33
AGGREGATION & INTERLINKAGES:THE IRISH CASE. Stephen Kinsella & G. Tiou-Tagba Aliti University of Limerick, Ireland

Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

Embed Size (px)

DESCRIPTION

A talk delivered at INET's db

Citation preview

Page 1: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

AGGREGATION & INTERLINKAGES:THE IRISH CASE.

Stephen Kinsella & G. Tiou-Tagba AlitiUniversity of Limerick, Ireland

Page 2: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

3 STORIES OF LINKAGES THIS

MORNING.

Page 3: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

1. CREDIT -> DEBT2. PRIVATE -> PUBLIC3. EXPECTATIONS -> REALITY

Page 4: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

0

10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

2004

Q1

2005

Q1

2006

Q1

2007

Q1

2008

Q1

2009

Q1

2010

Q1

2011

Q1

2012

Q1

Final Domestic Demand, €m

A DEMAND-DEFICIENT ECONOMY.

Page 5: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

Ireland and EU: Unemployment rates, 2002-2012

0

4

8

11

15

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012

EU Ireland

Page 6: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

<CREDIT -> DEBT>

Page 7: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages
Page 8: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

Use of household savings

Household savings peaked at !13.9 bn in 2009 and have since fallen back to !9.3bn in 2011. How households havebeen using their savings is illustrated in Figure 3. The line graph is the trend in actual gross household savings whilethe bar chart illustrates transactions in investment and borrowing by households1.

During the entire period there is a clear link between transactions in loans (Liabilities F.4) and transactions in grosscapital formation (GFCF) of households (P.5). The transactions in loans relate predominantly to borrowing to fundinvestment in property while the capital formation relates to the property investments themselves.

Since 2009 households have not beenborrowing, in net terms. At the same timeinvestment in property has fallen to levels thatcan be financed by the savings of the sectorwithout having recourse to borrowing. In fact thegross capital formation of households fell from ahigh of !25.6bn in 2006 to !4.8bn in 2011. Amajor use of household savings in 2011 was therepayment of loans or deleveraging, amountingto !9bn. The use of household savings to fundtransactions in assets e.g. deposits (Table 2 –Assets F.2) and insurance and pensioninvestments (Table 2 – Assets F.6) is alsoapparent in the graph.

Non-Financial Corporations (S.11)

Profits share of non-financial corporations

An increase in profits of !4.8bn between 2010and 2011 explains most of the improvement inthe profit share ratio for non-financialcorporations (NFCs). The operating surplus(B.2g/B.3g) or profits of these corporationsincreased from !41.5bn in 2010 to !46.3bn in2011 (see Summary Table). Practically all of thisincrease in profits has been earned by foreignowned multinational corporations operating inIreland and these profits accrue to the ownersabroad. The other main component of valueadded (B.1g) is compensation of employees (D.1Uses) (wages and salaries) which declined from!36.2bn in 2010 to !35.5bn in 2011.

1 It is important to make the distinction between balance sheet measures of household debt i.e. the outstanding stock of loans illustrated in Figure 2 and transactions inloans i.e. increases (+) or decreases (-) included in Figure 3.

8

-40

-30

-20

-10

0

10

20

30

40

50

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

!billions

Figure 3 Savings, Investment and Net Lending/Borrowing ofHouseholds

GFCF Net Capital Transfers

Shares DepositsLoans Insurance&PensionsGrossSavings

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

-

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Ratio!billionsFigure 4 Profit Share of Non - Financial Corporations

GrossValue Added Profits Profit Share

Page 9: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

Use of household savings

Household savings peaked at !13.9 bn in 2009 and have since fallen back to !9.3bn in 2011. How households havebeen using their savings is illustrated in Figure 3. The line graph is the trend in actual gross household savings whilethe bar chart illustrates transactions in investment and borrowing by households1.

During the entire period there is a clear link between transactions in loans (Liabilities F.4) and transactions in grosscapital formation (GFCF) of households (P.5). The transactions in loans relate predominantly to borrowing to fundinvestment in property while the capital formation relates to the property investments themselves.

