19
Global Governance 17(2011), 167-184 Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical survey of the resource curse—the idea that mineral and fuel abundance generates negative developmental outcomes in less developed countries. In particular, it examines the idea that mineral and fuel abundance generates growth-restricting forms of state interven- tion, extraordinarily large degrees of rent seeking, and corruption, which are generally argued to be negative in terms of the developmental out- comes they generate. The analysis surveys the Dutch disease, rentier state, and rent-seeking versions of the resource curse and finds they have signif- icant shortcomings in terms of theory and evidence. It also identifies some decisive factors that help determine the blessing thresholdbelow which the risk of a resource curse may be very highin mineral and fuel abun- dant developing countries. KEYWORDS: resource curse, economic perform- ance, rentier state, rent-seeking models, resource abundance. THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN MINERAL AND FUEL WEALTH AND ECONOMIC DE- velopment has been the subject of intense debates over the past century. Cen- tral to the effect of mineral and fuel wealth on long-mn economic growth is the stimulus that it can provide to industrial activities. One of the main lessons of world economic history of the past two centuries is that sustained economic growth is achieved with sustained and successful industrialization.' The idea that commodity exports generate domestic demand for manufactures has long been emphasized by development economists.^ Similarly, the "staple thesis" demonstrated that growth in backward areas commonly began through the ini- tial stimuli that primary product exports brought in terms of attracting capital and labor and inducing a more diversified production stmcture.^ Natural re- source rents, to the extent they are appropriated by state govemments, can relax common resource constraints to growth; namely, the savings, foreign ex- change, and fiscal constraints.'* Despite the historically positive association of natural resource abundance and industrial growth in many now-advanced countries, the literature covering less developed countries (LDCs) since the 1950s has largely drawn the oppo- site conclusion. Natural resources, for most poor countries, are deemed to be more of a "curse" than a "blessing."^ Stmcturalists, dependency theorists, and some Mcirxist theories of imperialism are well-known examples of the nega- tive view of natural resource export specialization as a basis for sustained in- 167

Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    11

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

Global Governance 17(2011), 167-184

Is There Really a Resource Curse?A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence

Jonathan Di John

This article provides a critical survey of the resource curse—the idea thatmineral and fuel abundance generates negative developmental outcomesin less developed countries. In particular, it examines the idea that mineraland fuel abundance generates growth-restricting forms of state interven-tion, extraordinarily large degrees of rent seeking, and corruption, whichare generally argued to be negative in terms of the developmental out-comes they generate. The analysis surveys the Dutch disease, rentier state,and rent-seeking versions of the resource curse and finds they have signif-icant shortcomings in terms of theory and evidence. It also identifies somedecisive factors that help determine the blessing threshold—below whichthe risk of a resource curse may be very high—in mineral and fuel abun-dant developing countries. KEYWORDS: resource curse, economic perform-ance, rentier state, rent-seeking models, resource abundance.

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN MINERAL AND FUEL WEALTH AND ECONOMIC DE-

velopment has been the subject of intense debates over the past century. Cen-tral to the effect of mineral and fuel wealth on long-mn economic growth isthe stimulus that it can provide to industrial activities. One of the main lessonsof world economic history of the past two centuries is that sustained economicgrowth is achieved with sustained and successful industrialization.' The ideathat commodity exports generate domestic demand for manufactures has longbeen emphasized by development economists.^ Similarly, the "staple thesis"demonstrated that growth in backward areas commonly began through the ini-tial stimuli that primary product exports brought in terms of attracting capitaland labor and inducing a more diversified production stmcture.^ Natural re-source rents, to the extent they are appropriated by state govemments, canrelax common resource constraints to growth; namely, the savings, foreign ex-change, and fiscal constraints.'*

Despite the historically positive association of natural resource abundanceand industrial growth in many now-advanced countries, the literature coveringless developed countries (LDCs) since the 1950s has largely drawn the oppo-site conclusion. Natural resources, for most poor countries, are deemed to bemore of a "curse" than a "blessing."^ Stmcturalists, dependency theorists, andsome Mcirxist theories of imperialism are well-known examples of the nega-tive view of natural resource export specialization as a basis for sustained in-

167

Page 2: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

168 Is There Really a Resource Curse?

dustrialization.^ For structuralists, such as Raul Prebisch, primary productswere subject to declining terms of trade and destabilizing price volatility. Fordependency theorists, natural resources were unlikely to stimulate growth par-ticularly if foreign multinationals doininated resource extraction and were al-lowed to repatriate profits. Marxists, such as Paul Baran, argue thatgovernments in poor economies were dominated by local elites (the so-calledcomprador bourgeoisie) whose interests were allied not with national develop-ment, but with foreign multinationals.

The enclave nature of mineral exports, it is argued by dependency theo-rists and structuralists, also meant that the leading export sector had few link-ages with the rest of the economy, lessening the stimulus resource booms haveon investment in non-mineral sectors. The theoretical and empirical weaknessof dependency theory, at least as it applies to Latin American historiography,has received thorough treatment.'' The variation and change of industrialgrowth within and across poor economies in Latin America made sweepinggeneralizations about the "development of underdevelopment" untenable.^Within debates over the role of natural resources on economic development,the role of mineral and fuel exporting activities (such as oil) has received spe-cial attention. One of the reasons that oil exporting nations have been consid-ered special cases revolves around some peculiar features of petroleumproduction. These peculiar features include the fact that such activities arelarge scale, enclave, capital intensive (usually with close links to multination-als), and pay much higher wages compared with the average wage in a laborsurplus economy. The well-above-average profit margins that accrue to oilproduction are characteristic of the low extraction costs and predominance ofground rent in the value of such production. The peculiar characteristics ofmineral and fuel rents have largely been viewed to have negative conse-quences for the macroeconomy. John Maynard Keynes, for instance, arguesthat, in the sixteenth century, discoveries of precious metals in America andthe subsequent inflow of income had an adverse effect on Spain's domestic in-dustries by raising wage levels above competitive levels.^

In sum, the general thrust of the resource curse arguments is that naturalresource abundance leads to poor economic performance and growth col-lapses, high levels of corruption and poor governance, and, in some models,greater political violence. In this article, I focus on the extent to which mineralabundance affects economic performance. The issue of whether mineral abun-dance generates greater political violence or increases the likelihood of author-itarianism has been treated elsewhere.'"

