28
1 ISSN 1835-9728 Environmental Economics Research Hub Research Reports Between Estimates of the Environmental Kuznets Curve David I Stern Research Report No. 34 July 2009 About the authors David Stern is a Hub Researcher based at the Arndt-Corden Division of Economics, Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies, Australian National University, Canberra, ACT 0200, AUSTRALIA. E-mail: [email protected] , Phone: +61-2-6161-3977.

ISSN 1835-9728 Environmental Economics Research Hub ......coefficients – i.e. the long-run effect. The less the correlation, the closer the static estimates will be to the impact

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    3

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 1

    ISSN 1835-9728

    Environmental Economics Research Hub Research Reports

    Between Estimates of the Environmental Kuznets Curve

    David I Stern

    Research Report No. 34

    July 2009

    About the authors David Stern is a Hub Researcher based at the Arndt-Corden Division of Economics, Research

    School of Pacific and Asian Studies, Australian National University, Canberra, ACT 0200,

    AUSTRALIA.

    E-mail: [email protected], Phone: +61-2-6161-3977.

    mailto:[email protected]

  • 2

    Environmental Economics Research Hub Research Reports are published by The Crawford School of Economics and Government, Australian National University, Canberra 0200 Australia. These Reports present work in progress being undertaken by project teams within the Environmental Economics Research Hub (EERH). The EERH is funded by the Department of Environment and Water Heritage and the Arts under the Commonwealth Environment Research Facility. The views and interpretations expressed in these Reports are those of the author(s) and should not be attributed to any organisation associated with the EERH. Because these reports present the results of work in progress, they should not be reproduced in part or in whole without the authorisation of the EERH Director, Professor Jeff Bennett ([email protected])

    Crawford School of Economics and Government THE AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY

    http://www.crawford.anu.edu.au

    mailto:[email protected]://www.crawford.anu.edu.au/http://www.crawford.anu.edu.au/

  • 3

    TABLE OF CONTENTS

    Abstract 4

    1. Introduction 5

    2. Econometric Theory 6

    3. Methods and Data 11

    4. Results 12

    5. Discussion and Conclusions 16

    References 17

  • 4

    Abstract

    A recent paper in the Journal of Environmental Economics and Management [18] points out

    that time effects are not uniquely identified in reduced form models such as the

    environmental Kuznets curve and proposes a solution that assumes that the time effect is

    common to each pair of most similar countries. The between estimator makes no a priori

    assumption about the nature of the time effects and is likely to provide consistent estimates of

    long-run relationships in real world data situations. I apply several common panel data

    estimators to the data set for carbon and sulfur emissions in the OECD collected by

    Vollebergh et al. [18] and the global sulfur dataset compiled by Stern and Common [13]. The

    between estimates of the sulfur-income elasticity are 0.732 in the OECD and 1.157 in the

    global data set and the estimated carbon-income elasticity is 1.612.

    Key Words: carbon, sulfur, environmental Kuznets curve, between estimator

    JEL Codes: C23, Q53, Q56

    Acknowledgments: I thank Elbert Dijkgraaf for providing the data used in their paper.

  • 5

    1. Introduction

    A recent paper in Journal of Environmental Economics and Management [18] points out that

    the time effects are not identified, a priori, in reduced form models such as the environmental

    Kuznets curve (EKC) and that existing EKC regression results depend on the specific

    identifying assumptions implicitly imposed. Their approach is to assume that the time effects

    are identical in each pair of most similar countries. In this paper, I propose to use the simpler

    between estimator – a cross section regression on the mean data for each country – as an

    alternative means of estimating relationships such as the EKC free from assumptions about

    the time effects. I apply the between estimator and other panel data estimators to the data sets

    used by Vollebergh et al. [18] and the global sulfur dataset used by Stern and Common [13].

    Panel data contains two dimensions of variation – the differences between countries – the

    “between variation” and the differences over time within countries – the “within variation”.

    Fixed effects estimation – also known as the “within estimator” – eliminates the average

    differences between countries prior to estimation. The coefficient estimates, therefore,

    primarily exploit the variation within the countries.1 The between estimator first averages the

    data for each country over time. Therefore, the coefficient estimates only exploit variation

    across countries and not within countries. As explained in the following section, in the

    absence of a variety of misspecification issues, both these and other panel estimators should

    converge on identical estimates in large samples when there are no time effects (Pesaran and

    Smith, 1995). But empirically the various estimators diverge due to misspecification error

    and differences in the treatment of time effects.

    In contrast to the time series and panel estimators that have been used to estimate the EKC to

    date, the between estimator makes no specific assumptions about the time process. To

    achieve identification it makes the two standard assumptions of linear regression that the

    regression slope coefficients are common to all countries (and implicitly time periods) and

    that there is no correlation between the regressors and the error term. Given these

    assumptions, the between estimator is a consistent estimator of the long-run relationship

    between the variables when the time series are stationary or stochastically trending and is

    super-consistent for cointegrating series [11].