Since 2009 households have not beenborrowing, in net terms. At the same timeinvestment in property has fallen to levels thatcan be financed by the savings of the sectorwithout having recourse to borrowing. In fact thegross capital formation of households fell from ahigh of !25.6bn in 2006 to !4.8bn in 2011. Amajor use of household savings in 2011 was therepayment of loans or deleveraging, amountingto !9bn. The use of household savings to fundtransactions in assets e.g. deposits (Table 2 –Assets F.2) and insurance and pensioninvestments (Table 2 – Assets F.6) is alsoapparent in the graph.

Non-Financial Corporations (S.11)

Profits share of non-financial corporations

An increase in profits of !4.8bn between 2010and 2011 explains most of the improvement inthe profit share ratio for non-financialcorporations (NFCs). The operating surplus(B.2g/B.3g) or profits of these corporationsincreased from !41.5bn in 2010 to !46.3bn in2011 (see Summary Table). Practically all of thisincrease in profits has been earned by foreignowned multinational corporations operating inIreland and these profits accrue to the ownersabroad. The other main component of valueadded (B.1g) is compensation of employees (D.1Uses) (wages and salaries) which declined from!36.2bn in 2010 to !35.5bn in 2011.

1 It is important to make the distinction between balance sheet measures of household debt i.e. the outstanding stock of loans illustrated in Figure 2 and transactions inloans i.e. increases (+) or decreases (-) included in Figure 3.

8

-40

-30

-20

-10

0

10

20

30

40

50

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

!billions

Figure 3 Savings, Investment and Net Lending/Borrowing ofHouseholds

GFCF Net Capital Transfers

Shares DepositsLoans Insurance&PensionsGrossSavings

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

-

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Ratio!billionsFigure 4 Profit Share of Non - Financial Corporations

GrossValue Added Profits Profit Share

Page 10: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

Use of household savings

Household savings peaked at !13.9 bn in 2009 and have since fallen back to !9.3bn in 2011. How households havebeen using their savings is illustrated in Figure 3. The line graph is the trend in actual gross household savings whilethe bar chart illustrates transactions in investment and borrowing by households1.

During the entire period there is a clear link between transactions in loans (Liabilities F.4) and transactions in grosscapital formation (GFCF) of households (P.5). The transactions in loans relate predominantly to borrowing to fundinvestment in property while the capital formation relates to the property investments themselves.

Since 2009 households have not beenborrowing, in net terms. At the same timeinvestment in property has fallen to levels thatcan be financed by the savings of the sectorwithout having recourse to borrowing. In fact thegross capital formation of households fell from ahigh of !25.6bn in 2006 to !4.8bn in 2011. Amajor use of household savings in 2011 was therepayment of loans or deleveraging, amountingto !9bn. The use of household savings to fundtransactions in assets e.g. deposits (Table 2 –Assets F.2) and insurance and pensioninvestments (Table 2 – Assets F.6) is alsoapparent in the graph.

Non-Financial Corporations (S.11)

Profits share of non-financial corporations

An increase in profits of !4.8bn between 2010and 2011 explains most of the improvement inthe profit share ratio for non-financialcorporations (NFCs). The operating surplus(B.2g/B.3g) or profits of these corporationsincreased from !41.5bn in 2010 to !46.3bn in2011 (see Summary Table). Practically all of thisincrease in profits has been earned by foreignowned multinational corporations operating inIreland and these profits accrue to the ownersabroad. The other main component of valueadded (B.1g) is compensation of employees (D.1Uses) (wages and salaries) which declined from!36.2bn in 2010 to !35.5bn in 2011.

1 It is important to make the distinction between balance sheet measures of household debt i.e. the outstanding stock of loans illustrated in Figure 2 and transactions inloans i.e. increases (+) or decreases (-) included in Figure 3.