Economic Explanations of the Resource CurseThe question of structural change in oil exporting economies has received con-siderable attention in the economics literature, particularly after the discovery

Page 3: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

Jonathan Di John 169

of North Sea oil and its impact on the industrial structure of such economiesas the Netherlands and the United Kingdom. The concem was focused on thesubsequent deindustrialization in output and employment, which took place inthese two economies following their resource booms, a phenomenon that hascome to be called "Dutch disease."

The logic of the simple Dutch disease theories can be described as fol-lows. In an economy in full-employment equilibrium, a permanent increase inthe inflow of external funds results in a change in relative prices in favor ofnontraded goods (services and construction) and against non-oil traded goods(manufacturing and agriculture), leading to the crowding out of non-oil trad-ables by nontradables. That is, an appreciation of the exchange rate leads to adecline in the competitiveness, and hence production and employment, of thetraded goods sector. The mechanism through which this change takes placefollows directly from the model's assumptions of full-employment equilib-rium and static technology. With these assumptions, the extemal funds (froman oil boom) can be translated into real domestic expenditure only if the flowof imports increases. However, since nontraded goods cannot be imported eas-ily (or only at prohibitive costs), a relative contraction of the traded goods sec-tor is inevitable. Otherwise, the resources needed to enhance the growth of thenontraded sector would not be available.

Thus, the model predicts that deindustrialization is the inevitable struc-tural change that occurs as a result of oil booms." It is important to note that,even without the restrictive assumptions of full employment, oil booms can in-duce more investment in nontraded investments and thus discourage manufac-turing investment. This is because the price of nontraded goods rises relativeto the price of non-oil traded goods as a result of exchange rate appreciation.A second mechanism through which manufacturing can become less compet-itive in this model is through the increase in manufacturing wage rates that re-sult from increases in aggregate demand for labor that oil booms can generate.In the short run, when productivity levels are fixed, unit labor costs in manu-facturing rise. This can, in the absence of compensating policies, lead to a lossin manufacturing competitiveness.

The association of deindustrialization as a disease stems from the uniquegrowth-enhancing characteristics the manufacturing sector can potentially em-body. The primacy of industrialization advocated in academic and policy cir-cles in the postwar period developed as a result of numerous studiesexamining the causes of backwardness in developing economies.'^ Primaryproducts (as well as services) were not believed to possess the "extemal dy-namic economies"'^ observed in the manufacturing industry where fastergrowth leads to increasing productivity manifested ultimately in the dynamicspecialization of employment.''*

The potential dynamism that manufacturing can generate opens up an im-portant role for policy in affecting the growth outcomes of oil booms. In the

Page 4: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

170 Is There Really a Resource Curse?

simple Dutch disease model, technology is assumed to be given (i.e., it is ablueprint), which means that additional foreign exchange is not of particularrelevance from the point of view of economic growth. However, when a latedeveloping country faces a technological gap, additional export revenues, ifchanneled by an appropriate industrial policy, can play an imporiant part sincethe additional foreign exchange can accelerate the process of importing ad-vanced technology and the machines that embody them. Additionally, if the in-dustrial strategy promotes "learning," additional revenues can theoreticallyaccelerate the growth process. For instance, during the boom, the govemmentcould promote industry by channeling resources toward that sector throughprotection, subsidies, or financial incentives. This can serve to modemize themanufacturing capital stock, which in tum can improve productivity.

This means that the structural change against non-oil tradables, such asmanufacturing, is not inevitable; rather, the outcomes of resource booms de-pend on state policy responses. Peter Neary and Sweder van Wijnbergen note:

Insofar as one general conclusion can be drawn [from our collection of em-pirical studies], it is that a country's economic performance following a re-source boom depends to a considerable extent on the policies followed by itsgovemment. . . . [E]ven small economies have considerable influence overtheir own economic performance.'̂

Evidence from Venezuela, for instance, suggests that policy responses, such asindustrial policy and exchange rate management, determine how oil booms af-fect the growth prospects of the economy.'^ What the Dutch disease literaturedoes not address is why growth-enhancing policies are chosen in some con-texts and not others, and, more important, why leaders correct ineffective poli-cies at a faster rate in some countries and not others.

Political Economy Explanations of the Resource Curse:Rentier State and Rent-seeking ModelsRentier state models attempt to explain why state decisionmakers in natural re-source-rich economies create and maintain growth-restricting policies.'''These models move beyond economic models of the resource curse, such asDutch disease models, by attempting to endogenize policymaking and institu-tional formation. The rentier state model posits the need to view poor eco-nomic performance in the context of oil abundance and booms as outcomes ofhistorically specific institutional arrangements and not causes of economic de-cline. These models are part of a growing trend of reviving the staples thesis,the notion that natural factor endowments or technology shape the relations ofproduction or institutional evolution of a society.'*

Page 5: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

Jonathan Di John 171

In the rentier state model, oil and mineral abundance is assumed to gen-erate growth-restricting state intervention, extraordinarily large degrees of rentseeking where these rent-seeking contests are assumed to be uniformly nega-tive in terms of the developmental outcomes they generate. There are severalimportant propositions that are developed within this framework. First, the ex-istence of a higher level of mineral rents increases rent-seeking and corruptionrelative to economies with lower mineral abundance. Second, increases in rentseeking and corruption generate lower growth. This is in part due to the factthat, with corrupt transactions, the need to keep bribes secret reduces the se-curity of property rights, which lowers investment in long-gestating projects.Third, oil rents provide a sufficient fiscal base of the state and, thus, reduce thenecessity of the state to tax citizens. This in tum reduces political bargainingbetween state and interest groups, which makes govemance more arbitrary,patemalistic, and even predatory. Fourth, the absence of incentives to tax in-temally weakens the administrative reach of the state, which results in lowerlevels of state authority, capacity, and legitimacy to intervene in the economy.