    Historically, the between estimator has been shunned by researchers due to a concern that

    1 Not all variation between countries is eliminated by the subtraction of country means from the data.

  • 6

    omitted variables represented by the individual effects may be correlated with the included

    explanatory variables. As the individual effects are absorbed into the regression residual

    term, this would be expressed as a correlation between the error term and the regressors and

    lead to inconsistent estimates of the regression coefficients. The random effects estimator,

    which treats the individual effects as error components, suffers from the same potential bias.

    The widely used Hausman test [6] tests whether there is a significant difference between the

    random effects and fixed effects estimates of a model, which should both be consistent

    estimators in the absence of such a correlation (assuming that there are no other econometric

    issues). There is commonly found to be a difference between these estimators in the EKC

    literature [13].

    However, this is only one of several potential misspecifications of panel data models. Hauk

    and Wacziarg [5] show that the between estimator is the best performer among potential

    panel data estimators even when the orthogonality assumption is violated but measurement

    error is present.

    The paper is structured as follows. The second section reviews the econometric theory

    concerning potential biases in panel data estimators. It concludes that, though all estimators

    may suffer from biases and/or inconsistency, the between estimator is the best practical

    estimator. The third section briefly reviews the methods and data used. The fourth section

    presents the results and the fifth concludes.

    2. Econometric Theory

    a. The Issue

    Differences between time series and cross-section estimates have long been discussed in the

    econometric literature [2]. In recent decades this interest has been transferred to panel data. A

    time series is simply a panel data set with only one individual and a cross-section a panel

    with a single time period. In addition to the estimators discussed in the introduction – within

    (fixed effects), random effects, and between estimates – the econometric literature reviewed

    in this section also discusses the average of static or dynamic time series regressions and OLS

  • 7

    as potential estimators for panel data.2 The standard EKC model for pollution emissions is

    given by:

    !

    ln(E /P)it

    =" + #1 ln(GDP /P)it + #2(ln(GDP /P))it2 + µ

    i+ $

    t+ %

    it (1)

    where E is emissions, P population, and GDP is measured in constant purchasing power

    parity adjusted dollars. i indexes countries and t time periods. The error term is composed of

    an individual component µ, a time component γ, and a remainder term ε. In the general case,

    all three error components are considered to be random variables. The fixed effects estimator

    assumes that the individual and time components are fixed intercepts. Time series models

    might treat the time component as a linear deterministic trend.

    Pesaran and Smith [11] point out that if the true data generating process (DGP) is static, the

    explanatory variables are uncorrelated with the error term, and any parameter heterogeneity

    across individuals is random and distributed independently of the regressors, all alternative

    estimators – time series or the various pooled estimators - should be consistent estimators of

    the coefficient means. It is the presence of dynamics and/or correlation between the

    regressors and the error term that results in differences between the estimators whether the

    true parameters are homogenous or heterogeneous. There is no essential difference between

    time series and cross-section estimates, only differences in the likely importance and impact

    of misspecification. In the following, I address the impact of each type of misspecification on

    the different estimators.

    b. Coefficient Heterogeneity

    Pesaran and Smith [11] argue that, in the absence of omitted variables or measurement error,

    the averaged time series and between estimators are consistent for large N and T, whatever

    the nature of coefficient heterogeneity. A traditional cross-section estimate, however, may

    suffer from a high level of bias because T = 1. In the presence of coefficient heterogeneity,

    FE and RE estimators for dynamic models will be inconsistent, as forcing the coefficients to

    be equal induces serial correlation in the disturbance, which results in inconsistency when

    2 There are many more potential panel data estimators including random coefficients models, maximum likelihood estimates, instrumental variable estimators etc.

  • 8

    there are lagged dependent variables. If the true model is static, static FE and RE should be

    consistent in the absence of other misspecifications.

    Pesaran and Smith analyze both stationary and non-stationary cases – static time-series

    estimates are of course superconsistent when the variables are I(1) and cointegrate. But, if the

    parameters vary across groups, the pooled estimates need not cointegrate. The between

    estimator is also a consistent estimator of the long-run coefficients even in the absence of

    cointegration, as long as the explanatory variables are strictly exogenous. They estimate a

    labor demand model (cross-section dimension: 38, time-series dimension: 29) using

    heterogeneous and pooled approaches. The static cointegrating time series regressions yield

    an average own price elasticity of -0.30 and a variety of dynamic time series models give

    elasticities up to -0.45. The between estimate is -0.523 and static pooled estimates are: OLS: -

    0.53, RE: -0.42, and FE: -0.41. Dynamic pooled estimates are much larger in absolute value,

    OLS: -3.28, RE: -1.83, and FE: -0.74. The bottom line is that there are no large differences

    between their static estimates though BE and OLS show greater elasticities, time series

    smaller elasticities, and fixed effects occupies a mid-point. The dynamic pooled estimators,

    however, deviate significantly from the estimators that Pesaran and Smith argue are

    consistent.

    c. Misspecified Dynamics

    Baltagi and Griffin [2] examined the effect of omitted dynamics in the case of stationary

    panel data. If the true data generating process (DGP) for a time series is dynamic and a static

    model is estimated there are omitted lagged variables. The value of the estimated coefficients

    depends on the correlation between the omitted lags and the current value of the variables.

