33
Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann [email protected] Simon Huang * [email protected] September 23, 2015 Abstract Some of the leading theories of momentum have different empirical predictions about its profitability conditional on market composition and structure. The over- confidence explanation provided by Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998), for example, predicts lower momentum profits in markets with more sophisticated investors. The information-based theory of Hong and Stein (1999) predicts lower mo- mentum profits in markets with lower informational frictions. The institutional theory of Vayanos and Woolley (2013) predicts lower momentum profits in markets with less agency. In this paper we use a dataset from a major 19th century equity market to test these predictions. Over this period there was no evidence of delegated management in Imperial Russia. A regulatory change in 1893 made speculating on the St. Petersburg stock market more accessible to small investors. We find a momentum effect that is similar in magnitude to those in modern markets, and stronger during the post-1893 period than during the pre-1893 period, consistent with the overconfidence theory of momentum. * William Goetzmann is with the Yale School of Management and NBER. Simon Huang is with the Cox School of Business, Southern Methodist University. We would like to thank Yong Chen, Adam Kolasinski, as well as seminar participants at Southern Methodist University and Yale University.

Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann [email protected] Simon Huang [email protected] September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

  • Upload
    others

  • View
    4

  • Download
    0

Embed Size (px)

Citation preview

Page 1: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Momentum in Imperial Russia

William [email protected]

Simon Huang∗

[email protected]

September 23, 2015

Abstract

Some of the leading theories of momentum have different empirical predictionsabout its profitability conditional on market composition and structure. The over-confidence explanation provided by Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998),for example, predicts lower momentum profits in markets with more sophisticatedinvestors. The information-based theory of Hong and Stein (1999) predicts lower mo-mentum profits in markets with lower informational frictions. The institutional theoryof Vayanos and Woolley (2013) predicts lower momentum profits in markets with lessagency. In this paper we use a dataset from a major 19th century equity market to testthese predictions. Over this period there was no evidence of delegated management inImperial Russia. A regulatory change in 1893 made speculating on the St. Petersburgstock market more accessible to small investors. We find a momentum effect that issimilar in magnitude to those in modern markets, and stronger during the post-1893period than during the pre-1893 period, consistent with the overconfidence theory ofmomentum.

∗William Goetzmann is with the Yale School of Management and NBER. Simon Huang is with the CoxSchool of Business, Southern Methodist University. We would like to thank Yong Chen, Adam Kolasinski,as well as seminar participants at Southern Methodist University and Yale University.

Page 2: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

1 Introduction

Momentum strategies, also known as relative strength strategies, are a class of long-short

trading strategies that buy past winners and sell past losers. Jegadeesh and Titman (1993)

first document the profitability of momentum strategies in a sample of U.S. stocks during

the period from 1965 to 1989. Many other studies extend this initial finding by documenting

momentum profitability in the post-1989 period, in equity markets outside of the U.S., and

in other asset classes.1 While there is an abundance of empirical evidence for momentum,

the debate on its underlying mechanism remains unsettled. For instance, Daniel, Hirshleifer,

and Subrahmanyam (1998) propose a model in which investor overconfidence about the

precision of private information generates the momentum effect. On the other hand, in

Hong and Stein’s (1999) model, the interaction of boundedly rational agents and the slow

diffusion of information generate initial underreaction and subsequent overreaction. More

recently, Lou (2012) and Vayanos and Woolley (2013) propose explanations of momentum

driven by flows into and between institutional money managers.

While these theories all generate the momentum effect, they have different predictions

about momentum profitability conditional of market composition and structure. Tests of

these predictions require significant variation for identification. In this paper we use a com-

prehensive dataset of monthly stock returns from the St. Petersburg Stock Exchange in

the 19th and early 20th centuries to test these predictions. The St. Petersburg Stock Ex-

change provides an ideal setting for investigating momentum because: 1) it is, as yet, an

untouched sample for finance researchers;2 2) there was no evidence of a delegated manage-

1See, e.g., Rouwenhorst (1998), Jegadeesh and Titman (2001), and Asness, Moskowitz, and Pedersen(2013).

2The majority of academic studies of the momentum effect use the database of U.S. stocks maintainedby the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP). The CRSP dataset starts in 1926. Even with manypapers that use different samples, the issue of whether these samples are really independent remains. Forinstance, Asness, Moskowitz, and Pedersen (2013) finds a strong common factor structure among momentumreturns from a set of diverse markets and asset classes.

1

Page 3: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

ment structure in the Russian Empire over this period;3 and 3) a regulatory change in 1893

substantially reduced the costs of speculative trading for less sophisticated investors. The

institutional theory predicts a muted momentum effect in such a market as the institutions

that the theory relies on to generate momentum were absent. The overconfidence theory pre-

dicts lower momentum profits during the pre-1893 period than during the post-1893 period,

because in the later period there was more market participation by those who are more sus-

ceptible to being overconfident. In contrast, the information diffusion theory predicts higher

momentum profits during the pre-1893 period, because market participation was narrower

and information flow was slower.

Our results are consistent with the investor overconfidence theory. Despite the absence

of a delegated management structure in our setting, we find that past medium-term winners

outperform past medium-term losers by as much as 74 basis points per month, which is

similar in magnitude to momentum profits in modern markets. Exposure to the market

factor cannot explain this outperformance. In addition, we find that the momentum effect is

small and insignificant during the pre-1893 period, but large and highly significant during the

post-1893 period. A placebo test using momentum returns from the London Stock Exchange

shows that the same empirical regularity is not observed in a market that did not undergo

a similar regulatory change.