Insights from Rent-seeking TheoryModem theories of rent seeking and corruption form a substantial part of theintellectual foundation of the rentier state model. The basic idea behind thesemodels is that there are substantial costs to the workings of an economy whenthe allocation of resources is channeled primarily through state leaders, whohave discretionary authority, rather than through bargains between private eco-nomic agents. In oil economies, because most revenues originate in the centralgovemment, the levels of state discretion in allocating resources and regulat-ing the economy tend to be higher than in most non-oil economies. In the ren-tier state model, the predominant view is that oil economies are subject to ahigher level of rent-seeking and corruption in comparison with non-mineralabundant economies.

Rent seeking can be broadly interpreted as activities that seek to create,maintain, or change the rights and institutions on which particular rents arebased. Rents refer to the "excess incomes," or the "proportion of eamings inexcess of the minimum amount needed to attract a worker to accept a particu-lar job or a firm to enter a particular industry."'^ Rents can take many formssuch as higher than competitive rates of retum in monopolies; extra incomeeamed from exclusive ownership of a scarce resource, whether natural re-sources or specialized knowledge; or extra income from politically organizedtransfers such as subsidies. Since rents specify incomes, which are higher thanwould otherwise have been eamed; they create incentives to generate andmaintain these rents. These influencing activities range from bribing and coer-cion to political lobbying and advertising. In the mainstream view, the avail-

Page 6: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

172 Is There Really a Resource Curse?

ability of rents is the ultimate source of rent seeking and cormption.^o Andsome have been even postulated an "iron law" of rent-seeking: "Wherever arent is to be found, a rent seeker will be there trying to get it."2'

Aaron Tomell and Philip Lane provide a more nuanced view of rent-seekingdynamics that may occur in oil abundant developing countries.22 Their modelconsiders an economy that lacks strong legal-political institutional infrastmc-ture and is populated by multiple powerful interest groups. In such an econ-omy, powerful groups dynamically interact via the fiscal process thateffectively allows open access to the aggregate capital stock. In equilibrium,this leads to slow economic growth and a "voracity effect" by which a shock,such as a terms of trade windfall, perversely generates a more than proportion-ate increase in fiscal redistribution and reduces growth.

In the Tomell and Lane model, if institutional barriers to discretionary re-distribution do not exist, an increase in the raw rate of retum in the formal sec-tor reduces growth. The intuition is as follows. An increase in the raw rate ofretum in the formal sector unleashes two conflicting effects: (1) a direct effectthat increases the profitability of investment in the formal sector; and (2) a vo-racity effect that leads each group to attempt to grab a greater share of the na-tional wealth by demanding more transfers. This is refiected in a higher tax inthe formal sector, which induces reallocation of capital to the informal sector,where it is safe from taxation. This shift reduces the growth rate in the econ-omy, counteracting the direct positive effect of an increase in the raw rate ofretum.

The empirical evidence suggests, Tomell and Lane argue, that Nigeria,Venezuela, and Mexico enjoyed significant oil windfalls, but dissipated theirrevenues.23 The model predicts a more than proportional increase in fiscalspending in response to a positive revenue shock. "The poor growth perform-ance of countries experiencing windfalls is suggestive that increases in publiccapital expenditure were not productively deployed and that appropriated re-sources were consumed, invested in safe but inefficient activities, or trans-ferred overseas."24

Critiques of Rent-seeking TheoryThe extent to which mineral economies generate both higher rent-seekingcosts and less developmental rent-seeking outcomes is ultimately an empiricalissue. There are several pieces of evidence to suggest that large inflows of re-sources (whether through oil or aid) lead to a worsening in economic perform-ance. Let us consider these issues in more detail.

First, the rentier state theory cannot explain the long-mn variation andchange in growth of mineral abundant economies (e.g., Botswana, Malaysia,Venezuela, Nigeria). Second, the variation and change in economic growth innon-mineral rich economies are not well explained (e.g., India, China, Tanza-nia, Malawi) either. Third, recent growth accelerations in aid-dependent

Page 7: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

Jonathan Di John 173

economies are not well explained (e.g., Mozambique, Uganda, Tanzania,Ghana). The fact that aid-dependent economies may be pursuing more liberaleconomic policies demonstrates that policy matters more than levels of rentsin the economy, although there is considerable debate as to whether liberaleconomic policies are best for LDCs.

In terms of the relationship between corruption and growth, there is alsolittle support for the rent-seeking variant of the resource curse. Table 1 sug-gests that mineral abundant economies do not appear to be more corrupt thannon-mineral abundant economies. Moreover, the evidence in the table sug-gests that corruption rates are indeterminate with respect to long-run growth.

In the period 1965-1990, the median annual average growth of thenon-mineral abundant developing economies did outpace the mineral abun-dant economies. However, in the same period, the median corruption rate ofthe non-mineral dominant economies was slightly higher than the mineraldominant economies. In the period 1990-2000, the mineral dominanteconomies grew slightly faster and were slightly less corrupt than thenon-mineral dominant economies. None of this evidence provides much sup-port for the rentier state and rent-seeking models.

With respect to the Tomell and Lane model, there are two important short-comings. First, there is little evidence that non-oil taxation has been significant inoil-dependent LDCs.̂ s Second, declines in oil exports per capita since the early1980s have not coincided with increased growth rates in many oil economies.^^If the model predicts that the "voracity effect" of oil booms generate declines in

Table 1 Growth and Corruption in Mineral-Abundant and Non-Mineral AbundantDeveloping Countries, 1965-2000

Mineral-abundant Non-mineral AbundantDeveloping Countries Developing Countries

(13 observations) (19 observations)

1965-1990Median GDP

growth rate (range) 4.3 (2.5 to 12.4) 5.6 (1.5 to 9.5)Median corruption

index 1980-1985 (range) 3.9 (0.2 to 6.5) 3.6 (0.7 to 8.8)1990-2000

Median GDPgrowth rate (range) 4.0 (1.6 to 7.0) 3.7 (-0.6 to 10.3)

Median corruption index1996 (range) 3.3 (0.7 to 6.8) 3.2 (1.0 to 5.0)

Sources: World Bank, World Development Indicators, various years; Transparency Interna-tional, Corruption Perception Index, various years.

