting interests mentioned in Chapter 3,

a priori hypothesis on the impact of income on occurrence

of waters with signal crayfish is difficult to formulate. If

only incomes from signal crayfish and preservation of

noble crayfish were at issue, an inverted U-shape between

occurrences of signal crayfish could be hypothesized,

where needs for side incomes increase up to a certain level

of income and then decrease. In other words, environ-

mental improvements (here, provision of noble crayfish)

are affordable first after a certain income level and then

increase. However, the recreational values from the cul-

tural tradition of fishing and eating crayfish in late summer

may be strong enough to offset this relation if the demand

for tradition is stronger than that for environmental

improvements.

Unfortunately, no records exist for market prices of

Swedish signal crayfish, biological growth and harvesting

cost. The only interest rate records available during the

entire period are those of Treasury bills, which have a

duration of three months (Sveriges Riksbank 2007). A real

interest rate is obtained by deflating the nominal rate by the

consumer price index.

In total, the data set contains 556 observations, and

descriptive statistics are presented in Table 1.

The total number of waters and waters with signal

crayfish vary considerably among municipalities, with an

average share of water with signal crayfish amounting to

0.25. Furthermore, the range of income per capita is high,

being approximately five times higher in the richest

municipality (Stockholm) as compared to the poorest

(Ydre). Real interest rate has fluctuated considerably being

lowest in 2005 and highest during the economic crisis in

early 1990s. Descriptive statistics also indicate that the

number of subscriptions to the fishery magazine ‘‘Fis-

kevard’’ is approximately two per thousand inhabitants.

The subscription rate is relatively high in municipalities in

different parts of the country, on the West coast of Sweden

and in mid Sweden. The average share of votes on the

Green party is 0.04, but it can be four times as high which

occurs in a municipality at the West coast of Sweden.

The Econometric Model and Results

The unbalanced panel consists of heterogeneous clusters

due to irregular records on crayfish, variables that are

constant over time and/or over space. Collected informa-

tion on number of accumulated signal waters, income and

voting behavior varies over time, where the length of the

214 Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220

123

Page 6: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

observed period for each municipality varies between

13 years and one year. The number of total waters is

constant over time and varies over municipalities while the

discount rate varies over time but not over municipalities.

These properties of the unbalanced panel introduce a par-

ticular type of heteroscedasticity imposing difficulties in

taking advantage of panel data properties to specify the

econometric model as a fixed effect model which is com-

monly applied in the Kuznets literature (Dinda 2004).

Hence, the econometric model is specified as a lognormal

regression model and it is estimated by the maximum

likelihood method (ML). The model is weighted by

municipality clusters in order to take advantage of panel

data properties. The model assumes that a random variable

is lognormally distributed if the logarithm of the random

variable is normally distributed making the heterogeneous

variance proportional to the square of the mean in order to

correct heteroscedasticity problems. According to Weems

and Smith (2004), when data exhibit overdispersion this

simple assumption on distribution facilitates the computa-

tional work, assuring robustness maximum likelihood

estimates.

Potter (2005) carried out tests in favor of lognormal

models where moderate-sized data indicate a good infer-

ence of maximum likelihood estimates. Chan and others

(2005) analyze residential air leakage in the US, explained

by household income level, housing characteristics and

energy programs, assuming a lognormal and normal dis-

tributions. Their findings show that in the presence of

irregularities in data a lognormal distribution assures

robustness estimates. Balintfy and Goodman (1973) ana-

lyze socio-economic factors in income inequality assuming

that income follows a lognormal distribution considering

group variances. Their main conclusion is that income

distributions can be approximated by a lognormal distri-

bution over much of their range, but their fit remains

poorest at the upper end.

From the theoretical analysis in chapter 3 it is noticed

that income changes can have effects on occurrences of

signal crayfish through two channels, directly and also

indirectly by the impacts on the attitude variables. In this

article we therefore test whether (1) attitude variables have

explanatory power, and (2) interaction effect between

income and attitudes are significant. Furthermore, the

income variable is given a quadratic form in order to test

for turning points with respect to negative and positive

effects of income on the occurrences of signal crayfish.