Daniel and Moskowitz (2013) document that the momentum trade occasionally experi-

ences large crashes. This suggests that, whatever the mechanism, momentum profits could

compensate for an infrequently occurring risk factor. Based on this idea, they propose a

method to manage this extreme left-tail risk.4 Interestingly, in our Russian sample extend-

ing more than 40 years, we find that while momentum returns are somewhat negatively

skewed, extraordinary crashes like those that occurred in the U.S. are absent. Our evidence,

therefore, is less consistent with theories that attribute high average momentum profits to

3The fund industry existed in the UK in this period but invested almost exclusively in bonds.

4See also Barroso and Santa-Clara (2013), Chuang and Ho (2013), Huang (2013), and Lou and Polk(2013).

2

Page 4: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

compensation for bearing crash risk, and the idea that momentum trading is a destabilizing

force. From a practical perspective, the evidence also suggests that momentum strategies do

not necessarily require protection against left-tail risk.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews related literature

and develops the hypotheses. Section 3 describes the data and methodology. Section 4

establishes the results. Section 5 concludes.

2 Related Literature and Hypothesis Development

Momentum strategies buy past medium-term winners and sell past medium-term losers.

Motivated by the observation that mutual funds tend to buy stocks that have recently

performed well, Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) systematically investigate the profitability of

such strategies for U.S. common stocks. For each portfolio formation month t, they form

portfolios based on cumulative stock returns from month t − J to t − 1 and hold them for

K months. They examine strategies for J ranging from 3 to 12 months and K also ranging

from 3 to 12 months. Using data during the period from 1965 to 1989, they find that past

winners significantly outperform past losers for all horizons considered and by as much as

1.49% a month.

Unlike a number of other anomalies examined, Fama and French (1996) find that their

three-factor model cannot explain momentum profits. After controlling for the Fama and

French (1993) factors, to which it is negatively correlated, momentum yields monthly alphas

of 1.74%. This deepens the momentum puzzle. The inability of pre-existing asset pricing

models to explain momentum has led researchers to add it as an additional risk factor

(Carhart (1997)).

Momentum does not seem to be a spurious result of data mining as its effects are also

present when other basis assets are used. Rouwenhorst (1998) documents momentum in

developed markets stocks while Rouwenhorst (1999) finds evidence of momentum in emerging

3

Page 5: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

markets. Using a U.S. sample, Moskowitz and Grinblatt (1999) demonstrate that industry

momentum strategies are just as profitable as individual stock momentum strategies. Asness,

Moskowitz, and Pedersen (2013) show that momentum is also present in cross-country equity

index, currency, and bond futures, as well as in commodity futures.

There is an ongoing theoretical debate as to what causes momentum. Using a risk-based

framework, Berk, Green, and Naik (1999), Johnson (2002), and Sagi and Seasholes (2007)

contend that past winners are riskier so that momentum is due to time-varying expected

returns. On the other hand, a number of behavioral models based on well-documented psy-

chological evidence also yield momentum as an implication. Barberis, Shleifer, and Vishny

(1998), Hong and Stein (1999), and Grinblatt and Han (2005) propose investor underreac-

tion to news as an explanation of momentum. De Long et al. (1990), Daniel, Hirshleifer,

and Subrahmanyam (1998), and Barberis and Shleifer (2003) argue that momentum could

be the result of overreaction to information by market participants.

This paper focuses on the investor overconfidence theory of Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Sub-

rahmanyam (1998), the information-based theory of Hong and Stein (1999), and the insti-

tutional theory of Vayanos and Woolley (2013). The Vayanos-Woolley theory is based on

flows between institutional money managers. Flows are triggered by changes in fund man-

agers’ efficiency, which investors can infer from past performance. Momentum arises if flows

exhibit inertia, and because rational prices underreact to expected future flows. According

to this theory, since a delegated management structure is notably absent in our setting, the

momentum effect should be relatively weak.5

The Daniel-Hirshleifer-Subrahmanyam model assumes a representative investor who is

overconfident about the precision of his private signal. New public signals on average are

viewed as confirming the validity of the investor’s private signal, so public information trig-

gers further overreaction to a preceding private signal. This continuing overreaction causes

5This prediction is not unique to the institutional theory. The data snooping critique of the momentumeffect also predicts that there will be no momentum in this out-of-sample setting.

4

Page 6: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

momentum in security prices. According to this theory and the basic intuition that small,

less sophisticated investors are more likely to exhibit the overconfidence bias, the momen-

tum effect should be stronger during times when there is more market participation by these

investors. In our sample, the post-1893 period is such a time. The Russian law PSZ 3-

9741 enacted on June 8, 1893 removed all restrictions prohibiting futures dealings in stocks.6

As a result, a speculative fever swept across Imperial Russia in the fall of 1893. According

to Owen (1991), “instead of being confined, as in 1869, to the Hotel Demuth in Petersburg

and, in Moscow, the Chizhov Court and the apartment of a Georgian princess, [trading

activities] enveloped all the big hotels, as crowds of people who owned interest-bearing secu-

rities sold them to buy dividend-paying stocks whose values were soaring.” Taken together,

the overconfidence theory predicts that the momentum effect should be stronger during the

post-1893 period than during the pre-1893 period.

The prediction of the Daniel-Hirshleifer-Subrahmanyam model stands in contrast to the

prediction of the Hong-Stein model. In the Hong-Stein model, two groups of boundedly

rational agents interact when information diffuses gradually across the population. Prices

underreact in the short run so momentum trading is profitable. As this theory argues that the

momentum effect is caused by the slow diffusion of information, it predicts that momentum

should be weaker during the post-1893 period than during the pre-1893 period. This is

because the increased public interest in the stock market caused by PSZ 3-9741 and general

technological progress in communication should have allowed information to flow faster in

the post-1893 period.

The paper closest to ours is Chui, Titman, and Wei (2003). They focus on intra-industry

momentum and on the real estate investment trust (REIT) industry in the U.S. They argue

that the REIT industry experienced a structural change in 1990. They use this identification

to test opposite predictions from the overconfidence theory and the information-based theory.