    The greater the correlation, the closer the static coefficients will be to the sum of the dynamic

    coefficients – i.e. the long-run effect. The less the correlation, the closer the static estimates

    will be to the impact coefficients – i.e. a short-run effect. Baltagi and Griffin argued further,

    that in panel data, the higher the correlation between lagged dependent variables the better

    the between estimator would estimate the long-run coefficients. The performance of the

    within estimator also depends on the relative amount of between and within variation in the

    data as correlations between cross-sections of demeaned data are usually lower than between

    cross-sections of raw data. They carry out a Monte Carlo analysis of a model with a very long

    lag structure, random effects errors, and no correlation between the explanatory variables and

    those errors. They fit dynamic models to the generated data (they do not fit static models).

  • 9

    Estimated lag length tends to be truncated. The between estimator gets very close to the true

    long-run elasticity while the within estimator provides good estimates of the short-run

    elasticity and somewhat underestimates the long-run elasticity. The within estimator is also

    strongly affected by changes in the dynamic structure or length of the time series, while the

    between estimator is not. All this is despite the cross-section dimension being only 18 (the

    time-series dimension is 14). OLS is slightly biased upwards.

    Van Doel and Kiviet [17] concluded that in general “static estimators usually underestimate

    the long-run effect” when the variables are stationary but are consistent under non-

    stationarity if there is cointegration. Two more recent papers further examine the

    performance of static estimators for stationary data. Pirotte [12] shows that even if the time

    dimension is fixed but N -> ∞ the between estimator converges to the long-run coefficients of

    a dynamic model. When there is little serial correlation the within estimator converges to

    short-run effects. If there are no individual effects, OLS converges to the long-run when the

    sum of the lag coefficients tends to unity as well as when there is less serial correlation but

    large individual effects. Egger and Pfaffermayr [3] also assume an underlying stationary,

    dynamic DGP. Using Monte Carlo analysis, they find that when the explanatory variables are

    not serially correlated the static within estimator is downwardly biased even compared to the

    short-run effects. But when the level of serial correlation is high the within estimator

    converges towards the long-run effects. On the other hand, the between estimator is biased

    downwards if serial correlation is high and the time dimension is small. In their simulations,

    on the whole, the parameter estimates are ranked from smallest to largest FE, RE, OLS, BE

    with even BE biased down from the true value.

    d. Omitted Explanatory Variables

    The one-way error components model assumes that the error term in a panel model is

    composed of an individual effect, which varies across individuals but is constant over time

    and a remainder disturbance that varies over both time and individuals [1]. If omitted

    explanatory variables are correlated with the included regressors, the regressors will be

    correlated with the individual effects and/or the remainder disturbance [4]. The fixed effects

    estimator eliminates the individual effects prior to estimation while the between estimator

    averages over the remainder disturbances of each individual. Therefore, panel OLS, random

    effects, between, and cross-section estimators will be biased if the regressors are correlated

    with the individual effects and the fixed effects and time series estimators will be unbiased.

  • 10

    But if the correlation is instead with the remainder disturbance, the between estimator will be

    consistent (though biased when the time series dimension is small) and all the other

    estimators will be inconsistent.

    In the case of the EKC, there may be many omitted variables but the most important is likely

    to be the state of technology [14]. While a large number of EKC studies allow for a common

    series of time dummies, others do not include any time effects, while others still include

    linear or more complex trends.

    If a linear trend is employed and the true technology trend is not deterministic and linear, a

    variable has been omitted. The rate of technological change certainly varies over time and

    there may well be a correlation between income and the level of technology adopted.

    Therefore, there is likely to be a correlation between both the remainder error and the

    regressors and between the individual effects and the regressors. A priori, there is no reason

    to prefer one estimator over the other on these grounds.

    e. Measurement Error

    Measurement error in the explanatory variables is a further factor to be considered [9]. As is

    well-known, measurement error induces a correlation between the error term and the

    regressors and biases the estimates downwards if the measurement error is not correlated with

    the regressors [7]. If measurement errors are non-systematic the between estimator will

    average them out over time and will be consistent but biased when the time series dimension

    is small, while the within estimator amplifies the noise to signal ratio by subtracting

    individual means from each time series.

    Hauk and Wacziarg [5] carry out a Monte Carlo analysis of an economic growth equation to

    examine the effects of both measurement error and omitted variables on alternative panel

    estimators. They find that the between estimator is the best performer in terms of having the

    minimum bias relative to fixed effects, random effects, and some GMM estimators

    commonly used in the growth literature.