Such a relation is found in several studies testing impacts

of changes in income on environmental damages in dif-

ferent countries (see Dinda 2004 for a review), and also for

environmental concern showed by Swedish municipalities

(Folke and Gren 2008). We also introduce a time variable

that reflects the changes during time not covered by the

explanatory variables, such as changes in general aware-

ness of environmental issues and climatic changes. A

dummy variable is also introduced for the three largest and

most densely populated cities in Sweden. This may reflect

specific characteristics such as distance to fishing waters,

which partly accounts for the missing harvesting cost

variable. Three different regression equations are then

specified according to

Model I (only economic factors):

Si;t ¼ ai þ b1Yi;t þ b2Y2i;t þ b3rt þ b8dt þ b9dsþ ei;t

Model II (economic factors and direct attitude

variables):

Si;t ¼ ai þ b1Yi;t þ b1Y2i;t þ b3rt þ b4Ei;t þ b5Mi;t þ b8dt

þ b9dsþ ei;t

Model III (economic factors, direct attitude variables

and interaction effect between income and attitudes):

Si;t ¼ ai þ b1Yi;t þ b1Y2i;t þ b3rt þ b4Ei;t þ b5Mi;t

þ b6Ei;tYi;t þ b7Mi;tYi;t þ b8dt þ b9dsþ ei;t

where i = 1,…,188 are the municipalities and

t = 1983,…,2004 are the observed years which are dis-

continuous for each municipality. The dependent variable

Si,t is the share of waters with signal crayfish, Yi,t is income

per capita, rt is the real market discount rate, Ei,t are votes

Table 1 Descriptive statistics; n = 556

Variable name Mean Std. dev. Median Min. Max.

Number of waters with signal crayfish 16.67 17.73 10.00 1.00 87.00

Total waters 154.51 130.68 135.00 1.00 1268.00

Share of signal waters 0.25 0.49 0.10 0.08 1.00

Income per capita, thousand SEKa 138.56 31.37 133.50 89.20 460.75

Real interest rate 5.27 3.64 4.42 1.13 10.84

Number of magazine subscription per 10000 ind. 17.14 16.8 10.66 0.00 92.24

Green party, share of votes 0.04 0.02 0.03 0.00 0.16

a 1 Euro = 9.52 SEK (August 11, 2008)

Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220 215

123

Page 7: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

for the Green party, Mi,t is the magazine subscriptions,

YI,tEi,t is the interaction effect between income per capita

and votes for the Green party, Ii,tMi,t is the interaction

effect between income per capita and magazine subscrip-

tions, dt is a time-specific dummy and ds is a site-specific

dummy for big cities Stockholm, Goteborg and Malmo.

Finally, ei,t denotes the model error term. Regression

results are presented in Table 2.

All three models show an expected negative impact of

the discount rate. The results also indicate a U-shaped

effect of increases in income, which support most of the

results in the related literature. However, the turning

points, where the negative impact of income changes

switches to a positive effect is high, differ between the

model specification, ranging from 280 thousand SEK/

capita (model III) to approximately 800 thousand SEK/

capita (model II). Considering that the median income is

SEK 133 000/year, the positive relation between income

and the share of water with signal crayfish occurs for

relatively few municipalities. This relatively high income

level for the turning point is in contrast with much previ-

ous results, where the turning points for emissions of

several types of pollutant are lower (see Stern 2004 for a

review).

Common to all models is also the positive impact factor

of time, which can be caused by exogenous changes not

included in the model, such as increased general awareness

of the threat of signal crayfish to noble crayfish at the

national level. Another common result is the positive, but

insignificant effect of the dummy for the three largest cit-

ies, which can reflect lower costs for access to waters in

densely populated municipalities. It is also interesting to

note that the successive inclusion of direct attitude

variables and interaction effects between attitude variables

and income increases the explanatory power of the equa-

tions. Furthermore, all variables except for the dummy

representing the three largest cities are significant irre-

spective of model design.