6These dealings are defined as any purchase of stock in the absence of cash and with delivery at a certaintime in the future.

5

Page 7: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

For chronological reasons, they do not comment on Vayanos and Woolley (2013). Our dataset

is independent of the CRSP dataset that is used by Chui, Titman, and Wei (2003) as well

as most other papers in this literature. Finally, their identification of the year 1990 is based

on two different factors: 1) the financial difficulties of banks and savings and loans in the

late 1980s and early 1990s that substantially reduced the amount of debt that was available

to finance commercial real estate; and 2) the 1993 legislation that made it easier for pension

funds to hold REITs in their portfolios.

Our paper is also part of an emerging literature on documenting momentum in historical

equity markets. Chabot, Ghysels, and Jagannathan (2009) document momentum in the U.K.

market over the period from 1866 to 1907. Geczy and Samonov (2013) compile a database

of U.S. stock returns over the period from 1801 to 2012. They find that momentum is

consistently profitable over this expansive period of time. Our current analysis not only

supports these authors’ findings that momentum is ubiquitous in pre-World War I markets,

but also allows a comparative analysis with respect to international correlation of momentum

returns, and documentation of the strategy’s frequency of crashes over long periods.

3 Data and Methodology

The St. Petersburg Exchange was established in the early 1800’s, about a hundred years after

the founding of the City of St. Petersburg. From 1732 to 1918, St. Petersburg was the capital

of the Russian Empire. The first stocks traded on the St. Petersburg Stock Exchange in

the early 1830s.7 As the Russian economy developed, the numbers of corporations with

shares traded on the St. Petersburg Stock Exchange grew rapidly. By 1914, more than two

hundred Russian corporations had their shares listed.8 Market participants mostly consisted

of ruling elites, company insiders, and wealthy merchants. Compared to a modern stock

7See Lizunov (2004).

8See Owen (1991). The St. Petersburg Stock Exchange closed down due to World War I in July 1914. Itreopened for two months in 1917 before it closed down again for 74 years after the Revolution of 1917.

6

Page 8: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

market, delegated managers such as mutual funds were notably absent.9

Our dataset of end-of-month stock prices for all companies listed on the St. Petersburg

Stock Exchange over the period from January 1865 to July 1914 was hand-collected from five

different sources. From January 1865 to December 1890, from January 1893 to December

1893, and from January 1897 to December 1904, end-of-month prices are from the Yearbook

of the Finance Ministry. From January 1891 to November 1892, end-of-month prices are

from the Bulletin of the Finance, the Industries and Trade. For the month of December

1892, end-of-month stock prices are from the Stock Exchange Newsletter. From January

1894 to December 1896, from January 1905 to December 1911, and from January 1914 to

July 1914, end-of-month stock prices are from the Commercial and Industrial Newspaper.

Finally, from January 1912 to December 1913, end-of-month stock prices are directly from

the St. Petersburg Stock Exchange. The data are available for download on the website of

the International Center for Finance at the Yale School of Management.

The methodology we used to process the raw data closely follows Goetzmann, Ibbotson,

and Peng (2001). The month-end prices were obtained by searching the end-of-month issues

for the last transaction price for each stock that month. When no transaction took place in

the last week, the latest bid and ask prices were averaged. In total, we collected 43,736 end-

of-month stock prices for 598 companies. From these, we calculated 38,090 monthly returns

for 543 firms. There were three instances of 50% price drops and we assumed they represent

stock splits.10 We only computed the returns when two adjacent prices are available, in

a similar manner as CRSP. The number of firms in the universe averaged 64 firms. It

reached a high point in April 1912 with 206 listed firms.11 The fact that the number of firms

9According to Abramov and Akshentceva (2014), the first mutual funds did not appear in Russia until1997. Over some of the period of our study, investment funds in London traded in Russian securities, raisingthe possibility of institutional influence via international channels. Virtually all British funds, however, heldfixed income securities. See, e.g., Goetzmann and Ukhov (2006) for details.

10Assuming otherwise does not change our results.

11In Goetzmann, Ibbotson, and Peng’s (2001) old NYSE dataset, the number of firms peaked at 114 inMay 1883.

7

Page 9: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

concurrently listed peaked at under 210, while the total number of firms in the database

exceeded 540 indicates that, not only did firms appear during the sample period, they also

disappeared.

We were able to obtain dividend data for the period from 1885 to 1915 from the same

sources. In total, we have 4,951 annual dividend payment observations for 478 companies.

Since we do not know whether these publications always reported dividends for all stocks

listed on the St. Petersburg Stock Exchange, we do not know whether exclusions of dividends

meant that they were not paid, or whether we failed to find them. The number of stocks

for which we have an unbroken series of annual dividend payment observations is small. In

analysis that follows, we assume that the dividends were paid at year-end, but changing this

assumption does not change our results.

We control for market risk exposure in our asset pricing tests. Since we are limited by

the fact that we lack data on shares outstanding, we use a simple procedure to construct a

price-weighted market index. For each month in our sample, we calculate monthly returns

for all stocks that trade in two consecutive months. We weight these returns by the price at

the beginning of the two months. The return of the price-weighted index over period t, rmt ,

is defined as

rmt =N∑i=1

(rit · wit) =

N∑i=1

(P it + Di

t

P it−1

·P it−1∑N

j=1 Pjt−1

) =

∑Ni=1(P

it + Di

t)∑Nj=1 P

jt−1

. (1)

Here rit represents the return of security i over the period t and wit represents the weight of

security i over period t, which is equal to P it−1/

∑Nj=1 P

jt−1 since the index is price-weighted.

Using a price-weighted index offers the benefit that its return closely approximates return to

a “buy and hold” portfolio over the period, and as such, is not sensitive to bid-ask bounce

bias (Canina et al. (1998)).

