Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    1/22

    Journal of Consumer Culture

    2014, Vol. 14(1) 324

    ! The Author(s) 2013

    Reprints and permissions:

    sagepub.co.uk/journalsPermissions.navDOI: 10.1177/1469540513509641

    joc.sagepub.com

    Article

    Prosumption: Evolution,

    revolution, or eternalreturn of the same?

    George RitzerUniversity of Maryland

    Abstract

    Prosumption, the interrelated process of production and consumption, is increasinglyobvious everywhere, but especially on the internet where people prosume, for exam-ple, Facebook pages, Wikipedia entries, and Amazon.com orders. But what is prosump-tion? Has it evolved out of recent behaviors? Or, is it new and revolutionary? Or, is itwhat weve always done? In fact, it is all three. Beyond dealing with these questions andre-conceptualizing much of what we do as prosumption rather than as either produc-tion or consumption, we reflect on the future of prosumption, as well as on thecontinuing utility of traditional concepts, paradigms, theories and methods that werecreated to deal with epochs, phenomena and processes seemingly focused on produc-

    tion or consumption.

    Keywords

    Prosumption, consumption, production, digital, eternal return of the same

    It is now possible to begin to get a handle on the full extent of a series of extremely

    important and closely related changes in everyday life, especially involving the

    economy. Changes in production are often noted and there has even been increas-ing, but still inadequate, attention to changes in consumption. However, changes in

    prosumption, the interrelated process of production and consumption,1 indeed

    the phenomenon itself, have generally not been recognized, at least until recently.

    This is a revised version of a paper presented as the annual Robin M Williams, Jr Lecture at the Eastern

    Sociological Society meetings in Boston, MA on 21 March 2013. I would like to thank Chih-Chin Chen, PJ Rey,

    Nathan Jurgenson, and the students in my spring 2013 graduate seminar on consumption at the University of

    Maryland for their input into this paper. Reviewers, as well the editor of this journal, made many useful

    comments on earlier drafts of this paper.

    Corresponding author:

    George Ritzer, University of Maryland, Art-Sociology Bldg, College Park, MD 20742, United States

    301-405-6418.

    Email: [email protected]

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    2/22

    They are largely invisible not only to scholars, but also to the people most actively

    involved in, and affected by, them.

    There are several reasons for the near invisibility of prosumption. The social

    changes associated with prosumption are usually so mundane (e.g. bussing ones

    own debris at a fast food restaurant) that they hardly seem worthy of note to those

    involved. In addition, they are occurring in so many diverse economic and, more

    broadly, social worlds (airports, the internet, etc.) that it is difficult not only to see

    their connections to one another, but also that they are part of some larger set of

    changes. Because they have largely not been recognized by laypeople and scholars,

    the phenomenon and these changes have not been researched, theorized, or even

    conceptualized until relatively recently. Without a significant concept, or set of

    concepts, to describe them, scholars and, more importantly, laypeople have been

    unable to discern the commonalities or connections among the diverse changes andthe even more diverse phenomena undergoing these changes.

    Beginning in 1980, scholars did begin, albeit haltingly, to conceptualize these

    changes, but they soon created a series of very different concepts often dealing with

    only a part of the broader economic and social changes, as well as the phenomena

    involved in those changes. As the number of these concepts grew over the years,

    their quantity and diversity tended to prevent scholars and laypeople from under-

    standing what the various changes and empirical phenomena had in common.

    The first significant contribution to conceptualizing prosumption was made by

    Alvin Toffler (1980; Toffler and Toffler, 2006), a popular writer, a futurist, withouta base in an academic discipline. Because his ideas lacked legitimacy, at least to many

    in the academic world, Tofflers work did not have a great deal of impact on scholars.

    Toffler was on target in his work on prosumption, but he was, as a futurist, ahead of

    the curve, especially because the arena in which his ideas were most relevantthe

    internetwas still in its infancy. While his 1980 book, Third Wave, devoted much

    attention to prosumption, it was only a small part of his larger argument about the

    Third Wave and the dramatic social changes on the horizon. It was that over-

    arching argument that received most public attention and was the source of great

    controversy. Prosumption was largely lost in the broader issues and the controver-sies that surrounded it. The concept failed to gain much traction among either lay-

    people or scholars in spite of the expansion of phenomena that clearly involved

    prosumption. A major social change away from production and consumption and

    toward prosumption was not only under way but was soon to accelerate.

    In the wake of Tofflers work on prosumption, and only in part as a result of it,

    scholars in a number of different fields began to accord greater attention to the

    changes involved. In the process, they either used or created other concepts to deal

    with them. This eventually led to a set of similar concepts that, in turn, led, at least

    in part, to a failure to see what they had in common. Among them are such ideas asdo-it-yourself (DIY) (Watson and Shove, 2008); craft consumption (Campbell,

    2005); Pro-Ams (Leadbetter and Miller, 2004); co-creation (Prahalad and

    Ramaswamy, 2004a, 2004b); service-dominant logic (Vargo and Lusch, 2004,

    2008); commons-based peer production (Benkler, 2006; Benkler and

    4 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    3/22

    Nissenbaum, 2006); collaborative capitalism involving both value co-creation and

    service dominant logic (Cova, Dalli and Zwick, 2011); crowd- and open-sourcing

    (Howe, 2009); putting customers to work (Ritzer, 1993); wikinomics based at least

    in part on the idea that businesses put consumers to work on the internet (Tapscott

    and Williams, 2006); the complete collapse of consumption into production (Zwick

    and Knott, 2009); Laugheys (2010) productive consumption; and the produser

    (Bird, 2011; Bruns, 2005, 2008). In spite of this conceptual proliferation, it is

    prosumption that remains the most popular and useful concept for understanding

    the full range of the changing economic and social phenomena of concern here.

    Despite this growth in work on prosumption (and related ideas), it remains a

    niche concept that is largely unknown to most observers. A key factor in this

    invisibility is the fact that within the social and economic worlds, there are hege-

    monic conceptsproductionandconsumptionthat are so omnipresent and power-ful that they strongly bias and limit the ways in which scholars and laypeople look

    at those worlds and what they see in them. As a result, they are largely unable to see

    the prosumption that is rife throughout the economy and the social world.

    Nonetheless, the hegemony of the concepts of production and consumption even-

    tually led to the greater acceptance and popularity (compared to similar ideas listed

    above) of the concept of prosumption because it involves a fusion of the concepts

    ofproduction and consumption. However, given these largely economic roots, the

    concept of prosumption inhibits our ability to see and fully understand the

    broader, non-economic dimensions of that process (for example, how they applyto the media and media studies).