Notes: A corruption index of 10 indicates minimum corruption, an index of 0 indicates maxi-mum corruption. Mineral abundant is defmed as those economies where mineral or fuel exportsin total exports are equal or greater to 35 percent in 1980; non-mineral abundant is defined asthose economies where mineral or fuel exports in total exports are less than 35 percent in 1980.

Page 8: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

174 Is There Really a Resource Curse?

growth rates, then declines in relative oil abundance should have led to less "vo-racious" rent-seeking and thus greater growth. This has not occurred. Declines onper capita oil rents in many oil-dependent LDCs in the period 1980-2005 havenot generally been associated with improved economic performance.^^

Critiques of Rentier State TheoryThere are several assumptions of the rentier state argument as developed byTerry Karl that drive the results. First, it is assumed that a weak state exists atthe time of the discovery of "extemal rents.''^^ Karl arbitrarily chooses oilbooms as the point in which state formation takes place in late developing oileconomies and makes the case that the timing of the discovery of mineral rentsis decisive for subsequent state capacity developments.^' Karl would arguethat Norway and Australia already possessed "strong" bureaucracies beforetheir mineral windfalls arrived and, thus, had countervailing industrial andagricultural interest groups to ensure that resource rents were well managed.

However, the Venezuelan case, which is the focus of Karl's petrostatestudy, does not corroborate her argument. Karl arbitrarily chooses the periodof oil discovery in the 1920s as the period of state formation in Venezuela. Thelong postcolonial history of Venezuela before then (1810-1920) was a periodof mineral resource scarcity in production terms.^o The focus on resourceabundance as determining state formation should have meant, according toKarl's argument, that Venezuela had ample time and stimulus to develop a"Norwegian" style bureaucracy by the time of oil discovery in the 1920s. Thisis because the petrostate problem can be avoided when state building has oc-curred prior to the introduction of the oil export activity.^'

In fact, the period 1810-1920 in Venezuela was a period where mineral re-source scarcity coexisted not with state building, but with incessant factionalcaudillo wars and fragmentation of the national territory.̂ ^ The Federal War(1859-1863) was among the most brutal in nineteenth-century Latin America.The negative effects of this contestation were reflected in economic performance:per capita income in Venezuela was approximately one-half the Latin Americanaverage by the period 1900-1920.33 Moreover, Karl's argument cannot explainwhy oil abundance in Venezuela has coexisted with periods of rapid growth andstagnation in the period 1920-2005.3'* More generally, the failure of central stateconsolidation in nineteenth-century Latin America was common and certainly notassociated with any one pattem of resource endowment.35

Second, rulers are assumed to own the natural resources. That is, they areassigned the property rights over resources. How rulers appropriate and main-tain power is not analyzed in any of the rentier state literature. By assigningrights to leaders, the whole problematic of how to manage "common pool re-sources" is neglected, when the real problem of common pool resources is, infact, analyzing the processes through which rights are assigned, enforced,maintained, and changed.^^ In other words, it is assumed that there are no col-

Page 9: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

Jonathan Di John 175

lective actors within the society who can impose some domestic conditional-ity on how those who occupy the state exercise their power.

The rentier state does not adequately address the question of the legiti-macy of state leaders and the political strategies that may support or under-mine the appropriation and use of mineral rents. The political coalitionsunderpinning a leader's power surely affect how mineral rents are managed.Since the state is a historically specific agent of coalitions, the very process ofclass, group, and coalition formation drives institutional formation andchange. Thus, the ways in which mineral rents are used is not prior to, but isessentially the by-product of political struggles, bargains, and settlements.

Third, leaders are assumed to have predatory as opposed to developmen-tal aims. The neglect of the political processes through which a leader appro-priates power limits our understanding of the motivations of state leaders. Thestate is not a thing, such as "a predator" or "rent-seeking maximizer," but a setof social relations. Why a pariicular coalition in power will not use oil rev-enues to diversify production is not addressed. Even if it is (unrealistically) as-sumed that the leader has absolute power and is thus the owner or residualclaimant in an economy, it does not necessarily follow that leaders will act inpredatory ways. Following Mancur Olson, a leader who has a long time hori-zon, what he calls a "stationary bandit," has the incentive to maximize the rateof economic growth as this will maximize the resources accruing to the statein the long run.̂ ^ Predatory behavior on the pari of leaders (such as confiscat-ing property rights) cannot be assumed or simply described, but needs to beexplained. Thus, the conditions under which predatory motivations dominatedevelopmental motivations in a mineral dominant economy are not addressedin the rentier state model.̂ «

Fourth, by choosing oil booms as the point at which state formation takesplace in late developing oil economies, Karl's model is subject to selectionbias. By definition, most countries that do not have a diversified agriculturaland manufacturing base become mineral dependent. In historical terms, almostall countries began as mineral dominant economies. For instance, the UnitedStates, Canada, Norway, Sweden, the Netherlands, Australia, and Malaysiawere, in earlier stages of development, more mineral dominant, less diversi-fied economies. Not only that, natural resources generally played a growth-enhancing role in stimulating capital accumulation and growth throughout thenow-advanced countries in the period 1870-1914.3^

The problem of selection bias renders many of the econometric studies,which suggest a positive correlation between resource abundance and pooreconomic growth, spurious. As Christa Brunnschweiler notes:

Assuming a strong positive correlation between natural resource abundanceand natural resource exports is by no means obvious given counter-examplesof resource-rich countries with relatively low primary exports such as Aus-

Page 10: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

176 Is There Really a Resource Curse?

tralia and Germany. Moreover, we could also plausibly argue that a dominantshare of primary resource exports in GDP is a strong indication for an overlyspecialized economy. Slow growth in countries with a large share of primaryexports may therefore be due more to economic policy leading to a high eco-nomic dependence on the natural resource sector, rather than a direct naturalresource curse.