8

Page 10: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

4 Results

Figure 1 shows the cumulative return of the price-weighted St. Petersburg Stock Ex-

change (SPSE) index shown on a log scale. Table 1 shows summary statistics for the

underlying monthly return of the index for the entire period from February 1865 to July

1914 and for each decade of the period. For comparison, we also calculate summary statis-

tics for the NYSE index constructed by Goetzmann, Ibbotson, and Peng (2001) over the

same sample period.

Over the entire period, the annual geometric return of the SPSE index is 5.78%. There

are periods of higher and lower growth. The annual geometric return is 9.7% in the second

half of the 1860s and 1.85% in the 1900s. The long-term mean is slightly below the 5.82%

annual growth experienced by the NYSE index over the same period. However, this long-

term mean is not a good estimate of the equity premium provided by the St. Petersburg

stock market because we know that, ex post, buy-and-hold investors lost 100% of their

investments after the Revolution of 1917. Finally, we observe that the volatility of the index

varies considerably. It is 11.03% over the entire sample period. It has a high of 17.06% in

the 1860s and a low of 6.98% in the 1880s.

4.1 Momentum Profits

We investigate the profitability of momentum strategies in this no-delegated-management

setting. The prediction based on Vayanos and Woolley’s (2013) institutional theory is that

the momentum effect should be relatively weak in the St. Petersburg stock market. Put

differently, we ask whether the existence of a delegated management structure is a necessary

condition for price continuation patterns. This investigation is also of interest from the point

of view that previously uncovered momentum profits could be a result of data snooping.

We follow Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) in forming the momentum strategies. The

portfolios are formed based on J-month lagged returns and held for K months. The stocks

9

Page 11: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

are ranked in ascending order on the basis of the lagged returns. An equally weighted

portfolio of stocks in the lowest past return tercile is the sell portfolio and an equally weighted

portfolio of the stocks in the highest return tercile is the buy portfolio. Table 2 presents

the average monthly returns of these portfolios for J and K that vary from a quarter to a

year. To ensure that our results are robust to the effect of non-synchronous trading and the

bid-ask bounce, which can be more important in our setting than in modern markets, we

also produce results where we skip the most recent month in the portfolio formation period.

Interestingly, in our Russian sample momentum strategies are consistently profitable

across different values of J and K, with the exception of the case where (J,K) = (3, 3).

Similar to the results originally provided by Jegadeesh and Titman (1993), the most suc-

cessful zero-cost strategy selects stocks based on their returns over the previous 12 months

and then holds the portfolio for 3 months. As shown in Panel A, this strategy yields 68

basis points per month when there is not a lag between the portfolio formation period and

the holding period; as shown in Panel B, momentum yields 77 basis points per month when

there is a one-month lag between the formation period and the holding period. In general,

the returns are higher when there is a lag between the formation period and the holding

period (Panel B) than when the formation period and the holding period are contiguous

(Panel A).

The natural question to ask next is whether exposure to the market factor can explain

the observed momentum profits.12 Table 3 shows that it is unlikely. It presents the betas

of the momentum strategies with respect to the market portfolio represented by the price-

weighted SPSE index. The betas are positive but low across different values of J and K.

The range is from 0.04 to 0.17. It is easy to see with back-of-the-envelope calculations that

exposure to the market factor cannot explain the magnitude of the momentum profits. Our

evidence, therefore, suggests that institutional frictions can at most be a partial explanation

12Unfortunately, we do not have the data to construct the small-minus-big (SMB) and high-minus-low(HML) factors of Fama and French’s (1993) three factor model.

10

Page 12: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

of momentum.

Following the momentum literature, we focus the rest of the paper on the momentum

strategy where (J,K) = (6, 6) and the most recent month in the portfolio formation period is

skipped. The results for this strategy are representative of the results for the other strategies

and are available upon request. Figure 2 plots the cumulative returns of the buy portfolio and

the sell portfolio of this strategy together with the cumulative return of the price-weighted

SPSE index.

4.2 The Effects of a Regulatory Change

The government of Imperial Russia enacted the law PSZ 3-9741 in June 8, 1893. It removed

all restrictions prohibiting futures dealings in stocks. We presume that those restrictions were

more binding for small and less sophisticated investors. As a result, market participation by

those who are more likely to be overconfident increased after the law. If the momentum effect

is caused by investor overconfidence as in Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998),

then momentum profits should be higher during the post-1893 period than during the pre-

1893 period. On the other hand, the information-based theory of momentum proposed by

Hong and Stein (1999) would predict that the momentum effect should be stronger in the

earlier period, when market participation was more narrow and information flow was slower.

To confirm the argument that market participation by less sophisticated investors in-

creased after the enactment of PSZ 3-9741, we begin our analysis by looking at changes in

aggregate liquidity. Less sophisticated investors tend to engage in noise trading. In Glosten

and Milgrom’s (1985) model, a risk-neutral market maker sets a bid-ask spread allowing

expected noise-trading profits to offset expected informed-trading losses. When they believe

they face a pool of more informed traders, they react by increasing the bid-ask spread. Con-

sistent with this prediction, both Lee, Mucklow, and Ready (1993) and Greene and Smart

(1999) find a positive link between noise trading and liquidity. Because we lack detailed

transaction data, we use a liquidity measure that rely on the incidence of observed zero

11

Page 13: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

monthly returns.13 Specifically, we measure illiquidity using the price-weighted proportion

of zero monthly stock returns.

Table 4 reports the results from our analysis on the liquidity effects of PSZ 3-9741. It

shows averages for the full sample and the periods before and after June 1893, as well as

differences in means between the two subsamples. Over the full sample, the average inci-

dence of zero returns is 14% for all stocks.14 We also divide each cross-section using stock

price, which we use throughout this paper as a proxy for size, to investigate cross-sectional

heterogeneity. Consistent with the idea that liquidity increases with size, the average in-

cidence of zero returns is 17% for low price stocks, and 13% for high price stocks. More

important, we see from the last row that liquidity improved substantially and significantly

after the enactment of PSZ 3-9741, and that the improvement is larger among small stocks,

which small investors tend to favor. The evidence thus supports the argument that average

investor sophistication decreased after PSZ 3-9741.