8

-40

-30

-20

-10

0

10

20

30

40

50

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

!billions

Figure 3 Savings, Investment and Net Lending/Borrowing ofHouseholds

GFCF Net Capital Transfers

Shares DepositsLoans Insurance&PensionsGrossSavings

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

-

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Ratio!billionsFigure 4 Profit Share of Non - Financial Corporations

GrossValue Added Profits Profit Share

Page 11: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

4

4. The sizable overhang of household debt is expected to be a drag on the recovery of consumption over the medium term. This paper describes the nexus between household wealth, saving, and consumption and provides estimates for the medium-term path of household saving and consumption. Under current macroeconomic assumptions, the savings rate is expected to decline gradually from 14 percent in 2011 to 12 percent by 2017. During the same period, household debt would decline from about 210 percent to 185 percent of disposable income. Alternative scenarios show how an accelerated speed of deleveraging could in part become self-defeating as lower demand depresses growth and incomes, whereas slower deleveraging could support growth but requires additional new lending.

B. The Consumption-Balance Sheet Nexus

5. The extent  of  households’  indebtedness  distinguishes  Ireland  from  comparators. During  the  last  decade,  households’  debt-to-income and leverage (debt-to-assets) ratios deteriorated markedly: households rapidly accumulated debt during boom times whereas household incomes and asset values declined severely during the crisis. The amplitude of debt accumulation and, subsequently, of income and house price declines has been more pronounced than in comparator countries where strong house expansions were also followed by a correction (Figures 3 and 4). As debt overhangs are known to take time to work off, households’  consumption-saving decisions may be affected in a more lasting manner.

10

15

20

25

30

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Ireland UK USA

Figure 4. Household Leverage Ratio 1/ (percent)

Sources: OECD; and IMF staff calculations1/Households' liabilities over households' financial and housing assets.

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

60

65

70

75

80

85

90

95

100

2002Q

1

2002Q

3

2003Q

1

2003Q

3

2004Q

1

2004Q

3

2005Q

1

2005Q

3

2006Q

1

2006Q

3

2007Q

1

2007Q

3

2008Q

1

2008Q

3

2009Q

1

2009Q

3

2010Q

1

2010Q

3

2011Q

1

2011Q

3

Consumption

Disposable income

Net borrowing/lending (RHS)

Net wealth (Index)

Sources: CBI; CSO; and IMF staff calculations.

Figure 2: The Turn of the Credit Cycle(Billions of 2002 euros)

70

90

110

130

150

170

190

210

230

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Ireland

Spain

UK

USA

Figure 3. Household Debt to Gross Disposable Income (percent)

Sources: OECD; and IMF staff calculations.

Page 12: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

Figure  1.  An  explosion  of  lending  by  private  sector  banks  led  to  Ireland's  current  malaise.  Source:  Kinsella  and  O'Sullivan,  2012.

Page 13: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

4

4. The sizable overhang of household debt is expected to be a drag on the recovery of consumption over the medium term. This paper describes the nexus between household wealth, saving, and consumption and provides estimates for the medium-term path of household saving and consumption. Under current macroeconomic assumptions, the savings rate is expected to decline gradually from 14 percent in 2011 to 12 percent by 2017. During the same period, household debt would decline from about 210 percent to 185 percent of disposable income. Alternative scenarios show how an accelerated speed of deleveraging could in part become self-defeating as lower demand depresses growth and incomes, whereas slower deleveraging could support growth but requires additional new lending.

B. The Consumption-Balance Sheet Nexus

5. The extent  of  households’  indebtedness  distinguishes  Ireland  from  comparators. During  the  last  decade,  households’  debt-to-income and leverage (debt-to-assets) ratios deteriorated markedly: households rapidly accumulated debt during boom times whereas household incomes and asset values declined severely during the crisis. The amplitude of debt accumulation and, subsequently, of income and house price declines has been more pronounced than in comparator countries where strong house expansions were also followed by a correction (Figures 3 and 4). As debt overhangs are known to take time to work off, households’  consumption-saving decisions may be affected in a more lasting manner.

10

15

20

25

30

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Ireland UK USA

Figure 4. Household Leverage Ratio 1/ (percent)

Sources: OECD; and IMF staff calculations1/Households' liabilities over households' financial and housing assets.