40

In other words, poor economic performance in many LDCs is more likely tobe due to mineral dependence rather than abundance per se.

Finally, rentier state theorists do not examine the possibility that mineralabundance can be central to the development of the manufacturing industry inparticular. For instance, Gavin Wright and Jesse Czelusta (2007) examine howand why technological development and collective leaming positively affectedthe development of natural resources in the US economy.'*' They demonstratehow large-scale investments in exploration, transportation, geological knowl-edge, and the technologies of mineral extraction, refining, and utilization in nat-ural resources contributed to long-run economic growth and industrialization inthe United States. Other authors explore how the development of natural re-sources led to increasingly high-tech industrial production in Sweden and Fin-land during the nineteenth and twentieth centuries.'*^ The key policy question toask is why natural resource revenues are used in ways that sustain economicgrowth and diversification in some countries and not in others. Lack of eco-nomic diversification and poor economic growth are why economies are min-eral dependent. If that is the case, then it makes sense to ask why, for example,political conflicts prevented growth in some mineral-dependent economies andnot in others.

Threshold Effects: Which Factors Enhancethe Development Prospects of Mineral andFuel Abundant Less Developed Economies?One of the main policy issues is to identify what are the decisive factors thathelp determine the blessing threshold—helow which the risk of a resourcecurse may be very high. There are three such thresholds worth noting. The firstconcems the fiscal capacity of the state to appropriate mineral rents in the firstplace. The second concems the ownership structure of the mineral sector it-self The third involves the ability of the state to develop dual-track growthstrategies. Let us consider briefly each in tum.

Taxing Resource Abundance EffectivelyNotwithstanding the potential danger of mineral booms for growth and gover-nance, recent commodity booms do offer an important opportunity for mineralabundant countries to generate significant tax revenues and increase their pol-

Page 11: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

Jonathan Di John 177

icy space. The potential revenue capture from such booms often can far out-weigh aid flows. However, recent experience suggests that, in sub-SaharanAfrica at least, this potential is not always being realized.

Consider the case of Zambia, which has experienced one of the worst de-clines in income per capita in the period 1960-2000.'*3 The reasons for the de-cline in Zambian economic performance are complex, but include acombination of the dismption of regional trading routes, the nationalization ofthe copper industry before the development of skilled workers and managersemerged on the domestic scene, and mismanagement of the state-owned cop-per industry. Copper production declined from 600,000 tons in the 1960s tojust over 300,000 tons by the end of the 1990s.

The response of the government in the late 1990s was to privatize thecopper industry and lower mineral royalties in order to attract foreign invest-ment. This was undertaken in the context of desperation; namely, historicallylow world copper prices, dechning copper production, and an unsustainabledebt burden. Its privatization strategy for copper included the reduction inthe corporate tax rate from 35 to 25 percent; exemption from customs dutyon inputs up to US$15 million; reduction of the mineral royalty from 2.0percent to 0.6 percent; exoneration from excise duty on electricity; an in-crease in the period for which losses could be carried, from ten to twentyyears; and exemption from the withholding tax on interest, dividends, royal-ties, and management fees."*"*

Indeed, the mining sector contributes less to govemment revenues than ei-ther the finance or telecom sectors. In sum, the mining companies effectivelypaid almost no income taxes in the period 2000-2006. The effect of these so-called incentives was that it would be decades before the govemment receivedsubstantial revenue from the new mining companies.

While the govemment in 2008 has considered raising the royalty rate to2.5 percent with the support of the Intemational Monetary Fund (IMF), thisrate is still low by the standards of Zambia's neighbors—an IMF survey of taxand royalty rates in developing countries found no other African countrycharging royalties with royalty rates below 2 percent, and some with royaltiesas high as 20 percent.'*^ As a result, taxes as a percentage of gross domesticproduct (GDP) declined from 18.4 percent in 1996 to 17.0 percent in 2005. In2006, the govemment received just $25 million in copper royalties out of a $2billion tumover in copper sales. This substantially hampers the extent to whichthe govemment can finance improvements in physical infrastmcture that areessential for reviving productive capacity and growth in the non-copper sec-tors of agriculture and light manufacturing.

Of course, lack of state appropriation of mineral booms can also be due totheft by govemment officials who do appropriate mineral rents, but do not passthem on to the treasury. The problem of theft of revenues is significant in some

Page 12: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

178 Is There Really a Resource Curse?

fragile states. It has been estimated that up to $200 billion of Nigeria's oil rev-enues have been stolen. To take another example, by 2006 royalty payments tothe treasury of the Democratic Republic of Congo were generating only $86,000per year despite several hundred million dollars of commodity exports.''^

It is possible to draw several policy implications from the cases of Zam-bia and the Democratic Republic of Congo. First, there is an urgent need formineral abundant states to enter into a renegotiation of mining contracts whenthey are unfavorable. Second, capacity building in the geological survey ca-pacity in sub-Saharan Africa needs to be developed in order to improve thebargaining power of states vis-à-vis multinationals.'^'' This is an area where theintemational financial institutions can play a leading role. Third, strengtheningthe legitimacy and enforcement of the Extractive Industries Transparency Ini-tiative (EITI) and the Kimberly process (under which diamonds traded have tobe certified as not originating from areas of conflict) may contribute to reduc-ing the illegal appropriation of mineral rents by domestic actors.