Next, we compare momentum profits before and after PSZ 3-9741 to differentiate the

overconfidence theory and the information diffusion theory. Panel A of Table 5 shows the

first set of results. In the first row, we see that the winners-minus-losers momentum strategy

generates small and statistically insignificant profits of 5 basis points per month during the

period from February 1865 to May 1893. In contrast, the same momentum strategy delivers

large and highly significant profits of 82 basis points per month during the period from June

1893 to July 1914. The difference in average momentum profits between the pre-1893 period

and the post-1893 period is 77 basis points per month and significant at the 1% level. It

is also interesting to note that the difference is contributed by both higher returns from

the winners portfolio (89 basis points vs. 63 basis points) and lower returns from the loser

portfolio (7 basis points vs. 53 basis points) in the later period.

13See Lesmond, Ogden, and Trzcinka (1999) for the theoretical treatment and Bekaert, Harvey, andLundblad (2007) for an application in emerging markets.

14Bekaert, Harvey, and Lundblad (2007) report average incidence of zero daily returns that range from8% for Korea to 52% for Colombia.

12

Page 14: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Panel B of Table 5 shows the results of a placebo test that we conduct using momentum

returns from Britain during the period from August 1866 to December 1892.15 Britain did

not undergo a similar regulatory regime change as Russia did in 1893, so we should not

detect significant difference in average momentum returns between the pre-1893 period and

the post-1893 period in Britain. We see that is indeed the case - the difference is 2 basis

points and not statistically significant. Taken together, our results are more consistent with

the overconfidence explanation to momentum.

4.3 Investigating Momentum Crashes

Daniel and Moskowitz (2013) document that, in the U.S. equity market over the period

from January 1927 to March 2013, the momentum trade on many occasions experiences

large crashes. These crashes are driven by the infrequent yet large-scale reversals of past

losers. Specifically, Table 2 of their paper shows that the 15 worst monthly momentum

returns range from -24.04% in January 1974 to -74.36% in August 1932. This raises the

possibility that peso problems could explain momentum, i.e., high average momentum profits

are compensation for bearing momentum crash risk (Rietz (1988); Burnside et al. (2010)).

We investigate such peso events in our sample. For a deeper understanding of momentum

and for risk management, it is also important to know more about the frequency as well as

the magnitude of the crashes.

Table 6 presents higher-order statistics of the momentum strategies. Panels A and B

present skewness and kurtosis. The momentum returns are in general negatively skewed. The

skewness estimates average -0.39 and are an order of magnitude smaller than the skewness

estimate of -4.7 reported by Daniel and Moskowitz (2013) for momentum in the U.S. stock

market. In addition, all of the momentum strategies have leptokurtic returns. The kurtosis

ranges from 2.22 to 4.95.

We target extreme outcomes of the return distributions. Panel C shows the minimum,

15We thank Ben Chabot for providing this data.

13

Page 15: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

or most negative momentum return observations and Panel D shows the maximum return

observations. The minimum returns are similar in magnitude to the maximum returns. More

important, there is no evidence of momentum crashes like those documented by Daniel and

Moskowitz (2013) for the modern U.S. stock market. The minimum ranges from -8% to

-16% while the maximum ranges from 8% to 15%. These results stand in stark contrast to

those from Daniel and Moskowitz (2013) and suggest that crashes may not be an inherent

feature of the momentum trade. We leave it for future researchers to investigate whether

momentum crashes are caused by modern features such as delegated management.

4.4 Characteristics of Momentum Strategies

The literature on momentum investing has also documented that momentum profits reverse

in the long run. For example, Jegadeesh and Titman (2001) document that, while momentum

portfolios yield significantly positive returns during the first 12 months following the portfolio

formation period, their cumulative returns in months 12 to 60 are negative.16 They argue

that this evidence is consistent with behavioral theories of momentum and reversal, but is

inconsistent with the risk-based theory proposed by Conrad and Kaul (1998).

We run a similar experiment where we look at the performance of the momentum strategy

in event time. Specifically, we investigate the average return on buying past winners and

selling past losers in the hth month after the strategy is put into place. Table 7 gives the

results in the first 36 months after portfolio formation.17 The average momentum returns

are uniformly positive in the first 12 months after portfolio formation, after which time they

turn negative. In untabulated results, we find some indication of time variation in the risk

exposure of the event time portfolios, but it is not sufficient to explain the profits. Even

though the profits turn negative in the second year after portfolio formation, they are not

always statistically significant. These results are strikingly similar to the results of Jegadeesh

16See also Rouwenhorst (1998).

17Due to the limitations of our historical dataset, we do not look beyond month 36.

14

Page 16: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

and Titman (1993), Rouwenhorst (1998), and Jegadeesh and Titman (2001).

Figure 3 presents cumulative momentum returns over a 36-month period after portfolio

formation. It reveals a substantial reversal of profits in the second and third years. Cu-

mulative momentum profits increase monotonically until they reach about 6% at the end of

month 12. Over the next 24 months, as much as half of those profits are reversed.

Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) measure momentum profits on size-based subsamples to

examine whether the profitability of the strategy is confined to any particular subsample

of stocks. Later researchers generally find that momentum profits decrease with firm size,

consistent with predictions from behavioral theories. The idea is that information tends to

be more uncertain and diffuse more slowly for small stocks (Hong, Lim, and Stein (2000);

Zhang (2006)). Again, we use price to proxy for size and present the average returns of the

momentum portfolios for two price-based subsamples in Table 8. We find that momentum

profits in the high-price subsample are all lower and less statistically significant than in the

low-price subsample. For the strategy where (J,K) = (12, 3), average return is 1% with

a t-statistic of 5.51 in the low-price subsample and 0.41% with a t-statistic of 2.86 in the

high-price subsample.