  • 11

    f. Conclusion

    There appears to be, therefore, a consensus that the between estimator is the best estimator –

    it uses a large sample of data (compared to time series estimates) and is consistent for both

    stationary and non-stationary data in the face of misspecified dynamics and heterogeneous

    regression coefficients. And despite the potential for correlation between the explanatory

    variables and the individual effects, it appears to perform well in real world situations [5].

    Cross-section estimates may, however, be significantly biased. And there is disagreement on

    the properties of other estimators whose performance depends on the specific properties of

    the data.

    It is likely that the data used in environmental Kuznets curve studies is stochastically trending

    but that given the overly simple nature of the EKC model cointegration is unlikely [10].

    Measurement error regarding PPP adjusted GDP and sulfur emissions is likely to be very

    significant. There is less error in the measurement of carbon emissions. Correlation between

    the regressors and omitted variables is very likely but there is no a priori reason I believe to

    assume that there is a more significant correlation between the country means of the

    regressors and the omitted variables than there is in the variation over time of the omitted

    variables and the regressors. In these circumstances the between estimator is likely to be a

    reasonably good estimator of the long-run relationship between income and emissions and at

    least better than other estimators.

    3. Methods and Data

    Equation (1) specifies the general model. I estimate this model for sulfur and carbon

    emissions. I also estimate a linear version of the model (setting ) for the between

    estimator. I use each of the following estimators: Between estimator, fixed effects, random

    effects, first differences, and pooled OLS. All the estimates apart from OLS are carried out

    using the PREGRESS procedure in RATS which computes standard errors taking clustering

    of residuals into account. OLS regressions were estimated in RATS using LINREG with the

    option CLUSTER. I estimated the fixed effects and random effects models with and without

    time effects. For OLS and the first differences estimator I estimated the model with and

    without a linear time trend.

    2 0

    Because the between estimator is a consistent estimator of the long-run relationship even in

    the absence of cointegration, I do not carry out tests of cointegration in this paper. The

  • 12

    extracted time effects are almost certainly non-stationary and, therefore, emissions will not

    cointegrate with income, but we will have a good estimate of the income elasticity of

    emissions.

    For the quadratic models, I computed the turning point at which the elasticity of emissions

    with respect to income switches from positive to negative as well as the mean and standard

    deviation of the elasticity under the assumption that the coefficients are known.

    Vollebergh et al. [18] raise the influence of outliers on their simple EKC estimates. For the

    between estimator I re-estimated the model eliminating one country at a time to determine to

    what degree the results were sensitive to influential observations. I report the distribution

    obtained from this exercise.

    Vollebergh et al. compiled a data set for sulfur and carbon emissions, GDP (in real 1990

    international dollars), and population for 24 OECD countries for the period 1960-2000. I also

    use the Stern and Common [13] sample of sulfur emissions and GDP per capita for 73

    developed and developing countries for the period 1960-1990. This allows us to evaluate the

    effect of restricting the sample to just OECD countries, which Stern and Common (2001)

    found had a major effect on the estimates.

    4. Results

    Table 1 presents the results for the EKC model applied to Vollebergh et al.’s sulfur emissions

    data. The R2 statistics are not comparable across different estimation methods. The turning

    points are all within sample. The mean of the income elasticity indicates which of the turning

    points fall in the lower half or upper half of the income distribution – positive elasticities

    indicate that the majority of the observations are on the rising limb of the EKC and vice

    versa. The models with time trends or time effects have somewhat higher turning points and

    more positive mean elasticities. The first difference estimates with a time trend yield the

    highest turning point of $19,008 1990 PPP Dollars. Fixed and random effects estimates of the

    turning points are a little higher than those in [13] for the OECD from 1960-1990 and are the

    lowest of the estimators. There is little difference between these two estimates especially for

    the models without time effects. In the latter case the Hausman statistic is just 0.0035

    (p=1.00) and in the case of time effects 0.456 (p=0.634). This result is important because it

  • 13

    indicates that the regressors do not appear to be correlated with the individual effects in this

    sample. Therefore, the between estimator is not likely to suffer from this bias either.

    Stern and Common [13] estimated an income elasticity of 0.67 for the OECD from the first

    difference estimates, which is identical to that found here for the longer period. However,

    while they found that the coefficient on the time trend in the first differences regression was -

    0.020 here it is -0.048.

    All these EKC estimates have a much higher degree of curvature than those in [13]. As

    shown by the standard deviations of the elasticities, each country’s estimated elasticity has

    typically moved over an implausibly wide range of values in the period of 40 years. For the

    random effects estimator with time effects the average income elasticity in the sample goes

    from 1.37 in 1960 to -1.97 in 2000. These results strongly contrast with Vollebergh et al.’s

    estimates [18]. Figure 4 in their paper shows that the average income effect remains positive

    through the whole time period for both sulfur and carbon. The curve is somewhat convex

    down suggesting a more or less constant elasticity.