A likelihood ratio test (LR) is conducted in order to test

for the explanatory power of each model. The result of the

test supports the specification of model II and model III

against model I, at a 5% significance level LR = 2.15 and

2.31, v(2,0.95)2 = 5.99 and v(4,0.95)

2 = 9.49, respectively. The

test is also performed to confirm the validity of model III

against model II, where the result of the test confirms the

specification of model III, LR = 2.15. It can also be noted

that the explanatory power of the results presented in

Table 2 is significantly higher then those obtained from

ordinary least square (OLS) estimates (see Table B2 in

Appendix B).

However, the positive and significant effect of votes on

the Swedish Green party on the dependent variable is

unexpected from the theoretical analysis carried out in

Chapter 3. One possible explanation can be that votes for

the Green party express concern about environmental

problems at a larger scale such as climatic change.

Another unexpected result from the theoretical analysis is

the negative effect of subscriptions on the fisheries mag-

azine, if this variable reflects interest in recreational

fishery. One possible explanation is misspecification in the

model in Chapter 3 where recreational values were

assumed to be related to the signal crayfish population.

Recreational values may instead be obtained from har-

vesting of signal crayfish, which implies a pressure on the

population. Another explanation can be that subscription

does not measure only recreational values but also reflects

Table 2 Lognormal model; regression results

Variable Model I Model II Model III

Coeff. t-value Coeff. t-value Coeff. t-value

Intercept 0.71 8.87 1.29 8.17 1.18 5.17

Income (Y) -0.0055 -7.12 -0.0096 -7.83 -0.0091 -5.04

Income2 (Y2) 0.000009 5.46 0.000016 7.62 0.00002 5.11

Real discount rate (r) -0.0118 -3.62 -0.0207 -6.65 -0.0122 -5.41

Time (dt) 0.0122 3.83 0.0104 3.47 0.0096 5.26

Three largest cities (ds) 0.34 1.45 0.31 1.10 0.42 1.64

Votes for Green party (E) 1.40 7.27 8.72 3.90

Magazine (M) -0.0073 -8.25 -0.0126 -4.79

Interaction (EY) -0.0542 -3.18

Interaction (MY) 0.000039 5.26

Variance 2.11 32.37 3.30 27.61 6.20 31.06

Log likelihood -953.65 -1025.55 -1099.85

216 Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220

123

Page 8: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

knowledge on the threat of signal crayfish to the noble

crayfish, and thereby partly captures environmental

concerns.

The interaction effects included in Model III counteract

the unexpected impacts of the attitude variable in Model II.

The negative interaction effect between voting on the

Green party and income indicates that higher incomes lead

to decreases in the share of waters with signal crayfish due

to increased environmental preferences as expressed in the

voting variable. Interestingly, the total impact of the Green

party is negative at income levels exceeding 160 thousand

SEK, which is well within the data range. Similarly, the

positive interaction effect between magazine subscriptions

and incomes can be interpreted as an increase in recrea-

tional demand as measured by the subscription variable at

higher income levels. However, the total negative effect of

a marginal change in subscriptions is the same for Models

II and III when evaluated at the mean income level. The

negative effect is then decreased only for relatively large

income levels, and becomes positive at annual income

exceeding 323 thousand SEK.

Summary and Discussion

The main purpose of this article has been to analyze and

test impacts of economic factors and attitudes on the

occurrences of signal crayfish in Sweden. A simple model

was used where attitudes were modeled within the frame-

work of dynamic harvesting model with multi-attribute

utility from signal crayfish. Independent and measurable

variables derived from the model were discount rate,

income, and attitudes to signal crayfish. An econometric

test was carried out based on a unique set of data on

number of signal crayfish waters in different Swedish

municipalities during the period 1983–2004. In order to test

the explanatory power of economic and attitude variables

on impact of attitude variables, three regression models

were estimated and compared: (1) inclusion of only eco-

nomic variables (income and discount rate), (2) economic

and direct attitude variables, and (3) economic, direct

attitude variables and interaction terms between income

and attitudes. All models resulted in a significant U-shaped

relation between signal crayfish occurrences and income

and a negative impact of the real discount rate. Inclusion of

attitude variables turned out to increase the explanatory

power of the regression equation significantly. Votes for

the Green party showed an unexpected positive sign, but

the total effect was negative when accounting for the

interaction effect with income. Subscription on a fisheries

magazine revealed a negative and significant effect, which

was unexpected if the variable reflects recreational

attributes.