    Some deper theoretical background

    Scholars and laypeople have long had a productivist bias (Ritzer and Slater,

    2001) when examining the economy (for a recent example of this bias, but focused

    on the internet, see Scholz, 2013). As a result, they tended to concentrate on pro-

    duction and work at the expense of consumption and leisure (as well as play). The

    latter were seen, at least until the years following the end of World War Two, asbeing of only minor significance. Most of those who studied the economy rarely

    recognized and acknowledged the importance of consumption or looked at it in a

    positive light.2 Consumption (and even more leisure) was seen as at best trivial and

    at worst as a wasteful social practice (Veblen, 1899/1994). The focus on production

    was especially strong after the onset of the Industrial Revolution and the growth in

    significance of factories that produced various goods as well as being a workplace

    for those who produced in them. The capitalist economic system greatly valued

    factories and the productive work that took place in them and, at least in its early

    history, accorded comparatively little importance to consumption.The emphasis on production is found in the work of the classical social theorists,

    most notably Karl Marx (as well as Adam Smith). In the labor theory of value that

    lies at the heart of Marxs theory of capitalism, it is production (work, labor) that

    gives commodities their value. Consumption, especially the demand of

    Ritzer 5

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    4/22

    consumers, plays no role in the value of commodities which is determined by the

    labor involved in them. What mattered most to Marx was the productive work, the

    labor, of the proletariat (as well as the fact that they were not rewarded adequately,

    indeed were exploited, by the capitalist). Max Webers (19045/1958) emphasis on

    production is clearest in his best-known work,The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of

    Capitalism (as well as companion works on other major world religions and their

    relationship, largely as barriers, to the rise of capitalism outside the Occident). The

    focus is on the role of Protestantism (especially Calvinism) in the rise of the spirit

    of capitalism and ultimately of capitalism itself (and, more generally, a rationa-

    lized economy) in the West. Webers productivist bias is even clearer in his greatly

    underrated General Economic History (1927/1981) where Weber is mainly inter-

    ested in the development of the Occidents rational capitalistic economy, as well as

    the barriers to the development of such an economy elsewhere in the world.Durkheim was much more interested in collective beliefs and collective morality

    than he was in the economy. For example, he saw socialism as a movement aimed

    at the moral regeneration of society through scientific morality (Durkheim, 1928/

    1962). His most systematic thinking on the economy is found in the Division of

    Labor in Society (Durkheim, 1893/1964). His ultimate interest is clear when he

    argues that the economic services that it [the modern division of labor] can

    render are insignificant compared with the moral effect that it produces and its

    true function is to create between two or more people a feeling of solidarity

    (Durkheim, 1893/1964: 17). In mechanical solidarity people were held togetherby the fact that they generally performed the same tasks and had the same respon-

    sibilities, whereas in organic solidarity people needed one another because they

    performed different tasks and had different responsibilities. Mechanical solidarity

    was strong because people tended to share a strong collective conscience, whereas

    the bonds were reduced in organic solidarity because of a weaker collective con-

    science. In terms of the economy, the focus was clearly on what people did (their

    work) and not on their role as consumers. Similarly, in terms of his proposals for

    dealing with the weakness of the collective conscience in organic solidarity,

    Durkheim (1893/1964: 5) proposed the occupational association, or an organiza-tion that would encompass all the agents of the same industry united and orga-

    nized into a single group. Rosalind Williams (1982) sees Durkheims focus on the

    occupational association as emblematic of the reign of the producer in his work.

    Of all of the classical theorists, Thorstein Veblen (1899/1994) is the best known

    for his work on consumption, especially the famous concept of conspicuous con-

    sumption. However, this work occupies a unique place in Veblens oeuvre which

    otherwise is almost completely devoted to production-related matters. Veblens pri-

    oritization of production begins with his assumptions about human nature, espe-

    cially the instinct for workmanship. This instinct is concerned with practicalexpedients, ways and means, devices and contrivances of efficiency and economy,

    proficiency, creative work and technological mastery of facts. . . a proclivity for

    taking pains (Veblen, 1914/1964:33). The instinct of workmanship is manifest in

    both the technical efficiency of the individual worker and in the technological

    6 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    5/22

    proficiency and accomplishments of the community as a whole (the industrial

    arts). The bulk of Veblens work is devoted to the conflict between what he calls

    business and industry. Those involved in industry seek to become ever more

    efficient, but they tend to be thwarted by those oriented to business and their interest

    in money, including large profits and low costs, rather than in efficiency and work-

    manship. Thus, business leaders often seek to keep production low (to inhibit, even

    to sabotage, those associated with industry) in order to keep profits high.

    This productive bias among social theorists and sociologists was not restricted to

    the economy; there was a tendency to privilege production over consumption in

    other spheres of the social world, as well. In the family, for example, the productive

    contributions, especially of men in the labor force, were accorded prime significance.

    Even before women entered the labor force in great numbers, the cult of domes-

    ticity led to a focus on the domestic work that women did in and for the family(Welter, 1966). This work, as well as their consumption functions within the family,

    was seen as of secondary significance to what men did, especially in the labor force.

    The classical thinkers inherited and lived and worked in a world in which the

    whole idea of a consumer was either non-existent or largely undeveloped. In an

    exhaustive historical genealogy of the idea of the consumer, Frank Trentman

    (2006: 23; italics added) says,

    The consumer was virtually absent from eighteenth-century discourse. Significantly, it

    only appears in seven of the 150,000 works of the eighteenth-century collections on line. . .Even after the French Revolution, when deputies in Restoration France considered

    consumers interests, it was only to render them insignificant compared to peoples

    social station and larger national interests represented by land, production and trade.

    In the early 19th century there was only limited use of the idea of the consumer,

    often to refer to physical or metaphysical processes of use, waste and destruction

    (Trentmann, 2006: 26). It was not until the 1890s that the intellectual pursuit of

    the consumer took off (Trentmann, 2006: 29). All of this is to say that the classical

    theorists were working in a context in which the whole idea of a consumer was un-,or at least under-, developed. Thus, not only were they drawn to the revolutions in

    production taking place around them, but they lacked a strong sense of the con-

    sumer to counter-balance the inclination to emphasize production. However, that

    is not to say that the classical thinkers were unaware of consumption.

    Marx was well aware that, for example, the consumption of various things (e.g.

    the raw materials, tools and machinery that allow labor power to function in the

    production process) was needed in order for production to occur (productive

    consumption). It could be argued that use value is all about consumption (to

    be produced, a commodity must be a use value; a commodity will be consumedonly if it is useful). Furthermore the C-M-C (Money-Commodity-Money) circuit is

    focally concerned with the exchange of commodities to be consumed (versus the

    M-C-M [Money-Commodity-Money]) circuit which is more concerned with the

    profit dynamic in capitalism that feeds continual and expanding production).

    Ritzer 7

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    6/22

    To the degree that there was a concern for consumption in Webers work on the

    Protestant Ethic, it was ultimately on the propensity of the Protestants to value

    frugality; to consume as little as possible. One of the major limitations of Webers

    argument on this was clarified by Colin Campbell (1987) who demonstrated that

    Weber did not take his argument far enough historically. Over time, the Protestant

    Ethic also gave birth to a consumerist ethic to parallel the early capitalist (produc-

    tivist) ethic.

    Williams (1982) interprets Durkheims moral crisis as one that involves the

    consumer, but she argues that his response to that crisis is to focus on the realm

    of the producer (and the role of occupational associations in resolving that crisis).

    Even in his later work, Durkheim turns to religion, especially the morality of reli-

    gion and its asceticism, as at least a constraint on consumption.

    Simmel is best-known for his micro-sociological work on forms of interactionand types of interactants, but he dealt with the economy in at least some of that

    work. His best-known work in this area, The Philosophy of Money (Simmel, 1907/

    1978), dealt with capitalism and the problems created by a money economy (e.g.

    cynicism, a blase attitude, increasing impersonality). Interestingly, this work, while

    far from silent on the issue of production (the development of a rational market),

    had much more to do with consumption.

    As the title suggests, Simmel is concerned with the money economy including

    many of the distortions associated with it. For example, the rapid circulation of

    money induces people to spend and in the process to acquire goods and to utilize arange of paid services. While money in general grows increasingly important, a

    specific quantity of money, especially if it seems to be a small amount, becomes

    more insignificant. As a result, it becomes increasingly easy to spend. Money, espe-

    cially in contrast to predecessors such as barter, leads people into what Simmel calls

    a temptation to imprudence. That can mean spending more money than one

    should (overspending) and going into debt in order to be able to consume at a

    desired level. While it was rather difficult to acquire debt in Simmels time, it has

    clearly become far easier today with, for example, credit cards (Ritzer, 1995, 2012;

    Manning, 2001; Marron, 2009) and other forms of easy credit. As a result, Simmelcan be seen as anticipating the debt and consumer orgies that precipitated the

    Great Recession that began in 2008, as well as its lingering effects.