    The between estimator for the quadratic model, however, clearly suffers from

    multicollinearity - both regression coefficients are insignificantly different from zero. The

    turning point is also very imprecisely estimated, though the elasticity has a narrower range

    than all but the first difference estimates. So I also estimate a linear model. The estimated

    elasticity is 0.732 though it is only significantly different from zero at the 10% level. This

    finding seems congruent with Vollebergh et al.’s [18] findings.

    To test the effect of influential data, I estimate the linear between estimator 24 times

    eliminating one country from each estimate. The lowest elasticity estimated was when

    Turkey was eliminated (0.566) and the highest when Switzerland was eliminated (0.989). The

    standard deviation is 0.081. Eliminating Turkey reduced the t-statistic of the elasticity to

    1.05. Omitting Switzerland increased it to 2.64.

    Figure 1 presents the linear between estimate together with the income part of each of the

    other estimates that include time effects. The average individual and time effect has been

    added to the fixed effects estimate and the first differences estimate has been given an

    intercept so that the mean fitted value is equal to the mean fitted value of the other estimators.

  • 14

    The first differences curve is flatter than the others and not so different from the linear

    between estimator in the upper income range. Random effects, fixed effects and OLS do not

    differ very substantially from each other.

    Figure 4 decomposes projected emissions based on the between estimator in a similar fashion

    to Vollebergh et al. [18]. The income effect is the population weighted mean of the fitted

    regression model in the given year. The time effect is population weighted mean residual.

    The constant term is, therefore, included in the income effect. I have not normalized the

    curves – the sum of the two curves is equal to average per capita emissions. The overall

    picture is similar to Vollebergh et al.’s Figure 4a.

    Table 2 presents the corresponding results for carbon emissions. The turning points are

    within sample for fixed and random effects and mostly out of sample for the other estimators.

    The turning point for the between estimator is effectively zero and the regression suffers from

    multicollinearity, so we again also estimate a linear model for the between estimator. In each

    case the majority of observations are on the rising limb of the EKC as shown by the mean

    elasticities. For fixed and random effects the models with time effects have slightly lower

    turning points than those without. For all the other estimators the reverse is true. The highest

    turning points are found for the OLS and first difference estimators with time effects

    ($57,505 and $51,334) and the maximum elasticity is 1.666 for the quadratic between model.

    The two-way fixed effects estimate of the turning point is almost identical to that in [18].

    There is again little difference between the fixed and random effect estimates indicating that

    omitted variables bias is not likely to be problematic in this sample. For the one-way model

    the Hausman statistic is just 0.0035 (p=1.00) and for the two-way model 0.124 (p=0.940).

    The coefficients on the time trends for OLS and first differences are negative but

    substantially smaller than the estimates reported above for sulfur. There is also much less

    variation around the mean of the income elasticities for all of the estimators compared to the

    estimates for sulfur.

    The estimated elasticity for the linear between model is 1.612 which is highly significantly

    different to zero (t = 6.322). It is also significantly greater than unity (t = 2.400). To test the

    effect of influential data I estimate the linear between estimator 24 times in each case

  • 15

    eliminating one country from the data. Eliminating Luxembourg (1.472) results in the lowest

    estimate of the elasticity while the highest estimate results when Switzerland was eliminated

    (1.791). The standard deviation is just 0.059.

    Figure 2 presents the analysis that Figure 1 provided for sulfur emissions. The between

    estimates look plausible though the OLS ones seem to fit to the data better in a naïve sense

    but are close to the between estimates throughout the income range. The first differences

    curve is again flattest. Random effects and fixed effects do not differ very substantially from

    each other.

    Figure 5 decomposes carbon emissions based on the linear between estimator. The picture

    differs from Figure 4b in [18]. Those results show no net reduction in emissions due to the

    time effect over the sample period, though there is a reduction from the mid 1970s on. Still,

    the income effect in these results has increased carbon emissions by more than the time effect

    has reduced them. Given ongoing improvements in energy efficiency and increases in the

    share of energy coming from nuclear power and natural gas over this period, it is not

    unreasonable to expect an important time effect for carbon, albeit a smaller one than for

    sulfur.

    The results for the global sulfur dataset in Table 3 show much more similar estimates of the

    income elasticity across the different estimators and the standard deviation of the elasticity is

    also much smaller than for OECD sulfur data in Table 1. The between estimate of the

    elasticity: 1.157 is not substantially different from the two way fixed effects estimate of

    1.104. Hausman statistics are 0.0317 (p = 0.968) and 0.601 (p = 0.548) for the random effects

    model without and with time effects respectively. Though the estimates without time effects

    or time trends are generally lower, all but the one-way fixed effects estimate yield out of

    sample turning points and in all cases the mean elasticity is positive. Figure 3 presents the

    fitted income effects, which are all fairly similar to each other. These estimates suggest that

    the between estimate of the elasticity from OECD data of 0.732 is not such an outlier as one

    might think. But the ASL data underlying Table 3 tends to systematically underestimate

    sulfur emissions from developing economies. So it is not surprising to find a higher elasticity

    for this data. Restricting the sample to just OECD countries gives an elasticity for the

    between estimator of 0.658 (standard error = 0.351).