However, although the data set is relatively large, the

results need to be interpreted with caution. One reason is

that the dependent variable measures share of waters with

signal crayfish and not the stocks of signal crayfish in

different municipalities. Furthermore, preferences for

environmental and recreational attributes can be revealed

in other ways, such as membership of nongovernmental

organizations. On the other hand, the econometric results

are robust with respect to alternative functional forms and

estimation methods. Furthermore, the U-shaped income

effect is supported by other studies. The results also adhere

to the unclear relation between attitudes and behavior,

which is the subject of much research in social sciences

(see e.g., Ester and others 2004)

What are then the potential policy conclusions from the

study? One observation is that the net impact on occur-

rences of signal crayfish from changes in income may be

positive. The spread of the species is then not likely to

decrease from economic development as measured by

increases in average income, which is one reason for

implementing policies in order to prevent further spread.

The significant impacts of the discount rate and attitude

variables indicate that both economic incentives and

information campaigns aimed at affecting attitudes have

impacts on the occurrences of waters with signal crayfish.

The expected negative impact of discount rate, which

reduces the streams of net utility from a crayfish popula-

tion, points to the relevance of economic incentives for

mitigating spread of signal crayfish, such as charge pay-

ments for waters with signal crayfish. The results also

support the use of information campaigns for affecting

attitudes, which have been used in Sweden during two

decades for combating spread of signal crayfish. However,

economic instruments have not yet been implemented, and

might therefore contribute to a larger decrease in the

occurrences of signal crayfish then continuous use of

information campaigns.

To the best of our knowledge, there is only one addi-

tional study testing the explanatory power of income

changes on occurrences of invasive species, Dalmazzone

(2000), which is applied to different countries. The results

from our study support those obtained by Dalmazzone

(2000) with respect to the significant and positive impact of

income changes on the occurrence of invasive species.

Similar to Sweden, several countries have introduced

information campaigns and command and control like

instruments, such as bans on imports of hazardous species,

for combating intentional spread of invasive species among

countries. As demonstrated theoretically by several studies,

such a policy might be quite expensive as compared to a

policy based on economic incentives (see Gren 2008 for a

review). The results from this study show that economic

factors affect spread of signal crayfish in Sweden, and,

Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220 217

123

Page 9: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

hence, economic policy instruments may have a potential

in mitigating further spread. However, the research on

appropriate choice of policy instrument at the international

and national scales is currently in its infancy state, in

particular with respect to empirical research on causes of

spread and design of policy instruments, which is needed

for making robust policy conclusions (e.g., Perrings and

others 2000; Gren 2008).

Acknowledgments We are much indebted to the Swedish Envi-

ronmental Protection Agency for financial support to the AquAlien

research program, and to two anonymous referees for valuable

comments. The authors are responsible for any remaining errors.

