29
March 17th 2010 Nottingham 1 Higher education returns and effects of ability composition 1. Motivation Increased higher education participation is likely to have various impacts on returns to degrees One channel – through implied changes in composition of different educational groups – has received relatively little attention Compositional changes of interest include by family class background and by ‘ability’ In the current work, we are

March 17th 2010Nottingham1 Higher education returns and effects of ability composition 1.Motivation Increased higher education participation is likely

  • View
    218

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 1

Higher education returns and effects of ability composition

1. Motivation

• Increased higher education participation is likely to have various impacts on returns to degrees

• One channel – through implied changes in composition of different educational groups – has received relatively little attention

• Compositional changes of interest include by family class background and by ‘ability’

• In the current work, we are interested in ability composition

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 2

2. Aims

We will focus on:

(i) The college wage premium(ii) Differences in the premium across different groups

- gender- ability/performance

Claim: Graduate Expansion -> changes in ability composition -> impact on college wage premium (etc) in ways consistent with evidence

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 3

3. Context

HE API in UK shows rapid expansion after mid-1980s,

with growth especially dramatic for women.

See Figure 1.

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 4

Figure 1a: Long-Term Trends in Participation in Higher Education (Age Participation Index (API))

API (%) Source: DfES. The W-Z window (LFS)

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

10

20

30

40

50

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 5

Figure 1b: Long-Term Trends in Participation in Higher Education (Age Participation Index (API))

API (%) Source: DfES. NCDS – BCS70 cohorts Note: (i) 1977-1989 conceals gender difference W-Z (LFS) 1977 1989 Λ

HE API males 22% 24% 2%pts HE API females 17% 23% 6%pts (ii) Wage observations capture cohort neighbour effects

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

10

20

30

40

50

Entry interval Wage obs interval

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 6

Figure 1c: Long-Term Trends in Participation in Higher Education (Age Participation Index (API))

API (%) Source: DfES. Span of USR entry cohorts and single HESA cohort 1982-1990 conceals magnitude of female growth

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

10

20

30

40

50

USR

HESA

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 7

Figure 1c: Long-Term Trends in Participation in Higher Education (Age Participation Index (API))

API (%) Source: DfES. GCS entry cohorts and DLHE cohort

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000

10

20

30

40

50

GCS85

DLHE 2003+

GCS90 GCS95 GCS99

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 8

4. Why did the HE API rise?

Demand-side factors:derived demand (SBTC)GCSE pass rates

Supply-side factors:Increase in places

- finance following student- end of binary divide

Loans system

W-Z: from mid-80s to mid-90s, SS dominated DD factors=> r (specifically, Pg) predicted to fall, cet. par.

s

r

D1D2

S=MC

r

s

S1S2

D=MB

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 9

5. Heterogeneity in ability

The simple model of the previous figures assumes workers are homogeneous and hence abstracts from possibility of compositional changes: note ability bias issue (schooling correlated with ability)

ssH

r

S1=MC1

sL

DL

DH

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 10

A fall in costs can produce a change in the ability composition (and hence in extent of ability bias):

(and also a change in the marginal return: see W-Z QR results)

ssL=sH

r

S1=MC1

DL

DH

S2=MC2

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 11

At the individual level, the issue of the relationship between ability and educational investments when individuals are heterogeneous is well-known and is associated with the problem of ability bias in estimates of returns to education.

At the macro (cohort) level, cohort changes (eg in participation) can impact on estimates of returns through changes in the extent of ability bias across cohorts.

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 12

Assume:

Within a cohort:

Across cohorts: . . .

,w w s a s

+ x (ability diff)

+ ability bias (if econometrician suffers

asymmetric information)

or

HK

s a

g

dw w w da

ds s a dsr r

p

R + value of signal (if employer suffers

asymmetric information)

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 13

Across cohorts:

can change because of changes in:

(i)

(ii)

(iii)

The literature has focused on (i) and (ii) (see Cawley et al., 2000) .