  • 16

    Figures 6 and 7 present the residuals or time effects for twelve of the countries for the

    between estimates in Table 1 and 2. Figure 6 is comparable to Figure 2 in [15]. The

    differences are that the latter study controls for the input and output structure of the economy,

    the sample of countries is smaller, and the time series extend from only 1971 to 2000. The

    frontier of the most efficient countries is here made up of Turkey, Switzerland (neither of

    which are included in [15]) and Japan. The latter country was on the frontier for most of the

    period in [15]. Australia and Turkey see a rise in emissions controlling for income, with

    Australia ending the period as the dirtiest country for its income level. Canada starts the

    period as the dirtiest. As found in [15], the countries end the period with the Germanic

    countries and Japan the cleanest and the Anglo-Saxon and Mediterranean countries the

    dirtiest with the exception of France. France is found to be relatively clean here, because [15]

    controls for nuclear power. It is clear that there is no particular relationship in the sample

    between income and efficiency. This explains why there is no significant difference between

    the random and fixed effects estimation.

    Switzerland has the lowest carbon emissions for its income level for every year in the sample.

    The UK starts the sample with the highest income-adjusted carbon emissions and Australia

    ends it. Turkey sees rising income adjusted emissions. So here too there is no relationship

    between the individual effects and income. There is also less of a clear-cut relationship

    between cultural regions and the final level of income-adjusted emissions. The Anglo-Saxon

    countries are in the upper half of the distribution. But so is Germany.

    5. Discussion and Conclusions

    Theory suggests that the between estimator is likely to perform well as an estimator of long-

    run relationships unless the correlation between the individual effects and the regressors in

    the panel data model outweighs other sources of estimation bias. The between estimator gave

    higher estimates of the emissions elasticity with respect to income than other estimators for

    the two samples of OECD data. For sulfur, however, the results shown in Figure 4 seem

    reasonably similar to Vollebergh et al.’s [18] results. In contrast to most past research, I

    found quite a large time effect for carbon, but it is smaller than the effect for sulfur and

    increasing energy efficiency and fuel switching could explain this effect even in the absence

    of strict climate policies in most countries. Regression using defactored observations finds

    that the coefficients for both the level and square of log income are significantly positive [19]

    and likely results in a similarly high income elasticity.

  • 17

    The between estimator is very simple to implement compared to either Vollebergh et al.’s

    approach [18], a structural time series approach [15, 16] or a de-factored regression [19]. The

    estimated time effects in this paper presumably include both a permanent time effect and a

    transitory component. Future research could decompose the time effect into transitory and

    permanent components using structural time series models or non-probabilistic filters such as

    the Hodrick and Prescott filter [8]. Of course, the models in this paper leave more

    unexplained than they explain. I am not advocating the simple emissions-income model as an

    adequate model of emissions. However, the between estimator can provide a consistent

    estimate of the income-emissions elasticity and can also be applied to more sophisticated

    models such as production frontiers.

    References

    [1] B. H. Baltagi, Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, 4th edition, John Wiley & Sons,

    Chichester, 2008.

    [2] B. H. Baltagi, J. M. Griffin, Short and long run effects in pooled models. International

    Economic Review 25(3) (1984) 631-645.

    [3] P. Egger, M. Pfaffermayr, Estimating long and short run effects in static panel models.

    Econometric Reviews 23(3) (2004) 199–214.

    [4] Z. Griliches, J. Mairesse, Productivity and R&D at the firm level. in Z. Griliches (ed.) R

    & D, Patents, and Productivity, University of Chicago Press, Chicago IL, 1987.

    [5] W. R. Hauk, R. Wacziarg, A Monte Carlo study of growth regressions, Stanford

    Graduate School of Business Research Paper No. 1836 (R1), 2006.

    [6] J. A. Hausman, Specification tests in econometrics, Econometrica 46 (1978) 1251-

    1271.

    [7] (2009) Hausman, Mismeasured variables in econometric analysis: problems from the

    right and problems from the left, Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(4) (2001) 57–67.

    [8] R. Hodrick, E. C. Prescott, Postwar U.S. business cycles: An empirical investigation,

    Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 29 (1997) 1-16.

    [9] Mairesse, J., Time-series and cross-sectional estimates on panel data: Why are they

    different and why should they be equal? in J. Hartog, G. Ridder, J.Theeuwes (eds.),

    Panel Data and Labor Market Studies, Contributions to Economic Analysis No. 192,

    North-Holland, Amsterdam, 1990.

    [10] R. Perman, D. I. Stern, Evidence from panel unit root and cointegration tests that the

  • 18

    environmental Kuznets curve does not exist, Australian Journal of Agricultural and

    Resource Economics 47 (2003) 325-347.