Appendix A: Derivation of Optimal Stock of Signal

Crayfish

The decision problem in Eq. 1 is solved by use of optimal

control. The Hamiltonian is then written as

H ¼ Uða1; . . .; am; YÞ þ kðGðSÞ � xÞ; ðA1Þ

which gives the first order condition for a maximum as

oH

ox¼ ðp� cÞðUY þ

X

i

Uai biSÞ � k ¼ 0 ðA2Þ

_k ¼ kðq� GSÞ �X

i

Uaiai ðA3Þ

_S ¼ GðSÞ � x ðA4Þ

where sub-index denotes partial derivatives and k is the

costate variable showing the change in V from a marginal

change in the stock of signal crayfish. By solving for

steady-state values, i.e. where _k ¼ 0 and _S ¼ 0; and

inserting (A2) into (A3), we obtain

q ¼ GS þP

i Uaiai

ðP

i Uai biSþ UYÞðp� cÞ : ðA5Þ

The impact of changes in the attribute productivity

parameters can be derived by applying the implicit function

theorem on (A5). In order to simplify the analysis, we

assume that the cross derivates of ai and Y are zero and that

the second derivatives of the utility function with respect to

the attribute parameters are zero. The impact of a marginal

change in ai is then

oS�

oai ¼Uaik

DðA6Þ

where D ¼ � GSSk2 � bðp� cÞ2GSUYY þ ðp� cÞ

Pi Uai

biðGSk� bÞÞ; k is derived from (A1) and b ¼P

i Uaiai:

When all Uai \ 0, the denominator, D, is positive,

since, by assumption UYY \ 0, and, for a simple logistic

crayfish growth function, GSS \ 0. When Uai [ 0, D [ 0

for small enough bðp� cÞ2UYY . Equation A6 is then

positive/negative when Uai [ ð\Þ0. Thus, the stock of

signal crayfish is increasing in intrinsic attributes with a

positive marginal utility such as recreational values, and

negative in attributes associated with negative marginal

utility such as preferences for preservation of noble

crayfish.

Similarly, the impact of a change in income, Yo, is

oS�

oY[ ð\Þ0 for

kP

i Uai bi � bðp� cÞUYY

D[ ð\Þ0

ðA7Þ

According to (A7), the impact of a marginal income

change on S* is negative(positive) for Uai \ ([)0.

Appendix B: Tables

Table B1 Correlation matrix

S Y r E M

S 1.000

Y .008 1.000

r .100 .411 1.000

E .085 .175 -.192 1.000

M -.210 -.208 -.040 -.117 1.000

S: share of waters with signal of total waters, Y: Income per capita, r: real discount rate, E: share of votes on the Green party, M: subscriptions on

the fisheries management magazine in relation to population

218 Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220

123

Page 10: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

References

Balintfy JL, Goodman SS (1973) Socio-economic factors in income

inequality: a log-normal hypothesis. Zeitschrift fur Nationalo-

konomie 33:389–402

Bockstael NE, McConnell KE (1981) Theory and estimation of the

household production function for wildlife recreation. Journal of

Environmental Economics and Management 8(3):199–214

Bohman P, Nordwall F, Edsman L (2006) The effect of the large-

scale introduction of signal crayfish on the spread of crayfish

plague in Sweden. Bulletin Francais de la.Peche et de la

Pisciculture 380–381:1291–1302

Born W, Rauschmayer F, Brauer I (2005) Economic evaluation of

biological invasions—a survey. Ecological Economics 55(3):

321–336

Cerenius L, Edsman L (2002) Protection of natives in a plague

situation. Bulletin Francais de la.Peche et de la Pisciculture

367:909–910

Chan WR, Nazaroff WW, Price PN, Sohn MD, Gadgil AJ (2005)

Analyzing a database of residential air leakage in the United

States. Atmospheric Environment 39:3445–3455

Dalmazzone S (2000) Economic factors affecting vulnerability to

biological invasions. In: Perrings et al (eds) Economics of

biological invasions. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, pp 17–

30

Dinda S (2004) Environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis: a survey.

Ecological Economics 49:431–455

Ehrardt-Martinez K, Crenshaw E, Jenkins C (2002) Environmental

strategies and policies deforestation and the environmental

Kuznets curve: a cross-national investigation of intervening

mechanisms. Social Science Quarterly 83(1):226–243

Ester P, Simoes S, Vinken H (2004) Cultural change and environ-

mentalism: a cross national appraoch of mass publics and

decision makers. Ambiente & Sociedade VII(2 Jul/Dec):43–65

Fjalling A, Furst M (1985) Information fran sotvattenslaboratoriet,

Swedish Fishery Board, 178 93 Drottningholm, Sweden, p 29

Fiskeriverket and Naturvardsverket (1998) Action plan for the

restoration of Noble crayfish. Swedish Environmental Protection

Agency, Stockholm, Sweden (in Swedish)

Folke O, Gren IM (2008) Environmental policy performance of

Swedish local governments: is it the mind or the money?