But see Blackburn and Neumark (1991, 1993, 1995) and R

s

a

dw

dsr

r

da

ds

osenbaum (2003).

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 14

The college wage premium (under pure signalling): uniform ability distribution.

*a a a a

ga na

*F a 1 *F a

f a

What happens if HE API grows? There is no change in . But this is a special result under the uniform distribution .

Blackburn and Neumark show that under a triangular distribution, falls . . .

da

ds

da

ds

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 15

Implication: Graduate expansion over cohorts -> compositional change -> a reduction in ability bias (or a lower value to the signal of a degree), ceteris paribus,and hence a lower estimate of the college wage premium.

The US literature on this was not developed further as the Blackburn-Neumark analysis was attempting to explain an increase in the college wage premium at a time of higher college participation.

Rosenbaum (2003) finds evidence supporting the view that compositional changes can explain longer term patterns in the college wage premium in the US. (see pdf . . .)

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 16

6. Evidence on the UK college wage premium over time

(i)Harkness-Machin (1999) was rising in the 80s and constant in

the 90sLikely explanation: SBTC in 80s raised rs and ra;

offset in 90s by graduate expansion

(ii)Walker-Zhu (2008)(LFS) Focus on birth cohorts of 66-68 vs 75-77 (see

Figure 1a, p. 5): API more than doubled.

Result: constant for men (15%) and

rising for women (40 -> 47%)

Conclusion: ra must have been rising to offset what must have been falling rs (and compositional changes)

/dw ds

/dw ds/dw ds

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 17

(iii) What can we learn from the birth cohort studies in Britain?

HE API HE API (%)+4 cohorts1 Men

Women

NCDS 13% (1977) 14% 12-18 34-381958Birth cohort

NCS70 18% (1989) 2 30% ? ?1970Birth cohort

1Eg, entering HE in 1993, graduating in 1996, 4yrs experience by 2000 when £ observed of 1970 birth cohort.2Conceals extent of growth in female participation in HE.

/dw ds

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 18

Predictions:

(a) Reduction in ability bias => fall in estimate of college wage premium, but offset by increases in rs and ra brought about by SBTC etc

(b) Given the much greater expansion in the HE API of women relative to men, we might expect the consequently greater compositional change for women to lead to a relative fall in the college wage premium of women.

for women might fall relative to that for men if:

(i) falls relatively more for women

(ii) falls relatively more for women

(iii) falls relatively more for women; which we

s

a

dw

dsr

r

da

dsexpect.

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 19

OLS CFAMales Coef. s.e. Coef. s.e.Non-degree HE 0.006 0.038 0.007 0.040

UG degree 0.146

∗∗∗0.040 0.146

∗∗∗0.041

PG degree 0.050 0.058 0.052 0.054

λ 0.000 0.001

N.obs. 1497 1497

R² 0.077 0.078

Wald test on parents' education (p-value)

Education equation 0.000

Wage equationa 0.185

Data: BCS70. The dependent variable is the natural logarithm of gross hourly wages, age 30. Wage premia are relative to individuals with 2 or more A-levels. The wage equation also includes a wide set of explanatory variables: see paper.λ are the generalized residuals computed from the ordered probit model for the highest educational qualification achieved. The CFA model is identified by parents' education that is included only in the education equation. The F-test refers to the exclusion of parents' education from the controls in the wage equation (2) in the CFA model only identified by functional form.

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 20

OLS CFA

Females Coef. s.e. Coef. s.e.

Non-degree HE 0.070

∗0.035 0.070

∗0.035

UG degree 0.178

∗∗∗0.035 0.178

∗∗∗0.035

PG degree 0.100

∗∗0.040 0.099

∗∗0.037

λ 0.000 0.000N.obs. 1,422 1422.000R² 0.11 0.111Wald test on parents' education (p-value)Education equation 0.001

Wage equationa 0.833

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 21

HE API HE API (%)+4 cohorts1 Men Women

NCDS 13% (1977) 14% 12-18 34-381958Birth cohort

NCS70 18% (1989) 2 30% 15 181970Birth cohort

Across the 2 cohorts, for men has been remarkably constantwhile for women has fallen dramatically, to be similar tothat for men. Supports hypothesis that compositional changesimportant.