    [11] M. H. Pesaran, R. Smith, Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic

    heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics 68(1) (1995) 79-113.

    [12] A. Pirotte, Convergence of the static estimation toward the long run effects of dynamic

    panel data models. Economics Letters 63(2) (1999) 151-158.

    [13] D. I. Stern, M. S. Common, Is there an environmental Kuznets curve for sulfur? Journal

    of Environmental Economics and Management 41 (2001) 162-178.

    [14] D. I. Stern, The rise and fall of the environmental Kuznets curve, World Development

    32(8) (2004) 1419-1439.

    [15] D. I. Stern, Beyond the environmental Kuznets curve: Diffusion of sulfur-emissions-

    abating technology, Journal of Environment and Development 14(1) (2005) 101-124.

    [16] D. I. Stern, The effect of NAFTA on energy and environmental efficiency in Mexico,

    Policy Studies Journal 35(2) (2007) 291-322.

    [17] I. T. van Doel, J. F.. Kiviet, Asymptotic consequences of neglected dynamics in

    individual effects models. Statistica Neerlandica 48(1) (1994) 71 – 85.

    [18] H. R. J. Vollebergh, B. Melenberg, E. Dijkgraaf, Identifying reduced-form relations

    with panel data: The case of pollution and income, .Journal of Environmental

    Economics and Management 58 (2009) 27–42.

    [19] M. Wagner, The carbon Kuznets curve: A cloudy picture emitted by bad econometrics,

    Resource and Energy Economics 30 (2008) 388-408.

  • 19

    Table 1: Vollebergh et al. Sulfur Data

    Constant ln(GDP/P) ln(GDP/P)2 Time Trend

    R^2 (adjusted)

    Turning Point Elasticity

    OLS -141.208 32.977 -1.793 0.272 9809.335 -0.754

    (23.165) (5.198) (0.290) (573.342) (1.567)

    OLS with Time Trend -111.706 25.859 -1.371 -0.036 0.389 12417.886 0.069

    (24.955) (5.673) (0.321) (0.008) (1995.649) (1.198)

    First Differences 16.409 -0.888 0.021 10246.47 -0.296

    (2.191) (0.118) (675.251) (0.776)

    First Differences with Time Trend 14.557 -0.738 -0.048 0.078 19007.94 0.666

    (2.138) (0.116) (0.006) (3006.541) (0.645)

    Fixed Effects 32.939 -1.823 0.803 8351.104 -1.354

    (1.044) (0.056) (111.505) (1.594)

    Fixed Effects with Time Effects 28.011 -1.499 0.821 11407.293 -0.178

    (1.120) (0.062) (515.918) (1.310)

    Random Effects -138.418 32.976 -1.825 8372.405 -1.346 (4.832) (1.042) (0.056) (110.769) (1.595) Random Effects with Time Effects -122.461 28.754 -1.557 10213.833 -0.529

    (5.069) (1.105) (0.060) (346.063) (1.361)

    Between Estimates Quadratic -64.531 15.536 -0.808 0.068 14890.973 0.334

    (87.752) (19.211) (1.048) (9545.615) (0.706)

    Between Estimates Linear 3.037 0.732 0.086

    (3.870) (0.411)

    Standard errors are in parentheses. The mean value of the elasticity is given but the standard error is the regular standard deviation not the standard error of the mean.

  • 20

    Table 2: Vollebergh et al. Carbon Data

    Constant ln(GDP/P) ln(GDP/P)2 Time Trend

    R^2 (adjusted)

    Turning Point Elasticity

    OLS -59.231 13.403 -0.667 0.568 22949.923 0.853 (10.617) (2.369) (0.132) (5422.287) (0.583)

    OLS with Time Trend -42.335 9.326 -0.425 -0.021 0.633 57504.708 1.326 (12.995) (3.027) (0.175) (0.008) (56622.970) (0.371)

    First Differences 5.934 -0.28 0.188 39128.776 (0.852) (0.046) (9353.152) (0.245)

    First Differences with Time Trend 5.732 -0.264 -0.005 0.191 51334.001 0.763 (0.856) (0.046) (0.002) (16823.577) (0.230)

    Fixed Effects 13.799 -0.711 0.954 16278.272 0.421 (0.383) (0.020) (264.012) (0.621)

    Fixed Effects with Time Effects 13.943 -0.727 0.956 14425.861 0.255 (0.420) (0.023) (550.354) (0.636)

    Random Effects -59.095 13.806 -0.711 16297.252 0.423 (1.777) (0.382) (0.020) (264.263) (0.622) Random Effects with Time Effects -58.735 13.769 -0.711 15849.711 0.383 (1.875) (0.405) (0.022) (396.067) (0.622)

    Between Estimates Quadratic 1.74 -0.411 0.11 0.611 6.442 1.666 (55.161) (12.076) (0.659) (280.378) (0.096)

    Between Estimates Linear -7.497 1.612 0.628 (2.400) (0.255)

    Standard errors are in parentheses. The mean value of the elasticity is given but the standard error is the regular standard deviation not the standard error of the mean.