European Association of Environmental Economics Conference

June 25–28, 2008. Gothenburg, Sweden

Gren IM, Isacs L, Carlsson M (2008) Costs of invasive alien species

in Sweden. Ambio, in revision

Gren IM (2008) Economics of management of invasive alien

species—choosing target and policies. Boreal Environmental

Research 13:17–32

Grossman G, Krueger A (1995) Economic growth and the environ-

ment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 60:353–377

Table B2 Regression results from OLS estimates

Variable names Model I Model II Model III

Coeff. t-value Coeff. t-value Coeff. t-value

OLS-nonlinear

Intercept 0.711 2.44 1.287 4.23 1.175 2.79

Income (Y) -0.005 -1.77 -0.010 -3.11 -0.009 -2.48

Income2 (Y2) 0.000009 1.44 0.000016 2.54 0.00002 2.89

Real discount rate (r) -0.012 -1.43 -0.021 -2.48 -0.022 -2.57

Time dummy (dt) 0.012 1.68 0.010 1.46 0.010 1.34

Big cities dummy (ds) 0.343 1.48 0.305 1.35 0.417 1.76

Green party (E) 1.397 1.25 8.718 1.27

Magazines (M) -0.007 -5.65 -0.013 -1.65

Interaction (EY) -0.054 1.08

Interaction (MY) 0.417 1.76

R2 0.20% 0.79% 0.83%

Log-likelihood -389.73 -372.36 -371.16

OLS-logarithmic

Intercept 17.392 1.93 28.623 3.23 39.588 3.77

Income (Y) -16.972 -2.10 -25.829 -3.27 -32.508 -3.75

Income2 (Y2) 3.654 2.03 5.456 3.11 6.137 3.38

Real discount rate (r) 0.281 2.27 0.135 1.07 0.166 1.30

Time dummy (dt) 0.070 7.33 0.069 7.44 0.072 7.58

Big cities dummy (ds) 0.471 1.78 0.276 1.07 0.333 1.24

Green party (E) 0.121 1.47 5.762 2.24

Magazines (M) -0.279 -6.41 0.108 0.09

Interaction (EY) -2.688 -2.19

Interaction (MY) -0.187 -0.35

R2 12.01% 19.54% 20.25%

Log-likelihood -465.98 -445.91 -443.48

Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220 219

123

Page 11: Incomes, Attitudes, and Occurrences of Invasive Species: An Application to Signal Crayfish in Sweden

Horan R, Lupi F (2005) Tradable risk permits to prevent future

introductions of invasive alien species into the Great Lake.