    Many other aspects of Simmels work, especially his numerous essays, deal

    either directly or indirectly with consumption. His essay on fashion (Simmel,

    1904/1971) attunes us to the greater consumption associated with constant changes

    in what is in (or out of) fashion. More generally, his overarching thinking on

    objective culture (Simmel, 1921/1968) relates to consumption in various ways.

    For one thing, the need to consume becomes part of the objective culture which

    pushes individuals in the direction of ever more consumption. For another, as partof objective culture, the pressure to consume grows increasingly distant from

    people and much more difficult to control. In fact, it is increasingly likely to control

    people and to lead them in the direction of hyper-consumption. Werner Sombart

    (1913/1967) devoted far more attention to consumption than his peers (except,

    8 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    7/22

    perhaps, for Veblen), especially in Luxury and Capitalism. There he reversed the

    usual argument and contended that it was the consumption of luxury goods that

    played a central role in the rise of capitalism. In spite of these exceptions, the classic

    theorists lacked a strong sense of consumption. This had many consequences, but

    the most important effect from the perspective of this essay is that without a sense

    of consumption to complement their focus on production, there was no way that

    the classical theorists could have developed the idea of prosumption.

    Overall, production has been a hegemonic concept since the Industrial

    Revolution. It retains that position to this day even though industry has declined

    in importance in much of the developed world, especially the United States, as has

    the manual work and production associated with it. Work, more generally, is itself

    less central with the rise in importance of consumption that more-or-less coincided

    with the decline of factories and the work associated with them. In spite of thesechanges, production (and the factory) remains important and retains its hold on

    popular and scholarly imagination; we continue to operate with a productivist bias.

    Since World War Two, consumption has grown in economic importance and, as a

    result, it has increasingly taken its place beside production as a hegemonic concept.

    With consumption now accounting for 70%, or more, of the American economy, it is

    natural for it to occupy a place beside production in thinking about the economy, as

    well as other sectors of the social world such as the family. Given the change, some

    social theorists began to shift from a productivist to a consumerist bias (e.g.

    Galbraith, 1958). The work of Jean Baudrillard, especially his Consumer Society(1970/1998), is particularly pivotal in this shift in focus. Interestingly, in spite of

    the title, Baudrillard continued to privilege production over consumption.

    Nevertheless, the key point from the perspective of this essay lies in the title of

    Baudrillards book heralding a shift in the 20th century from a society dominated

    by production to consumer society. Baudrillard argues that capitalists came to rec-

    ognize that the 19th century emphasis on regulating workers was no longer sufficient.

    In the 20th century the view emerged that consumers could no longer be allowed to

    decide whether or not to consume or how much or what to consume (Bauman, 1992

    takes a similar position). In many ways, a mirror image of the theories of the classicaltheorists emerged. While the latter focused almost exclusively on production (or

    separated their analysis of production and consumption into different works

    [Veblen, Sombart]), a number of theorists and empiricists in the late 20th century

    came to focus almost exclusively on consumption. Indeed, a distinct area of consumer

    or consumption studies emerged in several fields (e.g. anthropology, sociology, mar-

    keting), as did journals (e.g. Journal of Consumer Culture; Journal of Consumer

    Research) devoted to the study of consumption.3 A new section of the American

    Sociological Association, Consumers and Consumption, was launched in 2013.

    This was related to the view that had emerged in the wake of the work ofBaudrillard and others that we had moved, or were moving, from a modern to

    postmodern society. Among the things that were associated with the modern world

    was production, but the postmodern world came to be linked to consumption

    (Ritzer, Goodman, and Wiedenhoft, 2001). Thus, for example, Bauman argued

    Ritzer 9

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    8/22

    that the society of concern to classical theorists such as Marx was work-based.

    It was one in which its members were engaged primarily as producers. In

    contrast, a later-modern, or second-modern or post-modern stage. . . engages its

    membersagain primarilyin their capacity as consumers (Bauman, 1998: 24).

    More extremely, Bauman discusses the passage from producer to consumer soci-

    ety (Bauman, 1998: 24). Indeed, the ascendancy of consumer culture was seen as

    one of the hallmarks of the postmodern world (see Featherstones [1991]Consumer

    Culture and Postmodernism).

    The key point is that in the last several decades the two concepts of production

    and consumption have so dominated our thinking that they have prevented us

    from thinking in other ways about what transpires in the economic and social

    worlds. Furthermore, thinking in such binary terms, indeed thinking in modern

    binary terms in general, tends to distort our conceptions of the world. Specifically,the production-consumption binary prevents us from seeing the consumption (e.g.

    of raw materials, tools, labor time) that is inherent in production andthe produc-

    tion that is intertwined with consumption (for example, the work [e.g. shopping]

    involved in much consumption; the creation of the meaning of brands; producing

    an order on Amazon.com; creating a response after reading a blog, etc.). In other

    words, we are prevented from seeing the prosumption involved in what is conven-

    tionally thought of as distinct processes of production and consumption.

    Furthermore, the hegemonic status of the concepts of production and consump-

    tion has rendered us unable to see that prosumption, not production or consump-tion, is the primal (and still predominant) process (Ritzer, 2010a). That is, early

    humans consumed as they produced and produced as they consumed. More

    importantly, the hegemony of production and consumption has prevented us

    from seeing that we are in the midst of a largely unrecognized social change invol-

    ving a massive expansion in, and the development of dramatic new forms of,

    prosumption (Ritzer and Jurgenson, 2010; Ritzer, Jurgenson and Dean, 2012).

    Rethinking production and consumption in light of

    prosumption

    Figure 1 offers a perspective on prosumption not as a single process (or phenom-

    enon), but rather as a wide range of processes existing along a continuum. The

    poles of the continuum involve production redefined (a bit awkwardly, but more

    accurately) as prosumption-as-production (p-a-p) and consumption as

    prosumption-as-consumption (p-a-c). This means, among other things, that pro-

    duction and consumption, at least in their pure forms devoid of prosumption, do

    not exist on this continuum. There is no such thing as either pure production (with-

    out at least some consumption) or pure consumption (without at least some produc-tion); the two processes always interpenetrate. In the middle of the prosumption

    continuum production (-as-consumption) and consumption (-as-production) are

    more or less evenly balanced; it is there where something approaching balanced

    prosumption exists (see Figure 1).

    10 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    9/22

    The prosumption continuum

    Sociologists, social theorists and other students of society should have always

    focused on prosumption. At best, production and consumption should have

    been treated as special limiting cases, as ideal types (Weber, 1903/1917/1949:

    90), that do not exist in the real world economy, but may be useful in helping us

    to analyze the economic world. However, even that accords production and con-sumption too much importance since from the point of view of this discussion they

    are merely types, albeit extreme types, of prosumption. In other words, production

    and consumption are sub-types of prosumption; it is prosumption that is the more

    general process that subsumes the other two.

    A number of students of the internet (in many ways the contemporary home

    of prosumption) have come close to understanding the nature of prosumption and

    its relationship to production and consumption. For example, Howe (2009: 71)

    contends: Once upon a time there were producers and consumers. . . the con-

    sumer, as traditionally conceived, is becoming an antiquated concept.Interestingly, undoubtedly because of a lingering productivist bias, Howe is

    unable to see that the concept of the producer has also become outdated.