/dw ds

/dw ds/dw ds

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 22

7. Degree class signals

We now consider the premium associated with the award of a distinction to the most able graduates.

Compared to the case concerning the premium for a degree, we expect the premium for a distinction to reflect a relatively strong signalling element. (Note contrast between UK and US: see Arcidiacono et al., 2008.) But HKT interpretation works too.

The question we address is: how is da/ds likely to change following an increase in the HE API?

where now refers to the award of a distinction.

dw w w da

ds s a dsds

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 23

Theory

As HE API increases, da/ds rises and this causes the estimated premium for a distinction to rise, cet. par.. (nb: impact reduced by d↑)

Is this consistent with empirical evidence?

The premium under signalling for a high class degree award:

the uniform ability distribution.

*a a a a

da pa dp

*F a

ˆ

*

F a

F a

a

1

ˆF a

f a

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 24

USR data Ireland, Naylor, Smith, Telhaj (2009)1985 – 1993 graduating cohorts (+ HESA data for1998 leavers)(+ GCS data for 1985 and 1990 cohorts)

Administrative data on full graduate populations•Personal characteristics•Academic background•Family background•University/course information•First Destination Survey (EL-SD)

Problem with individual earnings (balloon surface)

Average occupational earnings (averaged over all years)

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 25

USR data, summary statistics for those in employment based on the 1993 cohort (continued)

Variable Mean MeanDegree Class Males Females

  First (I) 0.10 0.07

Upper Second (II.1) 0.45 0.55

Lower Second (II.2) 0.33 0.32

Third (III) 0.07 0.03

Sample size (n) 19476 19978

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 26

Average occupational earnings by subject field and degree class for the 1993 cohort

  MALES FEMALES  Mean n Mean n

450.28 19476 333.10 19978

Degree Class I 480.14 1909 351.31 1309 II.1 465.25 8791 338.44 10982 II.2 432.62 6471 322.58 6381 III 408.41 1344 319.06 642

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 27

Selected Results of occupational earnings equation for the 1993 cohort

    MALES FEMALESVariable Coeff  Coeff 

Degree class

I 0.038*** 0.037***

II.1 (default)

II.2 -0.054*** -0.042***

III -0.094*** -0.053***

Other -0.080*** -0.079***

Note: Premium for a good degree is 6.0%. Similar to estimate of 6.4% for BCS70 students graduating at about same time. From 1990 GCS data, premium for a good degree is 5.0%

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 28

Degree class coefficient estimates for the 1985-1993 and 1998 cohorts

1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1998 MalesI 0.003 0.006 -0.007 -0.006 0.001 0.027 0.027 0.042 0.038 0.046II.1 (default)FemalesI 0.012 0.012 0.018 0.028 0.026 0.033 0.025 0.053 0.037 0.067II.1 (default)

Why is this an interesting time period?

HE API 0.14 0.14 0.15 0.15 0.15 0.16 0.16 0.18 0.20 0.32

Correlation between API and Premia (1985 – 1993 cohorts):

(i)First, Males, = 0.81; (ii) First, Females, = 0.79;

(iii) Overall Span (1st to 3rd), Males, = 0.86; (iv) Overall Span, Females, = 0.64.

Over this time period, there is no strong evidence of substantial increases in rs or ra: W-Z show degree returns constant for both men and women at least prior to 1995 graduates.    

March 17th 2010 Nottingham 29

Conclusion

Observed changes across cohorts in returns to degrees by gender and in returns by class of degree awarded are consistent with the hypothesis that graduate expansion is the driver, mediated through the implied changes in ability composition across education groups .

Future work aims to examine how these patterns:

(i) have continued to evolve for later cohorts and

(ii) behave over time (with tenure/experience)