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

60

65

70

75

80

85

90

95

1002002Q

1

2002Q

3

2003Q

1

2003Q

3

2004Q

1

2004Q

3

2005Q

1

2005Q

3

2006Q

1

2006Q

3

2007Q

1

2007Q

3

2008Q

1

2008Q

3

2009Q

1

2009Q

3

2010Q

1

2010Q

3

2011Q

1

2011Q

3

Consumption

Disposable income

Net borrowing/lending (RHS)

Net wealth (Index)

Sources: CBI; CSO; and IMF staff calculations.

Figure 2: The Turn of the Credit Cycle(Billions of 2002 euros)

70

90

110

130

150

170

190

210

230

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Ireland

Spain

UK

USA

Figure 3. Household Debt to Gross Disposable Income (percent)

Sources: OECD; and IMF staff calculations.

Page 14: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages
Page 16: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages
Page 17: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

</CREDIT -> DEBT>

Page 18: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

<PRIVATE -> PUBLIC>

Page 19: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

5

Figure 5. Analytical Framework

InvestmentConsumption

Disposable income

Demand

Realchannel

Saving rate

Amortization

Lending

Outflows

Inflows

Lendingchannel

Collateral value

Asset prices

Gross wealth

Balance sheetchannel

Imports

Exports

RoW

Source: IMF staff.

RoW

6. The lending and balance sheet channels can create self-reinforcing cycles between borrowing and demand (Figure 5). Financial intermediation lifts the intertemporal budget constraint of the real channel and allows households to borrow against future income for the purpose of consumption and investment  (“lending  channel”).  Higher consumption and investment in turn nourish incomes and asset values, enhancing households’  ability  to  service their debt. This flow-based framework is complemented  by  the  “balance  sheet channel”  that  takes  into  account asset prices and wealth. By removing financial constraints, the lending channel lifts asset prices which in turn eases access to lending through higher collateral values and a lower propensity to save if agents treat the gain in wealth as being permanent. However, these effects also work in reverse as a vicious circle, with declining asset values leading to a sharp fall in lending and demand, feeding back into falling incomes and asset prices. In analogy to the financial accelerator described by Bernanke and Gertler (1989), the balance sheet channel can lead to overborrowing and act procyclically.

7. The procyclical dynamics of the lending and balance sheet channels can make household’s  deleveraging more costly and protracted:

Figures 6 and 7 exemplify the lending channel: In the crisis, growth collapsed and the savings rate jumped as banks stopped lending and households cut consumption and investment to free resources for repaying their loans (Figure 6). This switch in income

185

190

195

200

205

210

215

80

85

90

95

100

105

110

115

120

2008Q4 2009Q2 2009Q4 2010Q2 2010Q4 2011Q2 2011Q4

Gross disposable incomeHousehold loansDebt-to-income (in percent, RHS)

Figure 7: Decline in Income Versus Reduction in Debt (2008 Q4=100)

Sources: CBI, and IMF staff calculations.

-3

-2

-1

0

1

2

3

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

2003Q1 2005Q1 2007Q1 2009Q1 2011Q1

Household net borrowing/(lending)Saving rate (percent)Capital formationGDP growth (percent, RHS)

Sources: CBI; Haver Analytics; and IMF staff calculations.

Figure 6: Household Borrowing, Saving, and Growth(Billions of euros)

Page 20: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

The other financial intermediaries sector (S.123+S.124) continued to grow both in terms of assets and liabilitiesthroughout the period under review. Assets increased from !1,177.8bn in 2007 to !1,836.7bn in 2011 while liabilitiesincreased from !1,101.6bn to !1,851.6bn.

A notable shift affecting both sectors in 2011 was the decrease in the balance sheet of monetary financial institutionsand the increase in the other financial intermediaries sector which was due largely to a change in definition of moneymarket funds required by regulation of the European Central Bank. Money market funds, valued at !114bn, werereclassified as non-money market funds and therefore moved from sector S.122 to S.123.

In addition the balance sheets of the financial sector were impacted by the securitisation activity of banks during 2011.Loan assets, to the value of !17bn, were derecognised from the balance sheet of monetary financial institutions(S.122) resulting in a corresponding increase in the balance sheet of other financial intermediaries (S.123).