Jegadeesh and Titman (1993) find that the momentum strategy incurs significant losses

in January but achieves positive abnormal returns in each of the other months. Grinblatt

and Moskowitz (2004) study this seasonality carefully and attribute it to tax-loss selling.

Since the Russian government did not tax capital gains, we can perform a placebo test for

their hypothesis using our sample. Table 9 reports the average returns of the momentum

strategy in each month of the year. Consistent with the tax-loss selling hypothesis, we do

not find a significant seasonal effect for momentum in Russia.18 The momentum strategy

has statistically insignificant losses in January. The F -statistics show that differences in

momentum returns across the months are not statistically significant.

18Chabot, Ghysels, and Jagannathan (2009) also do not find a seasonal effect in momentum profits usinga sample of British stocks from the Victorian era, during which capital gains were also not taxed.

15

Page 17: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Finally, Table 10 reports a robustness check to make sure that our results are not due to

our treatment of missing data. Firms could drop out of the universe due to bankruptcy and

the worst case scenario is that equity investors get nothing. We ask whether assuming a -

100% return for exit firms would change our results. Our prior is that this grossly understates

the actual returns and introduce additional noise into the estimation process. This largely

bears out in the data. The average returns of the buy-minus-sell momentum portfolios are

roughly the same under the alternative treatment of exit firms. The t-statistics are generally

lower, but still significant at the conventional levels.

5 Conclusion

In this paper, we demonstrate momentum profitability in a novel, untouched sample. The

setting of our experiment - 19th century St. Petersburg Stock Exchange - has the unique

features that there was not a delegated management structure and that an exogenous shock

to market composition took place. We try to distinguish between three theories of mo-

mentum that have received much attention in the academic literature: the overconfidence

theory of Daniel, Hirshleifer, and Subrahmanyam (1998), the information-based theory of

Hong and Stein (1999), and the institutional theory of Vayanos and Woolley (2013). Our

evidence is most supportive of the behavioral theory that momentum is caused by investor

overconfidence.

16

Page 18: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

References

Abramov, A., and K. Akshentceva, 2014, The Determinants of Mutual Funds Performancein Russia, Working paper .

Asness, Clifford S., Tobias J. Moskowitz, and Lasse Heje Pedersen, 2013, Value and Momen-tum Everywhere, Journal of Finance 68, 929–985.

Barberis, Nicholas, and Andrei Shleifer, 2003, Style investing, Journal of Financial Eco-nomics 68, 161–199.

Barberis, Nicholas, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert Vishny, 1998, A model of investor sentiment,Journal of Financial Economics 49, 307–343.

Barroso, Pedro, and Pedro Santa-Clara, 2013, Momentum has its moments, Working paper.

Bekaert, Geert, Campbell R. Harvey, and Christian Lundblad, 2007, Liquidity and expectedreturns: Lessons from emerging markets, Review of Financial Studies 20, 1783–1831.

Berk, Jonathan B., Richard C. Green, and Vasant Naik, 1999, Optimal Investment, GrowthOptions, and Security Returns, Journal of Finance LIV, 1553–1607.

Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, Isaac Kleshchelski, and Sergio Rebelo, 2010, Do PesoProblems Explain the Returns to the Carry Trade?, Review of Financial Studies 24, 853–891.

Canina, Linda, Roni Michaely, Richard Thaler, and Kent Womack, 1998, Caveat Com-pounder: A Warning about Using the Daily CRSP Equal-Weighted Index to ComputeLong-Run Excess Returns, Journal of Finance LIII, 403–416.

Carhart, Mark M., 1997, On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance, Journal of FinanceLII, 57–82.

Chabot, Benjamin, Eric Ghysels, and Ravi Jagannathan, 2009, Momentum Cycles and Lim-its to Arbitrage Evidence from Victorian England and Post-Depression US Stocks Markets,Working paper .

Chuang, Hongwei, and Hwai-Chung Ho, 2013, Implied Price Risk and Momentum Strategy,Review of Finance 18, 591–622.

Chui, Andy C.W., Sheridan Titman, and K.C. John Wei, 2003, Intra-industry momentum:the case of REITs, Journal of Financial Markets 6, 363–387.

Conrad, Jennifer, and Gautam Kaul, 1998, An Anatomy of Trading Strategies, Review ofFinancial Studies 11, 489–519.

Daniel, Kent, David Hirshleifer, and Avanidhar Subrahmanyam, 1998, Investor Psychologyand Security Market Under- and Overreactions, Journal of Finance LIII, 1839–1885.

17

Page 19: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Daniel, Kent, and Tobias Moskowitz, 2013, Momentum Crashes, Working paper .

De Long, J. Bradford, Andrei Shleifer, Lawrence H. Summers, and Robert J. Waldmann,1990, Positive Feedback Investment Strategies and Destabilizing Rational Speculation,Journal of Finance XLV, 379–395.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1993, Common risk factors in the returns onstocks and bonds, Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3–56.

Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1996, Multifactor Explanations of Asset PricingAnomalies, Journal of Finance LI, 55–84.

Geczy, Christopher, and Mikhail Samonov, 2013, 212 Years of Price Momentum (The World’sLongest Backtest: 1801-2012), Working paper .

Glosten, Lawrence R., and Paul R. Milgrom, 1985, Bid, ask and transaction prices in aspecialist market with heterogeneously informed traders, Journal of Financial Economics14, 71–100.

Goetzmann, William N., Roger G. Ibbotson, and Liang Peng, 2001, A new historical databasefor the NYSE 1815 to 1925: Performance and predictability, Journal of Financial Markets4, 1–32.