    Similarly, Clay Shirky (www.shirky.com/writings/consumer/html) argues that

    the consumer is the Internets most recent casualty and that we are all produ-

    cers now. While Shirky is on the right track, we once again see the productivist

    bias at work here. He is able to dismiss the concept of consumption on the internet,

    but he remains in the thrall of the idea of production there (and presumably

    elsewhere).

    Viewed from todays vantage point, and armed with the concept of prosumption(and the continuum), we can now see that concepts true utility and significance as

    well as the many phenomena well-described by it. A number of examples of these

    phenomena are discussed below. We begin with examples from the material world

    and then turn to digital, as well as mixed material and digital, examples. The

    examples to be discussed below all lie toward the middle of the continuum in

    Figure 1; they are more balanced forms of prosumption. However, it is also the

    case that examples that lie at or near the extreme ends of the continuum exist. That

    is, processes approaching what we have traditionally thought of as production

    and consumption continue to have a role in the social world. For example, at theproduction end of the continuum we can still find the traditional factory worker

    (although better thought of as a prosumer-as-producer), while a consumer in an

    elite boutique staffed by many salespeople is a traditional shopper (although even

    in this case more of a prosumer-as-consumer).

    Prosumption-as-ProductionBalanced ProsumptionProsumption-as-Consumption

    Figure 1. The Prosumption Continuum.

    Ritzer 11

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    10/22

    It is important to make clear that the distinction between the material and the

    digital is made for discussion purposes only; the material and digital worlds increas-

    ingly interpenetrate. That is, we must avoid operating with a dualistic sense of the

    material and the digital worlds. Rather we should think in terms of augmented

    reality in which the digital and material worlds complement one another

    (Jurgenson, 2012). Acts of material prosumption such as cashing a check or check-

    ing a bank balance are more likely to occur on a computer or a mobile device and

    are thereby increasingly digital. Similarly, those actions involving immaterial pro-

    sumption such as creating a digital design on ones computer are increasingly likely

    to be materialized by 3-D printers (Anderson, 2012).

    Among the (mainly) material examples of (balanced) prosumption are lining up

    in cafeterias and more recently fast food restaurants to collect ones food and

    afterwards disposing of ones own leftovers; fetching ones own food purchasesand using self-checkout systems at super-and hyper-markets; building, really just

    putting together (although it is not as easy as it looks and products are often

    considered impossible-to-assemble) IKEA furniture (with the help of a sheet

    of instructions and maybe a small tool or two); buying and using on ones own

    medical technologies such as blood pressure and glucose monitors, as well as tests

    for PSA and cholesterol levels, pregnancy, male fertility, drug, tobacco and alcohol

    use, and HIV; and using smart phones to photograph and video dramatic events

    (e.g. the damage on Americas east coast caused by Hurricane Sandy in late 2012)

    and then sending the photos and videos to TV networks (like CNN) and localstations that show them on air almost immediately.

    Then there are such (mainly) digital examples as increasingly making all-but-the-

    most-complex travel arrangements on ones own through various websites (e.g.

    Travelocity, Expedia); doing all of the work on websites such as Amazon.com

    including making the appropriate choices for items to be purchased, providing

    needed delivery and payment information, and making ones way through the

    various steps needed to complete the process; as buyers doing the largely digital

    work of providing a body of information on themselves to eBay and if (when) they

    are sellers on that which they are offering for sale; diagnosing oneself (or at leastbelieving one is capable of self-diagnosis) as a result of the proliferation of infor-

    mation on the internet on every conceivable disease and the associated symptomol-

    ogies; co-creating and crowd-sourcing (producing) open-source software (e.g.

    Firefox, Linux) online and then downloading and using (consuming) it; producing

    and consuming most of what is found on the billion Facebook pages; contributing

    to and using Wikipedia; and writing and reading blogs.

    Although the material and the digital forms of prosumption always interpene-

    trate, the following examples more clearly demonstrate that interpenetration

    including producing the rental of a Zipcar online (with the help of various tech-nologies, of course) and then driving the car; producing the listings on Freecycles

    website and, along with the person receiving the object, taking the various digital

    12 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    11/22

    and material steps needed to transfer the object from giver to receiver; searching

    out and renting lodgings on Airbnb and eventually occupying the rented spaces in

    the homes of people in the locales to which one is traveling; tele-teaching and

    internet-based education on Massive Open Online Courses (MOOCs) where

    much of the burden of education is put on the students themselves (e.g. having

    students grade each others exams, even essay exams).

    Given the massive number and array of examples of prosumptionand the

    enumeration above only scratches the surface of the full range of this ever-expand-

    ing phenomenonthe topic to be addressed in the remainder of this paper is

    whether prosumption constitutes a revolutionary new development or whether it

    is consistent with earlier, even primal, forms of prosumption. Obviously, many of

    the examples iterated above rely on new and advanced technology (especially the

    computer and the internet), but the major issue is whether the basic actionsinvolvedthose that combine production and consumptionconstitute something

    new, even revolutionary.

    A revolutionary development

    The view that a revolutionary change is under way involves the idea that while we

    have always been prosumers, we are now witnessing the emergence of the new

    prosumer associated with, among others, the following realities. First, prosumers

    are performing tasks (e.g. checking themselves in and out of hotels and at airportkiosks) that they rarely, if ever, did before. Second, many people are no longer

    employed, or they are doing different kinds of work, because of the various things

    prosumers are now doing themselves without pay. Third, many companies are

    earning unprecedented profits because they are able to employ far fewer people

    than they would have if prosumers did not perform various tasks without pay.

    Fourth, people now get lots of things free of charge, especially on the internet, in

    part because of the free labor of prosumers (Anderson, 2010). Fifth, many of these

    developments have been made possible by new technologiesthe computer, inter-

    net, self-scanners, 3-D printersand they are leading to further technologicaladvances that will, among other things, further expand prosumption.

    The new prosumer has been made possible, and is defined, by the emergence of

    the new means of prosumption. This idea is derived from Marxs famous concept

    of the means of production and his less well-known idea of the means of consump-

    tion. Interestingly, Marxs (1884/1981: 471) definition of the means of

    productioncommodities that possess a form in which they. . . enter productive

    consumptionmakes it clear that he is aware, at least implicitly, of the process of

    prosumption. Since it combines production and consumption, the idea of product-

    ive consumption is obviously one way of thinking about prosumption, albeit onethat prioritizes production over consumption. Among the means of production for

    Marx are labor-time, tools, machines, and the factories in which they exist; that

    Ritzer 13

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    12/22

    which is used and used up in the process of production. The means of production

    are, in Marxs terms, then the means that make possible. . . the production of

    commodities (Ritzer, 2010: 50b).

    Marx (1884/1981: 471) also develops the idea of the means of consumption, but

    he defines it in a way that is at variance with his definition of the means of pro-

    duction. That is, they are defined as commodities that possess a form in which

    they enter individual consumption of the capitalist and working class (Marx,

    1884/1981: 471). Marx associates the luxury means of consumption with the

    consumption of capitalists and the necessary means of consumption with that

    of the working class. Basic foodstuffs would be necessary means of consumption

    while expensive automobiles such as Maseratis would be examples of luxury means

    of consumption.