Significant changes have taken place in the balance sheets of financial corporations in the wake of the global financialcrisis. Some of these changes are apparent in the accounts but some are less evident due to offsetting shifts withinthe sector. The following outlines the effect of more significant events on the balance sheets of the financial sector forthe period covered.

• NAMA issued debt securities: In 2010 the National Asset Management Agency (NAMA) was established topurchase land and development loans from participating credit institutions. By virtue of its legal structure it istreated as a Special Purpose Vehicle (SPV) and is therefore in the other financial intermediaries sector (S.123).Hence the issuing of debt securities, in return for loans that are transferred from these credit institutions, isincluded in the financial accounts as an increase in debt security assets (AF.33) of credit institutions (S.122) andan increase in liabilities of other financial intermediaries (S.123). In 2011, the process of transferring loans toNAMA in return for bonds continued but to a much lesser degree.

• Government transfers to credit institutions: In 2010 promissory notes were issued by the Irish government toinject capital into credit institutions. These transfers appear in item D.99 other capital transfers in the capitalaccount of the non-financial accounts while in the financial accounts they are included as a loan asset (AF.42)of credit institutions (S.122) and a loan liability of general government (S.13). In 2011, following the PCAR andPLAR ‘stress tests’ which took place in March, the Irish Government injected !16.5bn into the covered banksto ensure the capital requirements outlined in the tests were met. In the financial accounts, this injection ofcapital is treated as an equity liability (AF.51) of credit institutions with a corresponding asset in the generalgovernment sector.

• Eurosystem monetary policy operations: Advances to Irish Banks, as part of the Eurosystem monetary policyoperations, decreased in 2011. These advances are included in the financial accounts as deposit (AF.29)assets of the Central Bank (S.121) and deposit liabilities of credit institutions (S.122). In addition, the CentralBank deposit liability to the ECB decreased.

General Government (S.13)

The deterioration of General Government financescontinued in 2011 following the trend observed duringthe previous three years. Gross disposable income(B.6g) increased marginally by !0.4bn to !18.9bn inthe year, although this represents a 53 per centdecline from its peak value of !40.4bn in 2007.

Year on year the single greatest change was thedecrease of !26.2bn to !6.7bn in capital transfers (D.9)paid by government. This resulted in a fall of !28.4bn inthe net borrowing (B.9) of General Government to!20.0bn in 2011 from the 2010 level of !48.4bn.

10

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

120%

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

200

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Ratio!billions

Figure 8 Government Debt/GDP Ratio at marketprices

Government Debt GDP Government Debt/GDP

Page 21: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

General Government Debt (GGDebt)2, showed a gradual decline between 2002 and 2007, and has since risensharply standing at 106% of GDP at the end of 20113. In the current publication all liabilities are measured at marketvalue. Substituting this market valuation for theface value used in the calculation of GGDebtgives rise to a somewhat lower figure of 104% ofGDP.

The rapid rise in the ratio of debt to GDP since2007 is due to the combined effect of anincreasing government debt level during thisperiod and falling GDP. Although GDP increasedslightly by !2.5bn to !159.0bn in 2011, this wasoffset by a rise in government debt of !27.7bn.

Composition of government debt

The composition of general government debt isshown in Figure 9. The growth in totalgovernment liabilities in 2011 was dominated bythe rise of !30.6bn in loan liabilities (AF.4). Theincreasing trend toward financing the activities ofgovernment through direct loans over the period2010-2011 has offset the difficulties faced inraising finance in the sovereign bond marketduring this time. This is evident in Figure 9 wherefinancing through the issuance of securities(AF.33) has continued to decline, standing at!79.9bn at the end of 2011 from the 2010 level of!84.3bn. General government showed a nettransaction in AF.33 of -!9.9bn in 2011 indicatinga net reduction in the incurrence of liabilitiesthrough this instrument.