The Ownership Structure of Exporting IndustriesA second important threshold effect worth noting is the extent to which thereis a viable non-mineral, export-oriented private sector in an economy rich inminerals and fuels. The existence of important non-mineral private exporterscan act as a counterpoint to potential predatory behavior when the state dom-inates mineral exports. Such a private presence can also create a lobby groupadvocating exchange rate and other policies that promote export-led growth.In particular, such a lobby would likely demand exchange rate policies thatprevent Dutch disease-type appreciations of the currency as a result of min-eral booms.''^

Ricardo Hausmann and Francisco Rodriguez argue that the dramatic de-cline in capital accumulation and growth in Venezuela in the post-1975 period,for example, can be accounted for, both within closed and open capital accountmodels, by the country's inability to develop an alternative export industry.^?Nearly complete oil specialization is, they argue, a necessary ingredient of anexplanation of the Venezuelan economic collapse.^" Had there existed an alter-native export sector in Venezuela in 1980, the authors argue, the growth ofthatsector would have played a stabilizing role in the country's reaction to fallingoil revenues. In its absence, the domestic economy had to react to adverse oilshocks by contractions in domestic production. This process must continueuntil either the fall in oil revenues is halted or the real exchange rate falls suf-ficiently to make the production of non-oil tradables competitive.^' The au-thors show that of the ten oil exporting developing countries that experiencedsignificant export collapses in the period 1981-2002 (Mexico, Oman, Bahrain,Indonesia, Saudi Arabia, Trinidad and Tobago, Venezuela, Ecuador, Algeria,and Nigeria), only two of these countries (Mexico and Indonesia) were able toexperience a significantly strong growth of their non-oil exports (especially in

Page 13: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

Jonathan Di John 179

manufacturing) to compensate for the decline in oil exports and generate anoverall positive economic growth.

The Hausmann and Rodriguez argument provides an important contribu-tion to the resource curse argument by identifying that the degree of export di-versification matters for the growth prospects among oil exporting latedevelopers. And indeed they argue that policies that increase productivity inthe non-oil tradable sector would have improved the growth prospects of theVenezuelan economy.^2 However, their argument does not explain why non-oil tradable (and especially manufacturing) productivity was so poor and, as aresult, why non-oil export sectors did not emerge in a more dynamic and di-versified manner in Venezuela. This is because their model assumes a givenpath of productivity growth among oil exporters. A more complete understand-ing of the growth collapse in Venezuela and in other monoexport economiesmust not only identify the failure of export diversification, but also explain themechanisms underlying poor productivity growth in the non-oil tradable sec-tors of the economy in question.

Implementing Dual-track Growth StrategiesSince the role of the govemment is generally more pronounced in LDCs thatare rich in oil and minerals, there is likely to be significant amounts of pres-sure for patronage among contending groups and classes. Much of the rentseeking indeed leads to the creation of ineffective public spending and subsi-dization. However, the distribution of rents and privileges, especially to elites,is often central to the maintenance of political stability.53 In such cases, atrade-off between economic growth and political stability can emerge sincethose with access to state resources may be politically powerful, but not nec-essarily effective, risk-taking and dynamic producers.

In this context, the introduction of a dual-track growth strategy may bepromising. The basic idea of this strategy is to promote an emerging dynamicsector (Track 1) where competition and risk taking are promoted while contin-uing to protect and subsidize a vast array of politically powerful but uncom-petitive/inefficient producers in manufacturing and agriculture with the aim ofreducing social tensions and maintaining political stability (Track 2). Exam-ples of Track 1 strategies are export processing zones and industrial parks.Such a dual-track strategy postpones confrontation with established rent seek-ers while the dynamic sector drives competitive diversification of the econ-omy and also builds a pro-reform political constituency.^'' The main challengeof this strategy is to insulate or ring-fence the Track 1 sector from political andclientelist prédation and capture. In general, this strategy can be seen as a tran-sitional path to more growth-enhancing institutional reforms.

There are a range of countries that have attempted dual-track strategies.These include Malaysia, Indonesia, China, and Mauritius.^^ What is notewor-thy in all these cases is the existence of strong national political parties and or-

Page 14: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

180 Is There Really a Resource Curse?

ganizations underpinning executive authority. Strong, disciplined national par-ties not only enable the state to centralize patronage and make credible bar-gains and side payments to contending groups, but they also provide a focalpoint around which collective action and lobbying can occur in a relativelypredictable manner They additionally are central to providing the institutionalmechanisms for distributing patronage to regional elites and to imporiant po-litical constituencies in ways that either prevent challenges to authority ormaintain cohesion of the ruling coalition. Moreover, the necessity for nationalparties to build cross-ethnic and cross-regional alliances reduces the possibil-ity that significant politically destabilizing horizontal inequalities will de-velop. Thus, one important threshold for this strategy to work in mineralabundant economies would appear to be the existence or construction of viablenational political parties.

ConclusionThe proposition that oil abundance induces extraordinary corruption, rentseeking, and centralized interventionism, and that these processes are necessar-ily productivity- and growth restricting, is not supported by comparative or his-torical evidence. Similar levels of state centralization and corruption coincidedwith cycles of growth and stagnation in economies dependent on minerals andfuel. Explaining govemance and state capacity in such economies needs to beconsistent with this basic evidence. The extent to which mineral and fuel abun-dance generate developmental outcomes depends largely on the nature of thestate and politics as well as the structure of ownership in the export sector, allof which are neglected in much of the research curse literature. Much more re-search is needed to examine why some econotnies are able to effectively usemineral and fuel rents in productive ways. A further exploration of whichthreshold effects are decisive in affecting the development path of resource-richdeveloping countries may provide some useful policy insights. ®

NotesJonathan Di John is a senior lecturer in political economy of development at the Schoolof Oriental and African Studies, University of London, and a research fellow at theLondon School of Economics. His most recent book is From Windfall to Curse? Oiland Industrialization in Venezuela, 1920 to the Present (2009). He has done consul-tancy work for the World Bank, the Department for Intemational Development/UKAid, and the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, particularlyin the area of tax reform.

1. HoUis Chenery, Structural Change and Development Policy (New York; Ox-ford University Press, 1979); Nicholas Kaldor, Strategic Factors in Economic Devel-opment (Ithaca; New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations, CornellUniversity, 1967).

2. Arthur Lewis, "Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour,"Manchester School of Economics and Social Studies 22, no. 2 (1954); 139-191.