    However, there are logical problems in the way Marx uses the concept of themeans of consumption, especially in comparison to the paired notion of means of

    production. The means of production occupy an intermediate position between

    workers and products; they are the means that make possible both the production

    of commodities and the control and exploitation of the workers. In contrast, the

    way Marx uses the idea, the means of consumption are not means but rather the end

    products in his model of consumption; they are those things (either subsistence or

    luxury) that are consumed. In other words, there is no distinction in Marxs work

    between consumer goods and what are seen here as the means of consumption (fast

    food restaurants, supermarkets, Amazon.com).4

    To put it another way, in Marxswork there is no parallel in the realm of consumption to the mediating and expedit-

    ing role played by the means of production. Here, the means of consumption are

    clearly distinguished from that which is being consumed. The means of consump-

    tion play the same mediating role in consumption that the means of production play

    in Marxs theory of production. Just as the means of production are those structures

    that allow the proletariat to produce, the means of consumption are the structures

    that make it possible for people to acquire goods and services. Thus, the means of

    consumptionshould be defined (assuming we are going to do something we no longer

    should do and clearly differentiate between production and consumption), in par-allel with the definition of the means of production, as those means that make it

    possible for people to acquire goods and services (Ritzer, 2010: 50b).

    In the 19th century, consumption was a very cumbersome and time-consuming

    process involving, for example, long and slow treks to and from such means of

    consumption as specialized shops (e.g. butcher shops, grocers). Today, consump-

    tion is infinitely easier and consumption time is greatly reduced because of the

    development of such newer means of consumption as supermarkets and online

    shop-at-home services (e.g. Peapod).

    Given our interest in the prosumer, we also need the concept of the means ofprosumption, or those means that make it possible for people to prosume goods and

    services. In terms of the continuum depicted in Figure 1, IKEA leads prosumers to

    produce their own bookcases at home (prosumption-as-production), MOOCs

    lead students to consume college-level courses, and perhaps degrees, on their own

    14 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    13/22

    computers (prosumption-as-consumption), and ATMs lead to both doing the

    work involved in a bank withdrawal and obtaining and using the needed cash

    (balanced prosumption).5 Thus, IKEA, MOOCS, and ATMs are means of pro-

    sumption; they allow, even force, people to be prosumers. Since prosumption is

    such a desirable process from the capitalist point of view (fewer paid workers and

    more unpaid prosumers), we can expect the creation of an increasing number of

    new means of prosumption in the future. Both the means of production and the

    means of consumption are, in a sense, means of prosumption because production

    and consumption have been redefined in this essay as prosumption-as-production

    and prosumption-as-consumption. In another sense, if we treat them as binaries,

    we could say that both the means of production and the means of consumption are

    imploding into one another, especially on the internet, producing the means of

    prosumption. Also imploding into the means of prosumption are the actions weactually take on them. It is increasingly difficult to tell when we are producing,

    consuming or prosuming (assuming we can even make those distinctions) on these

    new means of prosumption. Those distinctions cease to have meaning when we are,

    for example, blogging.

    The new prosumer relates to many older means of prosumption such as the

    home workshop in which the DIY-er and the craft consumer are found.

    However, what especially interests us here are the new means of prosumption that

    are not only making the new prosumer possible, but are both expanding and

    revolutionizing the process of prosumption. Many new means of prosumptionare found in the material world (e.g. self-checkout systems, digital kiosks and 3-

    D printers), but they are especially important in the digital world (Amazon.com,

    Facebook, Wikipedia).

    The eternal return, or recurrence, of the prosumer

    While it is possible to think in terms of a series of revolutionary changes giving

    birth to the new prosumer, it is also possible to see the new prosumer as continuous

    with earlier, even primal, prosumers. Production and consumption were not clearlydistinct processes. Rather, people prosumed, that is they produced as they con-

    sumed and they consumed as they produced, or at least the processes were closely

    associated in form and temporally. Bruns (2008: 326), who focuses on the media,

    argues that prosumption,6 including that which takes place today on social net-

    working sites such as Facebook, is consistent with the social processes of prein-

    dustrial communities. Vargo and Lusch (2004: 12) operate from a marketing

    perspective in their discussion of service-oriented logic, one of the alternatives to

    the concept of prosumption (see above). They argue that that process harks back

    to pre-Industrial Revolution days. They cite Hauser and Clausing (1988) whooffer the following example of this:

    Marketing, engineering and manufacturing were integrated in the same individual. If a

    knight wanted armor, he talked directly to the armorer, who translated the knights

    Ritzer 15

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    14/22

    desires into a product, the two might discuss the materialplate rather than chain

    armorand details like fluted service or greater bending strength. Then the armorer

    would design the production process (cited in Vargo and Lusch, 2004: 12)

    In this case, the knight is directly involved in prosuming the armor in commu-

    nicating his desires about the material used, design elements, and the flexibility of the

    armor (modern prosumers increasingly do this with, for example, clothing designers).

    However, the knight lies more toward the prosumption-as-consumption end of the

    prosumption continuum because physical production remains in the hands of the

    armorer. In most other pre-industrial, especially primal, instances, the consumers are

    involved in much more than preliminary deliberations about the end-product; they

    are actually involved in the physical production of what they consume.

    Ballantyne and Varey (2008) make this clear in their discussion of the fact thatservice-dominant logic has much in common with the realities of pre-industrial

    society. The key is that in that epoch people were most often not simply involved

    in preliminary deliberations, but were involved in production for their own imme-

    diate use. In the absence of any large-scale production, people provided for the

    needs of their own families and communities. At this point in time, production and

    consumption were highly integrated, but this ended with the Industrial Revolution

    which, as Toffler (1980) pointed out, served to separate production and consump-

    tion (or at least seemed to). This involved a shift from personal value-in-use in pre-

    industrial society to market-based value-in-exchange in industrial society.Marketers have long operated with a value-in-exchange perspective, but when

    they shift to value-in-use it becomes clear that they are dealing with prosumers

    and that it is the latter who produce value. From this point of view, the role of

    producer or supplier involves supporting the value-creating process of the pro-

    sumer throughout the entirety of the production-consumption process. More gen-

    erally, this process involves (re-)connecting the processes of production and

    consumption seemingly severed in the Industrial Revolution.

    Ballantyne and Varey argue that a variety of recent changes have made it even

    clearer that production and consumption are tightly integrated and cannot beneatly distinguished from one another. Among these are the integration and re-

    integration of distribution channels, the emergence of collaborative global supply

    chains, as well as the increasing understanding that production and consumption,

    as well as procurement and distribution, are no longer separable aspects in a supply

    chain.

    All of this supports the view that prosumers and the process of prosumption are

    not new phenomena; indeed they are primal roles and processes that have taken on

    new and perhaps greater importance in the contemporary age, especially one

    increasingly dominated by the internet. This view stands in stark opposition tothe previously discussed idea that contemporary prosumption represents a revolu-

    tionary new development.