Ecological Economics 52:289–304

Inglehart R (1977) The silent revolution. Changing values and

political styles among Western publics. Princeton University

Press, Princeton, NJ

Inglehart R (1995) Public support for environmental protection: the

impact of objective problems and subjective values in 43

societies. PS: Political Science and Politics 28(1):57–71

IUCN (2000) IUCN guidelines for the prevention of biodiversity loss

caused by alien invasive species. Approved by the 51st meeting

of the IUCN Council, Gland, Swizerland, February

Kahn M (2007) Do greens drive Hummers of hybrids? Environmental

ideology as a determinant of consumer choice. Journal of

Environmental Economics and Management 54:129–145

Kataria M (2007) A cost-benefit analysis of introducing a nonnative

species: the case of signal crayfish in Sweden. Marine Resource

Economics 22:15–28

Knowler D, Barbier E (2005) Managing the Black Sea anchovy

fishery with nutrient enrichment and biological invader. Marine

Resource Economics 20(3):263–275

Lancaster K (1966) A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of

Political Economy 74(2):132–157

Lovell SJ, Stone S, Fernandez L (2006) The economic impacts of

aquatic invasive species: a review of the literature. Agricultural

and Resource Economics Review 35(1):195–204

McPherson M, Nieswiadomy M (2005) Environmental Kuznets

curve: threatened species and spatial effects. Ecological Eco-

nomics 55:395–407

MP (Green party) (2006) A greener Sweden—for a better quality of

life! At http://mp.se/files/107300-107399file_10371.pdf. Acces-

sed 1 Oct 2007

Olson L (2006) The economics of terrestrial invasive species: a

review of the literature. Agricultural and Resource Economics

Review 35(1):178–194

Owen A, Videras J (2007) Culture and public goods: the case of religion

and the voluntary provision of environmental quality. Journal of

Environmental Economics and Management 54:162–180

Perrings C, Williamson M, Dalmazzone S (2000) The economics of

biological invasions. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK

Pimentel D, McNair S, Janecka J, Wightman J, Simmonds C,

O’Conell C, Wong E, Russel L, Zern J, Aquino T, Tsomondo T

(2001) Economic and environmental threats of alien plant,

animal, and microbe invasions. Agriculture Ecosystems &

Environment 84:1–20

Potter DM (2005) A permutation test for inference in logistic

regression with small- and moderate-sized data sets. Statistics in

Medicine 24:693–708

SBF (Swedish Board of Fisheries) (2000) En undersokning om

svenskarnas sport-och husbehovsfiske. Finfo 2000:1, p 89

SBF (Swedish Board of Fisheries) (2006) The database of crayfish

occurrences. Stockholm, Sweden

Schwartz SH (1992) Universals in the content and structure of values:

theoretical advances and empirical tests in 20 countries.

Advances in Experimental Social Psychology 25:1–65

Schwartz SH (1994) Are there universal aspects in the structure and

content of human values? Journal of Social Issues 50(4):19–46

Shogren J, Tschirhart J (2005) Integrating ecology and economics to

address bioinvasions. Ecological Economics 52:267–271

Skurdal J, Taugbøl T, Burba A, Edsman L, Soderback B, Styrishave

B, Tuusti J, Westman K (1999) Crayfish introductions in the

Nordic and Baltic countries. In: Gherardi F, Holdich DM (eds)

Crayfish in Europe as alien species. How to make the best of a

bad situation. A. A. Balkema, Rotterdam, pp 193–219

SMHI (Swedish Meteorological, Hydrological Institute) (2006)

Register of lakes and rivers in Sweden. Norrkoping, Sweden

Smith VK (1991) Household production functions and environmental

benefit estimation. In: Kolstad C, Braden J (eds) Measuring the

demand for environmental quality. North-Holland, Amsterdam

Stern DI (2004) The rise and fall of the environmental Kuznets curve.

World Development 32(8):1419–1439

Swahn JO (2004) The cultural history of crayfish. Bulletin Francais de

la Peche et de la Pisciculture 372–373:243–251

Sveriges Riksbank (2007) Svenska marknadsrantor—statsskuldsvax-

lar. Stockholm

Swedish federation of fishing right owners (2008) Fiskevard. At

www.fiskevatten.org. Accessed 15 May 2008

Swedish Statistics (2006) Taxerad och beskattningsbar forvarvsink-

omst samt antal inkomsttagare, samtliga skattskyldiga, efter

kommun. Taxeringsar 1983–2006

Unestam T (1969) Resistance to the crayfish plague in some

American, Japanese and European crayfishes. Report of InstituteFreshwater Research, Drottningholm, 49:202–209

Unestam T (1972) On the host range and origin of the crayfish plague

fungus. Report of Institute Freshwater Research. Drottningholm

52:192–198

Vila M, Pujadas J (2001) Land-use and socio-economic correlates of

plant invasions in European and North African countries.

Biological Conservation 100:397–401

Weems KS, Smith P (2004) On robustness of maximum likelihood

estimates for Poisson-lognormal models. Statistics and Proba-

bility Letters 66:189–196

Westman K, Ackerfors H (1992) Kraftor—biologi, odling, fiske.

Kiviksgardens Forlag, Ystad, Sweden

220 Environmental Management (2009) 43:210–220

123