  • 21

    Table 3: Stern and Common Sulfur Data

    Constant ln(GDP/P) ln(GDP/P)2 Time Trend

    R^2 (adjusted)

    Turning Point Elasticity

    OLS -21.555 3.006 -0.118 0.348 331125 1.092 (11.128) (2.735) (0.166) (2114102) (0.228)

    OLS with Time Trend -20.69 2.749 -0.099 -0.016 0.354 938181 1.131 (11.190) (2.754) (0.167) (0.005) (8811351) (0.193)

    First Differences 2.357 -0.11 0.018 43496 0.571 (0.852) (0.054) (64100) (0.213)

    First Differences with Time Trend 2.305 -0.105 -0.002 0.018 53598 0.592 (0.861) (0.055) (0.006) (92130) (0.204)

    Fixed Effects 4.103 -0.206 0.899 20177 0.753 (0.438) (0.027) (5270) (0.400)

    Fixed Effects with Time Effects 3.709 -0.16 0.901 101165 1.104 (0.439) (0.027) (65409) (0.311)

    Random Effects -24.657 4.114 -0.206 21170 0.771 (1.757) (0.434) (0.026) (5612) (0.399) Random Effects with Time Effects -24.275 3.803 -0.174 54230 0.980 (1.756) (0.433) (0.026) (25922) (0.337)

    Between Estimates Quadratic -19.423 2.426 -0.079 0.361 4066974 1.136 (12.766) (3.242) (0.203) (75496413) (0.154)

    Between Estimates Linear -14.451 1.157 0.368 (1.436) (0.176)

    Standard errors are in parentheses. The mean value of the elasticity is given but the standard error is the regular standard deviation not the standard error of the mean.

  • 22

    Figure 1. Vollebergh et al. Sulfur Data

    6

    7

    8

    9

    10

    11

    12

    13

    7 7.5 8 8.5 9 9.5 10 10.5 11

    ln(GDP/P)

    lnSO2PBetweenOLSFEREFD

  • 23

    Figure 2. Vollebergh et al. Carbon Data

    4

    5

    6

    7

    8

    9

    10

    7 7.5 8 8.5 9 9.5 10 10.5 11

    ln(GDP/P)

    lnCO2PBetweenOLSFDFERE

  • 24

    Figure 3. Stern and Common Sulfur Data

    -16

    -14

    -12

    -10

    -8

    -6

    -4

    -2

    0

    5 5.5 6 6.5 7 7.5 8 8.5 9 9.5 10

    ln(GDP/P)

    lSO2PBetweenOLSFDFERE

  • 25

    Figure 4. Income and Time Effects: Between Estimator, Vollebergh et al. Sulfur Data

    -15000

    -10000

    -5000

    0

    5000

    10000

    15000

    20000

    25000

    30000

    35000

    40000

    45000

    50000

    1960

    1962

    1964

    1966

    1968

    1970

    1972

    1974

    1976

    1978

    1980

    1982

    1984

    1986

    1988

    1990

    1992

    1994

    1996

    1998

    2000

    Avera

    ge P

    er

    Cap

    ita S

    ulf

    ur

    Em

    issi

    on

    s

    Average Income EffectAverage Time EffectAverage Sulfur Emissions

  • 26

    Figure 5. Income and Time Effects: Between Estimator, Vollebergh et al. Carbon Data

    -2000

    -1000

    0

    1000

    2000

    3000

    4000

    5000

    6000

    1960

    1962

    1964

    1966

    1968

    1970

    1972

    1974

    1976

    1978

    1980

    1982

    1984

    1986

    1988

    1990

    1992

    1994

    1996

    1998

    2000

    Avera

    ge P

    er

    Cap

    ita C

    arb

    on

    Em

    issi

    on

    s

    Average Income EffectAverage Time EffectAverage Carbon Emissions

  • 27

    Figure 6. Sulfur Time Effects

    -4

    -3

    -2

    -1

    0

    1

    2

    3

    1960

    1961

    1962

    1963

    1964

    1965

    1966

    1967

    1968

    1969

    1970

    1971

    1972

    1973

    1974

    1975

    1976

    1977

    1978

    1979

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    AUSCANFRAGERITAJPNSPASWESWITURUKDUSA

  • 28

    Figure 7. Carbon Time Effects

    -1.5

    -1

    -0.5

    0

    0.5

    1

    1.51960

    1961

    1962

    1963

    1964

    1965

    1966

    1967

    1968

    1969

    1970

    1971

    1972

    1973

    1974

    1975

    1976

    1977

    1978

    1979

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1991

    1992

    1993

    1994

    1995

    1996

    1997

    1998

    1999

    2000

    AUSCANFRAGERITAJPNSPASWESWITURUKDUSA

    EERH34p7EERH RR 34