    The thinking of Friedrich Nietzsche and Walter Benjamin is helpful in con-

    ceptualizing prosumption in this way. Nietzsches ideas are highly abstract and

    16 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    15/22

    philosophical, but Benjamin has done the heavy lifting for us by being more

    concrete and sociological. He draws on Nietzsche (1999: 337) and applies his

    key concept of eternal return [or eternal recurrence] of the same (1999: 71)

    to the social world. This means, of course, that Benjamin (1999: 298) is critical

    of the concept of progress, especially of revolutionary progress. Therefore, he

    is implicitly critical of the idea that prosumption is a revolutionary (or evolu-

    tionary) development. That is, what appears to be revolutionary is from this

    perspective simply the return of some past reality. Thinking about eternal

    return is consistent with Benjamins roots in Marxian theory, especially dialectical

    thinking. In fact, Benjamin (1999: 357) sees dialectics as an example of eternal

    recurrence. Thus, thesis always returns in the wake of antithesis and syn-

    thesis.7 Theories of evolution and progress are not dialectical, but a theory of

    eternal return is certainly dialectical. Some of the clearest examples of eternalreturn exist, most generally, in the eternal cycle of nature and more specifically

    in the changes in weather (1999: 102) and the stars (1999: 116; 340). In the social

    world, Benjamin (1999: 464) argues that what has been within a particular

    epoch is always, simultaneously, what has been from time immemorial. For

    example, Benjamin (1999: 544) defines the modern as the new in the context

    of what has already been there. More specifically, he discusses the creation of

    the newest out of the oldest and sees it as the true dialectical theater of fashion

    (1999: 64). There is nothing new in fashion and, perhaps, everywhere else in the

    social world. In the realm of production, Benjamin (1999: 331) discusses theeternal return of the same as manifest in mass productions. In consumption,

    the arcade, an early means of consumption, involves eternal return in various

    ways, especially since it resembles earlier means of consumption such as bazaars

    and souks. Most generally, Benjamin (1999: 463) sees the whole of primal his-

    tory group[ing] itself anew in images appropriate to that [the 19th] century.

    Perhaps the phrase of Benjamins (1999: 116) that best fits with the approach

    to prosumption taken in this section is the following: primal history enters the

    scene in ultramodern get-up. In terms of our interest, the prosumption that

    predominated primordially, as well as at all times throughout history, has re-entered the scene today in various ways, especially in ultramodern forms on

    the internet and smart phones. Of course, in discussing the new, ultramodern

    forms Benjamin is acknowledging that what is returning is far from exactly the

    same as that which existed in the past. Benjamin here is taking a position that is

    consistent with Deleuzes (1986) emphasis on difference in eternal return.

    It may still be prosumption, but its ultramodern guise (e.g. on the internet;

    with 3-D printers) makes it different in various ways.

    An evolutionary view of prosumptionThe third perspective on prosumption is that it is not a revolutionary development,

    or an instance of the eternal return of the same, but rather that it is continuous with

    a number of recent developments which are, in turn, continuous with their

    Ritzer 17

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    16/22

    predecessors. For example, an internet shopping mall (but not the internet itself)

    such as Amazon.com can be seen as continuous with, and a logical development

    from, shopping malls. The latter, in turn, evolved from earlier prosumption sites,

    including arcades. Fast-food restaurants, as well as the food courts based, among

    other places, in shopping malls, are clearly derived, at least in part, from cafeterias.

    Going back much further in time, ancient food stalls by the sides of roads are other,

    much earlier, forerunners of fast food restaurants. More generally, many of the

    phenomena associated with contemporary prosumption are not new, although the

    role of prosumption in them has increased greatly in recent years. For example,

    people have always, or at least for quite some time, made their own travel arrange-

    ments; engaged in self-diagnosis and helped themselves medically; reviewed, at least

    informally, products and work performed by others; participated in auctions

    (Smith, 1990) not that different from eBay; and participated actively in their owneducation. Thus, from this perspective, prosumption is not a new process and its

    current manifestations are not inconsistent with past processes.

    Conclusion

    This discussion has highlighted a number of recent social changes broadly grouped

    under the heading of prosumption. The main issue is whether these changes are an

    example of the eternal return of the same, a revolutionary new development, or are

    continuous with earlier developments. The central conclusion of this paper is thatthey can be associated with all three processes.

    Many of these changes are consistent with earlier developments. To take an

    example not dealt with previously, the work that consumers do on Amazon.com

    is not dissimilar from that done by those who ordered products from the Sears

    catalogue in the late 19th century and well into the 20th century. While, as in this

    example, there is some continuity between present and past phenomena, there is

    much greater discontinuity. That is, a number of revolutionary changes havetaken

    place in the realm of prosumption. Many of those revolutionary changes involve

    the internet, itself an extraordinarily revolutionary development. Much of todaysprosumption takes place on the internet and would not be possible without that

    technology, as well as others such as the smart phone, the credit card and the

    express package delivery systems. New and emerging technologies will both

    increase and alter the nature of prosumption. The emergence and growing signifi-

    cance of those 3D printers will allow makers to produce an increasing array of

    products at home (Anderson, 2012).

    While there are both evolutionary and revolutionary changes in the realm of

    prosumption, perhaps the most interesting conclusion to be derived from this dis-

    cussion involves the eternal return of the same. We were all prosumers before therewas a distinction between producers and consumers; prosumption is our primal

    condition. Ironically, the major technological changes discussed here are making it

    clear that we are more like our ancestors than we imagine. That fact has been lost

    sight of in the last few centuries as we differentiated between, and thought of

    18 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    17/22

    ourselves as either, producers or consumers. However, we were prosumers then and

    we are clearly prosumers now. What seems so new and revolutionary today is little

    more than another stage in the eternal return of the prosumer who predominated at

    the earliest points in human history and, in fact, was predominant in the epochs

    that appeared to be defined by either producers or consumers. Thus prosumption

    is, simultaneously, something that is primal, ancient, recent, new, and even revo-

    lutionary. While we have devoted some attention to its historical roots and simila-

    rities, it is its new and revolutionary character that is likely to be increasingly

    important in the future. This is likely to be true not only on the internet, but

    also in the material world, as well as in the increasing interpenetration of the

    two. These changes are likely to become increasingly dramatic leading not only

    to more and more prosumption, but also to altered, even dramatically new, forms

    of prosumption. Thus, prosumption in the future will be radically different(increasingly high-tech), yet it will still, and always, be consistent with the primal

    state (decidedly low-tech), and recent history, of prosumption.

    However, there is something that will be radically different. We will not be

    returning to an era in which we think of clear differences between producers and

    consumers. In that sense, we are not returning to thinking in terms of the eras of

    the Industrial and the Consumer Revolutions (Cohen, 2003). We will increasingly

    be in the era of the prosumer revolution (or is it devolution?) where we will find it

    increasingly difficult to differentiate between production and consumption; between

    producers and consumers.Given this, what can we say about the future of prosumption? For one thing,

    fewer and fewer activities will exist near the (prosumption-as-) production and

    (prosumption-as-) consumption ends of the prosumption continuum. Those activ-

    ities will move more toward the middle of the continuum. That is, they will more

    clearly be examples of balanced prosumption. They will even more clearlynot be

    definable as anything approaching pure production or consumption. For

    another, while this will be true throughout the social and economic world, it will

    more clearly be the case in some realms rather than others. For example, we will see

    a continuation of the trend toward doing things ourselves rather than having paidemployees perform those tasks in the service sector of the economy. The immater-

    ial, especially the digital, worlds will be increasingly characterized by prosumption

    since it is very easy there to transfer immaterial tasks from those we think of as

    producers to those who are more clearly prosumers. While the digital world is the

    natural domain for this change, it will also occur in the more material world where,

    for example, patients will do more and more medical work.

    There will certainly be a continuation of processes in the material world that we

    have historically thought of as (pure) production (e.g. automobile manufactur-

    ing), although they will be increasingly found in less developed countries. However,a counter-trend of some importance is the fact that traditional production may

    increasingly be handled by advanced technologies in the developed world rather

    than human labor that dominates production in the less developed world

    (Brynjolfsson and McAfee, 2012; Markoff, 2012). Another counter-trend is

    Ritzer 19

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    18/22

    associated with the advent of, for example, 3-D printers allowing for what we have

    thought of as more traditional production in the developed world. The increase in

    prosumption, as well as the realization that it is prosumption andnotproduction or

    consumption that is the most central concept, will also cause us to re-examine age-

    old ideas in the social sciences. Among them are concepts developed for a society

    thought to be dominated by production such as alienation, exploitation, and

    rationalization. While this is a subject for another essay, we can exemplify the

    main point in the case of the concept of exploitation.