The consolidated liabilities of generalgovernment rose by !28.3bn in 2011 from!140.1bn to !168.4bn, as shown in Table 5. Thisincrease (which excludes liabilities of the sectorto itself) was due primarily to a rise of !30.7bn inconsolidated loan (AF.4) liabilities from 2010.

Bank capital injections, which occurred in 2011 tomeet the capital requirements demanded by thestress-tests, are most clearly evident in thefinancial accounts of general governmentthrough the instrument AF.512. This is reflectedin the financial transactions in Table 2 wheregovernment shows a net increase of !9.5bn in2011 of equity assets.

Gross savings (B.8g) increased by !1.3bn, a riseof 10.9 per cent, during 2011 resulting in a deficitof !10.3bn for the year. Overall, gross savingshave risen by !2.1bn since 2009. Government net borrowing was !48.4bn in 2010 and this was used to fund thepromissory notes which were issued by the Irish government to inject capital into credit institutions. Net borrowing in2011 fell to !20bn and this went to finance further capital injections into the banking system, seen as ‘Other CapitalTransfers’ (D.99) in the non-financial accounts.

2 Defined under EU regulations governing the Excessive Deficit Procedure as the sum of liabilities of S.13 in the categories AF.2 (Currency & Deposits), AF.33(Securities other than shares, excluding derivatives) and AF.4 (Loans) at face value.

3 Table 21b, National Income and Expenditure, 2011

11

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

!billionsFigure 9 Composition of General Government Debt

AF.2 Deposits AF.33 Securities AF.4 Loans

-60

-50

-40

-30

-20

-10

0

10

20

2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

!billions

Figure 10 Government Savings andNet Lending/Borrowing

Savings (B.8g) Net Lending/Borrowing (B.9)

Composition of Govt. Debt.

Page 22: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

AN OLD SCHOOL IDEA

Page 23: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages
Page 24: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages
Page 25: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

114,000

116,000

118,000

120,000

122,000

124,000

126,000

07:3 08:1 08:3 09:1 09:3 10:1 10:3 11:1

Eq 49-Eq 19: Households depositsheld by Financial Corporations (Assets)

350

400

450

500

550

600

650

07:3 08:1 08:3 09:1 09:3 10:1 10:3 11:1

shock Empirical data v alue

Eq16-Eq30: Gov ernment and Rest of the World bondsheld by Households (Assets)

170,000

180,000

190,000

200,000

210,000

07:3 08:1 08:3 09:1 09:3 10:1 10:3 11:1

Eq17-Eq52: Households loans from Financial Corporations (Liabilities)

40,000

45,000

50,000

55,000

60,000

65,000

70,000

07:3 08:1 08:3 09:1 09:3 10:1 10:3 11:1

Eq18-Eq34: Non-Financial and Financial Corporations equities held by Households (Assets)

Page 26: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

0

5,000

10,000

15,000

20,000

25,000

07:3 08:1 08:3 09:1 09:3 10:1 10:3 11:1

Eq 50-Eq 15: Gov ernment depositsheld by Financial Corporations (Assets)

20,000

40,000

60,000

80,000

100,000

07:3 08:1 08:3 09:1 09:3 10:1 10:3 11:1

Shock Empirical data v alue

Eq7-Eq31: Gov ernment bond (Liabilities)

-10,000

0

10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

50,000

07:3 08:1 08:3 09:1 09:3 10:1 10:3 11:1

Eq13-Eq55: Gov ernment loans from Financial Corporations (Liabilities)

12,000

16,000

20,000

24,000

28,000

07:3 08:1 08:3 09:1 09:3 10:1 10:3 11:1

Eq14-Eq35: Non-Financial and Financial Corporations equities held by Gov ernment (Assets)

Page 27: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

<EXPECTATIONS -> REALITY>

Page 28: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages
Page 29: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages
Page 30: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

Ireland 9 year Generic Bid Yield

Page 31: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages
Page 32: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

</EXPECTATIONS -> REALITY>

Page 33: Modeling Aggregation and Interlinkages

AGGREGATION & INTERLINKAGES:THE IRISH CASE.

Stephen KinsellaUniversity of Limerick, Ireland