Page 15: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

Jonathan Di John 181

3. Harold Innis, The Eur Trade in Canada (New Haven: Yale University Press,1930); Melville H. Watkins, "A Staple Theory of Growth," Canadian Journal of Eco-nomics and Political Science 29, no. 2 (1963): 141-158. Moreover, other authors finda generally growth-enhancing role of natural resource-rich countries in the period1870-1914; see, for example, Ronald Findlay and Mats Lundhal, "Resource-ledGrowth: A Long-term Perspective," WIDER Working Paper No. 162 (Helsinki: UnitedNations University; Worid Institute of Development Economics Research, 1999).

4. Alan Gelb et al.. Oil Windfalls: Blessing or Curse? (Oxford: Oxford UniversityPress, 1988), pp. 17-18.

5. Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Wamer find, in the period 1971-1989, that mineralexporters, on average, grew more slowly than the average growth of non-mineral ex-porters; Jeffrey Sachs and Andrew Wamer, "Natural Resource Abundance and Eco-nomic Growth," National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 5398(Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1995). However, DanielLederman and William Maloney, using the Sachs and Wamer data, fmd that there is notrobust evidence to suggest that resource abundance negatively affects growth; DanielLederman and William Maloney, "Trade Stmcture and Growth," in Daniel Ledermanand William Maloney, eds.. Natural Resources: Neither Curse nor Destiny (Washing-ton, DC: World Bank, 2007), pp. 15^0.

6. Raúl Prebisch, The Economic Development of Latin America and Its PrincipalProblems (New York: UN, 1950); Celso Furtado, Economic Development in LatinAmerica (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1970); Paul Baran and PaulSweezy, Monopoly Capital (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1966); Samir Amin,Unequal Development (Brighton, UK: Harvester Press, 1976).

7. Gabriel Palma, "Dependency: A Formal Theory of Underdevelopment or aMethodology for the Analysis of Concrete Situations of Underdevelopment?" WorldDevelopment 6, no. 7-8 (1978): 881-924; John Weeks, Limits to Capitalist Develop-ment: The Industrialization of Peru 1950-1980 (Boulder: Westview Press, 1985).

8. See Stephen Haber, "Introduction," in Stephen Haber, ed.. How Latin AmericaFell Behind: Essays in the Economic History of Brazil and Mexico, 1800-1914 (Stan-ford: Stanford University Press, 1997), pp. 1-33.

9. John Maynard Keynes, A Treatise on Money, vol. 2 (London: Macmillan, 1930).10. Michael Ross, "What Do We Know About Natural Resources and Civil War?"

Journal of Peace Research 41, no. 3 (2004): 337-356; Jonathan Di John, "Oil Abun-dance and Violent Political Conflict: A Critical Assessment," Journal of DevelopmentStudies 43, no. 6 (2007): 961-986. For a discussion of the conditions under which min-eral and fuel wealth affects regime type, see Thad Dunning, Crude Democracy: NaturalResource Wealth and Political Regimes (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008).

11. "Dutch disease" models are summarized in Peter Neary and S weder van Wijn-bergen. Natural Resources and the Macro Economy (Cambridge: MIT Press, 1986).

12. Raúl Prebisch, The Economic Development of Latin America and Its PrincipalProblems (New York: UN, 1950).

13. Allyn A. Young, "Increasing Retums and Economic Progress," Economic Jour-nal 38, no. 152 (1928): 527-542.

14. Sukti Dasgupta and A. Singh, "Manufacturing, Services, and Premature Dein-dustrialization: A Kaldorian Analysis," World Institute for Development EconomicsResearch Paper No. 2006/49 (Helsinki: World Institute for Development EconomicsResearch, 2006).

15. Neary and van Wijnbergen, Natural Resources and the Macro Economy, pp.10-11.

16. See Jonathan Di John, From Windfall to Curse? Oil and Industrialization inVenezuela, 1920 to the Present (University Park: Penn State University Press, 2009),pp. 35-76.

Page 16: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

182 Is There Realty a Resource Curse?

17. Hossein Mahdavy, "The Patterns and Problems of Economic Development inRentier States," in M. A. Cook, ed.. Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East(London: Oxford University Press, 1970), pp. 428-468; Terry Lynn Karl, The Paradoxof Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro States (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1997);Richard Auty, "Patterns of Rent-extraction and Deployment in Developing Countries:Implications for Govemance, Economic Policy and Performance," in George Mavrotasand Anthony F. Shorrocks, eds.. Advancing Development: Core Themes in Global Eco-nomics (Basingstoke: Palgrave, 2007), pp. 555-577.

18. Stanley Engerman and Kenneth Sokoloff, "Factor Endowments, Institutionsand Differential Paths to Growth Among New World Economies: A View from Eco-nomic Historians in the United States," in Stephen Haber, ed.. How Latin America FellBehind: Essays on the Economic Histories of Brazil and Mexico, 1800-1914 (Stanford:Stanford University Press, 1997), pp. 260-306.

19. Paul Milgrom and John Roberts, "Bargaining Costs, Influence Costs, and theOrganization of Economic Activity," in James Alt and Kenneth Shepsle, eds.. Perspec-tives on Positive Political Economy (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990),p. 269.

20. Paolo Mauro, "Corruption: Causes, Consequences, and Agenda for FurtherResearch," Finance and Development 35, no. 1 (1998): 11-14.

21. Dennis Mueller, Public Choice 11 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,1989), p. 241.

22. Aaron Tomell and Philip Lane, "The Voracity Effect," American EconomicReview 89, no. 1 (1999): 22-46.

23. Ibid., pp. 38-iO.24. Ibid., p. 40.25. On Venezuela, see Maria Moreno and Francisco Rodriguez, "Plenty of Room?

Fiscal Space in a Resource Abundant Economy," paper presented at UN DevelopmentProgramme conference, "Pro-poor Domestic Resource Mobilization: Securing FiscalSpace," Dakar, Senegal, November 2005.