    Exploitation is most typically thought of, at least from a Marxian perspective, in

    terms of paying the workers less than the value of what they produce. This is the

    basic source of surplus value and, in more conventional terms, of profit for the

    capitalists. However, in most cases prosumers are paid nothing by the capitalists

    who profit enormously from this arrangement. In fact, it could be argued that theyearn far greater profits because instead of the pittance normally paid to workers,

    they pay the prosumer nothing at all. As a result, from a purely economic perspec-

    tive, prosumers are exploited within a capitalist system and they are exploited to a

    greater extent than the proletariat. While this is true from a structural perspective,

    it is harder to defend from a social-psychological point of view. That is, the pro-

    letariat saw themselves as exploited, or at least many workers came to see them-

    selves in that way because of their increasing immiseration as well as the efforts of

    radical thinkers such as Marx and organizations such as socialist parties and labor

    unions. However, it is very difficult to imagine todays prosumers seeing themselvesas exploited or, more generally, accepting the idea that Marxian thinking applies to

    them (Rey, 2012). This is true, in part, because they lack the concept of the pro-

    sumer, as well as the fact that Marxian theory seems to apply to a bygone era.

    More importantly, it is likely that most prosumers enjoy all, or at least most, of

    what they do. They would be hard-pressed to think of themselves as exploited when

    they order products on Amazon.com, construct bookcases from IKEA, or use the

    ATM. Marxian theorists would say that such prosumers are suffering from false

    consciousness and that, in fact, they are deluding themselves into thinking they are

    not being exploitated. However, it is also possible that they are not exploited in aclassic Marxian sense and that the concept needs to revised to take into account

    these new realities. It is also possible that an entirely new concept is needed to deal

    with the greatly different situation confronting todays prosumers in contrast to the

    proletariat (who also, it is important to remember, were prosumers [p-a-ps]) of the

    heyday of factory-based capitalism. More generally, we need to revisit a broad

    range of sociological concepts created during and for eras dominated by produc-

    tion and consumption. At the minimum, we will need to revise them and, more

    extremely (and more likely), we will need to create new ideas not locked into the old

    and increasingly outdated production-consumption binary.In terms of its theoretical implications, the coming of age of work on the pro-

    sumer foretells a paradigm revolution in the study of the economy (Kuhn, 1962/

    1970; Ritzer, 1975/1980). Extant paradigms have taken either production or con-

    sumption as their image of the subject matter in the study of the economy. What

    20 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    19/22

    we are witnessing is the emergence of a new, third paradigm for which prosumption

    is that image. This could mean that the study of the economy will be even more

    multi-paradigmatic in the future than it has been in the past. However, it is also the

    case that prosumption, because it encompasses both production and consumption,

    could be the basis of a more integrated sociological paradigm that deals with all

    three simultaneously (Ritzer, 1981). This would move the study of the economy in

    the direction of the hard sciences where, at least in Kuhns view, single para-

    digms predominate. While this is possible, the more likely outcome, given the his-

    tory and current status of the social sciences, is one in which multiple paradigms

    coexist within the field. Paradigms encompass theories and methods and a new

    paradigm means major theoretical and methodological changes. Since prosump-

    tion encompasses production and consumption, one alternative is increased use of

    multiple theories and methods that allow the social scientist to get a handle on allof these processes. Another is the development of new theories and methods that

    are internally diverse enough to deal with these processes.

    Thus, the rise of interest in prosumption as an image of the subject matter in the

    study of the economy promises a range of dramatic paradigmatic, theoretical and

    empirical changes. One parallel example in the history of the field of sociology is

    the work of Emile Durkheim (1893/1964) and his contention that social facts are

    the subject matter of sociology. This led to the development of a new paradigm

    (the social facts paradigm), as well as theories (e.g. structural functionalism) and

    methods (e.g. historical-comparative research) oriented to the study of social facts(Ritzer, 1975/1980). It is possible that a revolution involving a new prosumer

    paradigm will have similarly powerful and wide-ranging effects.

    Finally, there is the issue of the implication of this discussion of the prosumer

    for the subject matter of The Journal of Consumer Culture (JCC). One obvious

    conclusion is that theJCCneeds to devote more attention to work on prosumption

    (and related concepts). A more extreme conclusion is that what is needed is the

    founding ofThe Journal of Prosumer Culture (JPC) to complement the JCC (as

    well as production-oriented journals).8 If the various theses of this essay have

    merit, it does seem likely that a journal of prosumer culturewill come into existencein the future. However, it is likely that the JCC (as well as journals focused on

    production) will not only continue to exist, but even flourish. Nevertheless, it will

    be increasingly important to recognize that theJCC(as well as production-oriented

    journals) is focusing on only one end of the prosumption continuum. That is, the

    focus of theJCC, and more generally of consumption studies, is, in the terms used

    in this essay, prosumption-as-consumption.

    Many other future changes could be discussed here, but that would move us in

    the direction of the kind of analysis that characterizes the work of Alvin Toffler.

    That kind of journalistic and futuristic analysis is usually demeaned in the socialsciences. However, we should remember that in 1980 it (and not the work of social

    scientists) yielded a conceptprosumptionthat has proven not only durable, but

    even more useful in the early 21st century than it was when it was created. It will

    likely be of increasing utility as the century unfolds.

    Ritzer 21

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    20/22

    Notes

    1. This constitutes a change in the definition of prosumption from my earlier work on the

    topic (e.g., Ritzer and Jurgenson, 2010). I no longer think of prosumption as involvingmore-or-less simultaneous production and consumption. A prosumer can produce

    something at one point in time (e.g., a crop) and consume it at a much later point

    in time. In spite of the passage of time, this still involves the process of prosumption as it

    is defined here. I would like to thank Georgia Handforth for helping me clarify this point.

    2. There are exceptions, of course, such as Lipovetsky (2002) and Livingston (2011).

    3. Of course, journals devoted to production continue to exist and occupy a largely parallel

    universe.

    4. To Baudrillard (1977/1998), the Parisian drugstore was a key means of consumption.

    5. While key points on the prosumption continuum are being distinguished in these examples,

    it should be clear thatallinvolve some combination of production and consumption.

    6. Bruns, as we have seen, prefers the closely related term of produsage.

    7. This, of course, is a great oversimplification of the dialectic; see, for example, Ritzer

    (2014) for an example of a more complex model.

    8. This would parallel the impact of Durkheims work and his founding of LAnnee

    Sociologiquein 1898.

    References

    Anderson C (2010) Free: How Todays Smartest Businesses Profit by Giving Something for

    Nothing.New York: Hyperion.

    Anderson C (2012) Makers: The New Industrial Revolution. New York: Crown.Ballantyne D and Varey RJ (2008) The service-dominant logic and the future of marketing.

    Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 36: 1114.

    Baudrillard J (1970/1998) The Consumer Society: Myths and Structures. London: Sage.

    Bauman Z (1992) Intimations of Postmodernity. London: Routledge.

    Benjamin W (1999) The Arcades Project. Cambridge: Belknap Press of Harvard.

    Benkler Y (2006) The Wealth of Networks: How Social Production Transforms Markets and

    Freedom. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Benkler Y and Nissenbaum H (2006) Commons-based peer production and virtue. Journal

    of Political Philosophy 14: 394419.

    Bird SE (2011) Are we all produsers now? Cultural Studies 20: 502516.Bruns A (2005)Gatewatching: Collaborative Online News Production. New York: Peter Lang.