Goetzmann, William N., and Andrey D. Ukhov, 2006, British Investment Overseas 1870-1913: A Modern Portfolio Theory Approach, Review of Finance 10, 261–300.

Greene, Jason, and Scott Smart, 1999, Liquidity Provision and Noise Trading: Evidencefrom the ”Investment Dartboard” Column, Journal of Finance 54, 1885–1899.

Grinblatt, Mark, and Bing Han, 2005, Prospect theory, mental accounting, and momentum,Journal of Financial Economics 78, 311–339.

Grinblatt, Mark, and Tobias J. Moskowitz, 2004, Predicting stock price movements frompast returns: the role of consistency and tax-loss selling, Journal of Financial Economics71, 541–579.

Hong, Harrison, Terence Lim, and Jeremy C Stein, 2000, Bad News Travels Slowly: Size,Analyst Coverage, and the Profitability of Momentum Strategies, Journal of Finance LV,265–295.

Hong, Harrison, and Jeremy C. Stein, 1999, A Unified Theory of Underreaction, MomentumTrading, and Overreaction in Asset Markets, Journal of Finance LIV, 2143–2184.

Huang, Simon, 2013, The Momentum Gap and Return Predictability, Working paper .

Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman, 1993, Returns to Buying Winners and SellingLosers: Implications for Stock Market Efficiency, Journal of Finance XLVIII, 65–91.

Jegadeesh, Narasimhan, and Sheridan Titman, 2001, Profitability of Momentum Strategies:An Evaluation of Alternative Explanations, Journal of Finance LVI, 699–720.

18

Page 20: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Johnson, Timothy C., 2002, Rational Momentum Effects, Journal of Finance LVII, 585–608.

Lee, Charles M. C., Belinda Mucklow, and Mark J. Ready, 1993, Spreads, Depths, and theImpact of Earnings Information: An Intraday Analysis, Review of Financial Studies 6,345–374.

Lesmond, David A., Joseph P. Ogden, and Charles A. Trzcinka, 1999, A New Estimate ofTransaction Costs, Review of Financial Studies 12, 1113–1141.

Lizunov, P.V., 2004, Sankt-Peterburgskaia birzha i rossiiskii rinok tsennikh bumag, 1703-1917 (Unknown, St. Petersburg).

Lou, Dong, 2012, A Flow-Based Explanation for Return Predictability, Review of FinancialStudies 25, 3457–3489.

Lou, Dong, and Christopher Polk, 2013, Comomentum: Inferring Arbitrage Activity fromReturn Correlations, Working paper .

Moskowitz, Tobias J., and Mark Grinblatt, 1999, Do Industries Explain Momentum ?, Jour-nal of Finance LIV, 1249–1290.

Owen, Thomas C., 1991, The corporation under Russian law, 1800-1917: A study in tsaristeconomic policy (Cambridge University Press, Baton Rouge, LA).

Rietz, Thomas A., 1988, The Equity Risk Premium: A Solution, Journal of Monetary Eco-nomics 22, 117–131.

Rouwenhorst, K. Geert, 1998, International Momentum Strategies, Journal of Finance LIII,267–284.

Rouwenhorst, K. Geert, 1999, Local Return Factors and Turnover in Emerging Stock Mar-kets, Journal of Finance LIV, 1439–1464.

Sagi, Jacob S., and Mark S. Seasholes, 2007, Firm-specific attributes and the cross-sectionof momentum, Journal of Financial Economics 84, 389–434.

Vayanos, Dimitri, and Paul Woolley, 2013, An Institutional Theory of Momentum and Re-versal, Review of Financial Studies 26, 1087–1145.

Zhang, X. Frank, 2006, Information Uncertainty and Stock Returns, Journal of FinanceLXI, 105–137.

19

Page 21: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Figure 1: The Price-Weighted SPSE IndexThis figure shows the cumulative return of the price-weighted SPSE index. The sample period is January1865 to July 1914.

20

Page 22: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Figure 2: Momentum Performance in Imperial RussiaThe momentum portfolios are formed based on J-month lagged returns and held for K months. The stocksare ranked in ascending order on the basis of the lagged returns and an equally weighted portfolio of stocksin the lowest past return tercile is the sell portfolio and an equally weighted portfolio of the stocks in thehighest return tercile is the buy portfolio. This figure shows the cumulative returns of the price-weightedSPSE index, as well as the buy portfolio and the sell portfolio where (J,K) = (6, 6). The sample period isJanuary 1865 to July 1914.

21

Page 23: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Figure 3: Cumulative Momentum Returns in Event TimeThe momentum portfolios are formed based on 6-month lagged returns. The stocks are ranked in ascendingorder on the basis of the lagged returns and an equally weighted portfolio of stocks in the lowest past returntercile is the sell portfolio and an equally weighted portfolio of the stocks in the highest return tercile is thebuy portfolio. This figure shows the average cumulative return to the zero-cost, buy minus sell, portfolio ineach month following the formation period. The sample period is January 1865 to July 1914.

22

Page 24: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Table 1: Summary StatisticsThis table presents summary statistics for the monthly return of the price-weighted SPSE index. The meanreturns and standard deviation are in percent and annualized. The sample period is January 1865 to July1914.

23

Page 25: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Table 2: Returns of Momentum Portfolios in Imperial RussiaThe momentum portfolios are formed based on J-month lagged returns and held for K months. The stocksare ranked in ascending order on the basis of the lagged returns and an equally weighted portfolio of stocks inthe lowest past return tercile is the sell portfolio and an equally weighted portfolio of the stocks in the highestreturn tercile is the buy portfolio. The average monthly returns of these portfolios are presented in this table.The values of J and K for the different strategies are indicated in the first column and row, respectively. Themomentum portfolios in Panel A are formed using returns over the entire portfolio formation period whilethe momentum portfolios in Panel B skip the most recent month in the formation period. t-statistics are inparentheses. The sample period is January 1865 to July 1914.