26. Di John, From Windfall to Curse? pp. 90-91.27.Ibid.28. Terry Lynn Karl, The Paradox of Plenty, p. 42.29. Ibid, pp. 40-43.30. The key term here is "in production terms." With hindsight, we know that

Venezuela had large oil reserves. However, no one knew about them in the nineteenthcentury nor was there any technological capacity in the country to discover, let alonedevelop, the vast oil and natural gas reserves that existed.

31. Terry Lynn Karl, The Paradox of Plenty, p. 13.32. Robert Louis Gilmore, Caudillism and Militarism in Venezuela 1810-1910

(Athens: Ohio University Press, 1964).33. Rosemary Thorp, Progress, Poverry and Exclusion: An Economic History of

Latin America in the 20th Century (Washington, DC: Inter-American DevelopmentBank, 1998), p. 353.

34. Di John, From Windfall to Curse? pp. 77-107.35. Miguel Angel Centeno, "Blood and Debt: War and Taxation in Nineteenth-

century Latin America," American Journal of Sociology 102, no. 6 (1997): 1565-1605.36. Elinor Ostrom, Governing the Commons (Cambridge: Cambridge University

Press, 1990).37. Mancur Olson, "Dictatorship, Democracy and Development," Amenca« Political

Science Review 87, no. 3 (1993): 567-576.

Page 17: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

Jonathan Di John 183

38. It should be kept in mind that developmental outcomes are not only, or evenmainly, the result of a leader's intentions or aims. Developmental outcomes are oftenthe unintended consequences of conflicts and political struggles. Also, the distinctionbetween developmental and predatory is not necessarily in binary opposition. Leaderswho do not have developmental aims will not necessarily become predatory.

39. Findlay and Lundhal, "Resource-led Growth."40. Christa Bninnschweiler, "Cursing the Blessings? Natural Resource Abundance,

Institutions, and Economic Growth," World Development 36, no. 3 (2008): 401.41. Gavin Wright and Jesse Czelusta, "Resource-based Growth: Past and Present,"

in Daniel Lederman and William Maloney, eds.. Natural Resources: Neither Curse norDestiny (Washington, DC: Wodd Bank, 2007), pp. 183-213.

42. Magnus Blomström and Ari Kokko, "From Natural Resources to High-techProduction: The Evolution of Industrial Competitiveness in Sweden and Finland," inDaniel Lederman and William Maloney, eds.. Natural Resources: Neither Curse norDestiny (Washington, DC: World Bank, 2007), pp. 213-259.

43. John Weeks, Victoria Chisala, Alemayehu Geda, Hulya Dagdeviren, TerryMcKinley, Carlos Oya, and Alfredo Saad-Filho, Economic Policies for Growth, Em-ployment and Poverty Reduction: Case Study of Zambia (London: Centre for Develop-ment Policy and Research, School of Oriental and African Studies, University ofLondon, 2004).

44. Alastair Fraser and John Lungu, "For Whom the Windfalls? Winners andLosers in the Privatisation of Zambia's Copper Mines" (Lusaka, Zambia: Civil SocietyTrade Network of Zambia, 2007), www.minewatchzambia.com/reports/report.pdf (ac-cessed 1 August 2010).

45. Thomas Baunsgaard, "A Primer on Mineral Taxation," Intemational MonetaryFund Working Paper No. WP/01/139 (Washington, DC: IMF, 2001).

46. Both examples drawn from Paul Collier and Anthony Venables, "Natural Re-sources and State Fragility," Oxford Centre for the Analysis of Resource RichEconomies Research Paper No. 31 (Oxford: OxCarre, 2009), pp. 18-19.

47. The potential of improving the bargaining position of governments is enor-mous. As of 2000, the average square kilometer of the African landmass had beneath itonly around $25,000 of known subsoil assets whereas the corresponding figure for thelandmass of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) is$125,000; Collier and Venables, "Natural Resources and State Fragility," p. 18. Sincethe subsoil assets of the OECD have been heavily exploited for a far longer period thanthose of Africa, it is likely that the true average value of Africa's subsoil assets exceedsthat of the OECD.

48. For a discussion of how and why ownership pattems within the oil sector itselfaffect governance and reform processes in transition economies, see Pauline JonesLuong and Erika Weinthal, Oil Is Not a Curse: Ownership Structure and institutions inSoviet Successor States (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010).

49. Ricardo Hausmann and Francisco Rodriguez, "Why Did Venezuelan GrowthCollapse?" paper presented at the Kennedy School of Govemment conference,"Venezuelan Economic Growth 1970-2005," Harvard University, Cambridge, April2006.

50. Ibid., p. 10.51. Ibid.52. Ibid., p. 12.53. Douglass C. North, John Joseph Wallis, and Barry R. Weingast, Violence and

Social Orders (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2009).

Page 18: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

184 Is There Really a Resource Curse?

54. Richard Auty and Nicola Pontara, "A Dual Track Strategy for Managing Mau-ritania's Projected Oil Rent," Development Policy Review 26, no. 1 (2008): 59-77.

55. On Mauritius, see Ronald Findlay and Stanislaw Wellisz, The Political Econ-omy of Poverty, Equity and Growth: Five Small Open Economies (New York: OxfordUniversity Press, 1993). On Malaysia, see Henry J. Bruton, The Political Economy ofPoverty, Equity and Growth: Sri Lanka and Malaysia (New York: Oxford UniversityPress, 1992). On China, see Yingyi Qian, "How Reform Worked in China," in Dani Ro-drik, ed.. In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives of Economic Growth (Princeton:Princeton University Press, 2003), pp. 297-333. On Indonesia, see Frank Flatters andGlenn Paul Jenkins, Trade Policy in Indonesia (Cambridge: Harvard Institute for Inter-national Development, 1986).

Page 19: Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of ...Is There Really a Resource Curse? A Critical Survey of Theory and Evidence Jonathan Di John This article provides a critical

Copyright of Global Governance is the property of Lynne Rienner Publishers and its content may not be copied

or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission.

However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.