    Bruns A (2008) Blogs, Wikipedia, Second Life and Beyond: From Production to Produsage.

    New York: Peter Lang.

    Brynjolfsson E and McAfee A (2012) Jobs, productivity and the great decoupling. New York

    Times, 11 December.

    Campbell C (1987) The Romantic Ethic and the Rise of Modern Consumerism. New York:

    WritersPrintShop.

    Campbell C (2005) The craft consumer: Culture, craft and consumption in a postmodern

    society.Journal of Consumer Culture 5: 2342.

    Cohen L (2003) A Consumers Republic. New York: Knopf.Cova B, Dalli D and Zwick D (2011) Critical perspectives on consumers role as produ-

    cers: Broadening the debate on value co-creation in marketing processes. Marketing

    Theory 11: 231241.

    Deleuze G (1986) Nietzsche and Philosophy. London: Continuum.

    22 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    21/22

    Durkheim E (1893/1964) Division of Labor in Society. New York: Free Press.

    Durkheim E (1893/1964) The Rules of Sociological Method. New York: Free Press.

    Durkheim E (1928/1962) Socialism. New York: Collier Books.

    Featherstone M (1991) Consumer Culture and Postmodernism. London: Sage.Galbraith JK (1958) The Affluent Society. New York: Houghton Mifflin.

    Hauser JR and Clausing D (1988) The house of quality. Harvard Business Review66: 6373.

    Howe, J (2009) Crowdsourcing: Why the Power of the Crowd Is Driving the Future of

    Business. New York: Crown Business.

    Jurgenson N (2012) When atoms meet bits: Social media, the mobile web and augmented

    revolution. Future Internet 41: 8391.

    Kuhn T (1962/1970)The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. Chicago: University of Chicago

    Press.

    Laughey D (2010) User authority through mediated interaction: A case of eBay-in use.

    Journal of Consumer Culture 10: 105128.Leadbetter C and Miller P (2004) The Pro-Am Revolution. London: Demos.

    Lipovetsky G (2002) The Empire of Fashion. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Livingston J (2011) Against Thrift: Why Consumer Culture is Good for the Economy, the

    Environment, and Your Soul. New York: Basic Books.

    Manning R (2001) Credit Card Nation: The Consequences of Americas Addiction to Credit .

    New York: Basic Books.

    Marron D (2009) Consumer Credit in the United States. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Markoff J (2012) Skilled work, without the worker. New York Times, 18 August.

    Marx K (1884/1981) Capital, vol 2. New York: International Publishers.

    Prahalad CK and Ramaswamy V (2004a) The Future of Competition: Co-Creating UniqueValue With Customers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Prahalad CK and Ramaswamy V (2004b) Co-creation experiences: The next practice in

    value creation. Journal of Interactive Marketing 18: 514.

    Rey PJ (2012) Alienation, exploitation, and social media. American Behavioral Scientist 56:

    399420.

    Ritzer G (1975/1980) Sociology: A Multiple Paradigm Science. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.

    Ritzer G (1981) Toward an Integrated Sociological Paradigm: The Search for an Exemplar

    and an Image of the Subject Matter. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.

    Ritzer G (1993) The McDonaldization of Society. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press.

    Ritzer G (1995) Expressing America: A Critique of the Global Credit Card Industry.Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press.

    Ritzer G (2010a) Focusing on the prosumer: On correcting an error in the history of social

    theory. In: Blattel-Mink B and Hellman K-U (eds) Prosumer Revisited. Wiesbaden: VS

    Verlag, pp. 6179.

    Ritzer G (2010b) Enchanting a Disenchanted World, 3rd edn. Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine

    Forge Press.

    Ritzer G (2012) Hyperconsumption and hyperdebt: A hypercritical analysis. In:

    Brubaker R, Lawless RW and Tabb CJ (eds) A Debtor World; Interdisciplinary

    Perspectives on Debt. New York: Oxford: pp.6080.

    Ritzer G (2014) Sociological Theory, 9th edn. New York: McGraw-Hill.Ritzer G, Goodman D and Wiedenhoft W (2001) Theories of consumption. In: Ritzer G and

    Smart B (eds) Handbook of Social Theory. London: Sage, pp. 410427.

    Ritzer G and Jurgenson N (2010) Production, consumption, prosumption: The nature of

    capitalism in the age of the digital prosumer. Journal of Consumer Culture 10: 1336.

    Ritzer 23

    at Universit degli Studi di Napoli 'L'Orientale' on April 22, 2015joc.sagepub.comDownloaded from

    http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/http://joc.sagepub.com/
  • 7/21/2019 Journal of Consumer Culture 2014 Ritzer 3 24

    22/22

    Ritzer G and Slater D (2001) Editorial. Journal of Consumer Culture 1: 58.

    Ritzer G, Dean P and Jurgenson N (2012) The coming age of the prosumer. American

    Behavioral Scientist 56: 379398.

    Scholz T (ed.) (2013) Digital Labor: The Internet as Playground and Factory. New York:Routledge.

    Simmel G (1904/1971) Fashion. In: Levine D (ed.) Georg Simmel. Chicago: University of

    Chicago Press.

    Simmel G (1907/1978) The Philosophy of Money, 3rd edn. London: Routledge.

    Simmel G (1921/1968) The Conflict in Modern Culture. In: In Etzkorn KP (ed.) Georg

    Simmel. New York, Teachers College: Columbia University.

    Smith C (1990) Auctions: The Social Construction of Value. Berkeley, CA: University of

    California Press.

    Sombart W (1913/1967) Luxury and Capitalism. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Tapscott D and Williams AD (2006) Wikinomics: How Mass Collaboration ChangesEverything. New York: Portfolio.

    Toffler A (1980) The Third Wave. New York: William Morrow & Company.

    Toffler A and Toffler H (2006) Revolutionary Wealth. New York: Doubleday.

    Trentmann F (2006) The modern genealogy of the consumer: Meanings, identities and pol-

    itical synapses. In: Brewer J and Trentmann F (eds) Consuming Cultures, Global

    Perspectives: Historical Trajectories, Transnational Exchanges. Oxford: Berg, pp. 1969.

    Vargo SL and Lusch RF (2004) Evolving to a new logic for marketing. Journal of Marketing

    68: 117.

    Vargo SL and Lusch RF (2008) Service-dominant logic: Continuing the evolution. Journal

    of the Academy of Marketing Science 31: 110.Veblen T (1899/1994) The Theory of the Leisure Class. New York: Penguin Books.

    Veblen T (1914/1964) The Instinct of Workmanship and the State of Industrial Arts.

    New York: Augustus M. Kelly.

    Watson M and Shove E (2008) Product, competence, project and practice: DIY and the

    dynamics of craft consumption. Journal of Consumer Culture 8, 1: 6989.

    Weber M (19045/1958) The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. New York:

    Scribner.

    Weber M (19031917/1947) The Methodology of the Social Sciences. New York: Free Press.

    Weber M (1927/1981) General Economic History. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Books.

    Welter B (1966) The cult of true womanhood: 18201860. American Quarterly18(2), Part 1:151174.

    Williams R (1982) Dream Worlds: Mass Consumption in Late Nineteenth Century France.

    University of California Press.

    Zwick D and Knott JD (2009) Manufacturing customers: The database as new means of

    production.Journal of Consumer Culture 9: 221247.

    Author Biography

    George Ritzer is Distinguished University Professor in the Department of

    Sociology at the University of Maryland, College Park, MD, USA. He continues

    to think and write about the implications of the changing nature of prosumption

    with the objective of writing a book on the subject.

    24 Journal of Consumer Culture 14(1)