24

Page 26: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Table 3: Betas of Momentum PortfoliosThe momentum portfolios are formed based on J-month lagged returns and held for K months. The stocksare ranked in ascending order on the basis of the lagged returns and an equally weighted portfolio of stocksin the lowest past return tercile is the sell portfolio and an equally weighted portfolio of the stocks inthe highest return tercile is the buy portfolio. The most recent month in the portfolio formation period isskipped. This table presents the betas of the zero-cost, buy minus sell, portfolios with respect to the marketportfolio represented by the price-weighted SPSE index. The values of J and K for the different strategiesare indicated in the first column and row, respectively. The sample period is January 1865 to July 1914.

25

Page 27: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Table 4: The Effects of PSZ 3-9741 on IlliquidityIn the spirit of Bekaert, Harvey, and Lundblad (2007), the illiquidity measure is the price-weighted proportionof zero monthly stock returns. This table presents tests of the difference in illiquidity before and after PSZ3-9741, a Russian law dated June 8, 1893 that removed all restrictions prohibiting futures dealings in stocks.These dealings are defined as any purchase of stock in the absence of cash and with delivery at a certaintime in the future. t-statistics are in parentheses.

26

Page 28: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Table 5: The Effects of PSZ 3-9741 on Momentum ReturnsThe momentum portfolios are formed based on 6-month lagged returns and held for 6 months. The stocks areranked in ascending order on the basis of the lagged returns and an equally weighted portfolio of stocks in thelowest past return tercile is the losers portfolio and an equally weighted portfolio of the stocks in the highestreturn tercile is the winners portfolio. This table presents tests of the difference in average momentum returnsbefore and after PSZ 3-9741, a Russian law dated June 8, 1893 that removed all restrictions prohibitingfutures dealings in stocks. These dealings are defined as any purchase of stock in the absence of cash andwith delivery at a certain time in the future. The momentum portfolios in Panel A are formed using stockslisted on the St. Petersburg Stock Exchange from February 1865 to July 1914. The momentum portfolios inPanel B are formed using stocks listed on the London Stock Exchange from August 1866 to December 1907.t-statistics are in parentheses.

27

Page 29: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Table 6: Higher-Order Statistics of Momentum PortfoliosThe momentum portfolios are formed based on J-month lagged returns and held for K months. The stocksare ranked in ascending order on the basis of the lagged returns and an equally weighted portfolio of stocksin the lowest past return tercile is the sell portfolio and an equally weighted portfolio of the stocks in thehighest return tercile is the buy portfolio. This table presents the higher-order statistics of the zero-cost, buyminus sell, portfolios. The values of J and K for the different strategies are indicated in the first column androw, respectively. Panel A and Panel B present the third and fourth moments, respectively. Panel C presentsthe smallest observed monthly returns. Panel D presents the largest observed monthly returns. The sampleperiod is January 1865 to July 1914.

28

Page 30: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Table 7: Momentum Returns in Event TimeThe momentum portfolios are formed based on 6-month lagged returns. The stocks are ranked in ascendingorder on the basis of the lagged returns and an equally weighted portfolio of stocks in the lowest past returntercile is the sell portfolio and an equally weighted portfolio of the stocks in the highest return tercile is thebuy portfolio. This table presents the average returns of the zero-cost, buy minus sell, portfolio in each monthfollowing the formation period. h is the month after portfolio formation. The sample period is January 1865to July 1914.

29

Page 31: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Table 8: Returns of Price-Based Momentum PortfoliosThe momentum portfolios are formed based on J-month lagged returns and held for K months. The stocksare ranked in ascending order on the basis of the lagged returns and an equally weighted portfolio of stocks inthe lowest past return tercile is the sell portfolio and an equally weighted portfolio of the stocks in the highestreturn tercile is the buy portfolio. The average monthly returns of these portfolios, formed using price-basedsubsamples of stocks, are presented here. The values of J and K for the different strategies are indicated inthe first column and row, respectively. Panel A and Panel B present, respectively, the momentum portfoliosformed using the low price subsample and the high price subsample. t-statistics are in parentheses. Thesample period is January 1865 to July 1914.

30

Page 32: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Table 9: Momentum Returns by Calendar MonthsThe momentum portfolios are formed based on 6-month lagged returns and held for 6 months. The stocksare ranked in ascending order on the basis of the lagged returns and an equally weighted portfolio of stocksin the lowest past return tercile is the losers portfolio and an equally weighted portfolio of the stocks inthe highest return tercile is the winners portfolio. This table presents the average returns of the zero-cost,winners-minus-losers, portfolio by calendar months. t-statistics are in parentheses. p-values for the F -testthat the returns are jointly equal in all calendar months are in brackets. The sample period is January 1865to July 1914.

31

Page 33: Momentum in Imperial Russia - Federal Reserve …...Momentum in Imperial Russia William Goetzmann william.goetzmann@yale.edu Simon Huang simon@smu.edu September 23, 2015 Abstract Some

Table 10: Sensitivity to Treatment of Exit FirmsThe momentum portfolios are formed based on J-month lagged returns and held for K months. The stocksare ranked in ascending order on the basis of the lagged returns and an equally weighted portfolio of stocksin the lowest past return tercile is the sell portfolio and an equally weighted portfolio of the stocks in thehighest return tercile is the buy portfolio. The average monthly returns of these portfolios are presented inthis table. The values of J and K for the different strategies are indicated in the first column and row,respectively. The results in Panel A are presented earlier and do not assume exit firms have -100% return.The results presented in Panel B assume exit firms have -100% return. t-statistics are in parentheses. Thesample period is January 1865 to July 1914.

32